The IT Revolution: Is It Evident in the Productivity Numbers?
Hornstein, Andreas ; Krusell, Per
There is little doubt that we are witnessing a technological
revolution. The question is, does this technological revolution have
revolutionary economic consequences? In particular, is economic
productivity growing at a much faster rate today, and if so, will it
continue to do so in the future? In this article, we review recent
literature on the measurement of productivity growth in the United
States. We find considerable evidence that the internet technology (IT)
revolution has had an impact on productivity.
In order to understand the effects of IT on today's economy,
one should look at the past century. When we consider postwar U.S.
productivity movements, two events stand Out: the impressive
productivity growth performance from the end of World War II up to the
early seventies, and the ensuing productivity slowdown, which lasted
until the mid-nineties. Labor productivity growth, which averaged about
2 percent per year from the fifties on, suddenly decreased to nearly 0
percent, and then seemed to settle at a rate around 1 percent. Moreover,
this postwar productivity pattern is observed not only for the U.S. but
throughout the western world.
This productivity slowdown remains quite poorly understood (for an
overview and detailed data, see Hornstein and Krusell [1996]). One
interpretation of the productivity data is that the fast postwar growth
was a transitional period that made up for the losses during the Great
Depression, and the post-1974 period of low productivity growth rates is
really the normal state of the economy. We are not convinced that this
view is correct. From our perspective, the productivity slowdown is
interesting because it occurred at the same time that IT applications
became more widespread in the economy. The paradox is that new
technology developments since that time have been associated with a
productivity slowdown, and not an upturn, at least until quite recently.
In other words, economists have had legitimate reasons to challenge
those talking about a technology revolution on economic grounds: for it
to have had significance, productivity growth (or economic welfare
measured in some other way) ought to have gone up.
This article points to a number of reasons why the technology
revolution may have had a significant impact on the economy's
production structure despite its apparent insignificance in aggregate
productivity statistics. First, we emphasize a number of methodological
issues that may have prevented standard accounting procedures from
detecting increases in productivity. Second, we take the view that the
technology revolution may have affected the production structure in a
quite asymmetric form, mainly showing its economic impact through
changes in relative prices. Given this view, we investigate the
hypothesis that the technology revolution, after all, has had important
consequences on productivity: (1) it has led to radical changes in
productivity among different sectors/factors of production; and (2) a
number of factors related to the technology developments themselves have
resulted in measures of aggregate performance that do not accurately
reflect the (positive) effects on the economy. We find that while the re
is some support for this hypothesis, the evidence is not conclusive.
In Section 1 we review recent methodological and measurement
advances in standard growth accounting, also known as "total factor
productivity" accounting, which uses some basic economic theory to
account for changes in productivity. The central question is the extent
to which we have been, and are still, witnessing a technology revolution
that has a large impact on the productivity of our economies. The IT
boom has radical implications not just as an example of rapid structural
change, but also from a measurement perspective. In particular, it seems
to have brought about, and promises to bring many more, large changes in
a range of products used as both inputs and outputs. Existing
measurement methods may quickly become obsolete as products change and
new products are introduced, and substantial work to improve these
methods, both theoretically and with new forms of data collection,
becomes of first-order importance. An increasingly large part of the
output of our economy now has a quality-improvement aspect to it that is
nontrivial to capture quantitatively. Quality mismeasurement is a long
recognized problem, especially in the service sector (where output is
often measured directly by input), and we can learn from attempts by
economists to deal with this sector. In this article we discuss--at a
broad level--what the main problems are and what advances have been
implemented so far. We then present the most recent estimates of
aggregate productivity change for the United States using improved
methods.
In Section 2 we review some recent literature on factor-specific
productivity (FSP) accounting. The FSP approach imposes additional
theoretical structure on the measurement of productivity and attempts a
more detailed account of the sources of the productivity change. The
motivation for moving from TFP to FSP measurement is based on the large
changes in various relative prices that we have observed during the past
few decades. First, equipment prices have fallen at a rapid rate; the
seminal work by Gordon (1990) documents these developments in detail,
based on careful quality measures of a large range of durable goods.
Second, relative prices of skilled and unskilled labor have gone through
large swings, most recently with a large increase in the relative wage
of educated workers. These relative price changes suggest that there are
factor-specific productivity changes. More theory is needed--that is,
more assumptions need to be made--in order to gain more precise insights
into the nature of the technology cha nges. We therefore spend time
developing some theory necessary to shed light on these issues on a
conceptual level, before discussing some recent practical applications.
1. TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY
Concept
Standard economic theory views production as the transformation of
a collection of inputs into outputs. We are interested in how this
production structure is changing over time. In this section we derive
the basic concepts used in productivity accounting.
We keep things simple and assume that there is one output, y, and
two inputs, capital k and labor n. The production structure is
represented by the production function, F: y = F (k, n, t). Since the
production structure may change, the production function is indexed by
time t. Productivity changes when the production function shifts over
time, i.e., there is a change in output that we cannot attribute to
changes in inputs. More formally, the marginal change in output is the
sum of the marginal changes in inputs, weighted by their marginal
contributions to output (marginal products), and the shift of the
production function y = [F.sub.k]k + [F.sub.n]n + [[F.sub.t]. [1] This
is usually expressed in terms of growth rates as
y = [[eta].sub.k]k + [[eta].sub.n]n + z, with z = [F.sub.t] / F,
where hats denote growth rates and the weight on an input growth
rate is the elasticity of output with respect to the input: [eta]k =
[F.sub.k]k/F and = [[eta].sub.n] = [F.sub.n]n/F. Alternatively, if we
know the elasticities we can derive productivity growth as output growth
minus a weighted sum of input growth rates. Indeed, it was Solow's
(1957) important insight that under two assumptions we can replace an
input's output elasticity, which we do not observe, with the
input's share in total revenue, which we do. First, we assume that
production is constant returns to scale, i.e., if we double all inputs,
then output will double. This implies that the output elasticities sum
to one: [[eta].sub.k] + [[eta].sub.n] = 1. Second, we assume that
producers act competitively in their output and input markets, i.e.,
they take the prices of their products and inputs as given. Profit
maximization then implies that inputs are employed until the marginal
revenue product of an input is equal to the price of that input. In
turn, this implies that the output elasticity of an input is equal to
the input's revenue share. For example, for the employment of
labor, profit maximization implies that [p.sub.y] [F.sub.n] = [p.sub.n],
which can be rewritten as [[eta].sub.n] = [F.sub.n]n/F =
[p.sub.n]n/[p.sub.y]y = [[alpha].sub.n] ([p.sub.i] stands for the price
of good i). With these two assumptions we can calculate productivity
growth, also known as total factor productivity (TFP) growth, as
z = y = (1 - [[alpha].sub.n] k - [[alpha].sub.n]n.
Implementation of the Solow growth accounting procedure thus
requires reliable information on the prices and quantities of inputs and
outputs. We discuss below some of the issues that arise in productivity
accounting and how they are affected by the current advances in
information technologies.
Implementation and Weaknesses
In this section we discuss issues of aggregation, changes of
quality versus quantity, missing inputs, and available observations on
prices. Finally, we briefly discuss the underlying assumptions of
constant returns to scale and perfect competition.
Aggregation
Any modern economy produces a large variety of commodities and uses
an equally large variety of commodities as inputs in production. In
order to make useful statements on the overall performance of the
economy, we have to define broad commodity aggregates. The theoretically
preferred aggregation procedure is the construction of Divisia indexes
(see, for example, Jorgenson, Gollop, and Fraumeni [1987] or Hulten
[[1973]). [2] In practice we approximate a Divisia index with a
chain-linked price and quantity index.
As an example, consider the production structure described above,
but assume that there are two types of labor: unskilled labor [n.sub.u]
and skilled labor [n.sub.s], which trade at prices [w.sub.u] and
[w.sub.s]. Suppose that skilled and unskilled labor combine and generate
the labor aggregate n = G ([n.sub.u], [n.sub.s]). The aggregator
function G is constant returns to scale. Using the same arguments as
above for the Solow growth accounting procedure, we can write aggregate
labor growth as a cost-share-weighted sum of the skilled and unskilled
labor growth rates
n = [[omega].sub.u][n.sub.u] + [[omega].sub.s][n.sub.s],
where [[omega].sub.u] = [w.sub.u][n.sub.u]/([w.sub.u][n.sub.u] +
[w.sub.s][n.sub.s]) and [[omega].sub.s] =
[w.sub.s][n.sub.s]/([w.sub.u][n.sub.u] + [w.sub.s][n.sub.s]). Notice
that the aggregator function is time invariant, i.e., the productivity
of skilled and unskilled labor does not change over time. Essentially,
this is an identification assumption: given our assumptions we can only
make statements about aggregate productivity, not about factor-specific
productivity. We will return to this issue below. In general, if we have
prices and quantities for a collection of commodities
{([p.sub.i],[q.sub.i]) : i = 1, ... ,m} we assume that there is a
constant returns-to-scale aggregator function q = Q
([q.sub.1],...,[q.sub.m]), and define the growth rate of the aggregate
quantity index as
q = [[[sigma].sup.m].sub.i=1] [p.sub.i][q.sub.i]/pq [q.sub.i] with
pq = [[[sigma].sup.m].sub.i=1][p.sub.i][q.sub.i]
and p is the implicit aggregate price index. The expression for the
growth rate of aggregate output is also the definition of the Divisia
quantity index for this particular collection of commodities.
