Consumption, savings, and the meaning of the wealth effect in general equilibrium.
Lantz, Carl D. ; Sarte, Pierre-Daniel G.
Pierre-Daniel G. Sarte
Over the latter half of the 1990s, the U.S. economy experienced
both a substantial decrease in the savings rate and a significant run-up
in household net worth. Between 1994 and 2000, the gross private savings
rate fell from 17 to 12 percent, while the personal savings rate
declined from above 6 percent to less than zero. Over the same period,
the value of household sector equity holdings (including those owned by
nonprofits, pensions, and other fiduciaries) increased nearly 150
percent for a dollar gain in excess of $6 trillion.
At some level, the decline in savings and the rise in household
equity value during that period appeared to point towards a
strengthening of the economy. According to the Permanent Income
Hypothesis (PIH), households save less in a given period if they expect
future increases in their income. Along these lines, the dramatic gain
in stock market wealth was thought to partly reflect future
opportunities made available to firms by rapid advances in information
technology. Both the fall in savings and the rise in net wealth seemed
consistent with the rapid growth of consumption during that period.
Despite the rosy outlook implied by the PIH at the close of the
decade, the U.S. economy slowed down considerably in 2000. Specifically,
the growth rate of per capita consumption fell to 2 percent in the first
quarter of 2001 from nearly 7 percent in the same quarter of the
previous year. Between the first quarter of 2000 and that of 2001,
household net worth fell by 8 percent, or $3.5 trillion. In light of
these developments, it seems only natural to question the significance
of the data in the late 1990s. With this question in mind, this article
seeks to emphasize the following points.
First, the PIH notwithstanding, a fall in savings today may not
necessarily reflect expected future gains in income, but rather the
current realization of a negative economic shock. Within the context of
a simple neoclassical growth model with investment adjustment costs, we
show that an unanticipated permanent fall in productivity leads to a
contemporaneous fall in both consumption and savings. The fall in
savings continues several periods into the future and a lower
steady-state level of savings ultimately emerges. It remains true, in
this model, that a fully anticipated increase in future productivity
also leads to a contemporaneous fall in savings as households seek to
smooth consumption. In the latter case, however, the savings rate
eventually reaches a higher steady state level as the shock is realized.
Second, it is important to recognize that discussions of the wealth
effect, such as those in Ludvigson and Steindel (1999) or Mehra (2001),
are often carried out in a partial equilibrium setting. In such a
setting, both the rate of interest and the level of wealth are exogenous with respect to contemporaneous consumption (i.e., wealth is a state
variable). In contrast, general equilibrium considerations imply that
wealth, the rate of interest, and consumption all contemporaneously react to the various disturbances affecting the economy. Thus, an
unanticipated permanent increase in productivity leads to a simultaneous
rise in both consumption and household net worth. Note, however, that
consumption does not respond directly to wealth. Rather, both variables
react simultaneously to the higher level of productivity. The
implication of this dual reaction is that the measured marginal
propensity to consume out of wealth is unlikely to be constant, as is
often assumed. Indeed, empirical studies such as those in Me hra (2001)
and Ludvigson and Steindel (1999) have found that the magnitude of the
wealth effect is dependent on the sample period in question. This lack
of time consistency in the wealth parameter would be expected if the
nature of the shocks impacting the economy was changing over different
sample periods.
In general, it can be misleading to think in terms of
households' marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. Such
thinking presumes that important movements in wealth exist that are
independent of economic fundamentals. However, the value of corporate
equity reflects the present discounted value of future firm dividends
and, in a general equilibrium framework, both the discount rate and
dividends respond to changes in the economic environment.
To make matters concrete, we show that consumption and wealth can
move in opposite directions in some cases. When a future increase in
productivity is fully anticipated, at the time of anticipation
consumption rises while the value of household equity falls. Although
households eventually hold more wealth in the new steady state, the
initial fall in equity value reflects higher future discount rates
consistent with the anticipated increase in productivity. A partial
equilibrium framework prohibits this finding from ever arising because
the rate of interest is held fixed. (1)
In this article, we first present some basic empirical facts
regarding consumption, savings, and wealth in U.S. data. We next outline
a simple theoretical framework that allows us to simultaneously explore
the price of corporate equity and households' consumption-savings
decisions. Finally, we analyze the results from several numerical
experiments related to both anticipated and unanticipated shocks to
total factor productivity.
