International pricing in new open-economy models.
Duarte, Margarida
Recent developments in open-economy macroeconomics have progressed
under the paradigm of nominal price rigidities, where monetary
disturbances are the main source of fluctuations. Following developments
in closed-economy models, new open-economy models have combined price
rigidities and market imperfections in a fully microfounded
intertemporal general equilibrium setup. This framework has been used
extensively to study the properties of the international transmission of
shocks, as well as the welfare implications of alternative monetary and
exchange rate policies.
Imperfect competition is a key feature of the new open-economy
framework. Because agents have some degree of monopoly power instead of
being price takers, this framework allows the explicit analysis of
pricing decisions. The two polar cases for pricing decisions are
producer-currency pricing and local-currency pricing. The first case is
the traditional approach, which assumes that prices are preset in the
currency of the seller. In this case, prices of imported goods change
proportionally with unexpected changes in the nominal exchange rate, and
the law of one price always holds. (1) In contrast, under the assumption
of local-currency pricing, prices are preset in the buyer's
currency. Here, unexpected movements in the nominal exchange rate do not
affect the price of imported goods and lead to short-run deviations from
the law of one price.
Empirical evidence using disaggregated data suggests that
international markets for tradable goods remain highly segmented and
that deviations in the law of one price are large, persistent, and
highly correlated with movements in the nominal exchange rate, even for
highly tradable goods. Moreover, there is strong evidence that the large
and persistent movements that characterize the behavior of real exchange
rates at the aggregate level are largely accounted for by deviations in
the law of one price for tradable goods.
In this article I make use of a simplified version of a two-country
model where the two markets are segmented, allowing firms to price
discriminate across countries, and where prices are preset in the
consumer's currency. This model generates movements in the real
exchange rate in response to unexpected monetary shocks, which are a
result of the failure of the law of one price for tradable goods. I then
compare this model to a version in which prices are preset in the
producer's currency and examine the implications of these two
alternative price-setting regimes for several key issues.
The price-setting regime determines the currency of denomination of
imported goods and the extent to which changes in exchange rates affect
the relative price of imported to domestic goods and the international
allocation of goods in the short run. That is, different pricing regimes
imply different roles for the exchange rate in the international
transmission of monetary disturbances. As we shall see, this assumption
has very striking implications for several important questions, namely
real exchange rate variability, the linkage between macroeconomic volatility and international trade, and the welfare effects of
alternative exchange rate regimes, among others.
While generating deviations from the law of one price that are
absent from models assuming producer-currency pricing, the assumption of
local-currency pricing still leaves important features of the data
unexplained. The key role of this assumption in the properties of
open-economy models suggests that it is necessary to keep exploring the
implications of alternative pricing structures in open-economy models.
In Section 1, I review the empirical evidence on the behavior of
real exchange rates and on international market segmentation and
pricing. In Section 2, I present the model with local-currency pricing
and explore the main implications of this pricing assumption. The final
section concludes.
1. SOME EVIDENCE ON REAL EXCHANGE RATES
I first review some empirical evidence on the behavior of real
exchange rates using aggregate data. I then turn to a review of the
evidence on the sources of movements in real exchange rates.
Real Exchange Rates and PPP
The real exchange rate between two countries represents the
relative cost of a common reference basket of goods. For two countries,
say the United States and Japan, the real exchange rate is given by
[P.sub.US]/[eP.sub.JP],
where [P.sub.US]and [P.sub.JP] represent the American and Japanese
price levels (measured in terms of dollars and yen, respectively) and
where e denotes the nominal exchange rate (defined as the dollar price
of one yen). (2)
The theory of purchasing power parity (PPP) predicts that real
exchange rates should equal one, or at least show a strong tendency to
quickly return to one when they differ from this value. The fundamental
building block of PPP is the law of one price: due to arbitrage in goods
markets, and absent barriers to trade, similar products should sell in
different countries for the same price (when converted in the same
currency). Large international price differentials would be only
temporary, as profit-maximizing traders would quickly drive
international goods prices back in line. Therefore, if arbitrage in
goods markets ensures that the law of one price holds for a sufficiently
broad range of individual goods, then aggregate price levels (when
expressed in a common currency) should be highly correlated across
countries. (3)
Because aggregate prices are reported as indices rather than
levels, most empirical work has tested the weaker hypothesis of relative
PPP, which requires only that the real exchange rate be stable over
time. (4) Figure 1 shows the log changes in the CPI-based dollar-yen
real and nominal exchange rates and the relative price level. In this
figure, which is typical for countries with floating exchange rates and
moderate inflation, it clearly stands out that short-run deviations from
PPP are large and volatile. In the short run, movements in the real
exchange rate mimic those in the nominal exchange rate, with no
offsetting movements in the relative price level. Not surprisingly,
early empirical work based on simple tests of short-run PPP produced
strong rejections of this hypothesis for moderate inflation countries.
