Competition among bank regulators.
Weinberg, John A.
The organization of bank regulation in the United States is
somewhat peculiar. Banks answer to an array of regulators, both federal
and state. To begin with, a bank can choose a national or a state
charter. National banks are regulated by the Office of the Comptroller
of the Currency (OCC). State banks are regulated by their home states,
as well as by a federal regulator. The Federal Reserve System regulates
state-chartered banks that are Federal Reserve members, and the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) regulates state, nonmember banks. A
bank, by its choice of charter and Federal Reserve membership, chooses
its regulators. There is a sense, then, in which U.S. federal bank
regulators are in competition with each other. How does this competition
affect bank regulation in the United States? On the one hand, one might
conclude that the need to compete with other agencies would motivate a
regulator to perform its tasks as effectively and efficiently as
possible. On the other hand, one might argue tha t the desire to attract
more clients could drive a regulatory agency to be loose.
Banking is not the only industry in which alternative regulatory
agencies compete with one another. Most other instances, however,
involve different geographic jurisdictions. For instance, to the extent
that environmental regulations vary from state to state, a
manufacturer's decision on plant location entails a choice among
potential regulators. The stringency of such regulations then has the
potential to become one tool by which states compete to attract
businesses. One could ask the same question about this competition as is
often asked about the interaction among bank regulators. Does
competition lead to effective or excessively loose environmental
control?
When the effects of the regulated activity, polluting for instance,
are predominantly local, geographic regulatory competition, as in the
case of state-level environmental rules, is analogous to the
jurisdictional competition studied by Tiebout (1956). Tiebout's
direct concern was the provision of "local public goods" by
local governments funded with local taxes in a setting with a mobile
population. His conclusion was that competition in the joint setting of
taxes and levels of public goods and services would lead to efficient
levels of government expenditures. The same logic applies to local
regulation of activities with local effects.
Bank regulation, however, does not have the same geographical
limits as some environmental regulation. While state banks are regulated
locally by state supervisory agencies, all banks have federal
regulators. Further, a bank can change its federal regulator without
having to relocate or make any other significant change in its
activities. In this environment, does the Tiebout logic of beneficial
competition still apply?
This article highlights how the effects of alternative regulatory
structures depend on assumptions about such underlying factors as the
regulators' objectives, and the way in which regulators' costs
are financed. This point can best be made in the context of a model that
captures important elements of bank and bank regulator activities.
Section 2 presents such a model. The model's emphasis is on the
role of bank examinations in assessing the quality of bank assets in the
presence of deposit insurance. In the context of this model, an
efficient regulatory policy is defined. Possible regulatory outcomes are
then studied under alternative assumptions about regulators'
preferences regarding banking industry performance and the extent to
which deposit insurance and bank examination are integrated activities
financed under a consolidated budget constraint. In some cases,
regulatory competition leads to efficient policy choices, while in
others competition results in inefficient outcomes. Notably, when the
financing of regulation and deposit insurance is not integrated,
competition among regulators can impose excessive costs on deposit
insurance.
1. BACKGROUND
In discussions about rivalry among alternative bank regulators, a
common concern is that regulators will "race to the bottom."
Each regulator, it is argued, will want to attract as many banks into
its constituency as possible. Further, this incentive to attract
"client" banks will outweigh the regulators' interest in
controlling bank risk-taking incentives. This so-called
"competition in laxity" will result in excessive costs to the
deposit insurance system. The possibility of a race to the bottom, as
discussed by Scott (1977), has partly motivated a number of proposals
for the consolidation of federal bank regulation.
The notion that competition might result in excessively lax or
otherwise inefficient regulation is not unique to banking. In the
general area of corporate governance and the market for corporate
control, it has been argued that states compete to be corporations'
charter locations by passing laws that inhibit corporate takeovers.
Since incumbent managers make location decisions, they might be
influenced by laws that protect their incumbency. Karpoff and Malatesta,
for instance (1989), report evidence that supports this hypothesis.
Similar arguments have been made about local environmental controls when
the effects of pollution extend beyond the local area. Local governments
and their constituents enjoy the economic benefits of a
manufacturer's decision to locate in their area but the
environmental cost is shared more widely.
These assertions that regulation results in a "race to the
bottom" by economic efficiency standards stand in sharp contrast to
Tiebout's notion of beneficial competition. The key difference is
seen in the example of environmental controls. Tiebout's result
applies when both the costs and the benefits of the pollution-generating
activity accrue to the constituents of the local governmental decision
maker. Inefficient regulatory choices are more likely to arise when the
costs spill over between localities.
