Limited Commitment and Central Bank Lending.
Goodfriend, Marvin ; Lacker, Jeffrey M.
Central bank lending is widely regarded as a vital part of the
public safety net supporting the stability of the banking system and
financial markets. An independent central bank can provide liquidity to
financial institutions on very short notice. [1] Indeed, central bank
lending has been a prominent part of regulatory assistance to troubled
financial institutions in recent years. The idea of a central bank as
lender of last resort, however, has been around at least since Walter
Bagehot wrote about it over 100 years ago. [2]
For most of that time it was taken for granted that central bank
lending had benefits with little or no cost. In the past decade, that
view has been challenged. For instance, in the United States the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) of 1991
recognized that Federal Reserve lending to undercapitalized banks has
the potential to impose higher resolution costs on the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC). More recently, the idea that lending by
the International Monetary Fund has led to increased risk-taking in
international financial markets is being taken seriously by financial
market participants and policymakers alike. [3] In the United States,
financial economists have acknowledged "moral hazard" to be a
problem for government financial guarantees ever since the savings and
loan crisis of the 1980s.
In this article we look at central bank lending in light of the
concerns about moral hazard. Our aim is a practical one: we present
principles to help guide central bank lending. Our approach builds on
the observation that central bank lending is a publicly provided line of
credit. Commercial lines of credit and central bank lending are similar
in that both provide substantial funding on very short notice.
Line-of-credit products are complex. We use recent advances in the
theory of financial contracts to interpret the structure of loan
commitments. By dissecting the incentive implications of the contractual
obligations and rights involved in credit lines, we appreciate the
tensions present in line-of-credit relationships. In particular, we see
how contract terms control the ex post incentives of the borrower and
the lender under limited commitment to assure that the line-of-credit
product is efficient. We then employ our understanding of these issues
to benchmark and inform our analysis of central bank lending.
The nature of the problem is this: A line-of-credit product is
designed to meet the current obligations of a firm when it is judged to
be illiquid though solvent. Inevitably, then, a loan commitment shifts
potential losses from short- to longer-term claimants. For instance, a
commercial bank's line of credit to an ordinary business has the
potential to shift losses to the borrowing firm's long-term
bondholders and residual claimants. Analogously, a central bank's
line of credit has the potential to shift losses from uninsured
creditors to the deposit insurance fund or general taxpayers. Likewise,
lending by the International Monetary Fund to finance a country's
balance-of-payments deficit has the potential to shift losses from
short-term creditors of that country to the country's taxpayers.
[4]
Private line-of-credit agreements, together with the firm's
capital structure, balance the liquidation costs of a conservative
lending policy against the moral hazard associated with more liberal
lending. Covenant provisions in line-of-credit agreements give private
lenders the ability and the incentive to constrain credit to insolvent firms when appropriate. In contrast, central banks appear to lack
explicit institutional mechanisms to credibly precommit to limit
lending. An excessively liberal central bank line of credit makes
short-term capital more inclined to move in the direction of favorable
yield differentials irrespective of the risk involved, with the idea
that the credit line could finance a quick withdrawal.
The inability to commit to limit lending is the principal weakness
of central bank lending policy. The problem is that central banks
responsible for the stability of the financial system are inclined to
lend whenever not lending could plausibly trigger a systemic crisis.
That inclination encourages both domestic and international "hot
money" investments--short-term investments that implicitly rely on
central bank liquidity support for repayment in the event of a
crisis--and thereby increases the scope for violent reversals and
flights to safety whenever the market begins to doubt central bank
lending intentions. We are agnostic about whether there is a
welfare-enhancing role for central bank lending. The critical policy
problem is how to limit central bank lending to socially appropriate
circumstances.
The article proceeds as follows. Section 1 contains a description
of the structure and mechanics of private lines of credit. In Section 2,
central bank lending is characterized as a line of credit and the
line-of-credit analogy is exploited to identify the nature and source of
the undesirable consequences of lending by central banks. In Section 3,
we consider how well some actual and possible components of central bank
lending policy cope with the problem of limited commitment. We conclude
that no simple institutional mechanisms could confidently precommit a
central bank to limit its lending. Reasoning by analogy to the
historical reduction of inflation, we argue that the only way for a
central bank to credibly limit lending is for it to build up a
reputation over time for lending restraint. Exploiting the inflation
analogy further, we describe a sequence of events that we think will be
necessary for a central bank to successfully acquire such a reputation.
1. THE ECONOMICS OF PRIVATE LINES OF CREDIT
The parallel between central bank lending and private lending under
lines of credit is illuminating for the similarities and the differences
that emerge (Goodfriend and King 1988). Both involve lending large
amounts on short notice. However, private credit lines are explicit
contractual commitments, while a central bank's commitment to lend
is a matter of policy choice. In this section we review the economics of
private lines of credit. We will focus in particular on what determines
the contingencies under which private banks deny credit.