(5) However, these studies did not allow for any dynamics of adjustment
to PPP and therefore did not address the validity of PPP as a medium- or
long-run proposition.
The conventional explanation for the failure of short-run PPP is
the presence of nominal price rigidities. If the short-term volatility
of nominal exchange rates were due mostly to monetary and financial
disturbances, then nominal price stickiness would translate these
disturbances into short-run fluctuations in the real exchange rate. If
this were true, however, we should observe a substantial convergence to
PPP in one to two years, as the adjustment of prices and wages takes
place. Purchasing power parity, therefore, would be reestablished in the
medium to long run. (6)
An extensive body of empirical literature has tested the hypothesis
of long-run PPP by looking at the mean-reverting properties of real
exchange rates. As is well known, it has proved rather difficult to find
evidence supporting convergence of real exchange rates to PPP even in
the long run. (7)
Most earlier empirical studies, which used only post-Bretton Woods
data, found it difficult to reject the hypothesis that bilateral real
exchange rates for industrialized countries follow a random walk under
floating exchange rates. (8) But if PPP deviations are very persistent,
then it may be difficult to distinguish empirically between a random
walk model and a slow mean-reversion model for the real exchange rate,
especially when this variable is highly volatile. As shown in Frankel
(1986), the post-Bretton Woods period may simply be too short to
reliably reject the random walk hypothesis. To overcome this problem of
low power in tests of the random walk hypothesis, Frankel used an
extended data set (annual data for the dollar-pound exchange rate from
1869 to 1984) and rejected the random walk model in favor of a
mean-reverting model for the real exchange rate. His point estimate for
the rate of decay of real exchange rate deviations was 14 percent per
year, which implies a half-life of PPP deviations of 4. 6 years. Other
studies that test convergence to PPP using long-horizon data sets tend
to find values for the half-life of PPP deviations between three to five
years. (9)
An alternative way to increase the power of unit root tests is to
expand the number of countries in the sample and to perform panel tests
of convergence to PPP. Frankel and Rose (1996), for example, use a panel
set of annual data from 1948 to 1992 for 150 countries. They estimate
half-lives for PPP deviations of about four years. Other studies using
panel data sets report similar estimates. Interestingly, these estimates
are also similar to those obtained using long-time series data sets.
In brief, studies using aggregate data provide strong evidence that
deviations from PPP are highly volatile and persistent. Consensus
estimates suggest that the speed of convergence to PPP is roughly 15
percent per year, implying a half-life of PPP deviations of about four
years. As we shall see next, a look at disaggregated data will provide
us with a much richer analysis of the sources of PPP deviations.
The Law of One Price: Market Segmentation and International Pricing
As I pointed out earlier, the idea underlying PPP is that the law
of one price holds for a wide range of individual goods. It has long
been recognized, however, that even for highly tradable goods and at
different levels of aggregation, deviations in the law of one price are
large, persistent, and highly correlated with movements in the nominal
exchange rate. (10)
One possible explanation for the failure of the law of one price is
that international markets are segmented by physical distance, like
different markets within a country. Engel and Rogers (1996), however,
show that both the distance and the physical border between countries
are significant in explaining the variation in prices of similar goods
across different U.S. and Canadian cities. They find that price
dispersion is much higher for two cities located in different countries
than for two equidistant cities in the same country. In fact, the effect
of the border is estimated to be equivalent to a distance of 1780 miles
between cities within one country. Engel and Rogers also show that
nominal price stickiness accounts for a large portion of the border
effect, suggesting that prices are sticky in the local currency and that
changes in the exchange rate lead to deviations in the law of one price.
Not only are failures of the law of one price significant but, as
recent evidence suggests, they also play a dominant role in explaining
the behavior of real exchange rates. Engel (1999) measures the
proportion of U.S. real exchange rate movements that can be accounted
for by movements in the relative prices of nontraded goods. Engel
decomposes the CPI real exchange rate into two components: a weighted
difference of the relative price of nontraded-to traded-goods prices in
each country, and the relative price of traded goods between the
countries. If tradables, as a category, closely followed the law of one
price, then all variability in the real exchange rate would be explained
by movements in the first component. However, Engel finds that movements
in the relative price of nontraded goods appear to account for almost
none of the movement in U.S. real exchange rates, even at long time
horizons. Instead, nearly all the variability can be attributed to
movements in the relative price of tradables. This finding strongly
suggests that consumer markets for tradable goods are highly segmented
internationally and that movements in the international relative price
of consumer tradables are very persistent. (11) Moreover, given the high
volatility of nominal exchange rates, these findings indicate that
consumer prices of most goods (either imported or domestically produced)
seem to be sticky in domestic currency terms.