The clean dichotomy between beneficial and harmful regulatory
competition relies on an additional important assumption involving the
governmental decision makers' objectives. In the case of
environmental regulation, the assumption is essentially that the local
government acts to maximize its constituents' welfare. Other
objectives are also possible, however. Stigler (1971) and Peltzman
(1976), and the extensive literature that follows their seminal work emphasize the political economy of interest groups as a determining
factor in regulatory decisions. Along these lines, one idea that is
often voiced is that of "regulatory capture." This term
expresses the notion that regulatory actions may be driven more by the
interests of the firms in the regulated industry than by considerations
of general or consumer welfare. In reference to banking in particular,
Kane (1996) has suggested that regulators' self-interest can shape
the outcomes of regulation. But there are alternative assumptions that
one might make about r egulators' objectives. One possibility is
that individuals who have some discretion in choosing regulatory actions
might be motivated by their personal reputations and career concerns.
Another possibility, particularly relevant to settings where regulators
can compete with one another, is that agencies seek to maximize their
influence by regulating a large portion of the industry.
Clearly, the effects of competition among regulators could depend
on regulators' motivations. In a setting of regulatory capture,
competition could exacerbate the tendency to weigh the interests of the
regulated industry above consumer welfare. If regulators are concerned
for their personal reputations, their behavior and their response to
competition would depend further on how they believe industry outcomes
affect their reputations. For instance, a concern for reputation might
cause bank regulators to be conservative, preventing banks from taking
actions that might have bad outcomes. Competition could counter this
tendency by inducing regulators to loosen their control of risk taking
in order to attract more client banks. While empirical evidence on the
behavior of bank regulators and the effects of regulatory competition is
sparse, Rosen (2001) has recently studied the characteristics and
behavior of banks that switch their federal regulator. He finds evidence
consistent with the idea that competition can be beneficial, as banks
tend to improve their performance following a switch.
In addition to the underlying motives of regulators, another key
factor affecting the way regulators behave under competition is the
means of financing regulatory costs. A regulator that must cover all of
its costs out of fees that it charges to its regulated businesses might
behave quite differently from one that draws on general public funding.
This distinction has in fact been highlighted in some recent discussions
about the organization of bank regulation. The OCC, for instance, covers
its expenses from examination fees, while the FDIC bundles regulation
with deposit insurance, paying for both out of deposit insurance
premiums. The OCC has argued (for example, in Hawke, 2002) that this
difference can distort banks choices among their alternative federal
regulators.
The following section sets out a model that focuses on the choice
of a regulatory mechanism to control the risk-taking incentives of banks
with insured deposits. That basic model provides a framework that allows
the consideration of a number of alternative assumptions about the
organization, financing, and motivation of regulators. An underlying
assumption is that regulators have some discretion in choosing the
parameters of their regulatory behavior. In the model, the key parameter is the frequency of examinations. While the actual degree of discretion
exercised by bank regulators on this dimension is limited by statute, it
is clear that, more generally, regulatory agencies have discretion over
the intensity and informativeness of examinations, variables that would
have the same effect as the simple probability that is chosen in the
model.
2. A MODEL OF BANK REGULATION
A bank will be represented as an agent making an investment
decision. The bank raises funds by issuing fully insured deposits.
Depositors, therefore, are not particularly interesting actors in this
model, as they supply funds perfectly elastically at the risk-free
rate-of-return, normalized to zero. A bank raises a fixed amount of
deposits, D, and can place funds into one of two investment projects,
represented as "actions" [a.sub.0] and [a.sub.1]. Each action
results in a probability distribution over the set of possible outcomes,
R = {-[theta], -1, 1, [theta]}, where 1 < [theta] < D. The outcome
is the bank's income (or loss), net of payment to depositors. Let
P(a) denote the vector of probabilities if action a is taken. The
specification of P([a.sub.0]) and P([a.sub.1]) is meant to capture the
notion that one of the actions, [a.sub.0], results in both higher risk
and lower expected return than the other. A simple specification that
captures this dominance is P([a.sub.0]) = ((1 - [p.sub.0]), 0, 0,
[p.sup.0]) and P([a.sub.1]) = (0, (1 - [p.sub.1]), [p.sub.1], 0), where
[p.sub.0] < 1/2 [less than or equal to] [p.sub.1]. Hence, action
[a.sub.0] represents a negative net-present-value investment, while
[a.sub.1] has an expected return at least as great as the risk-free
return.
Given full deposit insurance and the absence of any other
regulation or intervention affecting its choice, the bank will choose
the inferior action, [a.sub.0], if [p.sub.0][theta] > [p.sub.1],
which will be assumed to be true. The bank's choice of action is
subject to moral hazard, since the action cannot be observed by an
outsider without cost. Hence, the deposit insurer faces the challenge of
ensuring that the bank takes the productive action [a.sub.1]. The
following analysis assumes a large number of banks, so that, if action
[a.sub.1] is chosen by all banks, the fraction that earns positive
income is equal to the probability [p.sub.1] (and similarly for action
[a.sub.0]).
The problem facing the deposit insurer here is quite simple if the
insurer can impose ex post, state-contingent payments by the bank.
