Why does consumer sentiment predict household spending?
Mehra, Yash P. ; Martin, Elliot W.
The index of consumer sentiment is one of the most watched economic
indicators. It is widely believed in both the financial press and
academic circles that consumer sentiment has predictive content for
household spending. This belief in the predictive content of consumer
sentiment is in line with most previous research that indicates the
sentiment contains information about future changes in household
spending beyond that already contained in past values of other available
indicators.
Why does consumer sentiment predict household spending? In an
interesting paper, Carroll, Fuhrer, and Wilcox (1994)--denoted hereafter as CFW (1994)--have suggested two possible interpretations of the
predictive content of sentiment for household spending. One is that
sentiment predicts spending because it is an independent determinant of
consumer spending; changes in consumer "attitudes" cause
fluctuations in the economy. (1) An alternative interpretation is that
sentiment simply foreshadows the overall outlook for the economy: when
consumers are optimistic about the outlook for the economy, they give
upbeat responses to interviewers. On average, those expectations are
validated and spending eventually increases as foreshadowed by
sentiment. Sentiment, according to this interpretation, is thus just a
reflection of the overall state of the economy without being a causal
economic force.
The empirical evidence that can discriminate between these two
alternative interpretations of the predictive ability of sentiment for
spending is rather limited. CFW (1994) report evidence that favors the
first interpretation. In an economy where all consumers are
forward-looking and behave according to the standard permanent income
model as outlined in Hall (1978), consumption follows a random walk, and
hence changes in spending are unforecastable from any past information
known to consumers, including the lagged sentiment measures. However,
following the suggestion in Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) that some
households follow a rule of thumb and set consumption equal to income,
CFW (1994) have argued that in an economy containing both types of
consumers, sentiment might predict spending without being an independent
causal force. When the economic outlook is bright, forward-looking
consumers will give optimistic readings on the economy. On average,
their optimism will be vindicated and income will rise. When it does,
the spending of rule-of-thumb consumers will increase. Thus, by this
account, the survey responses of forward-looking households predict the
spending of rule-of-thumb households. In order to test this hypothesis,
CFW (1994) estimate consumption regressions in which spending depends on
lagged sentiment as well as on expected change in current income. The
response of consumption to current income is a proxy for the influence
of current economic conditions on spending, reflecting the presence of
rule-of-thumb consumers. They find that lagged sentiment remains
significant in the consumption equation, suggesting that sentiment is a
direct determinant of household spending.
In this article, we reexamine the evidence on why sentiment
predicts household spending. In most previous research, including that
of CFW (1994), the effect of sentiment on spending is investigated under
a number of simplifying assumptions. One such key assumption is that
there is no habit persistence in consumption. If this assumption is not
correct, then current consumption might depend upon lagged consumption,
income, and wealth variables. The sentiment measures might then
spuriously determine spending, because they are correlated with these
other determinants of spending that are omitted from the spending
equation. Another key assumption made in previous work is that the real
interest rate is constant, thereby ruling out the direct influence of
the expected change in the real rate on household spending. Hall (1988)
has argued that forward-looking consumers defer consumption in response
to high real rates, and hence consumption may follow a random walk once
we account for the response of consumption to the expected real rate. We
examine whether the results in previous research are robust to changes
in the underlying assumptions.
The empirical work presented here covers the sample period 1959Q1
to 2001Q2 (2) and indicates that the result in CFW (1994)--showing that
sentiment is a direct determinant of spending--is not robust to the
consideration of influences of other economic variables on spending. In
particular, the results indicate that current consumption is indeed
correlated with lagged consumption, income, and wealth variables.
Consumption is also sensitive to current changes in income and the level
of the real rate. Sentiment has no direct role to play in predicting
consumption once its indirect influences in predicting current changes
in income and the real rate are accounted for in spending equations. The
results indicate that lagged sentiment is significant in predicting
current changes in income and the real rate. Together these results
favor the second interpretation of why sentiment predicts household
spending, which is that sentiment foreshadows current expectations about
the economy and the interest rate but has no direct role in actually
causing fluctuations in spending.
This article proceeds as follows: Section 1 presents the empirical
methodology used for testing the influence of sentiment on spending, and
Section 2 presents the empirical results. In Section 3 we discuss the
results, and in Section 4 we offer concluding observations.
