The Euro and inflation divergence in Europe.
Duarte, Margarida
In January 1999, eleven European countries abandoned their
respective national currencies and monetary independence to adopt a
common currency, the Euro. (1) This event, in which several
industrialized countries formed a currency union, stands out in modern
monetary history by its uniqueness, and in due time, it will allow for a
better understanding of the implications of different monetary
arrangements among countries. Already, with four years of data
available, we can begin to learn from Europe's natural experiment.
In a flexible exchange rate regime, the equilibrium adjustment in
the relative price across countries associated with a given
country-specific shock results both from movements in nominal prices and
from movements in the relative price of the countries' currencies,
i.e., the nominal exchange rate. In a currency union, movements in the
nominal exchange rate are, by definition, no longer possible, and
equilibrium adjustments in the relative price across countries result
only from movements in nominal prices. (2) In addition, countries in a
currency union can no longer use monetary policy in response to such a
shock. The equilibrium adjustment of nominal prices associated with a
given country-specific shock reflects, among other factors, not only the
degree of asymmetry of the shock but also the degree of integration of
the different regions (namely, the mobility of factors of production or
the ability to automatically transfer resources across regions). The
more asymmetric the shock or the less integrated the different regions
in a currency union, the bigger the equilibrium adjustment associated
with a given shock. Hence, inflation differentials can be seen as an
indicator of regional asymmetries within a currency union. (3)
In this article I document the behavior of inflation dispersion and
inflation differentials in Euro-area countries before and after the
introduction of the Euro. This documentation supports the main message
of the article: that inflation dispersion and inflation differentials
(with respect to German inflation) within the Euro area have increased
after the adoption of the common currency. Moreover, inflation
dispersion in the Euro area has been higher than that observed in the
United States. Assessing the sources of inflation divergence in the Euro
area after 1999 suggests that countries with higher inflation rates tend
to have also had higher GDP growth rates and a lower price level when
the Euro was adopted. Finally, the variability of the inflation
differential with respect to German inflation has tended to increase for
most countries after the Euro was adopted.
This article is organized as follows. In Section 1 I briefly review
the process leading to the implementation of the European Monetary Union
(EMU). In Section 2 I provide a general discussion about currency
unions, and in Section 3 I document the behavior of inflation before and
after the Euro was adopted using twelve-month core CPI inflation data
from the eleven countries that adopted the common currency in January
1999. In the final section I state my conclusions.
1. A BRIEF REVIEW OF THE ROAD TO THE EMU
The process of European integration started shortly after World War
II, stimulated by the idea that a unified Europe would help ensure
peace. In 1950 Robert Schuman, France's foreign minister, proposed
that the coal and steel industries of France and Germany (then West
Germany) be coordinated under a single supranational authority. This
initiative lead to the European Steel and Coal Community, formed in 1952
together with Belgium, Italy, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands. Building
on the success of this organization, the European Economic Community and
the European Atomic Energy Community were established in 1957 by the
Treaty of Rome. These three organizations were later consolidated in
1967 to form the European Community (EC), known as European Union (EU)
since the ratification of the Maastricht Treaty in 1992.
As the Bretton Woods system became less stable during the 1960s,
the European Council decided in December 1969 to pursue the goal of
establishing an economic and monetary union in Europe by 1980. (4) A
three-phase plan designed by Pierre Werner (then prime minister of
Luxembourg) to achieve economic and monetary union within ten years was
approved in March 1971, and the first stage, involving the narrowing of
currency fluctuation margins, was launched. However, the instability in
foreign exchange markets in 1971 and the subsequent collapse of the
Bretton Woods system effectively brought the EMU project to a stop until
the end of the decade.