An alternative approach to studying the relationship between
exchange rates and goods prices is examining how firms in a industry (or
country) pass through changes in exchange rates to export prices. (12)
Knetter (1989, 1993) measures the degree of price discrimination across
export destinations that is associated with exchange rate changes for
U.S., U.K., German, and Japanese industry-level data. He finds that the
amount of exchange rate pass-through differs considerably depending on
the country and industry. Goldberg and Knetter (1997) provide an
extensive survey of the literature and find that local currency prices
of foreign products do not respond fully to exchange rate changes. While
the response varies by industry, on average exchange rate pass-through
to U.S. import prices is only about 50 percent after one year, mainly
reflecting changes in destination-specific markups on exports.
In brief, there is strong evidence that international markets for
tradable goods remain highly segmented and that deviations from PPP are
largely accounted for by movements in the relative price of tradable
goods across countries. At the consumer level, exchange rate
pass-through to import prices is virtually zero (suggesting that
consumer prices are sticky in domestic currency). At the producer level,
however, exchange rate pass-through is generally positive, but
substantially below one.
Transaction Costs and the Adjustment of PPP and Law of One Price
Deviations
Some recent empirical tests of long-run PPP and the law of one
price have abandoned the conventional framework, which assumes a linear
autoregressive process for the price differential. Instead, these
studies have started to look into nonlinear models of price adjustment,
where the speed at which price differentials die out depends on the size
of the deviation itself.
This alternative framework for the empirical analysis of price
differentials is motivated by the observation that commodity trade is
not costless. Persistent deviations from the law of one price are
implied as an equilibrium feature of models with transaction costs, for
deviations will be left uncorrected as long as they are sufficiently
small relative to the shipping cost. (13)
The simplest econometric model that implements the notion of a
nonlinear adjustment for price differentials assumes that the process is
well described by a random walk for small deviations (that is, when
deviations are within a "band of inaction") and an
autoregressive process for large deviations (that is, when deviations
are outside the band). (14) Taylor (2001) shows that the improper use of
linear models when the true model is nonlinear may produce a large bias
towards finding a low speed of convergence. (15) Intuitively, a linear
model will fail to support convergence to PPP if the true model is
nonlinear and the process spends most of the time in the random-walk
band. Using both monthly data from the 1920s and annual data spanning
two centuries, Michael, Nobay, and Peel (1997) reject the linear
adjustment model in favor of a nonlinear model and provide strong
evidence of mean-reverting behavior for PPP deviations for every
exchange rate considered. (16)
2. INTERNATIONAL PRICING IN NEW OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMIC MODELS
The common starting point for most of the recent research in
open-economy models with price rigidities is the model developed in
Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995). (l7) This model explores the international
monetary transmission mechanism in a general equilibrium setup
characterized by nominal price rigidities, imperfect competition, and
incomplete asset markets.
Obstfeld and Rogoff's model does not generate deviations from
the CPI-based purchasing power parity. This feature reflects the fact
that preferences are identical across countries and that all goods are
freely tradable, with prices set in the seller's currency. In this
model, there is complete pass-through of exchange rate changes to import
prices, implying that the law of one price always holds for all goods
and that the real exchange rate is constant.
Motivated by the empirical evidence on the sources of real exchange
rate fluctuations, several recent papers have extended Obstfeld and
Rogoff's framework in order to allow for pricing-to-market (18) and
deviations from the law of one price. This class of models assumes that
home and foreign markets are segmented, which allows imperfectly
competitive firms to price discriminate between home and foreign
consumers. (19) Consumers' inability to arbitrage price
differentials between countries is exogenous, possibly reflecting
arbitrarily high transportation costs at the consumer level. In addition
to market segmentation, this class of models also assumes that prices
are sticky in each country's local currency. That is, firms set
prices in advance in the buyer's currency, as opposed to the
standard assumption that prices are set in the seller's currency.
(20)
I next outline a basic model in which firms set prices in advance
in the local currency of the buyer (or pricing-to-market). The model is
then used to explore the main implications of pricing-to-market.
A Simple Model of Local-Currency Pricing
There are two countries, home and foreign. Households in each
country consume a continuum of differentiated goods, which are indexed
by i, i [euro] [0,1]. A fraction n of these goods is produced by firms
located in the home country, and the remaining fraction 1 - n is
produced by firms located in the foreign country. (21)
Home and foreign households have identical preferences. In the home
country, these preferences are defined by
U = [[summation over ([infinity]/t=0)] [[beta].sup.t] u ([c.sub.t],
[M.sub.t]/[P.sub.t], 1 - [l.sub.t]).
The term [C.sub.t] represents the agent's total consumption.
It is an index given by
[c.sub.t] = [[[[integral].sup.1.sub.0] [c.sub.t]
[(i).sup.[theta]-1/[theta]] di].sup.[theta]/[theta]-1] (1)
which aggregates the consumption of all differentiated goods,
[c.sub.t] (i). The parameter [theta] is the elasticity of substitution between any two differentiated goods, and for values of [theta] greater
than 1, different goods are imperfect substitutes in consumption.