1. EMPIRICAL MODEL AND METHOD
Permanent Income Hypothesis, Consumption Growth Regression, and
Consumer Sentiment
If all consumers in the economy are forward-looking and behave
according to the permanent income hypothesis as outlined in Hall (1978),
then consumption follows a random walk, changes in current consumption
being unforecastable from any lagged information known to consumers,
including sentiment. Intuitively, according to the permanent income
hypothesis, households consume their permanent income and they form
expectations of their permanent income rationally taking into account
all available information. To the extent that information is available
and relevant to consumption in period t + 1 ([C.sub.t+1]), it is already
imbedded in [C.sub.t]. Hence, the difference [C.sub.t +1] - [C.sub.t]
reflects new information regarding permanent income available at time t
+ 1. Since households form their estimates of permanent income
rationally, this change in consumption must be uncorrelated with any
available information, including lagged sentiment measures.
In order to further explain the random walk implication of the
permanent income hypothesis and highlight the underlying assumptions,
let us consider an infinitely lived representative consumer who chooses
current consumption based on the expected present discounted value of
his future income, not just his current income. He maximizes expected
discounted utility subject to an intertemporal budget constraint. Let us
assume that the utility function maximized by the representative
consumer is separable in time and depends only on contemporaneous consumption during each period, as shown in (1) below:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where C is consumption, [beta] is the subjective rate of discount,
and E is the expectation conditional on information available at time
period t. Equation (1) is the expected discounted utility. Let us assume
further that the representative consumer can borrow and lend at the
constant real rate of interest (r) and that any amount borrowed--say, in
period t--must be repaid in the future by setting consumption below
labor income. The consumer is assumed to choose a pattern of consumption
and asset holdings in order to maximize the expected discounted utility
function (1) subject to an intertemporal budget constraint. (3) The
first-order conditions for this problem include
(2) [E.sub.t] U' ([C.sub.t + 1]) (1 + r) / (1 + [beta]) =
U' ([C.sub.t]),
where U' is the marginal utility of consumption. Equation (2)
is the Euler consumption equation, which says the expected present value
of the marginal utility of consumption tomorrow equals the marginal
utility of consumption today.
If we further assume that the real rate of interest equals the
consumer's discount factor (r = [beta]) and that the marginal
utility function is linear in consumption, equation (2) reduces to
[E.sub.t] [C.sub.t+1] = [C.sub.t], which says that consumption today is
the optimal forecast of consumption tomorrow. Under the additional
assumption that expectations are rational, we can express the above
equation in the form of a consumption growth regression, as illustrated
in (3):
(3) [C.sub.t + l] - [C.sub.t] = [epsilon.sub.t + 1],
where s is a rational forecast error uncorrelated with any
information known to the consumer at time t. Equation (3) is Hall's
famous hypothesis that under the permanent income hypothesis, change in
consumption is unforecastable. Hence, according to this version of the
permanent income hypothesis, lagged sentiment should not help predict
future consumption growth. (4)
Consumer Sentiment in Consumption Growth Regressions, Including
Expected Income and the Real Rate
The random walk hypothesis developed in Hall (1978) has not done
well in empirical tests. Hall himself found that lagged changes in stock
prices help predict changes in consumption, while Nelson (1987) showed
that consumption growth is correlated with lagged growth in disposable
income. In an extension of the basic model, Hall (1988) has argued that
consumption is a random walk once any movements in the real interest
rate are taken into account. Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990), on the
other hand, have argued that consumption growth is a random walk once
the response of consumption growth to the contemporaneous change in
income is taken into account. Those who have empirically investigated
the role of consumer sentiment in predicting consumption often find that
lagged sentiment does have predictive content for future consumption
growth in reduced form regressions, a result inconsistent with the
random walk implication of the simple permanent income model. (5)
A possible explanation as to why the random walk implication of the
permanent income model has not done well in empirical tests is that some
of the underlying assumptions may not be consistent with the data. One
key assumption pertaining to the random walk result is that the utility
function is time-separable, so that the marginal utility of consumption
today depends only upon today's consumption. This assumption rules
out the presence of habit persistence in consumption behavior, which may
be important in practice. If there is habit persistence in consumption,
then current consumption might be correlated with lagged consumption and
hence correlated with lagged income and wealth variables (Dynan 1993).