In a new effort to establish an area of monetary stability, the
European Monetary System (EMS) was created in March 1979. (5) The EMS
allowed (initially) for currency fluctuations in a [+ or -] 2.25 percent
range around fixed bilateral rates, and it effectively reduced exchange
rate volatility among the participating currencies. It wasn't until
1988, however, that a new effort to establish a monetary union was made
when the Hanover European Council commissioned a report to Jacques
Delors (then president of the European Commission) on the implementation
of a monetary union. The resulting Delors Report laid out a three-stage
plan for the implementation of a monetary union, culminating with the
creation of a single currency. The first stage of this process began in
July 1990 and was marked by the dismantling of internal barriers to the
free movement of capital.
In February 1992 the European Council signed the Maastricht Treaty,
formally establishing the blueprint for economic and monetary
integration in Europe. It defined the precise time line for the three
stages leading to monetary union and set out the convergence criteria that member states had to pass in order to be eligible to adopt the
common currency (the EMU's final stage).
The first stage of the EMU project, already in place, ended in
December 1993. The second stage then began with the establishment of the
European Monetary Institute (which would later become the European
Central Bank--ECB). Its role was to strengthen the coordination of
monetary policies among member states and to make the preparations
required for a single monetary policy and currency.
The Maastricht Treaty laid out five convergence criteria that
member states had to meet in order to enter into the EMU's final
stage. These criteria were (1) public budget deficit below 3 percent of
GDP; (2) public debt less than 60 percent of GDP; (3) inflation rate
within 1.5 percent of the three EU countries with the lowest rates; (4)
long-term interest rates within 2 percent of the three lowest interest
rates in the EU; and (5) no nominal exchange rate movements outside the
EMS's margins for two years. These convergence criteria, which
imposed strict fiscal rules and required inflation and nominal interest
rates to converge across Europe, conditioned the conduct of both
monetary and fiscal policy in the EU countries before the actual
adoption of the common currency.
In the spring of 1998 the European Council announced the eleven
countries that would enter the EMU's third stage as well as the
irrevocable conversion rates between the Euro and each participating
currency. (6) The third stage started in January 1999 with the
introduction of the Euro as a medium of account. Euro banknotes and
coins were put in circulation in 2002.
With the start of the EMU's third stage, member countries
abandoned their monetary independence, and monetary policy came under
the control of the ECB. Its goal is to maintain medium-term price
stability in the Euro area, defined as a year-on-year increase in the
harmonized index of consumer prices (HICP) below 2 percent. (7) With the
start of the third stage, member countries also committed to the fiscal
rules set by the Stability and Growth Pact. This pact establishes a
limit of 3 percent of GDP for budget deficits, and it commits member
countries to aim in the medium term for budgets that are close to
balance or in surplus. (8)
Several countries may join the EMU in the next few years. In one
group are the three EU member states still pending political approval in
their countries to join the EMU: Denmark, Sweden, and the United
Kingdom. Another group includes the countries that are candidates to
join the EU in 2004 and are required to meet the Maastricht convergence
criteria. These countries are the Czech Republic, Cyprus, Estonia,
Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia.
2. CURRENCY UNIONS AND INFLATION DIFFERENTIALS
Monetary and Fiscal Policies in a Currency Union
In a currency union, different countries or regions share a common
currency. The issuance of the common currency and the conduct of
monetary policy is the responsibility of a central monetary authority.
(9) This institutional arrangement characterizes, for example, the
states that form the United States and the countries that form the EMU;
the authorities responsible for monetary policy are the Federal Reserve
System and the ECB, respectively.
The central bank of a currency union holds assets which may include
interest-bearing instruments issued by the governments of the different
regions (or countries) or by the federal government, and its liabilities
consist of the monetary base for the whole area. The monetary authority
adjusts the money supply through the purchase and sale of
interest-bearing assets. Note that since the member countries share a
common currency, interest-rate parity implies that the nominal interest
rate (on assets with similar characteristics) is the same across
countries in a currency union. The joint central bank earns seigniorage revenue from issuing the common currency, and this revenue can be freely
allocated across countries. (l0)
In contrast to monetary policy (which is decided at the central
level), fiscal policy is under the control of a member state or country
in a currency union. That is, member states or countries maintain a
fiscal authority, responsible for the conduct of fiscal policy in their
region. This fact does not preclude the existence of a central fiscal
authority as well. This is the case, for example, in the United States,
where fiscal policy at the federal level involves a large amount of
resources. In Europe, the resources involved in fiscal policy at the
central level are very small.
