Monetary policy in a low inflation environment.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr.
It's a pleasure to be here today and to have this opportunity
to comment on conducting monetary policy in a low inflation environment.
I've been at the Fed for more than thirty-two years and have had
the privilege of either advising monetary policymakers or being a
policymaker myself throughout my career. It has been quite a ride. For
much of this period the Fed was struggling either to prevent inflation
from rising further or to bring it down. As you know, over the last
several years we have succeeded in reducing the inflation rate to about
1 1/2 percent as measured by the core personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) price index--today's favored inflation index--and in
stabilizing the rate at that level. In the parlance of the day, we have
finally attained "price stability," meaning both low actual
inflation and the credible expectation in the minds of financial market
participants and the general public that it will persist, which together
constitute the monetary policy equivalent of finding the Holy Grail.
In my brief remarks I want to do four things. First, I will
compactly review several key aspects of the evolution of monetary policy
over the last thirty years. To appreciate fully the nature of the
challenge that lies ahead, it is essential to understand how price
stability was lost in the 1970s and regained in the '80s and
'90s. Second, I will try to convey the essence of the current
strategy of Fed monetary policy. I'll then close with a brief
discussion of the challenges monetary policymakers face in today's
low inflation environment, as I see them, and a pitch for explicit
inflation targeting as a means of preserving the substantial improvement
in the effectiveness of monetary policy during the Volcker-Greenspan
years. As usual, these views are my own and don't necessarily
reflect those of my Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) colleagues.
Also as usual, my views have been strongly influenced by discussions
with, and the writings of, my longtime Richmond Fed colleague Marvin
Goodfriend--in particular a preliminary version of a paper he will
deliver at a National Bureau of Economic Research conference on
inflation targeting later this month. He is not necessarily responsible,
however, for anything I say here today.
1. HOW PRICE STABILITY WAS LOST AND REGAINED
It is probably fair to say that, after periods of moderate
inflation in the 1950s, the economy returned to virtual price stability
in the early 1960s. The core CPI inflation rate fluctuated in a narrow
1.0 to 1.6 percent range between 1960 and 1965. Subsequently, as you all
know, it increased steadily to double-digit levels in the mid-1970s and
again in the late '70s.
This extraordinary and debilitating increase in inflation has been
attributed, in whole or in part, to many things: the two oil price
shocks in the '70s, excess demand associated with the Vietnam War buildup and the Great Society social programs, the ineffectiveness of
the Nixon Administration's price control program and the Ford
Administration's "Whip Inflation Now" program, and even
the failure of anchovy harvests off the coast of South America. Both
theory and historical evidence, however, indicate that inflationary
monetary policy was the central culprit.
The failure of monetary policy to contain inflation in this period
can be approached from several directions. Economists of a monetarist persuasion argue that persistently above-target money supply growth, and
the practice of adjusting the money supply target's base up each
year to accommodate the preceding year's upside miss, was the
principal operational deficiency. Currently, the more mainstream view
focuses on the failure of the Fed's short-run interest rate policy
to counter the rise of inflationary pressures promptly during business
expansions. The 1970s and early 1980s are sometimes referred to as the
period of "go-stop" monetary policy. Concerned about the
potential impact of policy tightening on employment and production, the
Fed would wait until a broad public consensus emerged that inflation was
a serious problem before acting decisively to contain it. By then,
however, it was generally too late to bring inflation down via tighter
monetary policy without at the same time touching off a recession. T he
cycles surrounding the 1980 and 1981-82 recessions illustrate this
pattern especially well.
More fundamentally, however, it is not an exaggeration to say that
Fed monetary policy lost all or most of its credibility as an effective
force against inflation in this period. As inflation began to rise,
financial markets and the public--even in the early stages of
expansions--quickly revised their inflation expectations upward. This
reinforced the upward pressure on current inflation, pushed up long-term
interest rates, and in general helped foster the macroeconomic malaise
described by the term stagflation.
Perhaps the most important lesson for monetary policy from this
experience is how difficult and costly it is for the Fed to rebuild its
credibility for low inflation once it has been lost--especially when,
for all practical purposes, it has been totally lost, as in the late
'70s and early '80s. Led by Chairman Volcker, the Fed had to
raise nominal short-term interest rates to unprecedented levels and
essentially induce one of the longest and deepest recessions in the
entire post--World War II era just to begin the process of restoring its
credibility for low inflation. It is highly doubtful that the process
could have begun without this costly recession, in which real GDP declined 2.8 percent and the unemployment rate rose to 10.8 percent. And
it has taken the Fed about twenty years--nearly a quarter century--to
complete the process.