The other key assumptions underlying the random walk result are
that the real rate is constant and that all consumers can borrow and
lend at the constant real rate. These assumptions may not be valid. The
real rate may vary over time, and some consumers may face borrowing
constraints and hence may be unable to smooth consumption over time. If
some consumers face borrowing constraints, then their consumption may be
tied to current, not permanent, income. Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990)
have argued that some consumers follow a rule of thumb and consume their
current income. In the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers, aggregate
consumption may appear sensitive to changes in current income. Other
analysts have argued that consumption may also appear sensitive to
changes in current income if the marginal utility of consumption depends
upon factors other than consumption. For example, Baxter and Jermann
(1999) have argued that consumers may substitute between home- and
market-produced consumption goods, and hence the marginal utility of
consumption may depend upon the labor-leisure choice, in addition to
depending upon the level of consumption. Thus, consumption may appear
sensitive to changes in current income.
Another interesting scenario in which the random walk result may
not hold is outlined in Goodfriend (1992). The Hall model described
above is the representative agent model in which the representative
agent is assumed to fully know the income process. The aggregate income
process is the individual income process, because all agents are assumed
to be alike. Goodfriend, however, considers an economy with
heterogeneous agents, where agents have individually specific income
processes that may differ from the aggregate income process. If there is
complete information about the aggregates, the random Walk result holds
at the aggregate level. However, if agents do not have contemporary
information on the aggregate income, as is the case in practice since
the aggregate income data are released with a lag, then aggregation
yields a consumption equation that violates the random walk result. In
particular, consumption is correlated with changes in lagged income.
Intuitively, in the absence of contemporary information on the aggregate
income, agents cannot distinguish between aggregate and relative shocks
affecting their individual incomes. As a consequence, if there is an
aggregate income shock, it may partially be interpreted as a shock to
the individual-specific component of individual labor income. If the
individual-specific component is less persistent than the aggregate
component, then agents will fail to adjust their permanent incomes
appropriately, and hence consumption observed will not move too much.
However, in subsequent periods, as information on the aggregate income
becomes available and the effect on actual income is observed to
persist, consumption will adjust fully and will appear sensitive to
lagged changes in actual income. (6)
In view of the considerations listed above, we examine the
predictive content of sentiment for future changes in consumption using
consumption growth regressions that allow for the lagged influences of
other economic determinants of spending on current consumption. In
particular, we consider consumption growth regressions of the form
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [E.sub.t - 1] [Y.sub.t] is income growth expected for period
t conditional on information at t - 1 ; [E.sub.t - 1] [r.sub.t] is the
real interest rate expected for period t conditional on information at t
- 1 ; Z is a set of control variables containing lagged values of
consumption and other plausible economic determinants of spending; and S
is an index of consumer sentiment. Equation (4) allows for the
possibility that consumption is sensitive to current income growth as
well as to the real rate. Furthermore, equation (4) also allows for the
possibility that consumption is correlated with lagged values of
economic factors (Z) other than consumer sentiment. For example, as
indicated before, lagged consumption or other variables might enter
directly into the consumption equation if there is habit persistence in
consumption behavior or if the marginal utility of consumption depends
upon factors other than the level of consumption.
In equation (4) consumer sentiment may help forecast consumption
growth through two channels. The first channel is an indirect one:
lagged sentiment helps predict consumption growth in period t because it
is instrumental in predicting current income growth and the level of
real interest rate for period t. The other channel is a direct one:
lagged sentiment directly enters the consumption equation (4). It is
possible that lagged sentiment may help predict consumption growth
through both channels. CFW (1994) use the evidence on the presence of
these two channels to distinguish between the two interpretations of why
sentiment helps predict consumption growth. Sentiment may be considered
an independent determinant of consumer spending if it directly enters
the consumption equation (all [c.sub.s] [not equal to] 0 in (4)). In
contrast, sentiment may be considered a passive predictor of spending
because it just foreshadows current economic conditions. In this
interpretation, lagged sentiment no longer directly enters the
consumption equation (4) once its role as a predictor of current income
and the real rate is allowed for in the consumption equation (all
[c.sub.s] = 0, but [lambda.sub.y], [lambda.sub.r] [not equal to] 0 in
(4)). In this interpretation, sentiment is a predictor of household
spending without being an independent causal force.
In previous research the predictive content of sentiment for
household spending has been investigated using restricted versions of
(4). For example, CFW (1994) investigate the role of sentiment using an
aggregate consumption equation of the form
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE]
and find that sentiment enters the consumption equation directly.
This empirical evidence is suspect. This specification of the
consumption equation implicitly assumes that lagged values of
consumption and other economic variables do not enter the consumption
equation directly. Moreover, consumption is assumed to be insensitive to
the expected real rate. If other relevant variables are omitted from the
consumption equation, then lagged sentiment may spuriously appear to
predict consumption. Others have investigated the role of sentiment
using reduced form consumption regressions of the form given below in
(6) (Brain and Ludvigson 1998):
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN AS]
In this specification, even though there is a set of control
variables including lagged values of consumption and other plausible
economic determinants of spending, such as interest rates and income,
consumption is still assumed to be insensitive to current income and the
real rate. In view of these considerations, we reexamine the role of
sentiment using instead the consumption equation (4).