The level of aggregation depends on the focus of the research.
Recent research on the effects of IT has tried to establish how much of
output growth can be attributed to IT capital accumulation and if the
spread of IT has affected TFP growth in various industries
differentially. For this purpose, researchers have constructed separate
aggregates for IT related capital, such as computing and communications
equipment and other capital goods. In this context, Divisia indexes have
the nice property that they aggregate consistently. Therefore, we can
first construct industry TFP growth from industry output, capital, and
labor growth, then use the industry data to construct aggregate output,
capital, and labor growth, and finally obtain aggregate TFP growth,
which is also a weighted sum of industry productivity growth rates (see
Jorgenson et al. [1987]).
Price, Quantity, and Quality
Until now we have worked according to the assumption that it is
easy to obtain prices and quantities for any particular commodity. Yet
the commodity structure of an industrial economy is not static: existing
commodities are improved upon or replaced by new commodities. Very often
the distinction between improvement and replacement is just a matter of
degree, and it is more useful to think of products as having certain
quality properties that are relevant to the purpose for which the
commodity is used, be it in consumption or production. For example, the
average car today is very different from the same car 20 years ago in
terms of its performance characteristics, its maintenance requirements,
etc. One way to measure the car production in the economy would simply
be to count the number of units produced, but this method clearly does
not reflect the superior quality of today's car relative to
yesterday's car, and it would lead one to underestimate output
growth and thereby productivity growth. The appropriate p rocedure is
then to adjust a car for its quality content, i.e., a car is weighted
according to its characteristics. Not accounting for quality change in
the production of cars would lead one to underestimate output and
productivity growth.
When commodities differ according to quality, we have to construct
quality-adjusted price measures. In order to see if a broadly defined
commodity has become expensive over time, we do not compare the price of
two similar commodities at different points in time, but we compare the
quality-adjusted prices. Only an increase in the quality-adjusted price
represents a true price increase. The use of quality-adjusted prices, or
hedonic prices, was pioneered by Griliches (1961). Gordon's (1990)
work on durable goods shows that the relative price of durable goods
declines at a substantially faster rate once one accounts for quality
change.
The counterpart of this observation is that, using Gordon's
(1990) price deflator, the quantity of durable goods produced increases
at a faster rate. For the case of investment goods, disregarding quality
change leads one not only to underestimate output growth, but also to
underestimate input growth because investment is used to construct
capital stocks. The effect on measured productivity growth can be
ambiguous since we underestimate both output and input growth.
Obviously, adjusting for quality change is more important for new
products in innovative industries such as IT. Recently this approach has
been successfully applied to the construction of computer price indexes
in the United States (see Cole et al. [1986]). This application was
successful because there was a well-defined and easily measured set of
characteristics describing the performance of computers.
When it is difficult to apply hedonic pricing--e.g., when it is
impractical or conceptually hard to distinguish products'
characteristics--there can be other ways to make quality adjustments. In
a recent innovative paper by Bils and Klenow (1999), one such method is
developed and put to work. Loosely speaking, the alternative to
brute-force measurement of quality components of products proposed by
Bils and Klenow is to use theory. Consider, for instance, vacuum
cleaners. Most households own one. However, there are many brands and
qualities of vacuum cleaners, and by looking at detailed household data
one can find out, on average, to what extent additional household income
translates into a more expensive vacuum cleaner. After using the cross
section to find out how income translates into quality, Bils and Klenow
(1999) turn to the time series and use aggregate changes in household
income to predict the added quality component in vacuum cleaner
purchases over time. This method is applied to a broad set of prod ucts,
and the results can be summarized in a downward revision of the growth
of the official Bureau of Labor Statistics price index by over 2
percentage points per annum (with a corresponding upward revision in
real output growth).
The problems of quality adjustment are well recognized but hard to
resolve. With the explosion of new IT-related products, quality
mismeasurements are likely to be more severe. Fortunately, IT advances
are likely to ease data collection in the future, but the brute-force
method surely needs to be complemented with alternative methods, such as
that of Bils and Klenow (1999).
In the service sector, a failure to account for changes in quality
may explain the poor productivity performance in a variety of
industries. A prominent example in the United States is the banking
sector, where until recently bank output was extrapolated based on bank
employment. As heavy users of IT, the financial industries have
substituted equipment capital for labor. Given the measurement
procedure, the capital-labor substitution had the unfortunate
consequence of lowering measured output while maintaining or increasing
the use of inputs. An incorrect measure of output thus results in
apparent productivity declines. Recent revisions define bank output as
an employment-weighted sum of the number of different transactions
performed (see Moulton [2000]). However, this still does not correct for
changes in the quality of transactions, such as convenience,
reliability, and speed. One might expect that future IT developments
will allow for further improvements along these quality dimensions.
Another sector whose contribution to the aggregate economy has
increased and where quality aspects are very important is the provision
of health services. For this sector one would have to construct medical
diagnosis price indexes that would account for the accuracy of the
diagnosis and the inconvenience to the patient, as well as treatment
price indexes that would account for the success rate, intrusiveness,
side effects, etc. of the treatment (see Shapiro, Shapiro, and Wilcox
[1999]).
Finally, to our knowledge, all productivity accounting exercises
assume that the quality of different types of labor remains constant
over time. That is, the overall quality of the aggregate labor force may
increase because the economy employs more skilled than unskilled labor,
but the quality of skilled and unskilled labor is assumed to remain the
same. We return to this issue in the next section.
Missing Inputs and Outputs
Closely related to the measurement of quality is the problem of
missing inputs and outputs, which can bias measured rates of
productivity growth. This problem is evident in the treatment of
expenditures on Research and Development (R&D) and software and in
the construction of capital stock series from investment and
depreciation.
Progress can be made toward solving the problem of missing inputs
and outputs. The recent National Income and Product Account (NIPA)
revision in the United States now includes one previously missing
capital input, namely computer software (see Moulton, Parker, and Seskin
[1999]). Before the NIPA revision, software was not treated as an
investment good, but as an intermediate good; it therefore did not add
to final demand. The inclusion of software investment has contributed
about 0.2 percentage points to total U.S. GDP growth from the early
1990s on (see Seskin [1999]). [3] Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) find that
software investment contributes about 5 percent to output growth and
that software capital makes up about one-ninth of total capital
accumulation. It is not clear if R&D spending should be treated the
same way as spending on software. Since R&D spending generates
knowledge, similar to "organizational" capital acquired by
firms when they learn how to use new IT, one could interpret this
knowledge capita l as a missing input. On the other hand, these
inputs--knowledge and organizational capital--are not traded commodities
so their accumulation might as well be captured as productivity
improvements.
Related to the question of missing inputs and outputs are
Kiley's (1999) and Whelan's (2000) discussions of capital
stock measurement. Research has shown that the perpetual inventory model
with geometric depreciation is a reasonable approximation to observed
depreciation patterns for durable goods. If the depreciation rate,
[delta], of a class of durable goods is constant over time, then the net
increase of the capital stock, k, is investment, x, minus depreciation,
[delta]k:
k = x - [delta]k.
Kiley (1999) argues that for high rates of capital accumulation,
such as those observed for IT over the last 20 years, observed
investment expenditures do not capture all resource costs associated
with capital accumulation. Resource costs that are incurred in the
process of new capital formation and are in addition to the observed
investment expenditures are called "adjustment costs."