Costs and Benefits of a Currency Union
By adopting a common currency, countries eliminate exchange rate
risk and the costs of currency conversion. (11) Under floating exchange
rate regimes, nominal exchange rates typically exhibit very high
variability, with standard deviations in the order of 7 or 8 percent for
quarterly data. (12) Obstfeld and Rogoff (2002) compute the welfare cost
of exchange rate variability in an explicitly stochastic version of the
"new open-economy macroeconomics" framework. (13) In this
context, they consider a monetary regime change that eliminates exchange
rate variability (by pegging the exchange rate) while maintaining the
variance of world monetary growth constant. For their parameterization,
which assumes a low degree of risk aversion, the cost of exchange rate
variability is about 1 percent of GDE. This calculation suggests that
the welfare losses due to exchange rate movements generated by monetary
shocks alone could be large. Furthermore, it reflects only the benefits
of eliminating exchange rate risk, that is, of fixing the exchange rate.
Adopting a common currency, however, is understood to have other
implications, such as deeper market integration, which may entail
additional benefits that are beyond the scope of the model in Obstfeld
and Rogoff (2002).
An increase in trade volume is typically stressed as an important
implication of reduced costs of currency conversion and the absence of
nominal exchange rate risk. Several recent empirical studies have
investigated the relationship between currency unions and trade. These
studies offer a wide range of estimates of the effect of the currency
union on trade and suggest that belonging to a currency union/board may
lead to an increase in trade with other members by as much as a factor
of three. Among these studies, Rose and van Wincoop (2001) estimate that
the Euro may lead to an increase in trade in the Euro area of about 50
percent. (14)
By joining a currency area, however, a country forgoes the ability
to use monetary policy to respond to region-specific macroeconomic disturbances. The inability to use monetary policy in response to
asymmetric shocks can be an important cost of joining a currency union,
particularly if asymmetric shocks represent an important source of
output fluctuations and if adjustment mechanisms across regions to these
shocks are absent. One such margin of adjustment across regions is
provided by factor mobility, which allows factors of production to be
easily reallocated in response to regional shocks. Another margin of
adjustment to idiosyncratic shocks across regions is the automatic
stabilization provided by sizeable transfer programs administered at the
union level. The federal income tax and unemployment insurance, which
automatically transfer resources from booming regions to those in
recession, are examples of such programs administered at the federal
level in the United States. Europe differs considerably from the United
States along these two dimensions: despite the elimination of barriers
to the movement of factors, labor mobility within Europe is still lower
than in the United States, and unlike the United States, Europe lacks a
sizeable system of transfers among states. Finally, countries in a
currency union may also incur strategic and political costs in
determining the allocation of seigniorage and the conduct of monetary
policy.
Price Level Divergence in a Currency Union
Countries in a monetary union share the same currency but need not
have the same price level: different regions within the union may have
different price levels and experience different inflation rates. (15)
The United States, a long-established currency union, provides a
benchmark for the magnitude of price differentials in a currency union.
Cecchetti, Mark, and Sonora (2002) use consumer price data for nineteen
U.S. cities from 1918 to 1995 and find that price level divergences
across U.S. cities are large and persistent: annual inflation rates
measured over ten-year periods can differ by as much as 1.55 percentage
points. Parsley and Wei (1996) use commodity level price data for
forty-eight U.S. cities from 1975 to 1992 and find persistent deviations
from the law of one price for both traded and nontraded goods. (16) They
also find that convergence rates for traded categories are higher than
those of nontraded goods or those found in cross-country data.
