The economics of financial privacy: to opt out or opt in?
Lacker, Jeffrey M.
A consumer's financial transactions give rise to a wealth of
very personal data. Every credit card purchase, every ATM withdrawal,
every loan payment, every paycheck deposit leaves an electronic trace at
a person's bank. Advances in information technology now allow firms
to collate information from disparate sources and compile comprehensive
profiles of individual behavior. The resulting databases can allow
businesses to target very specific consumer categories--high-income,
gun-owning dog lovers, for example--in ways that were never before
possible.
When should a bank be able to share information about you with
other businesses? Some consumer advocates want to protect
consumers' financial privacy by restricting such information
sharing. New technologies, they say, have encouraged increased
intrusions on consumer privacy, leading to more junk mail, more
telemarketing calls, and a heightened risk of identity theft. They argue
for tough "opt-in" laws that would require financial
institutions to obtain a consumer's explicit consent before sharing
personal information about them.
Banks and other financial service providers point out that
information sharing provides benefits to consumers by allowing for more
targeted marketing and services. The new technologies make it easier for
businesses to find consumers that would be interested in buying their
specialized products and services--hunting-dog training supplies, for
example. Such marketing directly benefits consumers when it results in a
voluntary purchase. In addition, greater information sharing can reduce
wasteful marketing to consumers that are likely to be uninterested. With
these benefits in mind, financial service providers argue for
"opt-out" laws that merely require them to give consumers the
right to request that their information not be shared.
After vigorous debate, Congress adopted an opt-out requirement for
banks and other financial institutions as part of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley
Act of 1999 (GLBA), legislation that was designed to encourage financial
modernization. Any financial institution that intends to share nonpublic
customer information with third parties (companies not related by
ownership ties) must give customers an opportunity to deny them
permission to do so, or opt out. In addition, financial institutions are
required to provide customers with an annual statement of their privacy
policy. Consumers received a blizzard of notices in the mall when those
provisions were fully implemented in the summer of 2001. (1)
The controversy did not end with the passage of the GLBA. The Act
allows individual states to adopt privacy provisions that are stricter
than the federal standard if they so desire. California's
legislature recently considered an opt-in law that would have required
financial institutions to obtain customer permission before sharing
information with third parties. Moreover, banks would have been required
to give consumers the right to opt out of information sharing with
affiliated companies (companies related by ownership ties).
This essay examines the opt-out/opt-in debate from the perspective
of the economics of financial privacy. The premise is that a financial
institution's privacy policy is a characteristic of the products
and services the institution offers. We can therefore apply the
well-understood principles governing how markets work when there are
important differences in product characteristics. The result is
surprising for both sides of the issue: it doesn't seem to matter
whether opt-out or opt-in is adopted as the standard. Either way,
competitive forces should bring about an economically efficient amount
of information sharing. In fact, even in the absence of opt-out or
opt-in laws, the amount of information sharing should be economically
appropriate. Opt-out/opt-in laws will be irrelevant as long as financial
institutions are not prevented from offering customers a range of
desirable privacy options.
The broad and multifaceted issues that surround privacy go well
beyond the opt-out/opt-in debate. Although this essay is narrowly
focused on the latter, the general principles outlined here have a much
wider application. At a fundamental level, opt-out versus opt-in is
really a question about the proper allocation of "rights" in
contractual relationships--a customer's right to privacy versus the
right of a financial institution to share its information. The answer
economics provides is that whether rights are allocated in accord with
opt-out or opt-in is irrelevant, as long as consumers and financial
institutions are free to agree to an alternative arrangement if it suits
them. Most financial privacy questions concern the specification of
rights of various parties in contractual relationships. The irrelevance
result of this essay thus should carry over to other related settings;
laws and regulations providing more (or less) "privacy rights"
should generally have little effect on consumers' financial
privacy. (2)
1. PRIVACY IN THE FINANCIAL MARKETPLACE
Financial privacy can be thought of as a bundle of characteristics
associated with a particular financial service. A bank that does not
share nonpublic customer information with third parties is providing its
customers a service with different characteristics from a bank that does
share such information. How do markets work when products or services
differ in their characteristics?
In well-functioning competitive markets, consumers selecting among
products with different bundles of characteristics are willing to pay
more for products with characteristics they value. Some characteristics
make a product more costly to provide. Producers are willing to supply
products with more costly characteristics only if they are compensated
for the additional cost. One would expect to see products with
characteristics for which a customer's willingness to pay exceeds
the incremental production cost. For example, some people are willing to
pay more for a car with a built-in CD player, but CD players are costly.