Besides consumption, the consumer's momentary utility also depends
on leisure, 1 - [l.sub.t], and real money balances held during the
period, [M.sub.t]/[P.sub.t], where [M.sub.t] are nominal balances and
[P.sub.t] is the home country consumption price index.
Let [P.sub.t] (i) represent the home currency price of good i.
Given these prices, [P.sub.t] represents the minimum expenditure
necessary to buy one unit of composite good c. The price index
corresponding to c is given by
[P.sub.t] = [[[[integral].sup.1.sub.0] [P.sub.t]
[(i).sup.1-[theta]] di].sup.1/1-[theta]] (2)
Given the aggregate consumption index (1), the household's
optimal allocation of consumption across each of the differentiated
goods yields the demand functions
[c.sub.t] (i) = [([p.sub.t](i)/[p.sub.t]).sup.-theta]] [c.sub.t], i
[euro][0, 1]. (3)
Note that home demand functions for foreign goods [c.sub.t] (i), i
[euro] [n, 1], do not depend on the nominal exchange rate. As we shall
see, this follows from the fact that the home price of foreign goods is
denominated in the home currency.
As outlined above, home and foreign markets are segmented,
effectively allowing firms to price discriminate across the two markets.
Therefore, home firm i, i [euro] [0, n], will choose separately the
price for its good in the home country, [p.sub.t], (i), and in the
foreign country, [p.sub.t.sup.*] (i), in order to maximize its total
profits. By assumption, these prices are denominated in the buyer's
currency. That is, [p.sub.t] (i) is denominated in home currency and
[p.sub.t.sup.*] (i) is denominated in foreign currency.
Home firm i operates the production function [y.sub.t] = [l.sub.t]
(i), where [l.sub.t] (i) represents hours worked, and period t profits
are given by [[pi].sub.t] (i) = [p.sub.t] (i) [c.sub.t] (i) + [e.sub.t]
[p.sub.t.sup.*] (i) [c.sub.t.sup.*] (i) -- [w.sub.t]([c.sub.t](i) +
[p.sub.t.sup.*] (i)). The term [w.sub.t] is the real wage rate and the
nominal exchange rate, [e.sub.t], converts the revenues from sales in
the foreign country into home currency. Profit maximization is made
subject to the firm's production function and home and foreign
demand functions for its good (equation (3) and the analogous expression
for the foreign consumer).
When nominal prices are flexible, home firm i sets its prices as
[p.sub.t] (i) = [e.sub.t] [p.sub.t.sup.*] (i) = [theta]/[theta]-1
[w.sub.t],
i.e., the optimal pricing function rule for each firm is to set its
price in each market as a constant markup over marginal cost. (22)
Therefore, the law of one price holds for each good, even though firms
have the ability to price discriminate across markets. The model with
flexible prices does not generate deviations from PPP. (23)
Next suppose that firms set prices in advance at a level that
achieves the optimal markup in the absence of shocks. Firms cannot
adjust prices within the period in response to shocks, accommodating
ex-post demand at the preset prices. Prices adjust fully after one
period. As before, firms are assumed to set prices in the local currency
of sale. Therefore, in this case, unanticipated changes in the exchange
rate lead to deviations in the law of one price. In this model,
deviations from PPP result only from deviations from the law of one
price, i.e., from movements in the relative price of similar goods
across countries.
The Transmission of Monetary Shocks
When prices are preset in the buyer's currency, an unexpected
depreciation of domestic currency has no expenditure-switching effect in
the short run. In response to the exchange rate change firms are assumed
to keep foreign currency export prices fixed, allowing their foreign
markups to adjust. Since consumer demand functions do not depend on the
nominal exchange rate and exchange rate pass-through to consumer prices
is zero on impact, changes in this variable are dissociated, on impact,
from allocation decisions.
In response to an unexpected positive shock to the home money
supply, the nominal exchange rate immediately depreciates. Since prices
only respond after one period and are denominated in the buyer's
currency, the adjustment in the nominal exchange rate translates into a
real depreciation and does not affect the relative price of home and
foreign goods in either country. Thus, the increase in total consumption
in the home country associated with the positive money shock is brought
about by an increase in consumption of both domestic and foreign goods
in the same proportion, as equation (3) shows. If, instead, prices were
set in the seller's currency, the increase in the nominal exchange
rate would lead to an immediate increase in the home currency price of
foreign goods ([e.sub.t][p.sub.t] (f), where [p.sub.t] (f) is now
denominated in foreign currency), while the price of home goods in the
home country, [p.sub.t] (h), would remain unchanged. Similarly, nominal
depreciation would reduce the foreign currency pr ice of home goods
([p.sup.*.sub.t](h)/[e.sub.t], with [p.sup.*.sub.t] (h) denominated in
home currency), while leaving the price of foreign goods in the foreign
country, [p.sup.*.sub.t] (f), unchanged. Thus, in this case, the
positive money shock would decrease the relative price of home to
foreign goods on impact in both countries (24) and both agents would
substitute consumption towards home goods and away from foreign goods.