Deviations in the price level across regions within a currency
union can arise from two sources. The first source is deviations from
the law of one price for traded goods across regions. The second source
is deviations in the relative price of nontraded goods across regions.
Let us consider a currency union with two regions, A and B, and
assume that the price index in each region is given by a geometric
weighted average of traded- and nontraded-goods prices:
[p.sub.i,t] = [[alpha] [p.sup.N.sub.i,t]] + (1 - [alpha])
[p.sup.T.sub.i,t], i = A, B,
where [p.sub.i,t] is the log of the price index, [p.sup.T.sub.i,t]
([p.sup.N.sub.i,t]) is the log of the traded-(nontraded-) goods price
index, and [alpha] is the share of nontraded goods in the price index.
(17) Clearly, asymmetric shocks within a currency union, with distinct
effects on the price index of traded or nontraded goods ([p.sup.T] or
[p.sup.N]) across regions, will generate a differential in the price
level across countries and an inflation differential. (18)
One such asymmetric shock is the following. If a country
experiences faster productivity growth in the sectors producing traded
goods (relative to the sectors producing nontraded goods) than the other
countries in the currency union, then this country will experience
higher inflation than the other countries. To see this, note that a
positive shock to productivity in the traded-goods sector leads to a
higher real wage in the country (since labor is assumed to be perfectly
mobile across sectors). In the nontraded-goods sector, the higher real
wage drives up the relative price of nontraded goods, since productivity
in this sector has not risen. Assuming that the law of one price holds
for traded goods, a higher relative price of nontraded goods in this
country raises this country's price level relative to that abroad.
The inflation differential associated with the shock to productivity in
the traded-goods sector is an equilibrium phenomenon and will persist
while productivity differentials persist across countries. An inflation
differential generated in this way is known as the Balassa-Samuelson
effect. (19)
At the inception of a currency union, another source of inflation
differentials is price level convergence. If price levels differ
initially across countries, then adopting a common currency will lead
prices to converge (at least to some extent), generating temporary
inflation differentials across countries. Price level convergence can
occur for both traded and nontraded goods.
For traded goods, increased market integration and price
transparency associated with the adoption of a common currency reduces
the scope for deviations from the law of one price, leading to temporary
inflation differentials for traded-goods price indices. (20) As for the
price of nontraded goods, the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis also suggests
that adopting a common currency narrows deviations in the price for
these goods across countries. To see this, note that in a currency
union, economic integration creates pressure for convergence in
productivity levels. Since tradable goods tend to be more capital
intensive than nontraded goods, the scope for productivity differentials
across countries in the nontraded-goods sector tends to be limited
relative to that in the traded-goods sector. Therefore, countries with
initially low productivity levels (which tend to be poorer and have
lower price levels) tend to experience higher productivity growth in the
tradable-goods sector as a result of convergence in productivity. As we
have seen before, prices of nontraded goods in the countries with lower
price levels tend to increase, converging to the higher price level of
wealthier countries. (21)
3. THE ADOPTION OF THE EURO AND THE BEHAVIOR OF INFLATION
In this section I document the recent behavior of inflation in
Euro-area countries. The measure of inflation I use is the twelve-month
percentage change of the core consumer price index (CPI) for each of the
eleven countries that adopted the Euro in 1999, at a monthly frequency.
(22) That is, inflation in month t in country j is measured by
[[pi].sup.j.sub.t] = CP[I.sup.j.sub.t]/CP[I.sup.j.sub.t-12] - 1.