The essence of this process, in my view, has been the Fed's
demonstration, particularly in two episodes, that it can preempt an
increase in inflation without precipitating a recession, and its success
in recent years in convincing the markets and the public that it will
routinely do so in the future. One of these episodes came early in the
process, in 1983 and 1984, as the economy recovered from the 1981-82
recession; the other was in 1994 when the recovery from the 1990-91
recession finally began to gather momentum. In both cases, incipient
inflationary pressures were quickly picked up by financial markets,
which produced what Goodfriend calls "inflation scares,"
characterized by sharply rising nominal bond rates. In both instances
the Fed acted swiftly and decisively to preempt inflation. The 1994
episode was especially important since it occurred at a time when Fed
policy had become much more transparent than earlier, as evidenced by
its decision that year to announce publicly its federal funds rate target immediately following each FOMC meeting.
2. THE CURRENT STRATEGY OF MONETARY POLICY
The U.S. economy has now enjoyed virtual price stability since
about 1996. There seems to be a growing consensus currently among
monetary policymakers, close observers of the policy process in
financial markets, Congress and the press, and individual Americans
interested in policy that price stability and the Fed's credibility
for low inflation should be sustained. This consensus is based partly on
a broader public appreciation of the high costs of reestablishing lost
credibility, as described above. More fundamentally, however, it appears
to reflect a recognition that the Fed's revived credibility is
beneficial to the economy--specifically, that the Fed can contribute
meaningfully to an improved longer-term U.S. economic performance in the
form of an increase in the sustainable growth of production and higher
employment. Further, the public seems less concerned than earlier about
possible short-run costs of low inflation, in terms of lower growth,
perhaps because the transition to low inflation has now been
accomplished. And since low inflation is broadly expected to persist,
the public would be surprised and disappointed if it were lost.
Consequently, the consensus arguably sharpens the Fed's
accountability for maintaining low inflation.
Against this background, I sense the emergence within the Fed of a
more cohesive strategy of monetary policy than at any other time in the
last three decades. To my mind it consists of two elements: (1) a strong
commitment to maintaining high credibility for low inflation
permanently, and (2) active management of real short-term interest rates
to help stabilize the economy in the short run. Regarding the first,
Goodfriend argues in his forthcoming paper that the Fed is now
practicing "implicit" inflation targeting. As he points out,
with the core inflation rate in the 1 to 2 percent range since the mid-
1 990s, it is hard to imagine the Fed now accepting a sustained
inflation rate significantly above 2 percent. Nor would it be likely to
accept a sustained rate significantly below 1 percent given the
increased sensitivity to the risk of deflation and the proximity of the
zero bound on nominal interest rates.
I personally believe that "implicit longer-term inflation
targeting" is an accurate description of the first element of the
Fed's current strategy. It is important to stress, however, that
its ultimate objective is not price stability and high Fed credibility
for its own sake, but the optimal financial foundation these conditions
provide for strong real growth and high employment.
Moreover, these conditions enable the Fed to pursue the second
element of the strategy: active countercyclical short-term interest rate
policy. When the Fed's credibility was very low in the 1970s and
early '80s, it was difficult--perhaps impossible--to conduct
countercyclical interest rate policy effectively. With the Fed's
long-run objective for inflation still unclear, the public could not
confidently deduce the longer-term ramifications of particular
short-term policy actions, and the Fed, in turn, could not confidently
predict the public's reaction to its actions. With its credibility
for low inflation now well established, the Fed can act both more
promptly and more aggressively to counter the effects of unanticipated
shocks and thereby stabilize the economy in the short run. Beginning
exactly two years ago today, the Fed began to ease policy in response to
the softening of the economy in the second half of 2000. It accelerated
the easing process in the wake of 9/11, and over the course of the
two-year period has reduced the federal funds rate 5 1/4 percentage
points, from 6 1/2 percent to its present level of 1 1/4 percent. This
is arguably the most aggressive series of policy easings taken to
cushion a softening economy in the Fed's history and may well
account for the apparent brevity of the recent recession despite the
extraordinary decline in the stock market, 9/11, and other shocks.
The two elements of the Fed's current strategy, then, are
complementary and mutually reinforcing. Implicit inflation targeting
enhances the effectiveness of countercyclical interest rate policy.