Data, Estimation, and the Issue of Constancy of Second Moments
We investigate the role of sentiment in predicting spending using
consumption equations of the form (4) and estimated using quarterly data
over 1959Q1 to 2001Q2. (7) Consumption is measured as per capita consumption of nondurables and services, in 1996 dollars (C). Labor
income is measured as disposable labor income per capita, in 1996
dollars (Y). (8) The real rate (r) is measured as the three-month
Treasury bill rate minus the contemporaneous inflation rate; the latter
is measured by the behavior of the consumption expenditure deflator. The
index of consumer sentiment used here is the Expectations Component of
the University of Michigan Sentiment Index. (9) The additional variables
(Z) considered here include past values of consumption growth and the
lagged residual from the cointegrating regression estimated using levels
of per capita consumption, labor income, and household net worth. The
evidence in Mehra (2001) indicates that consumer spending is
cointegrated with labor income and household wealth and that changes in
current consumer spending depend in part upon lagged income and wealth
variables through the error-correction term (Engle and Granger 1987).
The lagged residual from the cointegrating regression, when included in
the consumption equation of the form (4), captures in a parsimonious way
the response of current consumption to lagged values of income and
wealth variables. Wealth used in this cointegrating relationship is
measured as per capita net worth of households, in 1996 dollars.
Equation (7) below reports the cointegrating regression estimated
using real, per capita consumer spending, labor income, and household
net worth over 1959Q1 to 2001Q2:
(7) [C.sub.t] = 3.7 + .51 [Y.sub.t + .07] [W.sub.t + .002T],
(21.4) (46.1) (6.1) (21.7)
where all variables are in their natural log levels and where Y is
per capita labor income; W is per capita household net worth; and T is a
linear time trend. Parentheses below coefficients contain t-values
corrected for the presence of serial correlation and heteroscedasticity.
(10) All variables appear with theoretically expected signs and are
significant. Panel A in Figure 1 charts the (log) level of actual
consumer spending and the level predicted by the cointegrating
regression (7), and Panel B charts the gap between actual and predicted
levels, which is the residual from the cointegrating regression (7). As
can be seen in Figure 1, the actual and predicted consumption series
move quite closely and the gap variable appears stationary over the
sample period. In the consumption growth regression (4), the residual
series is one of the variables that appear in the set Z.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The consumption growth regressions like (4) and (5) relate
consumption to expected values of income growth and the level of the
real rate and have been estimated using instrumental variables methods
and assuming that expectations are rational (Hall 1988; Campbell and
Mankiw 1989). Under the assumption of rational expectations, consumers
take into account all known information in forming their expectations,
and the forecast error is uncorrelated with any lagged information.
Hence, period t - 1 values of information variables are valid
instruments. Hall (1988), however, notes that if the frequency with
which consumption decisions are taken is higher than the frequency of
observations (quarterly in our case), then under some assumptions the
residuals of equations may have the first-order moving average
structure. In that case, valid information for instruments will be any
information dated t - 2 or earlier. We follow Hall in using instruments
lagged t - 2 and before. The fact that aggregate data on income are
available with a one-period lag also implies that period t - 2 values
will be in the information set of consumers (Goodfriend 1992). The
instruments used are a constant, four lagged values of consumption
growth, change in the unemployment rate, change in the real rate, and
the level of the index of consumer sentiment. Following Campbell and
Mankiw (1989), we also report the test of overidentifying restrictions,
which is a test of the hypothesis that the instruments used are
uncorrelated with the residual of the consumption equation. (11)
The consumption regression (4) relates consumption to income growth
and the real rate among other factors. This regression assumes that
second moments measuring volatility of economic variables are constant,
implying that consumption is unaffected by second moments of expected
income and the real rate. Mehra (2003) has recently argued that over the
sample period (1959Q1 to 2001Q4) consumption is correlated negatively
with the second moment of the real rate, which measures interest rate
volatility. If the consumption equation is estimated ignoring the
presence of this negative correlation between consumption and interest
rate volatility, then the estimated interest rate coefficient ([lambda.sub.r]) that measures the response of consumption to the
expected real rate is biased downward. In view of such evidence, the
consumption growth regression (4) is estimated including the interest
rate volatility variable in a nonlinear fashion. In particular, the
consumption regression is estimated including the interest rate
volatility variable interacting with the real interest rate. (12)
2. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Table 1 presents instrumental variables estimates of the
consumption growth regressions like those in (4) and (5) for the full
sample period, 1959Q1 to 2001Q2. Row 1 presents the consumption equation
estimated including only current income growth as in Campbell and Mankiw