Figure 1 depicts the monthly core consumer price inflation for a
subset of Euro-area countries. Consumer price inflation declined
steadily during the second half of the 1990s but has recently started to
rise throughout the Euro zone. In the beginning of 1999, the
twelve-month inflation rate in most countries was below the ECB's
medium-term price stability target of 2 percent; this rate was above
this level only in Portugal and Spain (2.5 percent). By mid-2002, the
overall picture was quite different. Except for Germany and France, all
Euro-zone countries were above the 2 percent target. The twelve-month
core CPI inflation rate in June 2002 was 5.3 percent in Ireland, 4.5
percent in Portugal, and 3.9 percent in the Netherlands and Spain, for
example.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
I now turn to the behavior of inflation dispersion in the Euro area
in this period. Figure 2 plots two summary statistics for the dispersion
of inflation: the absolute difference between the highest and lowest
inflation rates and the (unweighted) standard deviation of inflation
rates across the Euro area from 1996:1 to 2002:12. The absolute spread
decreased sharply during the second half of the 1990s, from about 4
percentage points to about 2 percentage points by the end of the decade,
as the EU member countries aimed at fulfilling the convergence criteria
defined by the Maastricht Treaty. The absolute spread has increased
since then to nearly its level at the beginning of the sample (the
average absolute spread in 2002 was 3.8 percentage points). The graph
also shows a decrease in the standard deviation of inflation rates
across the Euro area before the common currency was adopted followed by
a subsequent increase. In 2002, the standard deviation averaged 1.2
percent, while in 1998 it averaged 0.6 percent.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The United States constitutes a long-established currency union,
and data on U.S. inflation dispersion provide a natural benchmark
against which to compare the recent increase in inflation dispersion in
Europe depicted in Figure 2. There is, however, relatively little data
on U.S. subnational inflation rates. In order to compare inflation
dispersion in the Euro area with that in the United States, I use annual
data on consumer price levels in nineteen U.S. cities from the Bureau of
Labor Statistics.
Figure 3 plots the two measures of inflation dispersion for the
United States from 1950 to 2001. The average absolute spread was 2.8
percentage points in the entire sample and 2.2 percentage points in the
last decade. The average standard deviation was 0.8 and 0.6 in these two
periods, respectively. (23) Comparing the dispersion of inflation rates
in the Euro area with that observed among U.S. cities indicates that the
former resembled the latter in the late 1990s. Notwithstanding the
existence of some episodes of high inflation dispersion in the United
States, the two measures of Euro-area inflation dispersion are currently
higher than the corresponding U.S. sample averages. (24)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
I now turn from these two summary statistics of inflation
dispersion to the distribution of inflation differentials with respect
to the German inflation rate across the Euro area. The choice of Germany
as the reference country reflects the fact that, prior to the adoption
of the Euro, the German monetary authority had a strong reputation for
advocating low inflation and that its inflation rate has been relatively
flat throughout the period considered (Figure 1). Focusing on the
distribution of inflation differentials allows some insight into the
nature of these differentials.
Figure 4 plots the inflation differential with respect to German
inflation for a subset of Euro-zone countries, and Figure 5 plots the
average inflation differential with respect to German inflation for each
Euro-area member country before and after the adoption of the Euro. The
former period averages inflation data from 1996 through 1998, and the
latter period averages inflation data from 2000 onwards. I have not
included the twelve data points for 1999 since the twelve-month
percentage change of consumer price indices for these data points
effectively cover both the period before and after the Euro was adopted.
[FIGURES 4-5 OMITTED]
It is apparent from these two figures that inflation differentials
within the Euro area have increased after the adoption of the common
currency for most countries, reinforcing the message from Figure 2. Over
the period before the Euro was adopted (1996 to 1998), average inflation
differentials ranged from 0.3 (Austria) to 1.7 (Italy) percentage
points. Inflation differentials have increased steadily across the Euro
since after 1999, and over the period from 2000 to 2002 they ranged from
0.4 (France) to more than 3 (Ireland) percentage points.
Assessing the sources of the inflation differentials observed in
the Euro area after 1999 is a complicated task. Drawing upon the
discussion in the previous section, I briefly look at the joint behavior
of inflation with the growth rate of output and initial price levels.