The Line of Credit Product
Lines of credit (loan commitments) specify a maximum amount that
can be borrowed and a formula that determines the interest rate on
advances, or "take-downs." Borrowing rates are usually set as
a fixed markup over a reference rate such as the LIBOR or the lending
bank's prime rate. Borrowers pay an up-front fee when the line of
credit is initiated, as well as an annual "commitment fee"
proportional to either the undrawn portion or the entire amount of the
commitment (Crane 1973, Schockley 1995). Line-of-credit lending is
generally secured by collateral, although the largest and most
creditworthy borrowers can obtain unsecured loan commitments. Some loan
commitments provide "back-up" support for commercial paper
issued by the firm; the loan is drawn down in the event that the firm
cannot roll over its maturing paper. In this case the line of credit
provides a bank guarantee for the liquidity of the commercial paper
issued by the firm, assuring holders of an orderly exit in adverse
circumstances (Calomiris 1998 ).
Loan commitment agreements contain covenants that place
restrictions on the borrower's future financial condition. If the
borrower violates one of the covenants, the lender has the right (though
not the obligation) to terminate the agreement and demand immediate
repayment. Some covenants utilize specific financial indicators--minimum
net worth, minimum working capital, or maximum leverage ratio, for
example. Other covenants restrict the disposition of assets or the
issuance of other debt.
Loan commitment agreements also generally contain a clause that
allows the bank to declare a default in the event of any
"materially adverse change in the financial condition of the
borrower." This ambiguously worded clause provides a backstop to
the other formal covenants, allowing the lender to terminate lending
when the borrower's financial condition deteriorates, even if the
specific covenants are technically satisfied. At the same time, a
borrower that is in good financial health can be assured that the bank
is still obligated to lend.
Because the markup does not vary with subsequent changes in the
borrower's creditworthiness, the line of credit represents an
implicit insurance arrangement--a credit risk derivative. The implicit
ex post insurance payout in a given state of the world is the present
value of the difference between the contractual markup and the risk
premium appropriate to that borrower in that state of the world. The
contract does not provide full insurance, however, because the bank can
limit large payouts by invoking covenants and denying credit. This
partial insurance is valuable to borrowers as a way of smoothing the
cost of contingent funding across various states of the world. Without a
line of credit, the firm would pay a high risk premium if it needed
funds when creditworthiness had deteriorated. With a line of credit, the
firm pays ex ante fees and agrees to the possibility that credit is
denied in some states in order to assure ex post access to funds at a
lower risk premium. The ex ante fees compensate the bank fo r the
implicit insurance provided.
Lines of credit tend to be provided by financial intermediaries, in
general, and banks, in particular. By diversifying over a large number
of risks that are to some degree independent, banks can offer
insurance-like products at low cost. Bank loan officers specialize in
evaluating creditworthiness, and are ideally suited to monitor the
borrower's condition over the life of the commitment. Such
information gathering, built up through repeated interactions with the
borrower, is crucial in evaluating later requests by the borrower to
take down credit. In addition, bank monitoring activities save costs for
other creditors. Historically, lending and related credit evaluation
activities often have been combined with the issue of demand deposits
(Goodfriend 1991, Nakamura 1993). Because of these advantages, banking
institutions have traditionally dominated the line-of-credit business.
Agency Problems
Modern theory explains financial contracts as the result of ex ante
negotiation among contracting parties in the context of competition from
alternative borrowers and lenders. Contractual provisions help control
agency problems-- adverse incentives that may arise due to asymmetric
information during the course of a contractual relationship. Bargaining
is presumed to lead to contractual arrangements that are efficient in
the sense that no other feasible contracts would make one party better
off without making some other party worse off. Competition ensures that
no contracting party is worse off than it would be if it contracted with
another party instead. [5]
When banks lend to commercial firms, the critical agency problem is
managerial moral hazard. Many managerial actions are difficult or
impossible to specify as explicit conditions of the contract, either
because they are not easily verifiable by the lender or a court, or
because their complexity makes them too costly to include. Continuing to
operate the business often yields private benefits to the
manager-borrower, known as "control rents," which are
impossible to transfer to outsiders. The manager may have significant
human capital tied to the existing organization and operation, the value
of which might be lost or diminished in a closure or liquidation. Also,
the manager may enjoy perquisites from controlling the cash flow of the
firm. More fundamentally, inducing the manager to take actions that
benefit the firm might require giving the manager a pecuniary interest
in the firm's profits. Borrowers and lenders may in some
circumstances have conflicting interests over such actions. When the net
worth of th e firm is low, the manager's interest in the
continuation of the firm strongly resembles an option; the manager would
reap much of the upside gain in the business, while the costs of a
deterioration would affect mainly the creditors. The manager can have a
distorted incentive to make "all-or-nothing" gambles on
excessively risky prospects.