(1989). The maintained hypothesis here is that consumption follows a
random walk once we account for the sensitivity of consumption to
current income, arising as a result of the presence of rule-of-thumb or
liquidity-constrained consumers. [X.sup.2.sub.1] is a chi-square
statistic that tests the hypothesis that the four lagged values of the
sentiment measure are not jointly significant when included in the
estimated consumption equation given in row 1. [X.sup.2.sub.2] is a
chi-square statistic that tests the hypothesis that the four lagged
values of the sentiment measure used in the prediction equation for
current income growth are not jointly significant. [X.sup.2.sub.2] is
large, suggesting that lagged sentiment contains information about
current income growth. However, [X.sup.2.sub.1] is also large, implying
that sentiment continues to have a predictive content for household
spending, even after one accounts for its indirect role in predicting
current consumption through the expected income channel. This result is
qualitatively similar to the one in CFW (1994), interpreted to mean that
sentiment is a direct determinant of consumer spending.
Row 2 in Table 1 estimates the consumption equation including
expected income growth as well as the lagged residual from the
cointegrating regression (7) that is estimated using levels of
consumption, income, and wealth variables. The lagged residual is
significant in the estimated consumption equation, suggesting that
current consumption is directly correlated with lagged income and wealth
variables. Consumption is still sensitive to current income growth, and
sentiment remains significant in predicting changes in current income
(see the t-value on expected income and the chi-square statistic
[X.sup.2.sub.2] in row 2, Table 1). However, sentiment no longer
directly enters the estimated consumption equation (see the statistic
[X.sup.2.sub.1] in row 2, Table 1). This result suggests that sentiment
is not a direct determinant of household spending. Together these
results suggest that since consumption is directly correlated with
lagged income and wealth variables, their exclusion from the estimated
consumption equation spuriously generates the result that sentiment is a
direct determinant of household spending.
Row 3 in Table 1 estimates the consumption equation including
expected income, the real rate, and the lagged residual from the
cointegrating regression. As can be seen, consumption is sensitive to
the expected real rate as well as to expected income (see t-values on
these variables in row 3, Table 1). The lagged residual is also
significant in the estimated consumption equation. However, the
chi-square statistic [X.sup.2.sub.1] is small, implying that sentiment
does not enter directly into the estimated consumption equation.
[X.sup.2.sub.3] is the chi-square statistic that tests the hypothesis
that lagged sentiment is not significant in predicting the real rate.
This statistic is large, suggesting that sentiment does happen to
contain information about current real rates.
In the consumption regressions discussed above, including the
lagged residual from the cointegrating regression captures the
dependence of current consumption on lagged income and wealth variables.
The results do not change if the consumption equation is estimated
including also lagged consumption growth. Row 4 of Table 1 reports the
consumption regression estimated including three lagged values of
consumption, in addition to the lagged residual of the cointegrating
regression. As can be seen, the estimates are still consistent with the
basic result: sentiment is not an independent determinant of consumer
spending.
Row 5 in Table 1 presents the consumption equation estimated using
instruments dated t - 1 and earlier. The estimated coefficients that
appear on various variables change to a certain degree. However, the
estimates still are consistent with the basic result that lagged
sentiment is not a direct determinant of spending once we control for
the influences of current income, the real rate, and other lagged income
and wealth variables on spending. The results do not change if a
consumption equation similar to the one in row 4 is estimated using
instead the University of Michigan Total Sentiment Index (see row 6 in
Table l).
3. DISCUSSION OF RESULTS
The empirical work indicates that consumer sentiment has predictive
content for future changes in income and the real rate. (13) However,
sentiment has no predictive content for consumption once we control for
the influences of income and the real rate on consumption that work
through the contemporaneous income and interest rate channels. Together
these results suggest that sentiment is not a direct determinant of
spending. One possible interpretation of these results based on
Goodfriend's (1992) model discussed above is that sentiment surveys
enable households to discriminate better between aggregate and relative
shocks affecting their individual labor incomes, as sentiment surveys
are available before data on the direct determinants of aggregate income
are released. By sharpening the assessment of the current aggregate
income and hence the aggregate shock, sentiment surveys enable more and
more households to adjust their individual permanent incomes
appropriately, thereby bringing consumption more in line with permanent
income. If consumer sentiment surveys do help in this signal processing,
then one would expect a diminished role of lagged income and hence
lagged sentiment measures in predicting current consumption at the
aggregate level. Hence, one may find that sentiment has no direct role
in determining spending once one controls for the direct influence of
current aggregate income on spending.