1. CONSUMPTION AND THE SAVINGS RATE IN U.S. DATA
Figure 1 shows the behavior of two alternate measures of the U.S.
savings rate over the past 41 years. Panel a of Figure 1 captures the
most basic National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) measure of
savings, Personal Disposable Income less Personal Consumption
Expenditures in 1996 dollars. The savings rate in panel b is computed
using Gross Private Savings which, in addition to Personal Savings,
includes retained earnings by firms. We can see that both measures of
the savings rate fell drastically over the 1990s and, by early 2001, had
reached their lowest recorded levels.
We suggested earlier that a desire to smooth consumption may lead
households to save less today if they expect future gains in their
income or, alternatively, to save more if they expect future declines in
their income. In particular, Hall (1978) argued that the consumption
behavior of a household at a given date was based on all of that
household's future discounted earnings. Milton Friedman (1957) was
perhaps the first to draw a distinction between changes in permanent and
transitory income. Figure 2 illustrates (normalized) movements in the
savings rate four quarters prior to each of the past five U.S.
recessions. In panel a, we can see that the personal savings rate
generally rises during the year prior to a recession. However, this
tendency is not clear-cut. Moreover, it is much less pronounced for the
gross private savings rate in panel b. In this case, in the four
quarters preceding two of five recessions, the savings rate either falls
or remains the same. Figure 3 plots the cross-correlations between our
two measures of the savings rate and output at different leads and lags.
Both the personal savings rate and the gross private savings rate show a
negative correlation with future values of GDP. Hence, there seems to be
some evidence to support the PIH. However, the magnitude of the
cross-correlations shown in Figure 3 is relatively low, and it is
possible that factors other than expectations of future changes in
income help drive the behavior of the savings rate.
2. A SIMPLE THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVE
In order to explore some of the issues introduced above, we now
describe a model that can be simultaneously used to price corporate
equity and address household consumption-savings decisions. For
simplicity, we abstract from the inclusion of a noncorporate sector and
intangible assets, as well as several aspects of the U.S. tax system.
McGrattan and Prescott (2000), however, suggest that these
considerations are important in calibration exercises meant to match
data from the NIPA and the Statistics of Income (SOT). In particular,
the authors argue that the historical behavior of asset prices and
returns can be largely explained by changes in tax and regulatory
policies as well as by the evolution of the institutions affecting asset
markets.
In this model, the economic environment consists of a large number
of identical households and firms. Each firm has access to a constant
returns technology,
[Y.sub.t] = [Z.sub.t][k.sup.[alpha].sub.t][n.sup.1-[alpha].sub.t],
0 < [alpha] < 1, (1)
where [Y.sub.t] is the firm's output at a given date t,
[n.sub.t] denotes labor input, [Z.sub.t] is a random technological shift
parameter, and [k.sub.t] represents the firm's capital stock. In
this article, we shall think of firms as owning their capital stock
instead of renting it from households. Households will be thought of as
owning claims on firms' net cash flows, e.g., equity shares.
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) suggest that if the stock of capital
includes a human component, then one will anticipate substantial
adjustment costs in investment. According to the authors, "the
learning process takes time, and attempts to accelerate the training
process are likely to encounter rapidly diminishing rates of
return" (p. 119). Hence, we model the evolution of a firm's
capital stock as
[k.sub.t+1] = (1 - [delta]) [k.sub.t] + [empty set]
([i.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]) [k.sub.t], (2)
where 0 < [delta] < 1 is the capital depreciation rate and
[i.sub.t] represents the firm's investment decision at date t. The
function [empty set](*), with [empty set]'(*) > 0, captures the
idea of adjustment costs in investment. Thus, the higher the level of
investment relative to the current capital stock, the more costly it
becomes to increase next period's capital. Observe that the
function [empty set]"(*) < 0 indexes the degree to which adding
to the capital stock becomes costly. (2) In addition, note also that the
book value of capital at date t, [k.sub.t], reflects investment
decisions made at date t - 1. Therefore, [k.sub.t] cannot respond
contemporaneously to changes in the economic environment. In contrast,
if we think of the firm as having a fixed number of equity shares
outstanding, the value of these shares can contemporaneously react to
disturbances affecting the economy. Put another way, we expect both
household net worth and consumption to move simultaneously in response
to various shocks.