It is logical then that consumers whose willingness to pay exceeds the
cost of the CD player would own cars with CD players.
Well-functioning markets generally provide goods and services that
are appropriate when judged against the benchmark of economic
efficiency. With regard to product characteristics, economic efficiency
means that a given product characteristic is supplied if and only if the
value of that characteristic to consumers exceeds its cost to society.
When markets function smoothly, the incentives of producers and
consumers are aligned with economic efficiency. Suppliers find it
profitable to provide products with the appropriate characteristics,
since consumers are willing to pay at least the additional cost.
Characteristics for which consumers' valuations fall short of the
cost of production cannot be profitably supplied.
Financial privacy is a service characteristic that some consumers
prefer. Many consumers harbor deep concerns about privacy in general and
financial privacy in particular. According to one recent poll, 56
percent of consumers say they are "very concerned" about
potential loss of privacy. (3) Overall, consumers seem to have three
main fears. (4) They fear being robbed or cheated by criminals that
obtain personal information. They fear embarrassing revelations due to
the disclosure of sensitive information. And they dislike intrusive
marketing in the form of telephone calls or junk mail. When financial
institutions share customer information with outside companies, it can
erode customer privacy on all three counts.
Providing greater financial privacy can be costly for a financial
service provider because it means foregoing the potential economic value
of information sharing. Marketers can make better decisions the more
information they have about prospective customers and are therefore
willing to pay banks to get it. Better information helps marketers find
customers who genuinely may be interested in buying their products and
saves them the expense of soliciting consumers who are not. These
benefits provide genuine economic value by increasing the probability of
a successful buyer-seller match and decreasing the probability of
wasting marketing efforts on those who would not be interested.
Consumers that place a high value on financial privacy ought to be
willing to pay for high-privacy financial services. If consumers prefer
that their bank not share nonpublic information about them with
unaffiliated companies, they should be willing to pay for this service
characteristic implicitly through lower deposit interest rates, higher
loan interest rates, or higher account-related fees. More directly,
banks could offer direct inducements--a bonus payment, coupon, or
sweepstakes entry, for example--to customers that agree to information
sharing. Many nonfinancial firms offer such enticements to customers
that return "product registration cards" filled out with their
name, address, and other information. Consumers that value financial
privacy would pay by foregoing their bank's offer. Similarly, many
grocery stores offer cards to customers that qualify them for discounts
when they present the cards at checkout stations. In exchange, stores
gather data on customer purchases.
Along the same lines, if sharing nonpublic customer information
with third parties is economically beneficial, financial institutions
should be willing to compensate their customers who allow them to do so.
(5) The outside firms with which the information is shared should be
willing to pay an amount up to the information's value to them. The
financial institution should then be willing to pass this along to their
customers in the form of higher interest rates on savings, lower
interest rates on loans, or lower fees. More directly, they should be
willing to simply pay those customers who agree to share an amount up to
the incremental value of the information.
Ideally, the economic benefits of financial privacy should be
balanced against the economic costs. When the economic value of sharing
nonpublic customer information with third parties falls short of the
value consumers place on preventing that information sharing, economic
efficiency would dictate that no information sharing takes place.
Similarly, when the economic value of sharing nonpublic customer
information with third parties exceeds the value consumers place on
preventing it, economic efficiency would dictate that information
sharing should take place. If the market for financial privacy is well
functioning, then we should see an economically efficient amount of
financial privacy.
2. DOES THE MARKET FOR FINANCIAL PRIVACY WORK WELL?
Is there anything different about financial privacy? Are the
markets for financial privacy poorly functioning in the sense that they
deliver outcomes that are not economically efficient? There does not
appear to be any plausible reason to think so.
For markets to misfunction in this sense, one of two conditions
must exist: either a divergence between the value of a product
characteristic to consumers and their willingness to pay it, or a
divergence between the cost to suppliers of providing that
characteristic and the overall cost to society. Divergences could be
caused by externalities, monopoly power, or verification problems.
An externality occurs when an action by one group affects the
well-being of others that do not transact with that group. For example,
burning leaves in my front yard raises the risk of fire for my suburban
neighbor. (6) Externalities are often invoked to explain a broad range
of government laws and regulations--prohibiting suburban leaf burning,
for example.