The fact that sentiment measures are so eagerly awaited and watched
both in the financial press and by many serious economic analysts
suggests they may be useful in sharpening the assessment of agents for
the current state of the economy as measured by the behavior of
aggregate income. The empirical result here indicating that sentiment
measures lose their statistical significance in predicting current
spending once one controls for the influences of the current state of
the economy on spending suggests that these sentiment measures may have
value as a summary statistic for the future course of consumption.
4. CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
Consumer sentiment might help predict household spending, either
because sentiment is an independent determinant of spending or because
it foreshadows current economic conditions. In order to distinguish
empirically between these two interpretations of the predictive content
of sentiment, we estimate the consumption equation that nests both these
interpretations. In particular, consumer spending is assumed to be
sensitive to current income and the real rate, in addition to depending
upon lagged spending, income, wealth, and sentiment variables. The
response of spending to current income and the real rate is a proxy for
the influences of current economic conditions on spending, whereas the
response of spending to lagged sentiment is a proxy for the direct
influence of sentiment on spending. In previous research the predictive
content of sentiment has generally been investigated using consumption
equations without controlling for the sensitivity of current consumption
to the expected real rate and lagged income and wealth variables. The
results here indicate that lagged sentiment has no direct role in
predicting spending once we control for the direct influences of current
income, the real rate, and other lagged determinants on spending.
Another interesting result is that consumer sentiment does have
predictive content for future changes in income and the real rate,
suggesting that sentiment measures are useful as a good barometer of the
near-term course of the economy and hence consumption. Since in real
time consumer sentiment measures are released before aggregate data on
the current state of the economy are available, sentiment measures may
be helpful in assessing the near-term direction of the economy. This may
explain why sentiment measures are so eagerly awaited in the financial
press and by many economic analysts.
Table 1 Testing the Predictive Content of Sentiment
(A) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII TEXT]
[[lambda]. [[lambda]. [SIGMA]. [lambda].
Row sub.y] sub.r] [b.sub.o] sub.s] sub.rr]
1 0.53
(5.9)
2 0.57 -0.37
(6.3) (2.0)
3 0.49 0.20 -0.58 -0.37
(5.7) (1.8) (3.5) (2.4)
4 0.32 0.19 -0.60 0.32 -0.27
(2.3) (2.1) (3.7) (1.6) (2.1)
5 (a) 0.26 0.16 -0.71 0.39 -0.37
(3.3) (1.9) (5.2) (4.5) (3.3)
6 (b) 0.33 0.22 -0.58 0.33 -0.28
(2.3) (2.3) (3.5) (1.7) (2.0)
p-value of
[X.sup.2. [X.sub.2. [X.sup.2. [[barR]. overidentify
Row sub.1] sub.2] sub.3] sup.2] restrictions
1 14.7 * 10.8 * 0.03 0.14
2 3.21 11.5 * 0.01 0.61
3 3.2 12.8 * 23.1 * 0.20 0.84
4 0.71 12.7 * 23.0 * 0.46 0.91
5 (a) 1.5 12.7 * 60.5 * 0.49 0.78
6 (b) 1.8 8.3 * 15.1 * 0.44 0.95
Notes: The coefficients reported above are instrumental variables
estimates of the consumption equation (A) over 192Q1-2001Q2, C is
consumption growth; Y is income growth; r is the ral rate; (r * Vol)
is the real rate interacting with the interest rate vilatility
variable; and LRC is the residual from the cointegrating regression
(7) of the text. The instrumesnt used are a constant, four lagged
values of consumption growth, change from the contegrating regression.
Instruments are dated period t - 2 and earlier. [X.sup.2.sub.1]
when included in the pertinent consumption equations are zero.
[X.sub.2.sub.2] and [X.sub.2.sub.3] are chi-square statistics that
test the joint significance of coefficients that appear on four lags of
sentiment in the first-stage regressions for income and real rate.
The test for over-identifying restrictions tests whether the
instruments used are correlated with the residual of the estimated
comsumption equation.