Conversely, active countercyclical policy makes implicit inflation
targeting acceptable, since the ability to act aggressively to stabilize
the economy in the short run provides a clear and easily understood
rationale for containing inflation.
3. CHALLENGES IN A LOW INFLATION ENVIRONMENT WITH IMPLICIT
INFLATION TARGETING
After such a long struggle, one might expect that Fed monetary
policymakers would be relatively comfortable now that price stability
has been achieved and credibility for low inflation has been
reestablished. And I think most, if not all, policymakers are more
confident that the Fed can contribute constructively to the
economy's longer-term performance rather than retarding it, as
occurred when inflation was high and variable, and credibility was low.
But the Fed still faces significant policy challenges in the new
low inflation environment. Historically, little practical attention has
been given to the possibility of excessively sharp disinflation and
deflation. And with the press here I need to emphasize at the outset
that I do not believe deflation is a serious present risk to the
economy. But policymakers obviously need to think more about how they
would deal with a deflationary threat, should one emerge unexpectedly,
when inflation is in a 1 to 2 percent range than when it is at 6, 7, or
8 percent. This is especially so with the nominal funds rate, our
principal short-term policy instrument, only 125 basis points above
zero.
We have been thinking about it, and I am quite confident that we
could deal with a deflationary threat successfully. In October 1999 the
Fed sponsored a conference in Woodstock, Vermont, on conducting monetary
policy in a low inflation environment attended by a large number of
leading monetary economists. The participants gave substantial attention
to deflation and how to deal with it should it arise in the future. More
recently, Fed Governor Ben Bernanke nicely summarized current thinking
on this issue in a speech to the National Economists Club. There is now
broad agreement that the most effective way to deal with deflation is to
prevent it from developing in the first place. In the present situation,
the Fed's aggressive easing over the last two years appears to have
preempted any significant drift toward either excessive disinflation or
deflation. Moreover, even if disinflation unexpectedly intensified and
the funds rate were reduced close to the zero bound, the Fed would still
have a number of channels a vailable to reestablish a comfortably
positive inflation rate. For example, it could increase broad liquidity
by purchasing long-term bonds.
The other potential policy challenge I see in today's low
inflation environment is how to handle an incipient increase in
inflation above its implicit target range. This possibility is not on
many radar screens currently, but it is obviously a longer-term
risk--arguably the most likely longer-term risk. I believe that the
policy experience of the 1970s, '80s, and '90s summarized
above argues strongly for prompt action to preempt any sustained
increase in inflation. If policymakers had precise, detailed
foreknowledge of the relative costs, in terms of lost production, of
alternative paths back to price stability, it might be feasible to tune
the return more finely. There is little evidence, however, that we have
such knowledge. Hence, it seems reasonable to resist any deviations from
price stability promptly and strongly--and preferably preempt them
altogether.
4. CONCLUSION--SUSTAINING THE PROGRESS
Hopefully these comments have convinced you that the conduct of
monetary policy in the U.S. has improved significantly during the last
two decades, and that this improvement of policy holds out the prospect
of an improved longer-term economic performance going forward. The trick
now is to sustain the progress. Much of the progress, in my view, is due
to the exceptionally strong leadership since 1979 of, first, Paul
Volcker and now Alan Greenspan. But, ultimately, high-quality monetary
policy--i.e., sustained credibility for low inflation as a foundation
for strong real growth--is too important to be dependent on exceptional
leadership alone, which, after all, cannot be guaranteed over the long
pull. The progress in recent years needs to be
institutionalized--"locked in"--in some manner.
There are probably several ways this could be accomplished. Earlier
I referred to one element of the Fed's current policy strategy as
implicit inflation targeting. My personal preference for
"hardening" our credibility is to make the implicit target
both explicit and quantitative--specifically, 1 to 2 percent, based on
the core PCE index. Explicit, quantitative inflation targeting is
practiced by a number of other leading central banks around the world,
and it would be consistent with the continuing evolution of Fed policy
toward greater transparency and accountability. Most importantly, it
would be a strong and visible step toward ensuring that the Fed's
current high credibility for low inflation will be maintained
indefinitely so that we can make our strongest possible contribution to
maximum sustainable growth in the long run and economic stability in the
short run.
This article is the text of a speech given by J. Alfred Broaddus,
Jr., president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, before the
Public Policy Forum of the American Finance Association on January 3,
2003. The author wishes to thank his colleague Marvin Goodfriend for his
assistance in preparing the article. The views expressed herein are
those of the author and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.