Is there an externality in the market for financial privacy? No, it
doesn't appear so. Sharing nonpublic customer information about a
consumer affects that consumer's privacy but not the privacy of
other consumers. The sharing institution is a counterparty of the
affected customer, and either can withdraw from the relationship. The
two of them have ample opportunity to take information sharing into
account when setting the terms of their relationship. Thus no parties
are affected by the information sharing except those who are
participants in the transaction.
"Public goods" are a type of externality that can result
in inefficiency and are defined by two properties. They are
nonrivalrous, meaning that one person's use does not detract from the ability of another to use it. And they are nonexcludable, meaning
that one cannot prevent people from using it. A lighthouse is a classic
example of a public good: one ship's use does not prevent another
ship's use, and you cannot prevent a ship from using it. (7)
Information is nonrivalrous because one person's use does not
prevent another from using the same information. But information is
excludable because you can prevent people from obtaining it. Therefore
financial information is not a public good.
Monopoly power is another possible cause of market misfunction.
When a firm is sheltered from competitive pressures it can raise prices
and restrain supply. Similarly, a protected monopolist may find it
profitable to supply too little of a desired product characteristic when
customers are prevented from seeking preferred characteristics from
other suppliers. This problem may have been relevant to the banking
industry decades ago when competition was severely limited by regulatory
restrictions on pricing, entry, and geographic expansion, but these
restrictions have been largely dismantled. As a consequence, the market
for financial services is now widely judged to be relatively
competitive. Thus it seems unlikely that banks or other financial
institutions are manipulating privacy policies because of significant
monopoly power. (8)
A third potential cause of market misfunction stems from the
difficulty of verifying whether a financial institution is living up to
its stated privacy policy. A customer that receives junk mail or
telemarketing calls may have a hard time discerning where the marketer
obtained the information. The spelling of a name or address can be
altered slightly in order to trace information sharing, but this
technique is obviously limited. In cases of identity theft it is often
impossible to determine exactly how the identity was stolen after the
fact.
Do verification problems interfere with the efficiency of the
market for financial privacy? Not necessarily. Note that there are a
number of mechanisms to help ensure that an institution lives up to its
privacy commitments, despite the difficulty of observing whether or not
it has done so. First, an institution that fails to comply with its
stated financial privacy policy may be liable for "unfair and
deceptive trade practices." If caught, the institution would be
subject to civil litigation as well as regulatory action by the Federal
Trade Commission. The potential legal costs can deter noncompliance,
even if the probability of detection is small. There is nothing
particularly unique about financial privacy in this regard. Consumers
often rely on hard-to-verify commitments by the firms they patronize--a
commitment to product quality, for example.
Second, institutions that wish to attract customers for whom
privacy is important will want to convince those customers of their
organization's commitment to its privacy policy. Such institutions
will have an incentive to cultivate and safeguard their reputation as a
high-privacy entity. At least one prominent bank has advertised a
"no telemarketing" promise, indicating that banks are capable
of actively competing on the basis of their privacy policies. (9) Third
parties can evaluate a financial institution's compliance, just as
Consumer Reports independently assesses the quality of consumer
products. The potential for embarrassing media publicity also motivates
an institution to live up to its commitments. Standard industry practice
is for a firm that rents its mailing list to approve every mailing or
telemarketing script that is used. Evidently firms believe that at least
some consumers could trace marketing contacts to them, with possibly
detrimental effects on their customer relationships.
While reputational considerations and laws on trade practices can
go partway toward ensuring that a firm is faithful to its stated privacy
policy, some would argue that these mechanisms are inherently limited
and imperfect. Enforcement is often costly and compliance is rarely 100
percent. Do these imperfections warrant legislative restrictions aimed
specifically at information sharing? No. Any entity attempting to verify
and enforce a financial firm's privacy commitments will confront
the same imperfections. A governmental effort to enforce a ban on
information sharing, for example, will face the same verification
difficulties--costly enforcement and incomplete compliance--as would any
private parties. So a government ban on information sharing would have
no advantage; in fact, it would have the disadvantage of possibly
preventing economically useful information sharing.
The market for financial privacy therefore appears to work fairly
well. This means that we should expect economically efficient outcomes:
information will be shared if and only if the economic benefits of
information sharing exceed the value consumers place on preventing
information sharing.
3. OPT-OUT VERSUS OPT-IN
Provided the market for financial privacy works fairly well, it
should not make much difference whether we adopt an opt-outlaw or an
opt-in law. Either way, an economically efficient level of information
sharing will result. Why is this so?