(a) Instruments are dated t - 1 and earlier.
(b) Sentiment measure used is the Total Component of the University
of Michigan Sentiment Index.
* Significant at 0.05 level.
APPENDIX: QUESTIONS IN THE MICHIGAN SURVEYS OF CONSUMERS
The University of Michigan publishes an overall index of consumer
sentiment and two component indices measuring current economic
conditions and consumer expectations. The overall index is based on
answers to five survey questions, presented below. Two of the survey
questions are used to calculate the current conditions component, and
three questions underlie the expectations component.
Current Economic Conditions
Component Questions
Q1 = "We are interested in how people are getting along
financially these days. Would you say that you (and your family living
there) are better off or worse off financially than you were a year
ago?"
Q2 = "About the big things people buy for their homes--such as
furniture, a refrigerator, stove, television, and things like that.
Generally speaking, do you think now is a good or a bad time for people
to buy major household items?"
Expectations
Component Questions
Q3 = "Now looking ahead--do you think that a year from now you
(and your family living there) will be better off financially, or worse
off, or just about the same as now?"
Q4 = "Now turning to business conditions in the country as a
whole--do you think that during the next 12 months we'll have good
times financially, or bad times, or what?"
Q5 = "Looking ahead, which would you say is more likely--that
in the country as a whole we'll have continuous good times during
the next 5 years or so, or that we will have periods of widespread
unemployment or depression, or what?"
For details on the underlying methodology, see the papers,
including the one by Richard T. Curtin, available at the public access
Web site of the Institute for Social Research:
http://www.sca.isr.umich.edu/.
The authors would like to thank Robert Hetzel, Marvin Goodfriend,
and Roy Webb for many helpful comments. The views expressed herein do
not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or
the Federal Reserve System.
(1) We use the term causal to indicate the presence of Granger
causality, meaning that sentiment has incremental predictive content for
spending (Engle and Granger 1987).
(2) The sample period covered here differs from the one used in CFW
(1994), 1955Q1 to 1992Q3. We begin in 1959 motivated in part by the easy
availability of consistent time series data on all the variables used
here, including the series on household wealth.
(3) See, for example, Attanasio (1998) for a simple derivation of
the Euler consumption equation.
(4) The random walk result can also be derived using the permanent
income hypothesis (PIH) originally proposed in Friedman (1957). The
Friedman PIH allows for the presence of a transitory component in
measured consumption as well as in measured income. Permanent
consumption follows permanent income. In the Friedman PIH, measured
consumption is a random walk if permanent income follows a random walk
and if there is no transitory component in consumption. In order to
explain it further, consider the following time-series representation of
the Friedman PIH, as in Falk and Lee (1990): [C.sub.t] = [C.sub.pt] +
[delta.sub.t], [Y.sub.t] = [Y.sub.pt] + [eta.sub.t], and [C.sub.pt] =
[beta][Y.sub.pt], where [C.sub.t] and [Y.sub.t] are measured consumption
and measured income, [C.sub.pt] and [Y.sub.pt] are permanent consumption
and permanent income, and [delta.sub.t] and [eta.sub.t] are transitory
consumption and income. Transitory components are assumed to be white
noise disturbances mutually uncorrelated and uncorrelated with the
permanent components at all lags and leads. From this formulation, it is
quite clear that measured consumption is a random walk if [delta.sub.t]
= 0 for all t and if permanent income follows a random walk. However,
consumption may not follow a random walk if there is a serially
correlated transitory component in consumption, such as the one that may
arise from the presence of serially correlated preference shocks. In
that environment, permanent income may not be a random walk (Sargent
1987, 374).
(5) In reduced form regressions, spending is regressed on lagged
values of the sentiment and other economic indicators including changes
in income, the interest rate, stock prices, and the unemployment tale.
See. (or example. Leeper (1992), Carrol, Fuhrer, and Wilcox (1994), and
Brain and Ludvigson (1998).
(6) Pischke (1995) extends Goodfriend's argument to the
economy in which agents have no information on economy-wide variables.
(7) The quarterly data used are of vintage 2002. We truncate the
sample in 200lQ2 so that our results would not be affected by recent
developments pertaining to terrorism or the war in Iraq.