Adjustment costs can affect productivity measurement in two ways. On the
one hand, the presence of adjustment costs could mean that standard
measures of output underestimate true output because they are net of
adjustment costs. On the other hand, we could say that standard
procedures overestimate true capital accumulation because the marginal
product of investment in the production of capital goods is not constant
at one, but declining. Whelan (2000) argues that for computers, current
procedures overestimate depreciation rates because they confuse physical
depreciation--which lowers the effective capital stock--with economic
dep reciation, which does not affect the effective capital stock. [4]
Finally, we want to raise the perennial favorite issue of market
versus nonmarket transactions, or how to value household production. One
of the presumed improvements generated by the Internet is the additional
convenience it provides to consumers: the Net makes product search and
price comparisons easier, provides access to certain services, and
reduces overall the time households have to spend on transactions. While
one can interpret this problem as one of missing inputs and outputs, to
us it appears to be a quality measurement problem. From the point of
view of the household, transactions have certain characteristics, and a
commodity or service obtained through the Net has different
characteristics than the same commodity or service obtained in a store.
Very little work has been done to date to assess the value of these
changes in characteristics.
Input Cost Shares
For the Solow growth accounting, we identify an input's output
elasticity with the input's revenue share. We therefore need
measures of the prices or rental rates of all inputs. This measurement
is apparently not a problem for the calculation of aggregate
productivity growth, for we have data on payments to labor and can treat
payments to capital as the residual. There is an issue, however, about
how to allocate proprietor's income; part of it is payment or labor
services and part represents capital income, but this issue appears to
be minor. Our problem is not completely solved, however, since we still
have to construct aggregate capital and labor series. If we define
aggregate capital and labor as an equally weighted sum of the different
types of capital and labor in the economy, we are done. These measures
of capital and labor, however, are not the theoretically preferred
Divisia indexes as discussed above, and for the construction of a
Divisia index we need to know the amount of the payment made to each c
omponent of the index, not just the sum of all payments. This
requirement creates a problem for the construction of capital
aggregates: Because capital is usually owned by producers, the services
of capital are not traded on spot markets, and we therefore have no
observations on rental rates for different types of capital. The usual
procedure is to make an assumption on the rate of return on capital and
then calculate the rental rate of capital implied by an asset pricing
equation (see Jorgenson, Gollop, and Fraumeni [1987]). The asset pricing
relationships are derived under the assumption that there is no
uncertainty, which is not an innocuous assumption if one believes that
the economy can experience a technological revolution. During a
revolutionary period, one would expect that first, overall uncertainty
would increase, and second, that not all types of capital would be
equally affected by the increased uncertainty.
Solow's Assumptions
Let us now consider the two theoretical assumptions underlying
Solow growth accounting: production is constant returns to scale and
producers are competitive. In the context of business cycles analysis,
it has been argued that Solow growth accounting systematically
mismeasures true changes in productivity because the underlying
assumptions do not hold, namely that there are increasing returns to
scale and that producers do not equate price to marginal cost (see Hall
[1988]). Extensive research in this area has not completely resolved all
issues, but it is apparent that constant returns to scale and
competition are reasonable approximations (Basu and Fernald 1999). A
remaining problem for short-run productivity accounting appears to be a
missing input: unobserved factor utilization, which is essentially a
theoretical construct and is very difficult to measure. We do not expect
this problem to affect medium-to long-term growth accounting since
theory suggests that there is no trend growth to this particular act
ivity.
We usually attribute changes in TFP to technological improvements,
but clearly TFP also reflects the effects of government regulations,
market structures, firm organization, prevailing work rules, etc. In a
nice case study, Schmitz (1998) describes how in the 1980s changing
competitive pressures on the U.S. and Canadian iron-ore mining industry
induced mines to change their work practices in a way that increased
their productivity without actually changing their technology. Standard
Solow growth accounting registers the change in TFP, but it does not
explain why it occurs. It is probably also true that productivity
changes of this variety will result in one-time improvements, and cannot
account for sustained productivity growth. Nevertheless, an explanation
of this observation would be useful because many discussions of IT
suggest that it makes the environment more competitive and induces firms
to respond with technological and organizational improvements. A
possible explanation might be based on a framework where (1) managers,
workers, and capital owners somehow share the surplus from operating a
firm, (2) the relative surplus shares depend on the relative bargaining
strengths of the different parties, and (3) changes in competitive
pressures have a differential impact on the parties' bargaining
positions. This framework would represent a radical departure from the
standard Solow growth accounting assumptions.
Recent Evidence on IT and Productivity Growth
We now review the most recent work on IT and aggregate productivity
growth using standard Solow growth accounting. The papers of Jorgenson
and Stiroh (2000), Oliner and Sichel (2000), Whelan (2000), and Kiley
(1999) focus on the contribution of IT capital to aggregate output
growth and changes in aggregate productivity growth rates during the
1990s. There are some differences in the studies' particular
definitions of IT capital, but the studies share the conclusion that in
the 1990s the contribution of IT capital accumulation to output growth
increased and productivity growth increased. Hall (1999, 2000) proposes
a method for measuring unobserved capital accumulation associated with
the diffusion of IT and studies the implications for TFP growth.
Aggregate TFP
Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) identify IT capital with computer
hardware and software and with communications equipment. They find that
from 1973-1990 to 1995-1998, the contribution of IT to aggregate growth
doubles and productivity growth triples. For the earlier time period, IT
investment accounted for one-tenth of output growth, and IT capital
accumulation made up one-fifth of total capital accumulation and about
one-tenth of total output growth. In the more recent period, IT
investment accounts for about one-fifth of output growth, and IT capital
accumulation makes up two-fifths of total capital accumulation and about
one-fifth of total output growth. At the same time, productivity growth
increases from an annual rate of 0.3 percent to 1 percent, a rate that
is about as high as the golden era of the 1950s and 1960s. Oliner and
Sichel (2000), using the same definition of IT capital and a somewhat
narrower definition of output, find a similar increase in productivity
growth and contribution of IT capital accu mulation to output growth.
Both studies find the increase in productivity growth rates to be
limited to the post-1995 period.
Whelan (2000) identifies IT with computing equipment and argues
that standard measures of depreciation overestimate the physical
depreciation rates of computing equipment. His estimates of computing
equipment stocks in 1998 exceed standard values by almost 50 percent,
which would indicate an enormous measurement error. The implied faster
growth rates and higher revenue shares for computing equipment double
the contribution of IT capital accumulation to output growth. Since
aggregate output growth is not affected by the redefinition of
depreciation rates, the higher contribution of IT capital accumulation
is offset by a corresponding decline in the contribution of other
capital and overall TFP growth.
In sum, the most recent studies find important productivity
improvements for the very last part of the 1990s, but the productivity
slowdown still appears to be a mystery. It is possible that the
productivity slowdown may simply be indicative of structural change and
that an increasing share of the economy is badly mismeasured. This
hypothesis is discussed in some detail in Hornstein and Krusell (1996),
although the main conclusion from that work--and any other work we are
aware of--is that there is suggestive but not much hard evidence at this
point that would allow us to reassess the 1973-1995 period. Structural
change can have important implications in economies with a number of
adjustment costs in the form of learning, reorganization, etc., and we
have noted the mismeasured quality problem in our discussion of methods.
In this context, Kiley (1999) also identifies IT with computing
equipment and performs a growth accounting exercise that allows for
adjustment costs to capital accumulation. [5] He finds that in the 1970s
and 1980s high IT capital accumulation rates actually reduced observed
net-output growth. Unlike other studies, which use standard Solow growth
accounting, he finds that aggregate productivity growth has remained
constant from the 1970s to the 1990s. Adjustment costs are a theoretical
concept used to motivate why short-run movements in investment are less
volatile than predicted by the standard growth model; it is very
difficult to obtain direct evidence on them. Since adjustment costs are
used to study short-run dynamics, they are usually normalized such that
they are zero when the investment-capital stock ratio is at its long-run
average. The available evidence on adjustment costs seems to relate to
local deviations from long-run averages. Obviously, for a new product
like IT, the investment-capital stock ratio will be very different from
its long-run value, which means that adjustment costs might be
substantial and can have a measurable impact on net-output growth. On
the other hand, we do not know if the local properties of adjustment
costs apply when investment-capital stock ratios are far from their
long-run averages.