Firms pay each unit of labor the wage rate [w.sub.t], and their net
cash flow at t is consequently given by
[z.sub.t][k.sup.[alpha].sub.t][n.sup.1-[alpha].sub.t] - [i.sub.t] -
[w.sub.t][n.sub.t]. (3)
We assume that this cash flow is paid to households in the form of
dividends, [D.sub.t]. Each firm attempts to maximize the present
discounted value of future profits. The representative firm's
problem, therefore, can be summarized as
max [[summation over].sup.[infinity].sub.[tau]=0]
[[PI].sup.[tau]-1.sub.i=-1][Q.sub.t+i][[z.sub.t+[tau]][k.sup.[alpha].
sub.t+[tau]][n.sup.1-[alpha].sub.t+[tau]] - [i.sub.t+[tau]] -
[w.sub.t+[tau]][n.sub.t+[tau]]], (P1)
subject to the sequence of constraints given by (2). In (P1),
[Q.sub.t-1] denotes the price of a security that pays one unit of the
consumption good at date t.
The solution to the firm's problem must satisfy the following
first-order conditions,
[w.sub.t] = (1 -
[alpha])[z.sub.t][k.sup.[alpha].sub.t][n.sup.-[alpha].sub.t], (4)
[[lambda].sub.t][empty set]'([i.sub.t]/[k.sub.t]) = 1, (5)
and
[Q.sub.t][alpha][z.sub.t+1][k.sup.[alpha]-1.sub.t+1][n.sup.1-[alpha]. sub.t+1]
= [[lambda].sub.t] - [Q.sub.t][[lambda].sub.t+1][(1 - [delta]) +
[empty set]([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1]) - [empty
set]'([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1])[i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1]], (6)
where [[lambda].sub.t] [greater than or equal to] 0 is the Lagrange
multiplier associated with (2). Equation (4) simply equates the wage
rate to the marginal product of labor. Equation (5) suggests that it is
optimal for the firm to invest up to the point where the cost of one
additional unit of investment (in terms of foregone profits) exactly
offsets the marginal gain from increasing next period's capital
stock.
As mentioned earlier, the representative household owns all firms
and receives their profits, [D.sub.t], as dividends. At date t, the
typical household's net worth, [A.sub.t], consists of stock market
wealth and bonds. Specifically, we denote the market value of household
equity by [V.sub.t][X.sub.t], where [V.sub.t] represents the price of
firms' outstanding equity shares and [X.sub.t] is the number of
shares held by the household. Agents also own one-period bonds,
[B.sub.t], where a bond purchased at date t pays one unit of the
consumption good at time t + 1. The representative household maximizes
its lifetime utility and solves
max [[summation over].sup.[infinity]/[tau]=0] [[beta].sup.[tau]]
[c.sup.1-[sigma].sub.t+[tau]] - 1/1 - [sigma], [sigma] > 0, (P2)
subject to the sequence of constraints
[c.sub.t] + [V.sub.t][X.sub.t+1] + [Q.sub.t][B.sub.t+1] =
([V.sub.t] + [D.subt.])[X.sub.t] + [B.sub.t] + [w.sub.t][n.sub.t]. (7)
Household income on the right-hand side of equation (7) stems from
the ownership of firms, with dividend earnings given by
[D.sub.t][X.sub.t], earnings from bonds, [B.sub.t], and labor income,
[w.sub.t][n.sub.t]. These earnings can be used to purchase consumption
goods, new equity shares, and bonds. The first-order conditions
associated with the household problem are
[c.sup.-[sigma].sub.t] = [[psi].sub.t], (8)
[Q.sub.t] = [beta] ([[psi].sub.t+1]/[[psi].sub.t]), (9)
and
[V.sub.t] = [beta] {([[psi].sub.t+1]/[[psi].sub.t])[[V.sub.t+1] +
[D.sub.t+1]}, (10)
where [[psi].sub.t] is the multiplier associated with the household
budget constraint (7). Note that equations (9) and (10) can be used.
together to yield
[V.sub.t] = [[summation over].sup.[infinity].sub.[tau]=1]
[[PI].sup.[tau]-1.sub.i=1] [Q.sub.t+i] [D.sub.t+[tau]]. (11)
In other words, the price of a firm's outstanding equity
shares reflects the expected present discounted value of its future
dividends. In this model, therefore, even shocks that affect only future
profit opportunities and discount rates will lead to changes in
today's household wealth.