(8) As in most previous research, we present results using
disposable labor income rather than disposable personal income that also
includes property income. The evidence in previous research is
consistent with the presence of a different marginal propensity to
consume out of labor and property incomes. Since the empirical work here
includes the lagged residual from the cointegrating regression that
includes labor income and wealth, the consumption regression indirectly
captures the influence of property income. Labor income is defined as
wages and salaries + transfer payments + other labor income - personal
contributions for social insurance - taxes. Taxes are defined as [wages
and salaries/(wages and salaries + proprietor's income + rental
income + personal dividends + personal interest income)] personal tax
and nontax payments.
(9) We use the Expectations Component because we are interested in
examining the impact of beliefs about future economic conditions on
current spending. For robustness, we do examine results using the Total
Index. The results with the Total Index are qualitatively similar to
those with the Expectations Component (see, for example, row 6 of Table
1). See the Appendix for the list of questions included in the sentiment
surveys.
(10) The reported t-values have been correcting allowing for the
presence of fourth-order serial correlation, as indicated by the
underlying estimated autocorrelation coefficients.
(11) This test is performed by regressing the residual from the
instrumental variables regression on the instruments, and then comparing
T times the R-squared from this regression, where T is sample size, with
the chi-squared distribution with (K-1) degrees of freedom, K being the
number of estimated parameters (Campbell and Mankiw 1989).
(12) The evidence in Mehra (2003) also indicates that the period
from 1979 to the early 1980s accounts for the presence of negative
correlation between consumption and interest rate volatility found in
the full sample. This subperiod coincides with the Fed aggressively
raising real rates in order to fight inflation. The increased volatility
that accompanied the high level of real rates may have led to increased
uncertainty about future real rates, deterring substitution of
consumption in time. In view of this consideration, we further restrict
the interactive interest rate volatility variable to take nonzero values
only over the subperiod 1979Q3 to 1984Q4. However, results are
qualitatively the same if the interactive variable is entered without
the dummy as above (see Mehra 2003).
(13) An additional table containing these first-stage regressions
is available upon request from the authors.
REFERENCES
Attanasio, Orazio P. 1998. "Consumption Demand." NBER Working Paper 6466 (March).
Baxter, Mariane, and Urban J. Jermann. 1999. "Household
Production and the Excess Sensitivity of Consumption to Current
Income." American Economic Review 89 (September): 902-20.
Bram, Jason, and Sydney Ludvigson. 1998. "Does Consumer
Confidence Forecast Household Expenditure? A Sentiment Index Horse
Race." Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 4
(June): 59-78.
Campbell, John Y., and Gregory N. Mankiw. 1989. "Consumption,
Income, and Interest Rates: Re-interpreting the Time Series
Evidence." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by Olivier J.
Blanchard and Stanley Fischer. Cambridge: MIT Press.
--. 1990. "Permanent Income, Current Income and
Consumption." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 8 (July):
265-79.
Carroll, Christopher D., Jeffrey C. Fuhrer, and David W. Wilcox.
1994. "Does Consumer Sentiment Forecast Household Spending? If So,
Why?" American Economic Review 84 (December): 1397-1408.
Dynan, Karen E. 1993. "Habit Formation in Consumer
Preferences: Evidence from Panel Data." Working Paper 143, Economic
Activity Section, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Engle, Robert F., and C. W. Granger. 1987. "Co-integration and
Error-Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing."
Econometrica 55 (March): 251-76.
Falk, Barry, and Bong-Soo Lee. 1990. "Time-Series Implications
of Friedman's Permanent Income Hypothesis." Journal of
Monetary Economics 26 (October): 267-83.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Goodfriend, Marvin. 1992. "Information-Aggregation Bias."
American Economic Review 82 (June): 508-19.
Hall, Robert E. 1978. "The Stochastic Implications of the Life
Cycle-Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence." Journal of
Political Economy 86 (December): 971-87.
--. 1988. "Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption."
Journal of Political Economy 96 (April): 339-57.
Leeper, Eric M. 1992. "Consumer Attitudes: King for a
Day." In Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review (July):
1-15.
Mehra, Yash P. 2001. "The Wealth Effect in Empirical
Life-Cycle Aggregate Consumption Equations." Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Economic Quarterly 87 (Spring): 45-68.
--. 2003. "Fed Policy and Estimation of Intertemporal
Elasticity of Substitution in Consumption." Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, mimeo.
Nelson, Charles R. 1987. "A Reappraisal of Recent Tests of the
Permanent Income Hypothesis." Journal of Political Economy 95
(June): 641-46.
Pischke, Jorn-Steffen. 1995. "Individual Income, Incomplete
Information and Aggregate Consumption." Econometrica 63 (July):
805-40.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1987. Macroeconomic Theory. Orlando, Fla.:
Academic Press.