Specifically, since the outcome [theta] is possible only if the risky
action is taken, the insurer could ensure the choice of the preferred
action, [a.sub.1], by "taxing" the outcome [theta]
sufficiently. (1) The analysis that follows assumes that such
state-contingent payments are not feasible unless costly actions are
taken. For instance, [theta] itself might be a random variable that
takes a value of one or higher. Realized outcomes can be uncovered by
the insurer only at a cost. Then, it is likely that such a tool would be
used by the insurer in the event of negative returns in order to give
the appropriate compensation to depositors. With positive returns,
however, actual returns might remain unmeasured (by outsiders) as long
as the bank makes its payments to depositors (plus an insurance
"premium" that covers the expected costs of measurement for
"failed banks"). This arr angement, however, would not solve
the moral hazard problem of inducing the bank to take the preferred
action. For any insurance premium [pi] paid by "solvent" banks
(banks with positive returns), if [p.sub.0][theta] > [p.sub.1], as
assumed, then [p.sub.0]([theta] - [pi]) > [p.sub.1](1 - [pi]). The
left-hand side of this inequality would be the bank's net return
under [a.sub.0], while the right-hand side gives the return if [a.sub.1]
is chosen.
An alternative assumption that prevents the regulator from being
able to force the bank to choose [a.sub.1] using ex post penalties
involves the differential observability of different outcomes. For
instance, one could assume that losses can be observed without cost but
that positive outcomes cannot be distinguished. This amounts to assuming
that it is possible to hide profits but not to hide or otherwise falsify losses. Mathematically, this assumption, which is maintained below, is
equivalent to assuming that the cost of monitoring realized losses is
zero.
In addition to the ability to measure outcomes after the fact,
suppose that the insurer has the ability to determine whether the bank
has chosen [a.sub.0] or [a.sub.1] before outcomes are realized and the
ability to close down a bank that is found to have chosen the inferior
investment strategy. An examination to determine the bank's action
choice results in a cost of [c.sub.a], and an early closure of a bank
results in a loss of l < (1 - [p.sub.0])[theta] - [p.sub.0][theta].
The Loss l can be thought of as the resource cost of closing a bank
early, and this cost is less than the expected losses from a bank that
has taken action [a.sub.0].
The regulator's problem is to choose a probability of
examination [phi], a course of action where an examination reveals
[a.sub.0], and a fee [pi] to charge banks that do not fall. (2) Any such
combination, ([pi], [phi]), will be referred to as a policy. The
assumptions above imply that it will be optimal to close a bank observed
to have chosen [a.sub.0]. Accordingly, an efficient policy can be
defined as a [phi] and a [pi] that solve the following problem.
max{[p.sub.1] - (1 - [p.sub.1]) - [phi][c.sub.a]}
s.t. [p.sub.1](1 - [pi]) [greater than or equal to] (1 - [phi])
[p.sub.0]([theta] - [pi]) (1)
and [p.sub.1][pi] [greater than or equal to] [phi][c.sub.a] + (1 -
[p.sub.1]) (2)
The objective function here is simply the total net returns from
the operations of the typical bank and the regulator--the bank's
expected net income minus the regulator's examination costs.
Payments from deposit insurance, payments to depositors, and fee
payments from the bank to the regulator are simply transfer payments.
Hence, the objective function represents the regulated banking
industry's net contribution to social welfare. The first constraint is an incentive compatibility constraint, stating that it must be in the
bank's interest to choose the productive action [a.sub.1]. The
left-hand side shows the expected return to the bank if it chooses
[a.sub.1], while the right-hand side shows the expected return from
[a.sub.0]. In both cases, the bank only earns a positive return, out of
which it pays the tax [pi], if it produces positive income. The
right-hand side is weighted by 1 - [phi], the probability of not being
monitored. If the bank is monitored and discovered to have taken action
[a.sub.0], the regulator closes the bank, and the bank earns nothing.
The second constraint is a consolidated budget constraint for bank
examination and insurance, stating that fees collected from solvent
banks must cover the examination costs and the costs of deposit
insurance payouts.
The choice of an efficient arrangement is quite simple. Note first
that the objective is equivalent to minimizing examination costs, and
therefore the examination probability [phi], subject to the two
constraints. Second, the constraints can be represented by Figure 1 in
which the incentive constraint is represented by the curve IC and the
budget constraint by the line B. (3) On B, which is linear in [pi] and
[phi], the value of [pi] when [phi] is zero is (1 -
[p.sub.1])/[p.sub.1]. Also along B, when [phi] = 1, [pi] = ([c.sub.a] +
1 - [p.sub.1])/[p.sub.1]. The shape of the incentive constraint can be
seen by rewriting it as
[phi] [greater than or equal to] 1 - [p.sub.1](1 -
[pi])/[p.sub.0]([theta] - [pi]).