Observe that the multiplier [[lambda].sub.t] in (5) can be
interpreted as the shadow price of installed capital. In particular, the
Appendix shows that equations (6) and (11) can be used to derive
[V.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.t][k.sub.t+1]. (12)
Since [empty set symbol](.) < 0, an increase in investment leads
to a rise in [[lambda].sub.t] by equation (5), as well as a rise in
[k.sub.t+1]. Hence, in thinking about the effects of various shocks
below, we need only keep track of the investment response in order to
understand movements in the value of corporate equity. (3)
An equilibrium for the economy we have just presented must satisfy
firms' optimality conditions (4) through (6), as well as
households' optimality conditions (8) through (10). In addition,
the goods market clearing condition,
[c.sub.t] + [i.sub.t] = [y.sub.t],
must hold. In equilibrium, we further have that [X.sub.t] =
[X.sub.t-1] = 1 for all t and, since households are identical, bonds are
in zero net supply, [B.sub.t] = 0 for all t. Equation (13) implies that
savings equals investment, [s.sub.t] = [y.sub.t] - [c.sub.t] =
[i.sub.t].
Before investigating the joint response of consumption, savings,
and wealth to different changes in the economic environment, we must
first assign values to the exogenous parameters of our model. Each
period represents a quarter, and we set [delta] and [sigma] to 0.025 and
2 respectively. These values for [delta] and [sigma] are standard in
quantitative studies of business cycles. In the steady state, equations
(9) and (11) imply that the price-earnings ratio, V/D, is given by
[beta]/(1 -- [beta]). Hence, we set [beta] to 0.983 in order to generate
along-run annualized price-earnings ratio of 14.5. (4) We set [alpha] to
1/3 which leads to an investment share in output of 20 percent in the
steady state. Finally, we set the parameter that governs the degree of
adjustment costs, [empty set], to -- 10. This calibration implies that
the elasticity of the investment: capital ratio with respect to
Tobin's q is approximately 5. Baxter and Crucini (1993) explore a
variety of possible calibrations for this elasticity param eter, ranging
from 1 to 15, without substantially altering their results. This remains
true in our framework.
On the Significance of the Wealth Effect in General Equilibrium
The solution to the model above implies a law of motion for the
vector of state variables, [s.sub.t+1] as a function of [s.sub.t], where
[s.sub.t] consists of the capital stock, [k.sub.t], and the random
technological shift parameter, [z.sub.t]. This solution also links
control variables, such as consumption, [c.sub.t], and the market
capitalization of firms, [V.sub.t], to the state variables. Therefore,
in a linearized form, we have
[c.sub.t] [c.sub.0] + [c.sub.k][k.sub.t] + [c.sub.z][z.sub.t] (14)
and
[V.sub.t] = [v.sub.0] + [v.sub.k][k.sub.t] + [v.sub.z][z.sub.t]
(15)
where [c.sub.0], [v.sub.0],... are functions of the deep parameters
of the model capturing preferences and technology. Solving for [k.sub.t]
in equation (15) and substituting the resulting expression in (14)
yields
[c.sub.t] = ([c.sub.0] - [c.sub.k]/[v.sub.k] [v.sub.0]} constant +
([c.sub.k]/[v.sub.k] [V.sub.t] } [beta] + ([c.sub.z] -
[c.sub.k]/[v.sub.k] [v.sub.z]) [z.sub.t] } [u.sub.t] (16)
This last equation often forms the basis of regression equations
that are meant to uncover the size of the wealth effect,
[partial][c.sub.t]/[partial][V.sub.t] = [c.sub.k]/[v.sub.k] = [beta].