Thus, having prices set in the buyer's currency eliminates, on
impact, the expenditure switching effect associated with unexpected
changes in the nominal exchange rate; the absence of this effect in turn
influences the international transmission of monetary disturbances.
Without pricing-to-market, monetary disturbances tend to generate
high positive comovements of consumption across countries and large
negative comovements of output. In response to a positive money shock in
the home country, the real exchange rate (i.e., the relative price of
consumption across countries) remains constant, leading to the large
positive comovement of consumption across countries. Consumption
increases in both countries, reflecting the increase in real money
balances in the home country and the decline in the consumer price index
in the foreign country. At the same time, foreign goods become more
expensive relative to home goods and both agents substitute consumption
towards home goods and away from foreign goods. Therefore, in response
to this expenditure-switching effect, production shifts away from the
foreign country to the home country, implying a negative comovement of
output across countries.
With pricing-to-market, a positive money shock in the home country
is associated with a real exchange rate depreciation, which leads the
comovement of consumption across countries to fall. In this case,
however, the relative price of home to foreign goods is left unchanged
and the elimination of the expenditure switching effect increases the
comovement of output across countries.
Implications of Local-Currency Pricing for Two-Country Models
Several recent papers have explored the implications of incomplete
short-run exchange rate pass-through for a series of wide-ranging
questions in international economics. Since the nature of international
pricing has a crucial effect on the international transmission of
monetary disturbances, this assumption substantially affects the
business-cycle properties of open-economy models, the welfare properties
of alternative exchange rate regimes, and the characterization of
optimal monetary and exchange rate policies. I now highlight some of
these issues.
Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2000) calibrate a stochastic pricing-to-market model and investigate whether the interaction of
staggered prices with money shocks can account for the observed behavior
of real exchange rates. (25) They show that their model is successful in
generating real exchange rates that are as volatile as in data, but not
as persistent. Since in a monopolistic competition framework unexpected
money shocks do not generate movements in the real exchange rate beyond
the periods of (exogenously-imposed) nominal stickiness, this model is
not able to generate sufficiently persistent real exchange rates. (26)
The business-cycle properties of different exchange rate regimes
are explored in Duarte (2001) in a calibrated pricing-to-market model.
Baxter and Stockman (1989) and Flood and Rose (1995) show that,
following a change from pegged to floating exchange rate systems,
countries with moderate inflations experience a systematic and sharp
increase in the variability of the real exchange rate, while the
behavior of other macroeconomic variables remains largely unaffected by
the change in regime. This puzzling evidence can be accounted for in a
model with prices set one period in advance in the local currency of the
buyer. By eliminating the expenditure-switching effect of exchange rates
in the short run, this model predicts a sharp increase in the volatility
of the real exchange rate following a change from fixed to flexible
exchange rates, without generating a similar pattern for the
volatilities of output, consumption, or trade flows.
Devereux and Engel (1998) compare the welfare properties of fixed
and flexible exchange rate systems in an explicitly stochastic setting.
Under uncertainty, firms incorporate a risk premium in their pricing
decision, which affects the equilibrium prices that are chosen. This
effect on equilibrium prices in turn has an impact on expected output
and consumption levels and ex-ante welfare levels. Devereux and Engel
show that the exchange rate regime influences not only the variance of
consumption and output, but also their average values, and that the
optimal exchange rate regime depends crucially on the nature of pricing.
They find that under producer-currency pricing there is a trade-off
between floating and fixed exchange rates, while floating exchange rates
always dominate fixed exchange rates under consumer-currency pricing.
The nature of currency pricing also has substantial implications
for the welfare effects of monetary policy and international policy
coordination. Since consumer import prices do not respond, in the short
run to changes in the exchange rate, pricing-to-market models predict
that unexpected currency depreciations are associated with an
improvement of the country's terms of trade, rather than with the
deterioration that occurs with producer-currency pricing. For example,
if the dollar depreciates and consumer prices are sticky (in the local
currency), then the dollar price paid in the United States for imported
goods remains the same, while the price of American exported goods rises
when translated into dollars. Betts and Devereux (2000) show that this
effect of domestic monetary expansions on the terms of trade raises
domestic welfare at the expense of foreign welfare. That is,
expansionary monetary policy is a "beggar-thy-neighbor"
instrument. This result contrasts sharply with the prediction from a
model wit h PPP, where a surprise monetary expansion in one country
raises welfare in both countries (Obstfeld and Rogoff 1995).
Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000b) argue that the positive relation
between exchange rate depreciations and terms of trade implied by
pricing-to-market models is at odds with the empirical evidence. They
present some evidence supporting the conventional idea that currency
depreciations cause the terms of trade to deteriorate. The role of the
degree of exchange rate pass-through in the allocative effect of
exchange rate changes and the importance of this mechanism in the
properties of open-economy models show that it is crucial to explore the
implications of new open-economy models with more realistic pricing
assumptions. In particular, it is important to study the implications of
models that can distinguish the apparent zero exchange rate pass-through
at the consumer level from the clearly positive (but smaller than one)
exchange rate pass-through at the producer level. In a recent
contribution to the literature, Corsetti and Dedola (2001) introduce
labor intensive distribution services in an otherwise standard two-
country model with preset wages. They show that the law of one price
fails to hold at both producer and consumer levels and that monetary
shocks may result in expenditure switching effects.
3. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This article focuses on the implications of alternative
international price-setting regimes in open-economy models that
incorporate nominal price rigidities and monopolistic competition. Most
of the recent research in this field has progressed under. the
assumption of either producer-currency pricing or consumer-currency
pricing. Since the nature of price setting determines the effect of
exchange rate changes on the relative price of imported to domestic
goods in the short run, the price-setting assumption determines the role
of exchange rates in shifting consumer allocation decisions across
countries. Therefore, the international monetary transmission mechanism
differs markedly under these two alternatives, yielding very different
predictions for many substantial issues in international economics.
Assuming that prices are set in advance in the consumer's
currency allows for short-run deviations in the law of one price for
tradable goods, which occur in response to unexpected changes in the
exchange rate. These deviations in turn generate movements in the real
exchange rate, as is suggested by recent empirical evidence.
Pricing-to-market models have been able to replicate a number of key
international business-cycle properties, both for floating exchange rate
periods and across alternative regimes.
In pricing-to-market models, exchange rate pass-through to consumer
import prices is zero in the short run. This feature of the model
implies that exchange rate depreciations and the terms of trade are
positively correlated, a relation that is not supported by the data.
While the data suggests that exchange rate pass-through at the
consumer level is indeed close to zero, it is clearly positive (but
incomplete) at the producer level. Given the crucial role played by the
international price-setting regime in the international transmission
mechanism of monetary disturbances, it is clearly important to explore
the implications of distinct exchange rate pass-throughs at the consumer
and producer levels.
The author would like to thank Michael Dotsey, Thomas Humphrey,
Yash Mehra, and John Walter for helpful comments. The views expressed in
this article do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1.) The law of one price states that, absent barriers to trade, a
commodity should sell for the same price (when measured in a common
currency) in different countries.
(2.) Suppose that the United States and Japan have the same price
levels when measured in their respective currencies (for example,
[P.sub.US] = [P.sub.JP] = 1) and that the nominal exchange rate is two
(that is, two dollars are required to buy one yen). Then, the Japanese
price level is two when measured in dollars and the real exchange rate
between the United States and Japan is 0.5.
(3.) For a thorough exposition of the evolution of the PPP theory
of exchange rates, see Humphrey and Keleher (1982, chapter 11).
(4.) In other words, relative PPP requires only that changes in
relative price levels be offset by changes in the nominal exchange rate.
(5.) See, for example, Frenkel (1981) or Krugman (1978).
(6.) See Stockman (1987) for an alternative, equilibrium view of
exchange rates.
(7.) For a survey of this literature and a more complete list of
references, see Froot and Rogoff (1995) or Rogoff (1996).
(8.) Typically, the real exchange rate, [q.sub.t], is assumed to
follow a linear AR(l) specification,
[q.sub.t] = [rho][q.sub.t]-1 + [[euro].sub.t],
where [[euro].sub.t] ~ N (0, [[sigma].sup.2]). This specification
means that the adjustment of PPP deviations is both continuous and of
constant speed, regardless of the size of the deviation. Given this
specification, the convergence speed is given by [lambda] = 1 - [rho]
and the half-life of deviations is given by H = ln 0.5/ln [rho].
(9.) Mussa (1986) demonstrates that real exchange rates tend to be
much more volatile under floating than under fixed exchange rate
regimes. Therefore, these long-horizon data sets mix data from different
regimes, which exhibit different properties for the real exchange rate.
See Lothian and Taylor (1996) for a response to this criticism.
(10.) See, for example, the empirical studies in Isard (1977),
Giovannini (1988), or Engel (1993).
(11.) One should note, however, that at the consumer level, even
highly tradable goods embody a large nontradable component.
(12.) Exchange rate pass-through is the percentage change in local
currency import prices resulting from a 1 percent change in the exchange
rate between the exporting and importing countries.
(13.) See Dumas (1992) and Ohanian and Stockman (1997) for
equilibrium models of exchange rate determination in the presence of
transaction costs. Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000a) argue for the importance
of transaction costs in explaining several puzzles in international
macroeconomics.