As I pointed out in the previous section, price level convergence
can be a source of inflation differentials when different countries with
initial distinct price levels adopt a common currency. (25) This
argument suggests that countries with lower price levels would exhibit
higher inflation rates than countries with higher price levels. I use
the comparative price levels from the OECD for January 1999 as a measure
of the initial differences in price levels among the countries in the
Euro zone. Figure 6 plots the average inflation rate after 2000 against
the comparative price level in 1999 for each country in the Euro area.
The plot shows a negative relationship between the price level and
subsequent inflation rates (the correlation coefficient is -0.6). (26)
This evidence suggests that price level convergence may be a partial
explanation for the different behavior of inflation across Euro-zone
countries. The process of price level convergence, however, is a
temporary one, and it has been under way in Europe throughout the 1990s.
(27) This fact suggests a reduced scope for future price level
convergence in Europe.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Figure 7 plots the average inflation rate after the Euro was
adopted in each Euro-zone country against its average growth rate of GDP
in the same period. This figure clearly suggests a positive relationship
between the average growth rate of output and average inflation after
the common currency was adopted. This figure suggests that, reflecting
the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis, the observed inflation differentials
could be indicative of a process of the convergence of productivity
levels (driving income convergence) across countries as well as
asymmetric shocks across countries (and desynchronized business cycles).
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Finally, in Figure 8, I plot the variance of twelve-month inflation
in the periods before and after the adoption of the Euro, as defined
before. This figure shows a tendency for increased inflation variability
after the adoption of the Euro relative to the previous period. The
variance of inflation increased in the later period for seven out of the
eleven countries considered. The most significant exception is Italy,
where the variance of inflation was substantially smaller after the Euro
was adopted.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
The Maastricht criteria forced the potential entrants in the EMU to
attain inflation convergence by 1998, a requirement that conditioned
these countries' use of monetary and fiscal policy throughout the
1990s. With the start of the EMU, the restriction on inflation
convergence was eliminated and the ECB took control of monetary policy
in the Euro area. The figures above suggest that the inability to use
monetary policy in response to country-specific shocks after the
requirement that countries attain inflation convergence was eliminated
is associated with an increase of inflation dispersion and volatility.
In the new European institutional framework, regional fiscal policy
is the only instrument available to the regional authorities to affect
regional inflation. Should a regional fiscal authority decide to use
fiscal policy to affect its inflation rate, it raises the question of
the effectiveness and implications of such policy. (28)
4. CONCLUSION
In this article I document the behavior of inflation dispersion and
inflation differentials in Euro-area countries before and after the Euro
was introduced. Inflation dispersion and inflation differentials (with
respect to German inflation) within the Euro area have increased since
countries lost monetary independence and were no longer required to
attain inflation convergence. Inflation dispersion in the Euro area
after the common currency was adopted has been higher than that observed
in the United States. Additionally, the variability of the inflation
differential with respect to German inflation has tended to increase for
most countries since the Euro was adopted.
These observed inflation differentials reflect both a temporary
process of price level convergence as well as the adjustment to
asymmetric country-specific shocks. To the extent that the process of
price level convergence is temporary, these differentials, if continued
or widened, are bound to start generating considerable attention,
prompting the debate over the criteria to be met by Euro-area countries
and the design and goals of regional policies. These differentials
naturally raise the question of the adequacy of a common monetary policy
for an area composed of heterogeneous constituent countries and, since
fiscal policy is the only tool available to regional authorities to
affect inflation, the question of the ability and desirability of using
regional fiscal policy to affect regional price differentials.
The author would like to thank Andreas Hornstein, Thomas Humphrey,
Roy Webb, and Alexander Wolman for helpful comments. This article does
not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) These countries were Austria, Belgium, Finland, France,
Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, and
Spain. Greece adopted the Euro in January 2001. Monetary policy in the
Euro area has been conducted by the European Central Bank (ECB) since
1999.
The remaining three members of the European Union (Denmark, Sweden,
and the United Kingdom) have, so far, decided to maintain their own
currencies and monetary independence.