Finally, Hall (1999, 2000)--or eHall, according to his latest
paper--starts out with the assumption that in the 1990s the spread of IT
was associated with the accumulation of a new type of capital, e-capital
for short, and that e-capital is not measured by standard National
Income and Product Accounting. This assumption reflects the observation
that the market value of private corporations relative to the
replacement cost of their physical capital increased from a factor of
one at the beginning of the 1990s to a factor of three at the end of the
1990s. eHall extends the standard growth accounting framework and
assumes that measured output is produced with physical capital,
e-capital, skilled labor, and unskilled labor and that new e-capital is
accumulated through the employment of skilled labor. [6] Using data on
the market value of firms in addition to the usual series on quantities
and factor rental rates employed in growth accounting, he constructs a
series for e-capital. He finds that with e-capital, the contribution of
other inputs and TFP to output growth is substantially reduced: without
e-capital, TFP accounts for two-fifths of total output growth; with
e-capital the combined contribution of e-capital and TFP accounts for
three-fourths of total output growth, and most of it is due to
e-capital. eHall's approach has the undesirable property that large
stock market reevaluations imply the creation/destruction of large
amounts of e-capital, since equity makes up a large portion of the
market value of firms. This property does not fit well with our
understanding of capital as a durable good. We can account for large
equity market reevaluations if we assume that a substantial fraction of
a firm's assets are indeed not reproducible, but that market values
reflect current and future production opportunities. This is an
important point to consider in an environment where new technologies
change the way we see the future.
Disaggregated TFP
Finally, we may want to know where technical change takes place. Is
it concentrated in particular industries, or do we see a general
increase in TFP for all industries? Is industry TFP growth related to
the use of IT? Evidence on these points is mixed.
Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) report TFP growth rates for a range of
two-digit industries. They find that TFP growth varies widely: the
best-performing industries include Trade, Electronic and Electric
Equipment, Agriculture, Industry Machinery and Equipment, Transport and
Warehouse; the worst-performing industries with negative TFP growth are
Services and Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate (FIRE). Two
observations are applicable. First, the results concerning the relative
ranking of industries and the fact that large parts of the economy
(FIRE, Services) show negative TFP growth rates are similar to those of
previous studies, i.e., accounting for IT has apparently not had an
impact. [7] Second, the impact of IT on particular industries appears to
be mixed. Given the advantages IT provides to inventory control and
production planning, industries such as Trade and Transportation and
Warehousing should have benefited from the diffusion of IT. On the other
hand, although a substantial fraction of IT investment is going to
Services and FIRE, the productivity performance of these industries has
not improved at all. Above, we have suggested that for these industries
IT diffusion may simply worsen the output measurement problem.
More specifically related to the production of computing equipment
is Oliner and Sichel (2000), who use changes in the relative price of
computers and semiconductors to evaluate the contribution of the sector
producing computing equipment to aggregate TFP growth.[8] They find that
despite the relatively small revenue share of the computing equipment
sector, that sector accounts for about half of total TFP growth.
Microstudies
We have noted that it is difficult to find any clear relationship
between the utilization of IT and the resulting TFP growth at the
industry level. However, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000a) argue that more
evidence on the impact of IT applications on productivity is available
for firm level data. Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000b) estimate the impact
of computing equipment on TFP growth at the firm level using a variation
of Solow growth accounting. Essentially they argue that TFP growth at
the firm level is positively correlated with the growth of computer
capital in the firm. They also suggest that the benefits from investment
in computer capital are delayed, which can be interpreted as being due
to needing to learn to use IT or to the accumulation of IT-related
organizational capital.
Bresnahan, Brynjolfsson, and Hitt (1999) study the interaction of
IT capital accumulation, firm-specific human capital accumulation, and
organizational change at the firm level. They use survey data on firms
to construct an index of human capital (average education levels, skill
levels as perceived by management, and occupational mix), an index of
human capital investment (training and screening activities), and an
index of how "decentralized" the firm's organizational
structure is (measures of team orientation). They find that their
measures of IT capital, human capital, and work organization are all
positively correlated. In particular, (1) firms that have a better
educated work force and a more decentralized work organization tend to
use more IT capital, and (2) firms that use more IT capital tend to
spend more on training their work force.
Finally, Brynjolfsson and Yang (1999) study the relation between
the stock of computer capital in a firm and the market value of that
firm. They argue that one dollar of computer capital in the firm raises
the market value of a firm by more than one dollar. They suggest that
this markup reflects other "unmeasured" capital which is
complementary to computer capital. In this context they point out that
when a firm implements a new information management system, the biggest
cost component is consulting, training, and software development, not
hardware expenditures. [9]
2. FACTOR-SPECIFIC PRODUCTIVITY
At times of significant technological change, the relative
importance of different inputs, or factors of production, may change
substantially because of specific technological innovations. For
example, during the last 30 years we have witnessed striking changes in
the relative prices of new equipment capital and in the premiums paid to
highly educated workers (skilled workers for short). These changes
likely reflect factor-specific technology movements, that is,
technological advances that have enabled some factors to enjoy large
increases in marginal productivity while others have seen none or have
decreased. In other words, factor-specific productivity measurements may
capture the economic signs of a technological revolution even when TFP
measurements show tranquility. The increased productivity of one factor
may lead to changes in the provision of factors--by changing the amount
of hours worked of different kinds of labor or by causing changes in the
accumulation of physical and human capital--in such a wa y that TFP does
not change much.
This hypothesis has been described and compared to past technology
revolutions, such as the introduction of electricity in the beginning of
the 20th century, in Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997). In this article, we
only discuss this possibility on a broad level; future work will explore
it in more detail. We point out the advantage of these multidimensional
productivity measures, and we underline their shortcomings. We also
present some recent examples of empirical work aimed at factor-specific
productivity (FSP) measurement.
Introducing Factor-Specific Productivity
Solowian productivity accounting shows how the productivity of all
inputs changes while it imposes a minimal amount of theoretical
structure. Factor-specific productivity accounting imposes more
theoretical structure than the Solowian method does, but also allows us
to evaluate productivity changes for individual inputs. Factor-specific
productivity accounting recognizes that TFP growth may not be exogenous,
but in fact can depend on the relative use of different inputs. This
recognition has important consequences for policy evaluation. For
example, whether or not government taxes or subsidizes the accumulation
of equipment capital affects capital stock accumulation, which in turn
may affect measured TFP growth. In order to evaluate the effect of a tax
or subsidy on equipment investment, one would need to know more about
the nature of the productivity improvements. In particular, it may be
that technological change interacts asymmetrically with different inputs
and that the effect of capital accumulation on T FP growth depends on
the nature of these interactions. We leave the discussion of policy and
other counterfactual experiments to a future paper. Here, we will show
some useful ways of allowing technological change to interact
differently with different inputs: we will characterize productivity
change multidimensionally.
To illustrate the difference between TFP growth and factor-specific
productivity growth, consider the basic neoclassical production
structure with output a function of capital and labor (see Section 1
above). Now impose the additional assumption that output is a
time-invariant function of efficiency units of each input
y = F([A.sub.k]k, [A.sub.n]n),
where k is the number of machines and [A.sub.k] is a
machine-specific productivity factor that changes over time (and
similarly for labor). The factor-specific productivities are assumed to
be exogenous. The marginal change in output is y = [F.sub.1] ([A.sub.k]k
+ k[A.sub.k]) + [F.sub.2]([A.sub.n]n + n[A.sub.n]). Assuming constant
returns to scale and perfect competition we can write the growth rate of
output as
y = (1 - [[alpha].sub.n]([A.sub.k] +k) + [[alpha].sub.n] ([A.sub.n]
+ n),
where [[alpha].sub.n], is the labor income share, and the
components of TFP growth are
z = (1 - [[alpha].sub.n]) [A.sub.k] + [[alpha].sub.n] [A.sub.n].
Since, with the exception of a Cobb-Douglas production function,
the labor income share depends on the input ratio, TFP growth will
depend on inputs. If the elasticity of substitution between inputs was
greater than one, the labor income share would decrease with an increase
in the stock of capital. In this case, we would expect that a subsidy to
capital increases TFP growth if and only if [A.sub.k] [greater than]
[A.sub.n]. In addition, TFP growth is not a goal in itself. Rather, a
government's objective might be a higher output growth rate, in
which case the relative importance of [A.sub.k] and [A.sub.n] clearly
matters again.
The disadvantage of factor-specific productivity accounting is that
it imposes substantially more structure than the assumption of constant
returns to scale and marginal-product pricing, as is sufficient for
Solow's TFP accounting. [10] As we will discuss below, much more
structure is typically needed in order to draw inference about
factor-specific productivity. The example above assumes that the
production technology is invariant over time with the inputs measured in
"efficiency units," such that technological change can take
only the form of increases in the efficiency factors. [11] The
quantitative results depend on the form of the F function (on the
elasticity of factor substitution especially).
Finally, we would like to address the potential quantitative
importance of considering FSP measures. One potential objection to FSP
is based on the observation that over the last century, aggregate labor
and capital shares have been remarkably stable in the United States.