Under an opt-outlaw, banks that value information sharing will be
willing to provide inducements to get high-privacy customers not to opt
out because information sharing can lower the cost of providing banking
services. Similarly, automakers are willing to discount the price of
cars without CD players, since these cars are less costly to build.
Banks will be willing to pay an amount up to the incremental value of
sharing the customer's nonpublic information. If that falls short
of the value the customer implicitly places on privacy, then the
customer will decline the inducement and opt out. In that case, the
economic value of the information sharing is less than the cost to the
customer of yielding this bit of privacy, and information sharing is not
economically efficient. Alternatively, the customer may feel that the
value of the inducement exceeds the value of preventing information
sharing, in which case the inducement is accepted and the customer does
not opt out. Here, the economic value of the informati on sharing
exceeds the cost to the customer of yielding this bit of privacy, and
information sharing is economically efficient.
Under an opt-in law, the reasoning and the result are exactly the
same. Banks will be willing to provide the same inducement to get a
customer to opt in as they would have provided to get a customer to
refrain from opting out--up to the economic value of the information
sharing. If that amount exceeds the value that the customer places on
preventing information sharing, then information sharing will take place
and is economically efficient. Otherwise the customer will refuse the
enticement; in this case information sharing is not economically
efficient and will not take place.
In fact, the same reasoning applies in the absence of opt-out or
opt-in laws. If the law is silent on whether banks need to seek
permission to share nonpublic information with third parties, banks
nonetheless could decide to do so on their own. If some customers truly
care about information sharing with third parties, they will seek out
banks that give them the option of preventing it. If information sharing
is economically useful, banks will find it more costly to serve
customers that insist on preventing it. Competition will force banks to
pass along the increased cost to high-privacy customers. Ultimately, an
economically appropriate amount of information sharing will take place,
with or without opt-out or opt-in laws.
The difference between opt-out and opt-in standards is like the
difference between treating CD players in cars as standard equipment or
as an add-on option. If CD players are an option, one would expect the
price of the option to reflect the incremental cost. If instead CD
players are standard equipment, the discount for cars without CD players
should reflect the incremental cost. It should not make a difference
whether car buyers have to ask to get a CD player in their car or ask
not to have one. Either way we should see a market-clearing quantity of
cars with CD players.
The debate between proponents of opt-out and opt-in seems
predicated on the view that the choice would affect how many consumers
would prevent information sharing. The hypothesis seems to be that fewer
consumers would opt out under an opt-out standard than would fail to opt
in under an opt-in standard. This could well be the case, but it would
be evidence that many consumers are relatively indifferent about
information sharing by their financial institution; they would not
bother to opt out, nor would they bother to opt in. If this is true,
then little is at stake for these consumers. Those who would neither opt
out nor opt in evidently place little value on preventing their
financial institution from sharing nonpublic information about them. The
economic efficiency implications of the choice between opt-out and
opt-in would therefore be negligible for them as well, even if
participation rates differed significantly.
4. AN ALTERNATIVE LINE OF REASONING: THE COASE THEOREM
The knowledgeable reader may have noticed that the logic of this
essay is closely related to the insights that Ronald H. Coase presented
in his celebrated paper "The Problem of Social Cost." (10)
(This paper was cited by the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences in
awarding him the 1991 Nobel Prize in Economics.) Coase wrestled with the
issue of externalities, the same issue as in my leaf-burning example.
Before Coase's paper economists generally believed that, absent
government intervention, externalities would result in inefficient
outcomes because one party (I, for example) would ignore the cost
(increased fire hazard) that his action (leaf burning) imposed on
another party (my neighbor). The contribution of Coase was to notice
that the two parties could negotiate an efficient solution to the
externality problem as long as the relevant rights were clearly
assigned. For example, if I am entitled to burn leaves, my neighbor
could offer to pay me not to, or could offer to help me dispose of them
by some other met hod. Alternatively, if I am required to obtain my
neighbor's permission to burn leaves, I could offer to pay my
neighbor. If the value to me of burning leaves is less than the value to
my neighbor of my not burning leaves, then my neighbor will pay me not
to do so in the first case. In the second case, I will be unwilling to
offer my neighbor enough money to get permission to burn leaves. Either
way we get an efficient outcome; I don't burn leaves. The general
proposition is that (under certain conditions) any well-defined
allocation of property rights leads to efficient outcomes. This result
is often called the Coase Theorem.