The right-hand side of this inequality is increasing and convex in
[pi]. The intercept of IC on the [phi]-axis is 1 -
[p.sub.1]/[p.sub.0][theta], which is greater than zero. Note also that
IC goes through the point (1, 1), so that IC and B cross at a point
where both [phi] and [pi] are less than one. Incentive compatibility
requires that a policy ([pi], [phi]) lie above IC, while the budget
constraint requires that a policy lie below B. The ([pi], [phi]) pairs
that satisfy both constraints (that is, the pairs in the constraint set)
are those that lie between IC and B. The efficient policy, which has the
lowest [phi] in the constraint set, is denoted ([[pi].sup.*],
[[phi].sup.*]), where [[pi].sup.*] is found from the consolidated budget
constraint at equality, given [[phi].sup.*].
The efficient policy varies with the model's parameters
largely in the way that one would suspect. For instance, a worsening of
the incentive problem, as would be represented by an increase in
[theta], leads to an increase in [[phi].sup.*] to maintain incentive
compatibility. To cover the increase in examination costs, [[pi].sup.*]
must increase as well. However, one such comparative statics result
might seem unexpected. Specifically, an increase in [c.sub.a], the cost
of an examination, leads to an increase in [[phi].sup.*], the frequency
of examinations. This counterintuitive result arises from the
interaction of the budget and incentive constraints. First, the rising
costs need to be met with an increase in the regulator's revenue by
increasing [pi]. Next, note that an increase in [pi] causes both the
right- and left-hand sides of the incentive constraint to fall. The
left-hand side fails faster, however, meaning that the bank may now find
it advantageous to take the high-risk, low-return action [a.sub.0] . To
counter this adverse incentive effect, it is necessary to increase the
examination frequency.
3. BEHAVIOR OF A SINGLE REGULATOR WITH A CONSOLIDATED BUDGET
CONSTRAINT
Suppose that a single government entity provides deposit insurance
and performs bank examinations. This agency chooses a policy ([pi],
[phi]) subject to the incentive and budget constraints in the problem
above. Hence, the regulator knows that if it chooses a policy that does
not satisfy the incentive constraint, banks will choose the high-risk,
low-return investment, [a.sub.0]. Under this investment choice, however,
the regulator will find it impossible to balance its budget. A balanced
budget is impossible because [p.sub.0][theta] - (1 - [p.sub.0])[theta]
< 0, and the most the regulator can charge banks that have positive
returns is [theta]. Hence, the necessity of meeting the budget
constraint assures that the regulator will enforce the efficient action,
independent of the regulator's objective. A regulator that was
willing and able to generate a budget deficit and whose behavior was
described by the regulatory capture hypothesis might tolerate action
[a.sub.0]. This action maximizes the banks' benefits fr om deposit
insurance and limited liability.
While a regulator facing the consolidated budget constraint will
always enforce the efficient action, that regulator will not always
choose the efficient policy ([[pi].sup.*], [[phi].sup.*]). This choice
depends on the regulator's objectives. A regulator that wants to
minimize costs will choose ([[pi].sup.*], [[phi].sup.*]). There may be
reasons, however, why a self-interested regulator would not seek to
minimize costs.
Another of the regulator's objectives could involve their
attitude toward bank failures. For example, a "conservative"
regulator could be characterized as one who is particularly averse to
bank failures that are seen after the fact to have been the result of
excessive risk taking. That is, regulators may seek to avoid the
eventual revelation that failed banks under their authority took action
[a.sub.0]. One way to achieve this goal would be for regulators to
choose policies that ensure that no banks choose [a.sub.0]. In the basic
model, with homogeneous banks, such regulators will choose the efficient
policy. The following subsection presents an extension of the model with
heterogeneous banks in which a conservative regulator could choose too
restrictive of a policy.
An Extension Involving Multiple Bank Types
Suppose that there are two types of banks, differentiated only by
their high-risk lending opportunities. A fraction [lambda] of the banks
will earn returns of [theta] (with probability [p.sub.0]) or -[theta]
(with probability 1 - [p.sub.0]) if they take action [a.sub.0], as
above. For the remaining banks, [a.sub.0] yields [theta]'(with
probability [p.sub.0]) or -[theta]' (with probability 1 -
[p.sub.0]), where [theta]' > [theta]. The banks with
[theta]' are "high risk," and those with [theta] are
"low risk." If these two types of banks were regulated
separately, with a separate ([pi], [phi]) for each, then the high-risk
banks would have both a higher fee ([pi]) and a higher frequency of
examination ([phi]). Figure 2 shows the separate incentive constraints
for the two types--IC for the low-risk banks and IC' for the
high-risk. It takes more frequent examination, and therefore higher
fees, to induce the high-risk bank to take the efficient action
([a.sub.1]). As long as both types are taking the efficient acti on,
then the budget constraint (B) is the same for both types. In this case,
the efficient policies with separate treatment for the two types would
be at the intersection of B and IC for the low-risk banks and at the
intersection of B and IC', the point labeled ([pi]',
[phi]'), for the high-risk banks.