These stable factor shares suggest that the aggregate production
function for the United States is well approximated by the Cobb-Douglas
function with constant factor shares and unit elasticity of
substitution. But with unit elasticity FSP and TFP accounting are
equivalent. There are several other observations, however, that indicate
substantial variation of factor income shares. First, stable shares are
mainly observed for the very broadest aggregates: labor versus capital.
For breakdowns of the labor input--into different skill (educational)
groups--shares have had strong trends and swings around trend. For the
capital income share, there is information that for our object of
interest--new equipment/IT-related capital--the cost share has i
ncreased dramatically. Second, if one looks at a cross section of
countries, especially including countries at a lower level of
development, then one sees that there is variation in the labor share
with development; at the very least, countries do not seem to have the
same labor shares. Third, and on a related point, some developed
countries have had much larger swings in the aggregate shares than what
has been observed in the United States; one example is the dramatic
increase of profit shares in France in the 1980s.
We now turn to factor-specific productivity measurement for the
four factors mentioned most often: capital equipment and structures and
skilled and unskilled labor.
Investment-Specific Technological Change
The recent decades of technological change and the current focus on
IT are often described as examples of how technology is
"embodied" in new equipment. The idea is that productivity
improvements occur in the sector producing equipment investment, and
these productivity improvements are transmitted to the rest of the
economy through new equipment investment. Today's higher
productivity in the investment-goods producing sector then effectively
enhances the production possibilities for consumption in the future,
through increases in the capital stock. The embodiment question has a
long history; see, for example, Solow (1959) and Jorgenson (1966), as
well as a recent discussion and evaluation in Hercowitz (1998).
Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell (1997) argue that for the postwar
United States, especially after the 1970s, most productivity growth was
of the embodied variety. [12]
In its most basic version, capital-embodied technological change
represents changes in factor-specific productivity: currently produced
new capital goods are relatively more productive than previously
produced capital goods. On the other hand, once we measure capital in
terms of efficiency units, we can interpret capital-embodied
technological change in terms of product-specific changes in TFP, namely
the productivity of the economy's investment goods sector relative
to the consumption goods sector. We follow this second interpretation,
but we discuss capital-embodied technological change in the current
section on changes in FSP, as opposed to in the previous section on
changes in TFP, because we impose considerably more theoretical
structure when we derive measures of capital-embodied technological
changes.
We first provide a general discussion of TFP accounting in a simple
two-sector model of the economy and how it relates to the usual measures
of aggregate TFP accounting. We follow this route in order to show how
the assumptions used by Greenwood et al. (1997) allow them to interpret
their results in terms of aggregate productivity in a one-sector
economy. Finally, we present Greenwood et al.'s (1997) results on
the relative contributions of sectoral TFP growth to aggregate growth.
Goods--consumption c and new capital x--are produced using the
factors capital and labor as inputs to constant-returns-to-scale
technologies
c = [z.sub.c][F.sub.c]([k.sub.c], [n.sub.c]) and x =
[z.sub.x][F.sub.x]([k.sub.x], [n.sub.x]);
total factor inputs can be freely allocated across sectors,
[k.sub.c] + [k.sub.x] = k and [n.sub.c] + [n.sub.x] = n;
and investment is measured in efficiency units. The technologies
may differ across sectors because of different factor substitution
properties ([F.sub.c] may differ from [F.sub.x]), and technological
improvements may occur at different rates ([Z.sub.c] may grow at a
different rate than does [Z.sub.x]. We normalize productivity relative
to the consumption goods sector, [Z.sub.c] = z and [Z.sub.x] = qz, and q
is the relative productivity advantage of producing new capital goods.
The evolution of the capital stock is described by
k (t) = x (t) - [delta]k (t).
One could now proceed and calculate sector-specific TFP growth as
described in the previous section. Greenwood et al. (1997) choose an
alternative route and use this setup to calculate and interpret TFP
growth within an aggregate growth accounting framework.
In the first section of the present article, we postulated--in
accordance with Solow's assumptions--a measure y of aggregate
output as equaling an aggregate production function of capital, labor,
and time. It was not made explicit in that framework what output was
made up of. In the one-sector neoclassical growth model, aggregate
output is by definition equal to the sum of consumption and investment,
y = c + x, but what is aggregate output in a multisector economy, such
as the two-sector model just described? Rather than starting with an
aggregate output concept, we will first summarize the production
possibilities in the two-sector economy described above by the
transformation function G(c, x, k, n, t) = 0. The function C tells us
what combinations of consumption and investment goods c and x the
economy can produce, given its total factor inputs k and n. Since
production is constant-returns-to-scale, the transformation function is
homogeneous of degree one in outputs and inputs.
Following our discussion of Divisia indices in Section 1, we can
define an aggregate output index and a measure of aggregate TFP growth
based on this output measure:
[y.sup.D] [equiv] [S.sub.c]C + (1 - [S.sub.c])x and [z.sup.D]
[equiv] [y.sup.D] - [alpha]k - (1 - [alpha])n.
The growth rate of the Divisia index of aggregate output is a
weighted average of the output growth rates in the two sectors, where
the weights are the revenue shares of consumption and investment,
[S.sub.c] = [P.sub.c]C/([P.sub.c]C + [P.sub.x]X). [13] The growth rate
of aggregate TFP is then defined analogously to the one-sector economy
as the difference between the aggregate output growth rate and the
weighted average of the aggregate input growth rates, where the weights
are the aggregate income shares of capital and labor, [alpha] =
[p.sub.k]k/ ([p.sub.k]k + [p.sub.n]n).
Divisia indices allow us to perform aggregate productivity
accounting, but there is no particular theoretical justification
suggesting that a Divisia index is the unique aggregator function for
the economy. [14] In fact, one can show that for multi-sector models
there does not exist an output aggregator; that is, in general no
function exists that relates some measure of aggregate output to
measures of aggregate inputs (Hall 1973). However, let us now assume
that G is separable so that it is possible to find an output aggregator:
G(c, x, k, n, t) = H(c, x, t) - F(k, n, t).
Here, we interpret F as the aggregate production function and H as
the aggregate output function, and both functions are homogeneous of
degree one. In particular, aggregate output is defined as y = H(c, x, t)
= F(k, n, t). Notice that we must in general allow both of these
functions to depend on time in order to allow technological change of a
general kind.
Now this setup can be specialized further to illustrate different
kinds of technological change: rather than allowing the variable t to
have a general influence on H and F, consider instead F(zk, zl) and H(c,
x/q), where z and q are time-dependent processes. That is, technological
change is expressed only through z and q, with z representing neutral
technological change and q investment-specific technological change.
[15] Can we obtain measures for the two types of technological change
for this aggregate specification of the economy? We might want to
proceed as in the case of the Solow residual, and define the
productivity growth rates based on the equations which relate output
growth to input or expenditure growth rates
y = [alpha]k + (1 - [alpha]) n + z = [s.sub.c]c + (1 - [S.sub.c])
(x - q)
But here we face a problem: Although our theory suggests that there
exists an output aggregate, we do not have a measure of that output
aggregate. In order to construct the measure of aggregate output, we
need to know the functional form of H and F and the values of the
productivity levels z and q. One way to proceed is to assume that there
is no investment-specific technological change, that is, q is constant.
With this assumption we have identified the aggregate output index. In
particular, the growth rate of aggregate output is equal to the Divisia
index growth rate [y.sup.D] defined above. On the other hand, we have
defined our problem away: There no longer is any investment-specific
technical change. [16]
Since Greenwood et al. (1997) want to study the role of
investment-specific technological change, they have to make other
assumptions in order to identify z and q. They assume that the factor
substitution properties in the two sectors of the economy are the same,
that is, [F.sub.c] = [F.sub.x] = F. With this restriction one can show
that H(c, x/q) = c + x/q, and that 1/q is the price of investment goods
relative to consumption goods. Greenwood et al. (1997) can recover H by
deflating nominal GDP with the consumption goods deflator; that is, they
define aggregate output in terms of consumption goods, [y.sup.GHK] =
[[p.sub.c]c + [p.sub.x]x]/[p.sub.c] = c + x/q. This is an unusual
definition of aggregate output--it does not coincide with the Divisia
measure--but it is justified within the confines of the model. In fact,
it is rather natural given that consumption is the ultimate source of
welfare in the model.
Suppose we next calculate aggregate TFP based on this definition of
aggregate output; we would then obtain
[z.sup.GHK] = [y.sup.GHK] - [alpha]k - (1 - [alpha])n = z.