The application to financial privacy should be clear. Opt-out and
opt-in are just different allocations of property rights. Opt-out means
financial institutions have the right to share information; customers
can ask them to stop. Opt-in means customers have the right to
no-information-sharing; financial institutions can ask them for
permission to share. Either way, according to Coase, the prediction is
an efficient amount of information sharing.
The Coase Theorem has its limitations, however. It is said to hold
only if "transaction costs" are zero; in other words, any
agreement that is in the mutual interest of the parties is actually
agreed upon. Transaction costs are the difficulties associated with
actually reaching an agreement among the affected parties. It may be
costly to communicate and coordinate among a large number of parties,
for example. When transaction costs are significant, the assignment of
property rights can affect efficiency. One premise of this essay, as I
discuss later, is that the costs of opting out are negligible, in which
case the Coase Theorem applies. (11)
The logic of this essay, however, differs subtly from Coase's
analysis. Coase envisioned bargaining between affected parties. As a
result, the assignment of property rights could alter the distribution
of net benefits, even if that assignment had no effect on efficiency.
For example, if I have the right to burn leaves, I get paid not to burn
them; yet if I need permission, I earn nothing when I don't burn
them. I am better off in the first case, while my neighbor is better off
in the second case. The assignment of rights thus alters the relative
wellbeing of my neighbor and me, even though either assignment leads to
efficient leaf-burning decisions. In competitive markets, in contrast,
the assignment of contractual rights generally does not affect
people's well-being. The choice between opt-out and opt-in
determines which rights are, by default, bundled together with financial
services. Under either regime, competition and free entry implies that
both high-privacy and low-privacy financial services will be av ailable
at prices reflecting their true cost. In competitive markets, the choice
of regime should have no effect on the net cost of financial services
with particular characteristics, just as a law mandating that CD players
be sold separately should have no effect on the total price of cars with
CD players. The efficiency implication of Coase's famous theorem carries over to competitive markets, however, and buttresses the case
made here: market mechanisms should work well at providing an efficient
level of financial privacy.
5. OPT-OUT IN PRACTICE: FEW CONSUMERS DO
During the first half of 2001, many banks began mailing out the
privacy notices required by the GLBA. Those that share nonpublic
customer information with unaffiliated companies are required to give
their customers the opportunity to opt out of third-party information
sharing. Although there is only limited evidence so far, press reports
suggest that the response rate is rather low. According to the trade
publication American Banker, industry estimates of the number of
consumers who have opted out "hover around 5 percent." (12)
One survey of savings banks showed that more than half were experiencing
an opt-out rate of one percent or less. (13)
Opting out does not appear to be very hard. The financial privacy
regulations require that financial institutions give customers a
"reasonable means" of exercising their right to opt out. The
regulations even offer examples of acceptable and unacceptable methods.
Providing a toll-free number to call or supplying a mail-in card for a
check-box response are deemed reasonable means. Requiring a customer to
write his or her own letter is not deemed reasonable.
Despite these requirements, critics claim that opting out is
difficult because privacy notices are complex, confusing, and hard to
read. (14) Food labels are often cited, in contrast, as a simple,
well-understood notice system. Some financial institutions, however, are
actively working toward simpler and clearer privacy notices. (15)
Apparently, they view that it is in their business interest to make
their notices as agreeable to their customers as possible. Many
institutions sent privacy notices for the first time in 2001, and some
experimentation and learning seem to be taking place. Perhaps opt-out
rates will rise as GLBA privacy notices are refined and consumers learn
about what they contain.
Nevertheless, the fact that so few bank customers are currently
taking the relatively easy step of opting out seems to indicate that
most consumers now place a negligible value on preventing financial
institutions from sharing nonpublic information about them with third
parties. A small fraction of consumers feel strongly enough to take
advantage of the opt-out option. This group appears to place a
significant value on guarding their financial privacy. But for a broad
majority of Americans, the value they place on financial privacy does
not exceed the inconvenience of exercising their right to opt out. (16)
This pattern--about 5 percent of people willing to take action to
protect their privacy--is consistent with other evidence on
consumers' privacy preferences. The Direct Marketing Association, a
marketing industry trade group, offers consumers the ability to opt out
of telephone or mail marketing by their members. The 4.2 million
participants in their telephone opt-out program represent about 4.2
percent of U.S. households with telephone service. The 4.0 million
participants in their mail opt-out program represent about 3.8 percent
of total U.S. households. (17)
A very low opt-out rate is also consistent with other choices
consumers make with regard to privacy. Few consumers disable cookies
when browsing the Internet. (Cookies are small files that a Web site
places on a user's computer to enable tracking the user on
subsequent visits.) Few consumers read privacy notices. Many consumers
readily provide their credit card number over the phone or to a waiter.