(14.) Specifically, the price differential [q.sub.t] follows the
process
[q.sub.t] = {c + [rho]([q.sub.t-l] - c) + [[epsilon].sub.t] if
[q.sub.t-l] > c,
[q.sub.t-l] + [[epsilon].sub.t] if c [greater than or equal to]
[q.sub.t-l] [greater than or equal to] -c,
-c + [rho] ([q.sub.t-l] + c) + [[epsilon].sub.t] if - c >
[q.sub.t-l],
where [[epsilon].sub.t] N (0. [[sigma].sup.2]). This process is
parametrized by [rho]. the autoregressive coefficient for deviations
from the band's edge, and c, which determines the amplitude of the
band of inaction.
(15.) Taylor (2001) also addresses the problem of temporal
aggregation and shows that the use of relatively low-frequency data may
also produce large biases in these estimates.
(16.) See also Obstfeld and Taylor (1997) and Taylor, Peel, and
Sarno (2001).
(17.) This work extends the model in Svensson and van wijenbergen
(1989), an endowment two-country dynamic general equilibrium model,
where monopolistic competitive firms set prices one period in advance
and asset markets are complete.
(18.) Strictly speaking, the term pricing-to-market refers to the
ability of firms to engage in third-degree price discriminations across
different export destinations. In its current use, however, the term has
come to include the additional assumption that firms set their prices in
advance in the local currency of the buyer.
(19.) See Betts and Devereux (1996) for the initial contribution.
(20.) In these models, the firm's choice of invoice currency
is exogenous. See Devereux and Engel (2001) for a recent contribution to
the literature in which exporting firms can also choose the currency in
which they set export prices. They find that exporters will generally
wish to set prices in the currency of the country that has the most
stable monetary policy.
(21.) The fractions n and 1 - n also represent the sizes of the
home and foreign countries, respectively.
(22.) In this monopolistic competition framework, markups are
constant, precluding the analysis of possible effects of exchange rates
on markups.
See Bergin and Feenstra (1998) for a pricing-to-market model with
translog preferences that departs from the monopolistic competition
framework.
(23.) This is a result of assuming that the elasticities of demand
are identical in both markets.
(24.) With seller's currency, this relative price in the home
country would be [p.sub.t](h)/[e.sub.t][p.sub.t](f), where [p.sub.t] (f)
is now preset in units of foreign currency. An unexpected rise in
[e.sub.t] lowers this relative price.
(25.) See Kollmann (1997) for a calibrated small open economy in
which both wages and prices are sticky.
(26.) See Bergin and Feenstra (2001) for an exploration of the
volatility and persistence properties of real exchange rates in a model
with translog preferences and intermediate inputs that generates
endogenous persistence. In a closed economy setup, Dotsey and King
(2001) build a model with structural features that substantially reduce
the elasticity of marginal cost with respect to output, generating
greater endogenous persistence. The implication of this model's
features for the behavior of real exchange rates in a two-country model
is still an open question.
REFERENCES
Baxter, Marianne, and Alan Stockman. 1989. "Business Cycles
and the Exchange Rate Regime: Some International Evidence." Journal
of Monetary Economics 23 (May): 377-400.
Bergin, Paul, and Robert Feenstra. 2001. "Pricing-to-Market,
Staggered Contracts, and Real Exchange Rate Persistence." Journal
of International Economics 54 (August): 333-59.
Betts, Caroline, and Michael B. Devereux. 1996. "The Exchange
Rate in a Model of Pricing to Market." European Economic Review 40
(April): 1007-21.
_____ 2000. "Exchange Rate Dynamics in a Model of
Pricing-to-Market." Journal of International Economics 50
(February): 215-44.
Chari, V. V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan. 2000. "Can
Sticky Prices Models Generate Volatile and Persistent Real Exchange
Rates?" Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department
Staff Report 223.
Corsetti, Giancarlo, and Luca Dedola. 2001. "International
Price Discrimination and Macroeconomics." Manuscript, Yale
University and Banca d'Italia.
Devereux, Michael, and Charles Engel. 1998. "Fixed versus
Floating Exchange Rates: How Price Setting Affects the Optimal Choice of
Exchange Rate Regime." NBER Working Paper 6867.
_____ 2001. "Endogenous Currency of Price Setting in a Dynamic
Open Economy Model." Manuscript, University of Wisconsin, Madison,
and University of British Columbia.
Dotsey, Michael, and Robert King. 2001. "Pricing, Production,
and Persistence." NBER Working Paper 8407.
Duarte, Margarida. 2000. "Why Don't Macroeconomic
Quantities Respond to Exchange Rate Variability? Comparing Fixed and
Floating Exchange Rate Systems." Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond.
Dumas, Bernard. 1992. "Dynamic Equilibrium and the Real
Exchange Rate in a Spatially Separated World." The Review of
Financial Studies 5: 153-80.
Engel, Charles. 1993. "Real Exchange Rates and Relative
Prices: An Empirical Investigation." Journal of Monetary Economics
32 (August): 35-50.