Greenwood et al.'s (1997) definition of TFP growth indeed
recovers exogenous productivity changes that are not contaminated with
the endogenous response of the economy to these productivity changes. On
the other hand, their definition of aggregate TFP actually recovers
productivity in the consumption goods sector and not in the
"aggregate economy." Given the assumptions they make, what
does the aggregate TFP index based on the Divisia output index recover?
Using the definition of [z.sup.D], we can show that
[z.sup.D] = [s.sub.c]z + (1 - [s.sub.c])(z + q).
That is, the Divisia-based residual is a revenue share-weighted
aggregation of the sector-specific residuals. Moreover, the relative
importance of for [z.sup.D] is measured by (1 - [s.sub.c])q/([z + (1 -
[s.sub.c]q]. Note that the displayed Divisia measure of aggregate TFP
growth mixes the exogenous sectoral productivity growth rates with the
economy's endogenous response to these growth rates as reflected in
the consumption and investment share. [17]
When Greenwood et al. (1997) implement their approach for the U.S.
economy, they use Robert Gordon's (1990) quality adjustments to
construct the quality-adjusted inverse relative price of new investment
goods 1/q. With the quality-adjusted investment series they construct
the capital stock, and with Solowian growth accounting methods for their
consumption-based output measure they construct a series for z. Their
method implies a growth rate of investment-specific technology of around
3 percent per annum, with growth in neutral technology of around 1
percent per annum. Moreover, consistent with the hypothesis of an
equipment-led technology revolution, the growth rate of the q series
increased, already beginning in the mid-1970s, by about half a
percentage point. This finding is also consistent with McHugh and
Lane's (1987) finding, based on cross-section evidence, that
adjacent vintages show significantly smaller productivity differences
prior to the mid-1970s. Of course, neutral technology slowed down consid
erably at around the same time-the TFP version of the productivity
slowdown. [18]
Building on this measurement, Greenwood et al. (1997) attribute, in
terms of the model and as an entirely structural exercise, a substantial
part of longterm output growth to investment-specific technological
change (growth in q) rather than neutral technological change (growth in
z).
How Technology Affects Skilled and Unskilled Labor
U.S. data over the last couple of decades reveal substantial
changes in the returns to education, the skilled wage premium. Moreover,
typical wage regressions show large increases in residual variance: wage
variance that cannot be attributed to observed characteristics such as
age, experience, education, race, or gender. Katz and Murphy (1992) and
earlier observers speak of "skillbiased technical change" as
the explanatory factor behind these wage developments. Alternative
explanations have been proposed, such as a decrease in union activity
and increased foreign competition for unskilled labor. Bound and Johnson
(1992), however, conclude that the lion's share of the changes in
relative wages reflect relative changes in factor-specific productivity.
In a recent paper, Krusell, Ohanian, Rios-Rull and Violante (2000)
provide a more structural explanation of the wage premium. They argue
that it is not factor-specific technological progress that increases the
relative productivity of skilled labor, but rather the rapid
accumulation of equipment capital together with a skilled labor-capital
complementarity that determines the wage premium.
Skill-Biased Technological Change
We will next discuss how factor-specific productivity measurements
have been used to rationalize changes in the wage premium. Consider a
production function with capital and the two types of labor of the
following kind:
y = F [k, G ([A.sub.s][n.sub.s], [A.sub.u][n.sub.u])],
where G is a CES function with substitution elasticity parameter v
and we have abstracted from capital-specific productivity
(alternatively, capital embodies technological change and k is measured
in efficiency units, as in the previous section on investment-specific
technological change). As above, we assume that F and G are
time-invariant, so that any technological change comes through
([A.sub.s], [A.sub.u]). When the two types of labor are paid their
marginal products, the production structure implies that
log [w.sub.s]/[w.sub.u] = v - 1/v. log [A.sub.s]/[A.sub.u] - 1/v.
log [n.sub.s]/[n.sub.u].
Katz and Murphy (1992) use this structure to interpret their
leading finding that in a regression of (the log of) relative wages on
(the log of) relative factor supplies and a time trend, using 1963-1987
aggregate U.S. annual data, one obtains:
log [w.sub.s]/[w.sub.u] = 0.033. t - 0.71. log [n.sub.s]/[n.sub.u]
Katz and Murphy (1992) conclude from this wage regression that (1)
the input elasticity v is about [sqrt]2; and (2) the productivity of
skilled labor relative to that of unskilled labor increased on average
by almost 12 percent per year over the period. [19] More interestingly
for our purposes, the wage premium first rose during the 1960s, fell
over the early 1970s, and finally rose sharply beginning in the late
1970s. The latter increase continued unabated through the end of the
1990s. What do these relative swings tell us about technology?
We first observe that a large range of different data sets (time
series as well as cross-section) and methods also yield an input
elasticity of [sqrt]2. This suggests that assuming a stable production
function with v = [sqrt]2 is reasonable, and we can thus back out the
entire sequence of factor-specific technology ratios using the same
methodology as in the example with investment-specific technological
change analyzed in Greenwood et al. (1997). For this data set, one
observes that (1) the overall increase of the wage premium is due to
arise of the relative productivity of skilled labor [A.sub.s]/[A.sub.u],
(2) the fall of the wage premium in the early 1970s is due to the
significant increase of the relative supply of skilled labor
[n.sub.s]/[n.sub.u], and (3) the relative productivity of skilled labor
started to rise sharply in the late 1970s.
The approach just described allows us to recover factor-specific
productivities, conditional on assumptions about the relative factor
substitutabilities. In particular, it assumes that skilled and unskilled
labor are equally substitutable with capital. Going back to a well-known
paper by Griliches (1969), it has long been argued that most production
technologies exhibit "capital-skill complementarity." That is,
capital and skilled labor are more complementary than are capital and
unskilled labor.
Capital-Skill Complementarity
Krusell et al. (2000) argue that the higher wage premium is
actually due to capital accumulation since skilled labor is relatively
more complementary with capital than is unskilled labor. [20] They
capture the differential complementarity between capital and skilled and
unskilled labor using the following nested CES production technology
y = F [[A.sub.u][n.sub.u], G(k, [A.sub.s][n.sub.s])],
where F and G are CES functions. This structure, unlike the one
studied in the previous section, allows capital-skill complementarity.
If the factor elasticity between capital and skilled labor is denoted
[micro], and that between unskilled labor and either skilled labor or
capital is denoted v, then we have capital-skill complementarity if
[micro] [less than] v. Capital-skill complementarity means that the
relative wage will change when the capital stock changes, even if labor
inputs and labor-specific productivity levels do not change. Krusell et
al. (2000) show that with an estimate of [micro] in line with the
findings from the labor demand literature (see, for example, Hamermesh
[1993]), a v around [square root]2, and a measure of quality-adjusted
capital, the relative wage movements in the data can be quite closely
tracked without any change in the relative labor productivity
[A.sub.s]/[A.sub.u]. [21] When Krusell et al. (2000) relax the
assumption of constant relative labor productivity, they find that the
relative productivity of skilled labor grows at a modest 3 percent per
year.
Notice how the results of Krusell et al. (2000) stand in sharp
contrast to the conclusion based on Katz and Murphy's (1992) work.
When relative wage changes are driven by changes in relative labor
productivities alone, a different capital accumulation behavior would
have no effect on wages. On the other hand, from the perspective of
Krusell et al. (2000), there would have been no rapid increase in the
skill premium in recent years had it not been for the faster growth rate
of capital. In sum, it appears plausible that equipment-specific
technological change, possibly accompanied by some additional,
independent skill-biased technological change unrelated to equipment,
lies behind the large movements in relative wages of the last 30 years.
That is, relative wage data can be usefully employed to understand the
nature and evolution of aggregate technology in the economy.
Factor-Specific Productivity and Relative Factor Endowments
Our discussion of factor-specific productivity so far has assumed
that it evolves exogenously. In a recent study Caselli and Coleman
(2000) apply the methods of Krusell et al. (2000) to a cross section of
countries. Some of their results seem to suggest that countries choose
among a menu of skilled-unskilled labor productivities and that these
choices depend on the countries' relative factor endowments.
Caselli and Coleman (2000) obtain measures of capital and skilled-
and unskilled-labor input measures for a large cross section of
countries. The authors then assume marginal-product pricing and estimate
a nested CES technology, which is common in form across countries. Given
the estimated CES parameters, they back out a set of factor-specific
productivity levels, one for each country. Although the results are
preliminary as of this moment, three interesting conclusions appear from
our perspective. First, capital-skill complementarity receives support.