(18) The picture that emerges, then, is that a few consumers place
significant value on preventing information sharing by their financial
institutions, but the broad majority of consumers are relatively
indifferent.
6. OPT-OUT IN PRACTICE: FEW BANKS PAY
Financial institutions do not appear to be offering inducements to
customers to get them to refrain from opting out. This suggests that the
economic value of sharing nonpublic customer information is relatively
low. Otherwise financial institutions would find it worthwhile to
compensate their customers for their cooperation. In fact, not all
institutions are even engaged in information sharing that would trigger
the opt-out requirement. A survey of savings banks found that fewer than
one-third needed to send out opt-out notices. (19)
Banks do not lack opportunities to share customer information.
There is an active market for consumers' names, addresses, and
other personal information. Individual merchants rent their customer
lists to marketers, often through list brokers. Credit bureaus offer
selections from their databases based on age, income, occupation, family
status, net worth, type of automobile, religion, and so on. According to
its Web site, Equifax even offers a selection based on a person's
carburetor type. American Express offers customer lists selected on the
basis of purchase patterns--shoe buyers that spend more than $1000
annually, for example. Lists are available from magazines, membership
organizations, book clubs, and merchants. (20)
Apparently, the market for consumer information does not provide
banks with sharing opportunities that would make it worthwhile to offer
material rewards for consumer cooperation. A glance at the prices for
such information suggests why--prices are relatively low. Rates for
lists of merchandise buyers, for example, appear to be relatively
consistent, ranging from 8 cents to 13 cents per name as of early 2001.
Base prices at one large credit bureau range from 1.65 to 4 cents per
name per mailing, depending on volume, with add-on charges for
additional selection criteria ranging from .25 cents per name for length
of residence, title, or gender to 2 cents per name for net worth. Thus
the value to a financial institution of sharing nonpublic customer
information might not be large enough to warrant offering a significant
sum to customers.
7. WHY IS FINANCIAL PRIVACY AN ISSUE NOW?
Applying economics to financial privacy leads to the conclusion
that financial markets can provide an appropriate balance between
consumers' desires for privacy and the economic value of
information sharing. If this is true, then why do surveys show
widespread consumer concern about privacy yet few consumers taking
action to opt out of information sharing? And why has there been such
clamor for privacy legislation in the past few years, culminating in the
financial privacy provisions of the GLBA?
The dramatic changes in communications and computing technologies
in recent years might help explain why so many recent surveys report
consumer concern about privacy. Financial institutions have always
possessed detailed information about their customers. Moreover, active
markets for customer lists have been around for decades. (21) Only
recently, however, has the collation and analysis of information from
disparate sources become highly automated. This technological advance
allows more targeted marketing efforts; a company can solicit
high-income, gun-owning dog lovers, for example. The resulting
improvement in marketing success rates appears to have led to an
increase in the number of mail and telephone solicitations.
Before the technological developments that lowered the cost of
manipulating databases, assembling such detailed consumer profiles was
not economically feasible. Consumers came to view the limited nature of
information sharing by financial institutions as an implicit part of
their contractual relationship, relying on the practical obscurity of
what other firms knew about them. (22) Since widespread information
sharing was impractical then, few surveys asked how consumers felt about
it. New technologies have dispersed the fog of practical obscurity that
formerly surrounded many consumer transactions. The privacy concerns
that appear in consumer surveys could represent ex post regret at the
lack of contractual constraints on information sharing. This conflicts,
however, with the evidence cited earlier indicating that most consumers
do not feel strongly about information sharing. Alternatively, perhaps
consumer preferences haven't changed, but consumers are merely
asked about them more often today. Now that inter firm information
sharing is economically viable, we see surveys on the subject.