It may not be possible for the regulator to distinguish between the
two types of banks. That is, the regulator may have to set a single
policy ([pi], [phi]) that applies to all banks. In this case, the policy
([pi]', [phi]') is the least-cost policy that insures that all
banks take action [a.sub.1]. However, this might not be the most
efficient policy. In particular, if [lambda] is close to 1, so that
high-risk banks represent only a small fraction of the population, a
policy that prevents only the low-risk banks from taking the high-risk
action may be preferable. The best such policy is one that just
satisfies the incentive constraint for the low-risk banks, allows
high-risk banks to take action [a.sub.0], and satisfies the budget
constraint,
[[lambda][p.sub.1] + (1 - [lambda])(1 - [phi])[p.sub.0]][pi] (3)
[greater than or equal to] [lambda](1 - [p.sub.1]) + (1 -
[lambda])(1 - [phi])(1 - [p.sub.0])[theta]' + (1 - [lambda])[phi]l
+ [phi][c.sub.a].
This budget constraint is represented by A in Figure 2, and the
policy at the intersection of A and IC is denoted ([pi], [phi]). When
[lambda] is large, A lies very close to B, as in the figure. Compared to
([pi]', [phi]'), ([pi], [phi]) involves increased costs
associated with the failures and early closures of high-risk banks but a
cost savings associated with the reduced examination frequency for all
banks. When [lambda] is large enough, the savings will outweigh the
costs, making ([pi], [phi]) the efficient policy.
In this extension of the model, the chosen policy may depend on the
regulator's preferences and objective. As always, a
welfare-maximizing regulator will choose the efficient policy. Suppose,
however, that the regulator has the conservative preferences outlined
above. That is, the regulator is particularly concerned with preventing
bank failures that are found after the fact to have been caused by
"excessive" risk taking. This concern might arise, for
instance, because the regulator is sensitive to how such failures will
affect his or her reputation, either with the legislature or with the
public at large. Such a conservative regulator might well choose the
policy ([pi]', [phi]'), even when the efficient policy is
([pi], [phi]), (4) This, then, is a case where competitive pressure
among alternative regulators might be particularly beneficial.
4. COMPETITION BETWEEN TWO COMBINED INSURANCE AND REGULATION
AGENCIES
As seen above, the interaction between the incentive and
insurance-regulation budget constraints is the key to determining
desirable policies. As an initial step in examining
"competition" among regulators, consider the case in which
each regulator also has deposit insurance responsibilities for the banks
that it regulates. That is, each regulator has its own consolidated
budget constraint. The interaction between the regulators is then
described as a game in which each regulator chooses a policy, and banks
respond by choosing between the regulators. Assume that if the
regulators choose identical policies, banks divide evenly between the
regulators.
To complete the specification of the game requires a specification
of how the regulators' payoffs respond to the policy choices. These
payoff functions would reflect the regulators' objectives, which
might include such goals as cost minimization, or minimization of risk
taking by banks (preventing banks from choosing [a.sub.0]). In a setting
with competing regulators, it is likely that whatever other criteria the
regulators are considering, they also care about their share of the
regulated industry. This objective might, for instance, arise out of a
desire by the regulator to maximize its influence on the industry.
In the previous subsection's extension of the basic model,
suppose there are two regulators that care about two things. First, as
discussed above, they are conservative, with a dislike for failures or
early closures associated with banks taking the action [a.sub.0].
Second, each has a preference for regulating as large a share of the
industry as possible. One could put more structure on these preferences
by, for instance, specifying a function by which the regulators evaluate
different possible outcomes. Even without such added structure, however,
it is possible to examine the nature of the interaction between
regulators' policy choices. An equilibrium (Nash equilibrium) of
the game is a pair of policy choices, one by each regulator, such that
neither can do better by changing policy, given the policy of the other.
Notice first that given the nature of the game, and assuming the
regulators have the same preferences, equilibrium must involve both
regulators choosing the same policy. If they have different policies and
all banks prefer one of the policies, then the regulator with the less
preferred policy will certainly prefer to mimic the other and share the
industry. (5) Two likely candidates for equilibrium policies are the
"conservative" policy ([pi]', [phi]') from Figure 2
and the efficient policy ([pi]', [phi]'). Recall that the
latter policy is efficient under the assumption that [lambda], the
relative number of low-risk banks, is large enough.
Can ([pi]', [phi]') be an equilibrium policy? Suppose one
regulator has chosen this policy and consider the other's optimal
response. In particular, consider the second regulator's choice
between ([pi]', [phi]') and ([pi]", [phi]") in
Figure 2. All banks will prefer ([pi]", [phi]"); low-risk
banks prefer it for its lower fee, and high-risk banks also enjoy the
potential gains from taking the high-risk action. Note that this policy
is also feasible, since it satisfies the consolidated budget constraint
(A) that holds when high-risk banks choose [a.sub.0]. Given that its
counterpart has chosen ([pi]', [phi]'), a regulator will
choose ([pi]", [phi]") if the perceived benefit of regulating
more banks is greater than the perceived cost of allowing a small number
of high-risk banks to take action [a.sub.0]. Suppose the weights that
the regulator places on these criteria are such that ([pi]",
[phi]") is the preferred of the two policies. Then ([pi]',
[phi]') is not an equilibrium policy. Neither, of course, is
([pi]", [phi]"), since a rival can attract all banks away with
a policy along A with a lower [pi] and a lower [phi]. In this case,
bidding by regulators results in an equilibrium policy of ([pi], [phi]).