Second, countries appear to have very different mixes in factor-specific
productivity levels. In particular, there seems to be a negative
correlation between [A.sub.s] and [A.sub.u] in the cross section:
Countries with high skilled-labor productivities tend to have low
unskilled-labor productivities and vice versa. [22] This correlation
suggests the existence of a "productivity possibility
frontier," but the results also indicate that the choices along the
([A.sub.s], [A.sub.u]) frontier still leave much to be explained: many
countries are significantly inside the frontier and thus are operating
inefficiently. Third, countries with relatively more skilled labor tend
to have relatively high skilled labor productivities and vice versa.
This tendency suggests that a country's technology choice depends
on its factor endowments, a point which has been made by Acemoglu (see,
for example, Acemoglu [2000] and Acemoglu and Zilibotti [1998]).
3. A UNIFIED VIEW OF THE LAST QUARTER CENTURY?
What emerges from the sections on TFP and FSP measurement is a view
of technological change in the United States that is based on major
improvements in equipment production, with major effects on both
aggregate and factor-specific productivities. Several questions arise,
however, regarding the effects of TFP and FSP change. The first of these
relates to the productivity slowdown. Among the most significant
productivity movements over the entire century is the large slowdown in
TFP starting around 1973. Can the asserted improvements in
equipment-producing technologies be made consistent with the
productivity slowdown? Some recent papers advance the hypothesis that
learning problems associated with the use of the new equipment may have
been responsible for the aggregate slowdown. [23] However, empirical
assessments of learning costs in implementing new technology are
inherently difficult (see, for example, the recent arguments in Atkeson
and Kehoe [2000] and Hornstein [1999]) and we are far from being able to
r each a conclusion regarding this hypothesis. Nevertheless, the
possibility remains an interesting one.
Second, changes in technology are unlikely to occur only in the
United States; insights about the efficiency of different production
methods, new blueprints, and capital travel relatively easily across
borders. Does international data support the above productivity
analysis? The European data tell a different story about labor markets
than the U.S. data. Whereas unemployment stayed low in the United
States, it increased dramatically in Europe, and European relative wages
did not move nearly as much as U.S. relative wages. However, the
unemployment response in Europe occurred concurrently with the relative
wage response in the United States, so a common underlying explanation
should not be ruled out.
In particular, it seems quite plausible that differences in labor
market institutions, and one common shock, can yield quite different
responses in two economies. Our hypothesis, thus, is that more heavily
regulated and unionized labor markets can make skill-biased
technological change lead to increases in the rate of unemployment
instead of increases in the skill wage. This hypothesis has been
explored theoretically in Ljungqvist and Sargent (1998), Marimon and
Zilibotti (1999), and recently in Hornstein, Krusell, and Violante
(2000). [24] As labor market theory with frictions--allowing a
nontrivial role for unemployment--has not advanced as far quantitatively
as has neoclassical theory, it is too early yet for a firm evaluation of
this hypothesis. As for data on equipment relative prices, we do not
know of European data comparable to the U.S. data by Gordon (1990) on
the more recent revisions for some equipment categories in the NIPA.
Improvements in equipment price measurement should, in our view, be plac
ed high on the agenda in the United States and even higher in Europe.
A unified view of the macroeconomic productivity and labor market
performances during the last quarter century in the western world is a
very interesting one that ought to be explored in much further detail.
It can be viewed as a "third industrial revolution," placing
advanced equipment and IT on center stage. We believe that careful
reassessments of input and output measurements, together with theory
developments aimed at structural evaluation of the main hypothesis,
would be most productive.
Parts of this paper have been prepared for the European Commission,
Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Seminar on
"Economic Growth in the EU." Any opinions expressed are those
of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. Andreas
Hornstein: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
andreas.hornstein@rich.frb.org. Per Krusell: Department of Economics,
University of Rochester, pekr@troi.cc.rochester.edu, and consultant to
the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
(1.) The marginal change of a variable is its instantaneous rate of
change over time; that is, if we write the value of a variable at a
point in time as x (t), then the marginal change is the time derivative x (t) = [delta]x (t) / [delta]t. Nothing is lost in the following if the
reader interprets x (t) as the change of a variable from year to year,
that is, x (t) - x (t - 1).
(2.) We define the Divisia index below.
(3.) The 1999 NIA revisions increased real GDP by about 0.4
percentage points for the period 1992-1998. Revised price index numbers contributed about 0.1 percentage points. The remaining increase was
mainly due to the revised treatment of software expenditures, but also
reflects the effects of the revised output measurement in the banking
sector (Seskin 1999).
(4.) Usually the depreciation rate for a particular type of capital
good is estimated from a cross section of quality-adjusted used capital
goods prices. Older capital goods are less efficient due to
depreciation, and this is reflected in their lower prices. Assuming
geometric depreciation, the slope of the age-price line for the
different vintages of used capital goods reflects the depreciation rate.
Suppose in addition not only that capital goods depreciate, but that
their lifetime is finite because at some age it is no longer profitable
to operate a capital good (economic depreciation). In this case the
slope of the age-price line also incorporates the effects of a declining
remaining service life for the capital good. For capital goods with long
service lives this effect is not very important, but for computers,
which currently have quite short service lives, this effect may dominate
the physical depreciation.
Whelan (2000) suggests that for computer equipment, current
procedures identify all of the slope of the price-age line with physical
depreciation, even though most of it is due to a finite service life. If
this is true, then this procedure may underestimate the computer capital
stock during the early phase of computer capital accumulation because it
depreciates computer capital too fast. On the other hand, this procedure
also assumes that capital is around for a much longer time period than
the actual service life of capital, that is, it overestimates the
capital stock in the later phase of computer capital accumulation. One
would expect that after some time, these two effects would balance and
the measured capital stock would be about right.
(5.) Solow growth accounting is based on standard economic theory,
as represented by the growth model, and it does not include adjustments
costs. The introduction of adjustment costs forces Kiley (1999) to
deviate from the usual nonparametric Solow growth accounting procedure:
He has to specify a functional form for the adjustment cost function.
(6.) eHall also relates the interaction of e-capital and skilled
and unskilled labor to the idea of skill-biased technical change. We
discuss this issue in the sections on multifactor productivity growth
below.
(7.) Unfortunately, Jorgenson and Stiroh have not yet calculated
industry TFP numbers for post-1995.
(8.) See also our discussion of Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell
(1997) in the next section.
(9.) The recent reclassification of software expenditures as
investment should ameliorate this problem in the NIPA.
(10.) There is a sense in which factor-specific productivity (FSP)
accounting imposes less structure than TFP accounting. In the example
above we back out FSP for capital, given a functional form for
production. But FSP essentially represents a change in quality, and a
more structured procedure would try to obtain measures of quality, as
discussed above for TFP.
(11.) There are alternative, tractable structural approaches to how
technology changes over time. For example, one could specify a CES
function with elasticities changing exogenously over time. More
structurally still, Cordoba (2000) describes the sequential adoption of
output technologies with higher and higher capital shares. He then
shows, with closed-form solutions, that this form of "structural
change" implies increases in the capital-output ratio while
allowing the interest rate to remain constant; these properties seem to
well approximate the development path of many countries.
(12.) This finding relates to the observations by Jorgenson and
Stiroh (2000) and Oliner and Sichel (2000) on sectoral TFP growth
discussed in the previous section.
(13.) See our definition of Divisia indices in the section
"Aggregation," above.
(14.) As stated in the first section, Divisia indices have certain
nice properties in terms of aggregation (they are revenue-weighted
sectorial indices, and this property applies to output, input, and
productivity indices), but this does not mean that they are in any sense
the "true" aggregators for an economy.
(15.) This is a slightly more general version of the model
Greenwood et al. (1997) analyze (they use specific functional forms for
H and F), but cast in a one-sector form.
(16.) An interesting question is, Is this model potentially
consistent with the falling relative price of investment? In principle
the answer is "yes" because a falling relative price can be
obtained by appropriate assumptions on H. As the economy grows, the
isoquants may significantly change shape so as to produce a continuous
relative price change. Although this perspective seems rather academic,
it is a logical possibility.
(17.) In "Introducing Factor-Specific Productivity" we
discussed why this might be undesirable.
(18.) A very similar exercise is conducted in Gort, Greenwood, and
Rupert (1999), where quality-adjusted data are used not only for
equipment but also for structures, thus identifying both a qe and a
[q.sub.s] series.
(19.) In the wage regression, the coefficient on the log of
relative factor supplies represents 1/v, that is v = 1/0.71.
Furthermore, if the relative productivity of skilled labor grows at the
rate (1 +[gamma]), ([A.sub.s]/[A.sub.u])t = (1 +
y)([A.sub.s]/[A.sub.u])t-1, then in the wage regression the coefficient
on time represents v - 1/v log(1 + y), that is y [approx] .033.v/v - 1.