Observe that the only source of random disturbances in equation (16)
stems from movements in productivity, [z.sub.t]. Moreover, because
changes in equity [V.sub.t] are necessarily correlated with changes in
fundamentals, [z.sub.t], it will be important to make use of
instrumental variables to properly estimate the coefficient [beta] That
being said, since all movements in both [C.sub.t] and [V.sub.t] are
generated from changes in economic fundamentals, estimates of the
marginal propensity to consume out of wealth are of little use in this
environment. More to the point, the expression
[partial][C.sub.t]/[partial][V.sub.t] is meaningful only to the degree
that there exist significant exogenous movements in net worth,
[partial][V.sub.t], that are unrelated to changes in underlying economic
conditions. Such movements may re flect, for example, the existence of
stock market bubbles. In our environment, however, changes in
consumption and wealth are necessarily linked through movements in
productivity and given by
([partial][C.sub.t]/[partial][Z.sub.t] = ([C.sub.k]/[C.sub.v])
[partial][V.sub.t]/[partial][Z.sub.t] + ([C.sub.z] -
[C.sub.k]/[V.sub.k][v.sub.z]) (17)
= [C.sub.z].
3. NUMERICAL EXAMPLES
We will now explore the behavior of our economy when the underlying
source of uncertainty lies in total factor productivity, [Z.sub.t]. We
shall examine the effects of both unanticipated and anticipated changes
in productivity, and outline significant differences in the way the
economy reacts to these shocks. To emphasize these differences, we shall
also compute the cross-correlations of consumption and the savings rate
with stock market wealth under both these parameterizations of
productivity shocks.
The Effects of Unanticipated Shocks in Productivity
Figure 4, panel a, depicts an unanticipated and permanent 1 percent
fall in productivity. As a result of this shock, output falls
immediately as depicted in Figure 4, panel d, and continues falling
towards a lower steady state value. Observe that both consumption and
savings mimic the output response. Both variables fall at the time of
the shock and eventually reach a lower steady state level. In this case,
therefore, a fall in savings does not indicate better times ahead, as a
naive interpretation of the PIH suggests. Instead, by allowing
households to consume some of their capital, diminished savings behavior
softens the fall in consumption. It remains true, of course, that the
economy is unambiguously worse off in the long run.
In this numerical experiment, the savings rate decreases
dramatically on impact and then rises on its way to the final steady
state. This is shown in Figure 5, panel b. In the new long-run
equilibrium, however, the savings rate is ultimately lower relative to
its level in the period prior to the shock. This example suggests that
it may be difficult to identify the source of a given decline in the
savings rate in the data. In particular, we shall see below that one
version of the PIH continues to hold in general equilibrium. That is, an
anticipated increase in future productivity also leads to a decrease in
the savings rate today, followed by a gradually increasing path. In the
case of this anticipated increase, however, the savings rate eventually
increases all the way to a higher steady state level.
Figure 5 also shows that the interest rate, firms' dividends,
and the market value of equity all decrease when the negative
productivity shock is realized. Given equation (12), the fall in equity
is relatively easy to follow. Because the level of savings falls in
response to the shock, firms are forced to cut back on investment, which
directly leads to a decrease in the value of corporate equity. Note that
this decline in equity is consistent with the fall in aggregate
dividends in Figure 5, panel c, but is mitigated by the decrease in
interest rates during the transition to the new steady state. Since the
rate of interest is simply the inverse of [Q.sub.t] in equation (9), the
steady fall in consumption in Figure 4, panel b, indeed implies a
decline in interest rates until the new long-run equilibrium is reached.
Finally, in this example, Figures 4b and 5d show that consumption
and wealth respond to the shock in the same direction. As we have
already pointed out, however, it should be clear that there is no sense
in which consumption responds directly to movements in wealth.
Furthermore, the nonlinearity of the impulse responses implies that the
measured marginal propensity to consume out of wealth will not be
constant in this case. This implication is at variance with studies,
such as Davis and Palumbo (2001) and Poterba and Samwick (1995), that
have attempted to measure the additional increase in consumption
stemming from a rise in household equity.