In contrast, the absence of competition results in the conservative
policy of ([pi]', [phi]'); a sole conservative regulator need
not compete for clients and can instead focus only on making sure that
no banks have an incentive to take [a.sub.0].
The discussion in this section implicitly involves a
regulators' objective function that exhibits a trade-off between a
taste for regulating as large a share of the industry as possible and a
distaste for "excessive" risk taking by banks. The preceding
paragraph describes a situation in which the former (the desire to
increase "turf") is strong enough that it eliminates the
conservative policy ([pi]', [phi]') as a potential equilibrium
outcome. Indeed, this is a case in which regulators' interest in
increasing their turf serves a useful social purpose. Of course, it is
possible for the other component of regulators' preferences, their
desire to limit risk taking, to be strong enough to support ([pi]',
[phi]') as an equilibrium policy. The following example illustrates
these points, by taking the assumptions of this section and adding an
explicit regulatory objective function.
Example 1 Label the regulators 1 and 2, and let regulator i's
preferences be represented by
[alpha][F.sup.i] - [beta][D.sup.i]
where [F.sup.i] is the fraction of the industry that i regulates,
and [D.sup.i] is the fraction of the banks regulated by i that take
action [a.sub.0]. The parameters [alpha] and [beta] measure the strength
of the regulators 'preferences for the two objectives. Now consider
regulator 2's choice of policy if regulator 1 has chosen
([pi]', [phi]'). In particular, consider regulator 2's
choice between ([pi]', [phi]') and a policy along A with lower
[pi] and [phi] than at ([pi]', [phi]'). The point ([pi]",
[phi]") gives one such policy. If ([pi]', [phi]') is
preferred, then that is the equilibrium policy. If regulator 2 chooses
([pi]', [phi]'), then the industry is evenly divided between
the regulators, and no banks will choose [a.sub.0]. That is, [F.sup.2] =
1/2 and [D.sup.2] = 0. On the other hand, regulator 2 can capture the
entire industry by choosing ([pi]", [phi]") at the cost of
inducing high-risk banks to take action [a.sub.0]. In this case,
[F.sup.2] = 1, and [D.sup.2] - (1 - [lambda]). Regulator 2 will prefer
([pi]', [phi]') over ([pi]", [phi]") if [alpha]/2
[greater than or equal to] [alpha] - [beta](1 - [lambda]), that is if
[alpha]/[beta] [less than or equal to] 2(1 - [lambda]). As suggested
above, if the relative distaste for risk taking is strong enough (if
[beta] is small enough relative to [alpha]), then the conservative
policy ([pi]', [phi]') can be an equilibrium. On the other
hand, for any given preference specification, if the population of
high-risk banks is small enough ([lambda] is big enough), then
([pi]', [phi]') will not be an equilibrium. When this is the
case, then the efficient policy ([pi], [phi]) is the equilibrium.
The efficient outcome that arises from regulatory competition is
similar to the outcome that would arise in this environment if, instead
of being determined by regulators, [pi] and [phi] were set by private
providers of deposit insurance with the ability to monitor and shut down
banks under certain circumstances. A monopolist private insurer in this
setting would pick high fees and a high probability of monitoring. In
fact a monopolist's profit-maximizing decision, at least under some
auxiliary assumptions, is to choose [pi] = [phi] = 1. Competition, on
the other hand, would cause rival insurers to bid their insurance and
monitoring offers down to the efficient policy.
One key to the efficiency result in this section is the
consolidated budget constraints the regulators face. That is, each
regulator is both an insurer and an examiner of its banks, and neither
can draw on other sources of funds to cover any of its costs. With this
assumption, the so-called "race-to-the-bottom" characteristic,
by which regulatory competition leads to too little regulation (too
little monitoring) cannot be an equilibrium result. From the status quo of ([pi], [phi]) with regulators splitting the industry, the only way a
regulator can attract more banks is by offering a policy that induces
all banks to choose the high-risk action. But no such policy can satisfy
the consolidated budget constraint. This is true by the basic
assumptions of the model. (6) If all banks choose investments with
negative expected value, there are not enough resources in successful
banks to cover all the costs of insurance; let alone examination costs.
Hence, a race to the bottom will not occur. When a regulator is both an
examiner and an insurer of banks, the regulator internalizes the effects
of examination policy on the deposit insurance fund.