_____. 1999. "Accounting for U.S. Real Exchange Rate
Changes." Journal of Political Economy 107 (June): 507-38.
_____, and John Rogers. 1996. "How Wide Is the Border?"
American Economic Review 86 (December): 1112-25.
Flood, Robert, and Andrew Rose. 1995. "Fixing Exchange Rates:
A Virtual Quest for Fundamentals." Journal of Monetary Economics 36
(December): 3-38.
Frankel, Jeffrey. 1986. "International Capital Mobility and
Crowding-out in the U.S. Economy: Imperfect Integration of Financial
Markets or of Goods Markets?" In How Open Is the U.S. Economy?, ed.
R. W. Hafer. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books: 33-67.
_____, and Andrew Rose. 1996. "A Panel Project on Purchasing
Power Parity: Mean Reversion Within and Between Countries." Journal
of International Economics 40 (February): 209-24.
Frenkel, Jacob. 1981. "The Collapse of Purchasing Power Parities During the 1970's." European Economic Review 16
(May): 145-65.
Froot, Kenneth, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. "Perspectives on PPP
and Long-Run Real Exchange Rate Rates." In Handbook of
International Economics, vol. 3, ed. K. Rogoff and G. Grossman.
Giovannini, Alberto. 1988. "Exchange Rates and Traded Goods
Prices." Journal of International Economics 24 (February): 45-68.
Goldberg, Pinelopi, and Michael Knetter. 1997. "Goods Prices
and Exchange Rates: What Have We Learned?" Journal of Economic
Literature 35 (September): 1243-72.
Humphrey, Thomas, and Robert Keleher. 1982. The Monetary Approach
to the Balance of Payments, Exchange Rates, and World Inflation. New
York: Praeger Publishers.
Isard, Peter. 1977. "How Far Can We Push the 'Law of One
Price'?" American Economic Review 67 (December): 942-48.
Knetter, Michael. 1989. "Price Discrimination by U.S. and
German Exporters." American Economic Review 79 (March): 198-210.
_____. 1993. "International Comparisons of Pricing-to-Market
Behavior." American Economic Review 83 (June): 473-86.
Kollmann, Robert. 1997. "The Exchange Rate in a
Dynamic-Optimizing Current Account Model with Nominal Rigidities: A
Quantitative Investigation." IMF Working Paper 97/7.
Krugman, Paul. 1978. "Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange
Rates: Another Look at the Evidence." Journal of International
Economics 8 (August): 397-407.
Lane, Philip. 2000. "The New Open Economy Macroeconomics: a
Survey." Trinity Economic Paper Series, Paper No. 3.
Lothian, James, and Mark Taylor. 1996. "Real Exchange Rate
Behavior: the Recent Float From the Perspective of the Past Two
Centuries." Journal of Political Economy 104: 488-509.
Michael, Panos, Robert Nobay, and David Peel. 1997.
"Transaction Costs and Nonlinear Adjustment in Real Exchange Rates:
An Empirical Investigation." Journal of Political Economy 105
(June): 862-79.
Mussa, Michael. 1986. "Nominal Exchange Rate Regimes and the
Behavior of Real Exchange Rates: Evidence and Implications."
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 25: 117-214.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. "Exchange Rate
Dynamics Redux." Journal of Political Economy 103 (June): 624-60.
_____. 2000a. "The Six Major Puzzles in International
Macroeconomics: Is There a Common Cause?," NBER Working Paper 7777.
_____. 2000b. "New Directions for Stochastic Open Economy
Models." Journal of International Economics 50 (February): 117-53.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Alan Taylor. 1997. "Nonlinear Aspects
of Goods-Market Arbitrage and Adjustment: Heckscher's Commodity
Points Revisited." Journal of the Japanese and International
Economies 11 (December): 441-79.
Ohanian, Lee, and Alan Stockman. 1997. "Arbitrage Costs and
Exchange Rates." Manuscript, University of California, Los Angeles,
and University of Rochester.
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1996. "The Purchasing Power Parity
Puzzle." Journal of Economic Literature 34 (June): 647-68.
Stockman, Alan. 1987. "The Equilibrium Approach to Exchange
Rates." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 73
(March/April): 12-30.
Svensson, Lars, and Sweder van Wijnbergen. 1989. "Excess
Capacity, Monopolistic Competition, and International Transmission of
Monetary Disturbances." Economic Journal 99 (September): 785-805.
Taylor, Alan. 2001. "Potential Pitfalls for the
Purchasing-Power-Parity Puzzle? Sampling and Specification Biases in
Mean-Reversion Tests of the Law of One Price." Econometrica 69
(March): 473-98.
Taylor, Mark, David Peel, and Lucio Sarno. 2001. "Nonlinear
Mean-Reversion in Real Exchange Rates: Toward a Solution to the
Purchasing Power Parity Puzzles." International Economic Review 42
(4): 1015-42.
[Figure 1 omitted]