The Effects of Anticipated Changes in Productivity
We now study the model economy's response to an anticipated
permanent positive shock to total factor productivity. One
interpretation of such a shock may involve the conception of a new
technology whose actual implementation is likely to take time. We shall
see that in the short run, there exist similarities in the way savings
respond to an anticipated positive shock and an unanticipated negative
shock. These similarities, while they can make the interpretation of
savings data ambiguous at times, eventually dissipate in the long run.
Figure 6, panel a, depicts a 1 percent positive shock in total
factor productivity that takes place four periods in the future. This
shock, however, is fully anticipated by both households and firms in the
current period. Because productivity, and thus output, is expected to
increase, household consumption immediately rises in Figure 6, panel b.
This response reflects a desire to smooth consumption that is implicit
in the household problem. However, since the capital stock, [k.sub.t],
is fixed at time zero, output cannot change at the time of the shock. It
must be the case, therefore, that savings initially fall in a way
consistent with the PIH, as shown in Figure 6c.
Observe that because the initial increase in consumption is
sustained until the productivity shock takes place, the level of savings
continues to fall in the short run. Therefore, as households find it
optimal to temporarily consume part of the capital stock, output
declines between period 0 and period 4. Once the positive productivity
shock occurs in period 4, consumption, savings, and output all increase
and begin converging towards their new steady state. In our context,
adjustment costs limit the extent to which households wish to increase
consumption initially. To be specific, since firms will find it optimal
to increase investment once the shock occurs, and the marginal product
of capital will consequently rise, it will be important that the capital
stock not be too low at the point of the shock. Recall that the nature
of investment adjustment costs is such that the higher the level of
investment relative to the current capital stock, the more costly it
becomes to increase the next period's capital.
Figure 7, panel d, shows that the value of corporate equity
actually falls when the productivity shock is anticipated at time zero.
This result can be most easily understood in terms of the fall in
savings in Figure 6c and the resulting decline in investment. More
importantly, this finding clearly indicates that consumption, as shown
in Figure 6b, and wealth do not have to move in the same direction. This
result is at odds with many empirical studies in which consumption
always responds positively to wealth within the assumed theoretical
framework. On a related note, the impulse responses depicted in Figures
6 and 7 suggest that the data in the late 1990s were not necessarily
indicative of a future strengthening of the economy. As we pointed out
in our introduction, both consumption and wealth rose during that period
while savings fell. Our numerical experiment suggests that an
anticipated positive shock to productivity, while leading to a fall in
savings and a rise in consumption during the current period, generates a
fall in wealth initially.
Finally, Figure 7, panel a, illustrates a remarkable increase in
the interest rate in the period prior to the realization of the shock.
This noticeable increase is consistent with the jump in consumption that
occurs in the next period when the shock takes place. In particular, the
high rate of interest prevents consumption from rising too dramatically
in anticipation of the productivity increase. Moreover, observe that the
interest rate spike is also consistent with the initial fall in wealth
in Figure 7c. Once the shock has occurred, the high rate of interest
depicted in Figure 7a is no longer part of the present discounted value
calculation with respect to future earnings. As a result, the value of
corporate equity increases markedly.
Implied Cross-Correlations between Consumption, Savings, and Wealth
Thus far, we have seen that the nature of productivity shocks,
whether they are anticipated or unanticipated, has significant
implications for the reactions of key economic variables. In particular,
we have seen that wealth and consumption do not always have to respond
in the same direction to a given productivity shock. We will emphasize
this point below by showing important differences in the
cross-correlation pattern of the data generated under each type of
shock.
Figure 8 presents the cross-correlations of consumption and the
savings rate with stock market wealth generated by the model. As in the
real-business-cycle literature, we first assume (in Figures 8a and 8b)
that the dominant source of uncertainty lies in productivity shocks,
which we calibrate as
ln [z.sup.t] = [[rho].sub.z] ln [z.sub.t-1] + [[epsilon].sub.zt],
(18)
where [[rho].sub.z] = 0.95 and [[epsilon].sub.zt] is an i.i.d.
normal random variable with mean zero and standard deviation 0.01. The
model statistics depicted in Figure 8 are the mean values calculated
from 200 simulations of samples with 216 observations each, the number
of quarterly observations in postwar U.S. data. Figures 8c and 8d
present the same cross-correlations under the assumption that all
productivity shocks are anticipated four periods in advance.