(20.) Similar points, but in different theoretical structures, have
been made in Greenwood and Yorukoglu (1997) and Caselli (1999).
(21.) Krusell et al. (2000) emphasize the relative
complementarities between equipment capital and skilled and unskilled
labor. The quality-adjusted equipment capital stock is again based on
the work of Gordon (1990) and subsequent updates, especially for IT
technology.
(22.) It is an open question whether these findings are robust to
better measurement of capital; with appropriate quality adjustments,
large differences can be observed in capital stocks, and the
capital-skill complementarity hypothesis then has implications for the
factor-specific productivity measurements.
(23.) See, for example, Hornstein and Krusell (1996) and Greenwood
and Yorukoglu (1997).
(24.) Related work, focusing more on wages than on unemployment, is
found in Violante (1999) and Aghion, Howitt, and Violante (1999).
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, Daron. "Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor
Market," Journal of Economic Literature (forthcoming).
_____, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. "Productivity
Differences," Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming).
Aghion, Philippe, Peter Howitt, and Giovanni Violante.
'Technology, Knowledge, and Inequality." Working Paper.
University of California, Berkeley, 1999.
Atkeson, Andrew and Patrick J. Kehoe. 'The Transition to a New
Economy Following the Second Industrial Revolution," Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper 606, September 2000.
Basu, Susanto, and John G. Femald. "Why Is Productivity
Procyclical? Why Do We Care?" International Finance Discussion
Working Paper 638. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
June 1999.
Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow. "Quantifying Quality
Growth." Mimeo, 1999.
Bound, John, and George Johnson. "Changes in the Structure of
Wages in the 1980s: An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations,"
American Economic Review, vol. 82 (June 1992), pp. 371-92.
Bresnahan, Timothy F., Erik Brynjolfsson, and Lorin M. Hitt.
"Information Technology, Workplace Organization and the Demand for
Skilled Labor: Firm-level Evidence," Quarterly Journal of Economics
(forthcoming).
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Lorin M. Hitt. "Computing
Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence," Working Paper, 2000b.
_____. "Beyond Computation: Information Technology,
Organizational Transformation and Business Performance," Journal of
Economic Perspectives, vol. 14 (Fall 2000a), pp. 23-48.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Shunkyu Yang. 'The Intangible Costs
and Benefits of Computer Investments: Evidence from the Financial
Markets." Proceedings of the International Conference on
Information Systems, Atlanta, Georgia, December 1997 (revised April
1999).
Caselli, Francesco. "Technological Revolutions," American
Economic Review, vol. 89 (March 1999), pp. 78-102.
_____, and John Coleman. "The World Technology Frontier,"
Working Paper, University of Chicago, 2000.
Cole, Roseanne, Y. C. Chen, Joan A. Barquin-Stelleman, Ellen
Dulberger, Nurhan Helvacian, and James H. Hodge. "Quality-Adjusted
Price Indexes for Computer Processors and Selected Peripheral
Equipment," Survey of Current Business, vol. 66 (January 1986), pp.
41-50.
Cordoba, Juan Carlos. "Transient Growth and Structural
Change." Mimeo, University of Rochester, 2000.
Gordon, Robert J. The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices. Chicago,
IL: University of Chicago Press, 1990.
Gort, Michael, Jeremy Greenwood, and Peter Rupert. "Measuring
the Rate of Technological Progress in Structures," Review of
Economic Dynamics, vol. 2 (January 1999), pp. 207-30.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Mehmet Yorukoglu. Carnegie-Rochester
Conference on Public Policy XLVI, 1997 [1974], pp. 49-95.
_____,Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell. "Long-run Implications
of Investment-Specific Technological Change," American Economic
Review, vol. 87 (June 1997), pp. 342-62.
Griliches, Zvi. "Capital-Skill Complementarity," Review
of Economics and Statistics, vol. 51 (November 1969), pp. 465-68.
_____. "Hedonic Price Indexes for Automobiles: An Econometric Analysis of Quality Change," in The Price Statistics of the Federal
Government. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1961, pp.
137-96.
Hall, Robert E. "e-Capital: The Link between the Stock Market
and the Labor Market in the 1990s," Working Paper, 2000.
_____. "The Stock Market and Capital Accumulation," NBER Working Paper 7180, 1999.
_____. "The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S.
Industry," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 96 (Oct. 1988), pp.
921-47.
_____. "The Specification of Technology with Several Kinds of
Output," The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81 (July-August
1973), pp. 878-92.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. Labor Demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1993.
Hercowitz, Zvi. "The 'Embodiment' Controversy: A
Review Essay," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 41 (February
1998), pp. 217-24.
Hornstein, Andreas. "Growth Accounting with Technological
Revolutions," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
vol. 85 (Summer 1999), pp. 1-22.
_____, and Per Krusell. "Can Technology Improvements Cause
Productivity Slowdowns?" in Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg,
eds., Macroeconomics Annual 1996. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1996, pp.
209-59.
_____, and Giovanni Violante. "Technology, Policy, and the
Inequality-Unemployment Tradeoff." Mimeo, 2000.
Hulten, Charles R. "Divisia Index Numbers," Econometrica,
vol. 41 (November 1973), pp. 1017-26.
Jorgenson, Dale W. "The Embodiment Hypothesis," Journal
of Political Economy, vol. 74 (February 1966), pp. 1-17.
_____, Frank Gollop, and Barbara Fraumeni. Productivity and U.S.
Economic Growth. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1987.
Jorgenson, Dale W., and Kevin J. Stiroh. "Raising the Speed
Limit: U.S. Economic Growth in the Information Age," Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity (forthcoming).
Katz, Lawrence, and Kevin Murphy. "Changes in Relative Wages:
Supply and Demand Factors," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.
106 (February 1992), pp. 35-78.
Kiley, Michael T. "Computers and Growth with Costs of
Adjustment: Will the Future Look Like the Past?" Finance and
Economics Discussion Working Paper 36. Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, July 1999.
Krusell, Per, Lee Ohanian, Jose-Victor Rios-Rull, and Giovanni
Violante. "Capital-Skill Complementarity and Inequality: A
Macroeconomic Analysis," Econometrica, vol. 68 (September 2000),
pp. 1029-53.
Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent. "The European
Unemployment Dilemma," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 106 (June
1998), pp. 514-50.
Marimon, Ramon, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. "Unemployment vs.
Mismatch of Talents: Reconsidering Unemployment Benefits," Economic
Journal, vol. 109 (April 1999), pp. 266-91.
McHugh, Richard, and Julia Lane. "The Role of Embodied
Technical Change in the Decline of Labor Productivity," Southern
Economic Journal, vol. 53 (April 1987), pp. 915-24.
Moulton, Brent R. "Measurement of Banking Services in the U.S.
National Income and Product Accounts: Recent Changes and Outstanding
Issues." Presented at a meeting of the BEA Advisory Committee, May
5, 2000.
_____, Robert P. Parker, and Eugene Seskin. "A Preview of the
1999 Comprehensive Revision of the National Income and Product Accounts:
Definitional and Classificational Changes," Survey of Current
Business, vol. 79 (October 1999), pp. 7-20.
Oliner, Stephen D., and Daniel E. Sichel. "The Resurgence of
Growth in the Late 1990s: Is Information Technology the Story?"
Finance and Economics Discussion Working Paper 20. Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, March 2000.
Schmitz, James A., Jr. "Reorganizing Work to Increase
Productivity: The Dramatic Recovery of the United States and Canadian
Iron-ore Industries." Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis,
1998.
Seskin, Eugene P. "Improved Estimates of the National Income
and Product Accounts for 1959-98: Results of the Comprehensive
Revision," Survey of Current Business, vol.79 (August 1999), pp.
15-43.
Shapiro, Irving, Matthew D. Shapiro, and David W. Wilcox.
"Quality Improvement in Health Care: A Framework for Price and
Output Measurement," American Economic Review, vol. 89 (May 1999),
pp. 333-37.
Solow, Robert M. "Investment and Technological Progress,"
in Kenneth J. Arrow, Samuel Karlin, and Patrick Suppes, eds.,
Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences 1959. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press, 1960, pp. 89-104.
_____. "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 39 (August
1957), pp. 312-20.
Violante, Giovanni. "Technological Acceleration, Skill
Transferability and the Rise in Residual Inequality." Mimeo,
University College London, 1999.
Whelan, Karl. "Computers, Obsolescence, and
Productivity," Finance and Economics Discussion Working Paper 6.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 2000.