(2) For example, as will be seen later, in response to faster
productivity growth in its traded-goods sector (than in the other
sectors), a country will experience a real exchange rate appreciation
(an increase in its relative price), which in a currency union
translates into higher inflation.
(3) This discussion is closely related to that of optimal currency
areas. The theory of optimal currency areas dates back to Mundell
(1961), but it gained renewed interest in the last decade with the
European project for a currency union. This theory stresses the relative
importance of internal factor mobility and external factor immobility in
defining the appropriate domain for a currency area.
(4) The European Council is composed primarily of the president of
the European Commission (the executive body of the EU) and the heads of
government of the member states and their foreign ministers.
(5) The participating countries in the EMS were the six countries
that formed the EC since its inception, plus Denmark and Ireland (which
joined the EC in 1973). The United Kingdom also joined the EC at this
date but opted not to participate in the EMS.
(6) Of the remaining four EU member countries not entering the Euro
zone in 1999, Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom chose not to
participate, while Greece was viewed, at this stage, as not having
fulfilled the necessary conditions for the adoption of the Euro.
(7) The HICP is the weighted arithmetic average of the consumer
price indices for the Euro-area countries. The weight of each country is
its share of private domestic consumption expenditure in the Euro area.
See Svensson (2002) for a critical evaluation of European
monetary-policy strategy.
(8) The Stability and Growth Pact also defines the exceptional
conditions under which breaching the 3 percent budget deficit limit can
be accepted and establishes how and when fines can be levied against
countries that display excessive deficits.
(9) I am restricting attention to arrangements in which a group of
countries (or regions) shares a common currency and monetary policy is
decided by a joint central bank. I am, therefore, abstracting from
arrangements in which a country (typically small) adopts the currency of
a large anchor country.
(10) Sibert (1994) considers the problem of allocating seigniorage
in a currency union.
(11) The European Commission estimated that costs of currency
conversion in the European Union amount to 0.4 percent of the
area's GDP.
(12) See, for example, the data presented in Chari, Kehoe, and
McGrattan (2002).
(13) The "new open-economy macroeconomics" framework was
set forth by Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995), and it represents an important
workhorse model in international economics. This model introduces
nominal rigidities into a two-country general equilibrium model.
(14) See Rose (2002) for a review of this literature and for a
complete list of references. This paper, in particular, uses
meta-analysis for evaluating and combining the disparate estimates from
different studies. He finds that the combined estimate implies that a
currency union approximately doubles trade.
(15) Much of the existing literature on monetary unions associates
a common currency with a common price level. See, for example, Canzoneri
and Rogers (1990) or Bergin (2000). In contrast, Bergin (2002) and
Duarte and Wolman (2002) model currency unions allowing consumer price
levels to differ across regions.
(16) The law of one price states that, absent trade barriers, a
commodity should sell for the same price (when expressed in the same
currency) everywhere.
(17) Of course, if the weight [alpha] differs across regions, then
the price level will also differ across regions due to the difference in
composition of the indices (even if [p.sup.N] and [p.sup.T] are
identical across regions).
(18) Denoting the inflation rate in period t, the percentage change
in the price level from t - 1 to t, as [[pi].sub.t], it follows that the
inflation differential can be approximated by a weighted average of the
inflation differential in traded- and nontraded-goods indices:
[[pi].sub.A,t] - [[pi].sub.B,t] [nearly equals to] [alpha]
([[pi].sup.N.sub.A,t] - [[pi].sup.N.sub.B,t]) + (1 - [alpha])
([[pi].sup.T.sub.A,t] - [[pi].sup.T.sub.B,t]).
(19) See, for example, Chapter 4 in Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) on
the Balassa-Samuelson effect.
(20) The ECB Monthly Bulletin (October 1999), for example, provides
strong evidence for the convergence of car prices across Euro-area
countries.
(21) Natalucci and Ravenna (2002) analyze the choice of the
exchange rate regime for accession countries to the EMU when these
countries need to meet both inflation and nominal exchange rate criteria
but are experiencing a real exchange rate appreciation due to increased
productivity in the tradable-goods sector (the Balassa-Samuelson
effect).