As we can see from the simulations in Figure 8, the
cross-correlation patterns of consumption and savings with wealth are
quite different depending on the nature of productivity shocks. When
shocks are unanticipated, the contemporaneous correlation between
consumption and wealth is very near 1. This contemporaneous correlation,
however, is much lower at 0.25 when productivity shocks are anticipated.
Therefore, to the degree that the U.S. economy is continuously hit by a
variety of shocks that are both unanticipated and anticipated--to
technology, preferences, or even public expenditures--and whose
processes may have changed over time, it is unlikely that a regression
of consumption on wealth would uncover a stable coefficient over
different sample periods.
Finally, it is important to recognize that the cross-correlation
patterns depicted in Figure 8 may change significantly with the
particular model at hand. For instance, Constantinides (1990) and Abel
(1990) suggest that habit formation is an important factor in explaining
consumption behavior. When subject to habit formation, consumption
reacts to various shocks only with a lag, and this lag may be essential
in helping us understand U.S. consumption data. In addition, the model
we have examined does not allow for the presence of credit-constrained
households. For these households, consumption may be more tied to
current income and wealth than is suggested by permanent income
households.
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
At the close of the 1990s, the U.S. economy experienced declining
savings, a rise in household equity value, and rapidly growing
consumption. At some level, this data appeared indicative of a
strengthening economy going forward. The Permanent Income Hypothesis
(PIH) indeed suggests that savings should fall in the current period if
increases in income are expected in the future and that the fall in
savings would simply reflect households' desire to smooth
consumption.
Contrary to this optimistic scenario, the U.S. economy slowed down
considerably in 2000. Consequently, it seems natural to reevaluate the
significance of the data in the late 1990s. With this task in mind, we
have stressed the following points.
First, the PIH notwithstanding, a fall in savings does not
necessarily reflect the expectation of future gains in income but can
instead reflect the current realization of an unanticipated, negative
economic shock. In the case of an unanticipated decline in productivity,
the level of savings continues to fall until it reaches a lower steady
state level. In contrast, in response to an anticipated positive shock
to future productivity, savings eventually rise to a higher steady state
level even if they fall initially.
Second, we have attempted to make clear that consumption and wealth
simultaneously react to fundamental changes in the economic environment.
In a general equilibrium context, there is no sense in which consumption
responds directly and positively to changes in wealth. The latter notion
has, in fact, been the starting point for many empirical studies, but we
have shown that when a future increase in productivity is fully
anticipated, consumption and wealth may initially move in opposite
directions. Furthermore, because both the consumption and wealth
responses to productivity disturbances are nonlinear, the measured
marginal propensity to consume out of wealth is unlikely to be constant.
In light of these results, the data on consumption, savings, and wealth
in the late 1990s should not necessarily have been interpreted as
presaging a future strengthening of the economy. Our numerical
experiments suggest that an anticipated rise in productivity, while
leading to a fall in savings and an increase in consumptio n in the
current period, initially generates a short-run decline in wealth. The
last response is at odds with the behavior of wealth at the end of the
last decade.
* The views expressed in this article are the authors' and do
not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. We wish to thank Michael Dotsey,
Margarida Duarte, Thomas Humphrey, and Yash Mehra for helpful
suggestions. All errors are our own.
(1.) See Kiley (2000) for a more detailed description of stock
price behavior in a production economy versus a partial equilibrium
setting.
(2.) For an early discussion of this formulation of investment
adjustment costs, see Abel and Blanchard (1983).
(3.) Hayashi (1982) shows that equation (12) always holds when the
production technology is constant returns to scale.
(4.) Until recently, this value has been approximately the average
implied by the S&P 500 index since 1949.
REFERENCES
Abel, Andrew B. "Asset Prices under Habit Formation and
Catching Up with the Joneses," American Economic Review, vol. 80
(May 1990), pp. 38-42.
____, and Olivier J. Blanchard. "An Intertemporal Model of
Saving and Investment," Econometrica, vol. 51 (May 1983), pp.
675-92.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. Economic Growth. New
York: McGraw-Hill, 1995.