Economists are often skeptical of survey evidence on consumer
preferences, but it is not the sincerity of consumers' responses
that is in doubt. Surveys rarely confront consumers with the cost
consequences of their choices. When asked whether they desire greater
privacy without reference to cost, they are likely to say
"yes"--more of a good is generally preferred to less, after
all. But when confronted with real-life choices, many consumers decide
that the benefits of greater privacy are outweighed by the costs. One
recent study found a dramatic disparity between consumers' stated
privacy preferences and their actual online behavior. (23) Participants
answered many "highly personal" questions, despite having
stated that privacy was important to them. The discrepancy between
widespread consumer "concern" and the willingness of many
consumers to readily compromise their privacy could well reflect the gap
between the artificial choices implicit in survey questions and the real
choices consumers actually face. (24)
8. CONCLUSION
The economics of financial privacy is based on the notion that a
financial institution's privacy policy is a characteristic
associated with the products and services the institution offers. In
well-functioning markets, prices reflect product characteristics;
consumers are willing to pay more for characteristics they value, and
producers charge more for characteristics that are more costly to
supply. Consumers that value financial privacy ought to be willing to
pay for privacy policies that they prefer. And if it is economically
beneficial to share information with other companies, financial
institutions ought to be willing to compensate their customers for
permission to do so. The fact that few banks seem to be paying customers
not to opt out is strong evidence that the economic value of information
sharing is relatively small. And the fact that so few consumers are
opting out, despite the low cost of doing so, is evidence that few
consumers place a significant value on preventing information sharing.
This line of reasoning also leads to a stark and surprising
conclusion: the choice between opt-out and opt-in standards is
irrelevant. Under an opt-out standard, banks could pay customers to
refrain from opting out, while under an opt-in standard banks could pay
customers to opt in. Either way, financial markets should deliver an
efficient amount of information sharing. One puzzle remains, however:
Why is financial privacy such a controversial issue if few consumers
care enough about preventing information sharing to take simple steps to
prevent it? Nevertheless, the economics of the issue is clear--financial
privacy laws like the GLBA accomplish less than either privacy advocates
or their critics presume.
(1.) The deadline for compliance was July 1, 2001. For more
information on the financial privacy provisions of the GLBA, see the
Federal Trade Commission's Web site (Federal Trade Commission
2002). The privacy provisions of the GLBA apply to any institution
engaged in activities that have been deemed "financial in nature or
incidental to such financial activities" under the Bank Holding
Company Act. This means that whenever the Fed and the Treasury determine
that an activity is financial in nature and therefore a permissible
activity for a financial holding company, the entire financial industry
is brought under the privacy provisions of the GLBA.
(2.) For other economic analyses of financial privacy. see Kahn,
McAndrews, and Roberds (2000) and Bauer (forthcoming).
(3.) National Consumers League (2000).
(4.) Research by Alan Westin, as cited in Paul (2001).
(5.) See Kovacevich (2000).
(6.) One could argue that the two parties could negotiate an
efficient solution to this problem; my neighbor can simply pay me not to
burn leaves, or can sue me if the fire spreads. For additional
explanation see the section on the Coase Theorem.
(7.) Coase (1974) pointed out, however, that coastal lighthouses
are often funded from fees charged to ships using nearby ports, so even
the services of lighthouses are at times excludable. A lighthouse is
therefore only a public good when ships cannot be excluded from using
its services if they do not pay--for example, in settings where most
ships are on long-distance voyages.
(8.) If financial institutions were exercising market power and
this resulted in inefficient financial product characteristics, a more
appropriate remedy would be for regulators to ensure effective
competition rather than regulate service characteristics. Moreover, it
would appear inconsistent to regulate service characteristics on the
grounds of impediments to competition while not regulating service
prices.
(9.) The phrase appeared in television advertising for Capital One
during November 2001. As of this writing (January 17. 2002), the
company's home page prominently features the following description
of their "New No-Hassle Card": "9.9% Fixed APR on
Everything, No Telemarketing, No Annual Fee."
(10.) Coase (1960).
(11.) The costs are negligible in part because of the regulations
that require financial institutions to provide customers with a
"reasonable means" of opting out. In a sense, then, this part
of the allocation of property rights has efficiency implications
consistent with the Coase Theorem. The reasonable-means provision
appears to be an efficient choice since it minimizes the
"transaction costs" of opting out. Friedman (2000) applies
Coase's approach to a broad array of privacy issues in which
transaction costs are nonnegligible.
(12.) Lee (2001).
(13.) America's Community Bankers (2001).
(14.) See transcripts and supporting documentation from the
workshop on effective privacy notices hosted by the Federal Trade
Commission and the federal financial regulatory agencies (Federal Trade
Commission 2001).
(15.) See the presentations by Marty Abrams, John Dugan, Patricia
Faley, and David M. Klaus at the privacy notices workshop along with the
public comments submitted by Walter Kitchenman, Vance Gudmundsen, and
Steve Bartlett in connection with the event (Federal Trade Commission
2001).
(16.) One could argue that consumers are just lazy, but this
reasoning leads to the same conclusion; the value they place on
financial privacy is not enough to motivate them to opt out.