Of course in the United States, the multiple federal bank
regulatory agencies do not each face their own consolidated budget
constraints. Instead, the FDIC provides deposit insurance to all banks.
It finances this insurance with premiums charged to insured institutions
(or more generally, by the maintenance of a fund built up by banks'
premium payments). The FDIC finances its regulatory and supervisory
costs out of the same revenue source as its insurance. At the same time,
the FDIC's financial resources are supplemented by the full faith
and credit of the federal government. The Federal Reserve pays for its
regulatory activities out of its general revenue from central bank
operations. The OCC covers its costs out of a fee charged to the banks
it regulates. The next section considers how these differences
complicate the interaction among regulators.
5.UNCONSOLIDATED BUDGET CONSTRAINTS
When the financing of deposit insurance and bank regulation are not
consolidated, there is a possibility that competition among regulators
will lead to undesirable results. The simplest way of examining this
possibility is to assume that deposit insurance is financed out of
general government revenues, while regulatory agencies cover their
examination costs, and the costs associated with the early closure of
banks, from the fees they charge. In this case, a regulator's
budget constraint, assuming incentive compatibility, is
[p.sub.1][pi] [greater than or equal to] [phi[[c.sub.a].
For a policy such that the incentive constraint is not satisfied,
the budget constraint is
[p.sub.0][pi] [greater than or equal to] [phi]([c.sub.a] + l),
where l is the resource cost of closing a bank that is examined and
found to have taken action [a.sub.0]. These two constraints are shown in
Figure 3 as [B.sup.u] and [A.sup.u] respectively.
This section considers the simplest case of a single type of bank
(a single [theta]-type) and regulators whose objective is narrow and
parochial. That is, each regulator simply seeks to maximize its turf, or
the share of the market it regulates. Recall that under these
assumptions, when regulators also faced consolidated budget constraints,
competition led to efficient policies. Here that is not the case. Note
that the efficient policy ([[pi].sup.*], [[phi].sup.*]) from Figure 1,
because it satisfies the consolidated budget constraint, yields surplus
funding to a regulator that only needs to cover examination costs. That
is,
[p.sub.1][[pi].sup.*] = [[phi].sup.*][c.sub.a] + (1 - [p.sub.1])
> [[phi].sup.*][c.sub.a].
Now consider the policy ([[pi].sup.1], [[phi].sup.1]). This is the
lowest cost policy that induces banks to choose [a.sub.1] and covers
examination costs. This policy cannot be an equilibrium when regulators
care only about the size of their turf. The policy ([[pi].sup.1],
[[phi].sup.2]) will be strictly preferred by all banks, because it
allows them the opportunity to gamble for the large return, [theta].
Among policies that induce banks to choose [a.sub.0], however,
regulators will continue to bid for banks by reducing [pi] (moving along
[A.sup.u]). Hence, with this specification of objectives and budget
constraints there is a tendency for the regulatory process to unravel
altogether, resulting in an equilibrium with no examination ([phi] = 0)
and no fee charged to banks by regulators ([pi] = 0). In the absence of
any external constraint on regulators' discretion, the agencies
have no incentive to engage in more than minimal regulatory activities.
This case, then, represents the so-called "race to the
bottom."
Now suppose that conservativeness, as specified in earlier
sections, is also a part of the regulators' objectives. The
previous subsection argued that a regulator with such a mix of motives
might be willing to loosen regulation in a way that induces only a small
number of banks to take action [a.sub.0]. With only a single type of
bank, however, a regulator is less likely to choose a policy that causes
all banks to take [a.sub.0], even if doing so attracts many more banks
to that regulator. This logic leads to an equilibrium policy of
([[pi].sup.1], [[phi].sup.1]), assuming that there is no separate fee
assessment for deposit insurance. While this policy preserves
banks' incentives to take the efficient action, it requires a net
subsidy to the combined activities of insurance and regulation.
With consolidated budget constraints, regulators directly
internalize the effect of regulatory actions on deposit insurance
exposure. This automatic connection is lost when regulation and
insurance are separately funded. This separation creates a sort of
artificial externality that has an effect similar to the externalities that can interfere with the Tiebout result of efficient policies under
competition among local governments.
6. SUMMARY AND CONCLUDING REMARKS
The preceding sections presented a model in which the key function
of bank regulation is the monitoring of the investment choices made by
insured banks. The model predicts policy choices by regulators that
depend on the structure of the banking industry (captured by the
distribution of bank types), regulators' objectives, and the
financing of bank regulation and deposit insurance (captured by the
regulators' budget constraints). The key findings of the analysis
are: 1) a single regulator facing a consolidated budget constraint and a
homogeneous banking industry will typically choose an efficient policy;
2) if there are multiple bank types with a small number of particularly
high-risk banks, a single regulator with conservative preferences toward
bank risk taking may choose an excessively strict policy; 3) with
consolidated budget constraints for all regulators, competition for
"turf" among multiple regulators can lead to efficient
policies; and 4) competition for turf among regulators whose budget
constraints only cover examination costs (and not insurance costs) leads
to a "race to the bottom."