Baxter, Marianne, and Mario J. Crucini. "Explaining
Saving-Investment Correlations," American Economic Review, vol. 83
(June 1993), pp. 416-36.
Constantinides, George M. "Habit Formation: A Resolution of
the Equity Premium Puzzle," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98
(June 1990), 519-43.
Davis, Morris A., and Michael G. Palumbo. "A Primer on the
Economics and Time Series Econometrics of Wealth Effects," Federal
Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series Working Paper
2001-09 (January 2001).
Friedman, Milton. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press, 1957.
Hall, Robert E. "Stochastic Implications of the Life-Cycle
Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence," Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 86 (December 1978), pp. 971-87.
Hayashi, Fumio. "The Permanent Income Hypothesis: Estimation
and Testing by Instrumental Variables," Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 90 (October 1982), pp. 895-916.
Kiley, Michael T. "Stock Price Fundamentals in a Production
Economy," Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion
Series Working Paper (January 2000).
Ludvigson, Sydney, and Charles Steindel. "How Important Is the
Stock Market Effect on Consumption?" Federal Reserve Bank of New
York Policy Review, vol. 5 (July 1999), pp. 29-51.
McGrattan, Ellen R., and Edward C. Prescott. "Is the Stock
Market Overvalued?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review, vol. 24 (Fall 2000), pp. 20-40.
Mehra, Yash P. "The Wealth Effect in Empirical Life-Cycle
Aggregate Consumption Equations," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly, vol. 87 (Spring 2001). pp. 45-68.
Peek, Joe. "Capital Gains and Personal Savings Behavior,"
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 15 (February 1983), pp. 1-23.
Poterba, James M. "Stock Market Wealth and Consumption,"
Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 14 (Spring 2000), pp. 99-118.
____, and Andrew A. Samwick. "Stock Ownership Patterns, Stock
Market Fluctuations, and Consumption," Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 1995 (Issue 2), pp. 295-357.
[Figure 1 omitted]
[Figure 2 omitted]
[Figure 3 omitted]
[Figure 4 omitted]
[Figure 5 omitted]
[Figure 6 omitted]
[Figure 7 omitted]
[Figure 8 omitted]
RELATED ARTICLE: APPENDIX: DERIVATION OF TOBIN'S q
This appendix describes the derivation of equation (12) in the
text. Specifically, multiplying both sides of equation (6) by
[k.sub.t+1] [greater than or equal to] 0 yields
[[lambda].sub.t][k.sub.t+1] = [Q.sub.t][alpha][y.sub.t+1] +
[Q.sub.t][[lambda].sub.t+1] [(1 - [delta])[k.sub.t+1] + [empty
set]([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1])[k.sub.t+1]]
-[Q.sub.t][[lambda].sub.t+1][empty
set]'([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1])[i.sub.t+1] .
In this last expression, [(1 - [delta])[k.sub.t+1] + [empty set]
([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1])[k.sub.t+1]] is simply [k.sub.t+2] while
[[lambda].sub.t+1][empty set]'([i.sub.t+1]/[k.sub.t+1]) = 1 by
equation (5). Therefore,
[[lambda].sub.t][k.sub.t+1] = [Q.subt.][[y.sub.t+1] -
[w.sub.t+1][n.sub.t+1] - [i.sub.t+1]] +
[Q.sub.t]([s.sub.t+1])[[lambda].sub.t+1][k.sub.t+2]
}[D.sub.t+1]
since [alpha][y.sub.t+1] = [y.sub.t+1] - [w.sub.t+1][n.sub.t+1]. By
repeatedly substituting for [[lambda].sub.t+j][k.sub.t+j+1], j [greater
than or equal to] 1, we have
[[summation over].sup.[infinity].sub.[tau]=1][[PI].sup.[tau]-1.sub.i=0][Q.sub.t+i ][D.sub.t+[tau]] = [[lambda].sub.t][k.sub.t+1],
where [[summation
over].sup.[infinity].sub.[tau]=1][[PI].sup.[tau]-1.sub.i=0][Q.sub.t+i
][D.sub.t+[tau]] is simply [V.sub.t] by equation (11) in the text. Thus,
[[lambda].sub.t] has the interpretation of Tobin's q.