(17.) The three main credit bureaus also offer a program through
their trade group that allows consumers to opt out of pre-approved
credit offers, but the credit bureaus do not release statistics on the
number of consumers opting out.
(18.) According to a recent survey, 24 percent of consumers protect
their privacy by disabling cookies (Harris Interactive Inc. 2001). An
American Bankers Association poll found that 36 percent of consumers
said they had read their bank's privacy notice (American Bankers
Association 2001).
(19.) America's Community Bankers (2001).
(20.) For information on lists see Equifax (2001), American List
Counsel (2002), and Worldata (2002).
(21.) I recall my father managing rentals of his company's
mailing list in the 1960s. The list was kept on "addressograph
plates"--metal strips embossed with names and addresses. While
these strips could be linked together for automated addressing of mass
mailings, any sorting or selection had to be handled manually. The list
was rented out through mailing houses that handled the actual printing
and distribution. All rentals had to be approved by list owners.
Decoys--false names and addresses--were included in the list to provide
a means of verification by the list owner.
(22.) Gramlich (1999).
(23.) Spiekermann, Grossklags, and Berendt (no date available).
(24.) Harper and Singleton (2001).
REFERENCES
American Bankers Association. 2001. "ABA Survey Shows Nearly
One Out of Three Consumers Read Their Banks' Privacy Notices."
News Release (7 June).
American List Counsel. 2002. http://www.amlist.com [17 January].
America's Community Bankers. 2001. "ACB Privacy
Compliance Survey." Manuscript (November).
Bauer, Paul. "Consumer's Financial Privacy and the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act." Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic
Commentary (forthcoming).
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. "The Problem of Social Cost."
Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 1-44.
-----. 1974. "The Lighthouse in Economics." Journal of
Law and Economics 17 (October): 357-76.
Equifax. 2001. TotalSourceXL. Consumer Database (Fall).
http://www.equifax.com/business_solutions/information_services/docume
nts/Fall_2001_TotalSource_XL_Rate_Card.pdf [17 January 2002].
Federal Trade Commission. 2001. Interagency public workshop
entitled Get Noticed: Effective Financial Privacy Notices, 4 December,
at The Ronald Reagan Building and International Trade Center,
Washington, D.C. http://www.ftc.gov/bcp/workshops/glb/index.html [17
January 2002].
-----. 2002. "Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act: Financial Privacy and
Pretexting." http://www.ftc.gov/privacy/glbact/index.htm1 [17
January].
Friedman, David. 2000. "Privacy and Technology." Social
Philosophy & Policy 17 (Summer): 186-212.
Gramlich, Edward M. 1999. "Statement to the U.S. House
Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit of the
Committee on Banking and Financial Services." 21 July 1999. Federal
Reserve Bulletin 85 (September): 624-26.
Harper, Jim, and Solveig Singleton. 2001. "With a Grain of
Salt: What Consumer Privacy Surveys Don't Tell Us."
Manuscript, Competitive Enterprise Institute (June).
Harris Interactive Inc. 2001 "A Survey of Consumer Privacy
Attitudes and Behaviors." Manuscript.
Kahn, Charles M., James McAndrews, and William Roberds. 2000.
"A Theory of Transactions Privacy." Working Paper 2000-22.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Kovacevich, Richard M. 2000. "Privacy and the Promise of
Financial Modernization." The Region 14 (March): 27-29.
Lee, W. A. 2001. "Opt-Out Notices Give No One a Thrill."
American Banker (10 July).
National Consumers League. 2000. "Online Americans More
Concerned about Privacy than Health Care, Crime, and Taxes, New Survey
Reveals." News Release (4 October).
Paul, Pamela. 2001. "Mixed Signals." American
Demographics 23 (March): 45-49.
Spiekermann, Sarah, Jens Grossklags, and Bettina Berendt. No date
available. "Stated Privacy Preferences versus Actual Behaviour in
EC environments: A Reality Check." Manuscript, Humboldt University.
Worldata. 2002. Worldata & WebConnect Online Datacard Library.
Online database. http://www.worldata.com [17 January].
The author is Senior Vice President and Director of Research. This
article first appeared in the Bank's 2001 Annual Report. It
benefited from the comments of the author's colleagues in the
Bank's Research Department, especially John weinberg. Marvin
Goodfriend, Laura Fortunato, Ned Prescott, Aaron Steelman, and John
Walter, and from the assistance of Elise Couper. The views expressed are
the author's and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.