(22) Core consumer price indices exclude food and energy prices,
which are considered the most erratic components of price indices. The
data are taken from Eurostat.
I have not included data for Greece, which adopted the Euro in
January 2001.
(23) Cecchetti, Mark, and Sonora (2002) study the dynamics of these
price indices for U.S. cities. They estimate that price index
divergences across U.S. cities are temporary but surprisingly
persistent, with a half-life of nearly nine years.
(24) In comparing Figures 2 and 3, the distinct time samples as
well as the distinct frequency of the data should be noted. Using annual
(instead of monthly) frequency data for the EMU countries leads to the
same conclusion.
(25) The ECB has emphasized price level convergence as an important
source of inflation differentials in the Euro area. See, for example,
the ECB Monthly Bulletin (October 1999).
(26) Comparative price levels, a measure of the differences in
price levels between countries, are from the OECD Main Economic
Indicators.
(27) See Rogers (2001) for evidence on price level convergence in
Europe during the 1990s. He concludes that while price level convergence
contributed to observed inflation differentials within the Euro area in
2000, other forces explain most of those cross-country differences in
inflation.
(28) See Duarte and Wolman (2003) for an analysis of the
implications of using fiscal policy to affect regional inflation in a
currency union.
REFERENCES
Bergin, Paul. 2000. "Fiscal Solvency and Price Level
Determination in a Monetary Union." Journal of Monetary Economics
25 (February): 37-53.
--. Forthcoming. "One Money One Price? Pricing to Market in a
Monetary Union." European Economic Review.
Canzoneri, Matthew, and Caroll Ann Rogers. 1990. "Is the
European Community an Optimal Currency Area? Optimal Taxation Versus the
Cost of Multiple Currencies." American Economic Review 80 (June):
419-33.
Cecchetti, Stephen, Nelson Mark, and Robert Sonora. 2002.
"Price Level Convergence Among United States Cities: Lessons for
the European Central Bank." International Economic Review 43
(November): 1081-99.
Chaff, V. V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan. Forthcoming.
"Can Sticky Price Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Exchange
Rates?" Review of Economic Studies.
Duarte, Margarida, and Alexander Wolman. 2003. "Fiscal Policy
and Regional Inflation in a Currency Union." Mimeo, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond.
European Central Bank. 1999. "Inflation Differentials in a
Monetary Union." Monthly Bulletin (October): 35-44.
Mundell, Robert. 1961. "A Theory of Optimum Currency
Areas." American Economic Review 51 (September): 657-65.
Natalucci, Fabio, and Federico Ravenna. 2002. "The Road to
Adopting the Euro: Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Regimes in EU
Candidate Countries." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Board of Governors.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. "Exchange Rate
Redux." Journal of Political Economy 103 (June): 624-60.
--. 2002. "Risk and Exchange Rates." In Contemporary
Economic Policy: Essays in Honor of Assaf Razin, edited by E. Helpman
and E. Sadka. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Parsley, David, and Shang-Jin Wei. 1996. "Convergence to the
Law of One Price Without Trade Barriers or Currency Fluctuations."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (November): 1211-36.
Rogers, John. 2001. "Price Level Convergence, Relative Prices,
and Inflation in Europe." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Board of
Governors.
Rose, Andrew. 2002. "The Effect of Common Currencies on
International Trade: A Meta-Analysis." Mimeo, Haas School of
Business, University of California-Berkeley.
--, and Eric van Wincoop. 2001. "National Money as a Barrier
to Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union." American Economic
Review 91 (May): 386-90.
Sibert, Anne. 1994. "The Allocation of Seigniorage in a Common
Currency Area." Journal of International Economics 37 (August):
111-22.
Svensson, Lars. 2002. "A Reform of the Eurosystem's
Monetary-Policy Strategy Is Increasingly Urgent." Mimeo, Princeton
University.