The previous section's simple specification of unconsolidated
budget constraints still does not match the actual organization and
financing of bank deposit insurance and regulation in the United States.
Most notably, one of the Agencies--the FDIC--finances both insurance for
all banks and regulation for its banks out of the "fees" it
charges to all banks. Further, by choosing to be regulated by the OCC or
the Fed, however, a bank does not reduce the fees that it pays to the
FDIC for insurance. Accordingly, the way in which fees enter into
banks' choices of regulators is more complicated in reality than in
this article's model. Still, since the financing of insurance and
regulation is separated for all other banks other than those regulated
by the FDIC, the budgetary externality discussed in this article is
present.
Many other characteristics of actual bank regulation have also been
left out of the analysis. Rather than presenting a richly detailed
description of actual regulatory institutions, this article's
intent was to present a simple analytical framework for thinking about
the interaction among alternative regulators. In spite of the inherent
over simplification, the basic results of this article's analysis
are likely to carry over to more complex environments. Competitive
interaction among regulators can have beneficial effects, but the
separation of the financing of insurance and regulation can make those
benefits less certain.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
(1.) For a discussion of using the regulation of bank capital
structure to achieve ex post payments by banks, see Prescott (2001).
(2.) In principle, one could allow for two distinct fees, depending
on whether a surviving bank has or has not been examined. In the
analysis below, it is assumed that the regulator must charge a single.
nondiscriminating fee to all surviving banks.
(3.) The figure incorporates the additional assumption that
[c.sub.a] < 2[p.sub.1] - 1. This assumption says that examination
costs are less than the average net income under action [a.sub.1], and
it is a sufficient condition for a nonempty constraint set. This
assumption also ensures that the maximum value of the objective function
in the efficient regulation problem is positive. That is, a regulated
banking industry yields positive social surplus.
(4.) A caveat is in order regarding the specification of
"efficiency" when the regulator has a preference, whether
personal or political, for preventing all banks from choosing [a.sub.0].
Strictly speaking, the social welfare function would be the
industry's net income minus examination costs minus any utility
cost to the regulator that results if some banks choose [a.sub.0]. The
latter is assumed to be small relative to banks' income and
examination costs. That is, while such a utility cost, even when small,
can affect a regulator's choice of policy, it is assumed that the
cost is small enough that it does not affect the determination of an
efficient policy.
(5.) It is also possible for the regulators to have different
policies and for each type of bank to prefer a different one of the
policies. This could only happen, however, if at least one of the
policies is not incentive compatible for at least one of the types,
since the two bank types' preferences among incentive compatible
policies (policies that induce the action at [a.sub.1]) are identical. A
regulator that attracts only high-risk banks with a policy that induces
action [a.sub.0] cannot satisfy its consolidated budget constraint.
Therefore, such a mix of strategies is not an equilibrium outcome.
(6.) The key assumption here is that [a.sub.0] represents an
investment with a negative net present value. However, if [a.sub.0] were
a positive net-present-value investment but dominated by [a.sub.1], the
efficient policy result would still hold. With all banks taking
[a.sub.0], [pi] would have to be large in order to satisfy the
consolidated budget constraint, making it impossible to choose a ([pi],
[phi]) that banks prefer to ([pi], [phi]).
REFERENCES
Hawke, John D. 2002. "Remarks by John D. Hawke, Jr.,
Comptroller of the Currency before the 38th Annual Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition." Chicago, Illinois, 9 May.
Kane, Edward J. 1996. "Foundations of Financial
Regulation." In Rethinking Bank Regulation: What Should Regulators
Do? proceedings of the 32nd Annual Conference on Bank Structure and
Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 309-33.
Karpoff, J., and Malatesta E. 1989. "The Wealth Effects of
Second Generation State Takeover Legislation." Journal of Financial
Economics 25: 295-312.
Peltzman, S. 1976. "Toward a More General Theory of
Regulation." Journal of Law and Economics 19: 211-40.
Prescott, Edward 5. 2001. "Regulating Bank Capital Structure
to Control Risk." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 87 (Summer): 35-52.
Rosen, R. J. 2001. "Do Regulators Search for the Quiet Life?
The Relationship Between Regulators and the Regulated in Banking."
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2001-05.
Scott, K. E. 1977. "The Dual Banking System: Model of
Competition in Regulation." Stanford Law Review 30: 1-49.
Stigler, G. 1971. "The Economic Theory of Regulation."
Bell Journal of Economics 2: 3-21.
Tiebout, C. 1956. "A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures."
Journal of Political Economy 64: 416-24.
This article has benefited from helpful comments from Kartik
Athreya, Jeffrey Lacker, Yash Mehra, and Tom Humphrey. The views
expressed herein are the author's and do not represent the views of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.