If left unchecked, the moral hazard problem at a firm tends to grow
over time. Losses erode net worth to the point where risk incentives
shift. The firm begins to seek out investments with large potential
payoffs, hoping to gamble its way back to health. The cost of such
investments is below-normal rates of return under conditions in which
the large payoffs are not realized. As a result, net worth is most
likely to erode further, exacerbating the moral hazard problem. Each
round of losses further strengthens risk-taking incentives.
Moral hazard can involve more than just the borrower. Other
creditors will adopt a strategy that depends on the behavior of the
firm's line-of-credit provider. If a lender pulls a line of credit
that backs up a commercial paper program in a situation in which the
borrower does not have the funds to roll over maturing claims, the firm
defaults and investors may take a loss. The rate of return on the
commercial paper will therefore reflect market expectations about the
future funding behavior of the lender. Overly lax lending policy will
show up as an inappropriately small risk premium on the firm's
commercial paper or as an overly generous willingness to lend on the
part of private investors. This issue is crucial for firms with illiquid
assets that wish to issue liquid liabilities, because their creditors
will be particularly concerned about prospects for future liquidity. A
lender who is confident of the solvency of the firm will be willing to
lend, while a lender who believes that the firm is insolvent wil l
likely withdraw funds.
At the time the lending contract is negotiated, the contracting
parties will anticipate the agency problems that could arise. Financial
contracts deal with agency problems in two ways. First, contractual
conditions explicitly constrain a manager's decisions. Such
constraints show up in lending agreements as loan covenants, which we
discuss in detail below. Second, contractual provisions affect the
contingencies which force a change in control that removes the manager
of the firm from a decision-making role. Liquidation is a leading
example; the firm's tangible assets are sold and the proceeds are
distributed to creditors. A "reorganization" supervised by a
bankruptcy court is another type of change in control; management is
often removed, but even when it remains in place its decisions are
sharply constrained while the firm is under court-sponsored supervision.
Changes in control serve three purposes in the context of the
agency problems that afflict lending arrangements. First, removing
existing management prevents further value-wasting actions. Second,
separating management from the quasi-rents associated with controlling
the firm acts as a pecuniary punishment that helps provide ex ante
incentives to manage the firm faithfully. Third, control changes
facilitate restructuring the firm's liabilities in order to realign
them with changed circumstances and allow repayment of creditors that
wish to terminate their relationship with the firm.
Liquidation will be efficient ex post if it maximizes the total
value of the firm. Inefficient liquidation--selling the firm's
assets for less than the value of the firm as a going concern--reduces
the total expected value of the firm when it occurs, and thus reduces
the ex ante expected value of the firm. Ex ante both parties will prefer
provisions that reduce the likelihood of inefficient ex post
liquidation. On the other hand, managerial control rents are
extinguished when the firm is liquidated. The loss of these rents is a
social cost of liquidation. Since control rents can only accrue to the
managers, lenders will not take them into account in deciding when to
liquidate. The cost of transferring control rights to lenders is that
they will want to liquidate too often--when liquidation value exceeds
the value as an ongoing concern, excluding control rents. Efficient
liquidation rules balance the benefit of control changes against the
cost of inefficient liquidation (Diamond 1993).
Credible Commitments
The circumstances under which control changes take place are
determined by contractual terms (as well as the implicit background
rules embodied in the relevant legal codes) that determine the
assignment of property rights under various contingencies. The borrower
and the lender will have an incentive ex ante to design contractual
provisions so that ex post decisions about liquidation and the
allocation of control rights are efficient, in the sense that they
maximize the expected ongoing value of the concern as a whole, subject
to the constraints imposed by the agency problems they face. [6] Loan
covenants and collateral provisions play a central role in structuring
the ex post incentives to effect control changes under line-of-credit
arrangements.
Loan Covenants
Under the conditions defined in the covenants, the lender has the
right to withdraw funding. If the borrower cannot obtain funding
elsewhere, as is likely (see discussion below), the lender can
essentially force reorganization or liquidation. Absent violation of the
covenants, the borrower retains control of the firm. Loan covenants thus
can be viewed as a means for conditionally transferring control of the
reorganization/liquidation decision to the lender. Covenants also
control other forms of ex post moral hazard directly by limiting the
manager's right to take on new risks, change lines of business,
assume new indebtedness, and so on (Aghion and Bolton 1992, Berlin and
Mester 1992).
Loan covenants can be quite strong. In practice, however, the
violation of a loan covenant is merely an occasion for renegotiation
between lender and borrower. The lender can waive the violation or use
the ability to declare (technical) default as leverage to obtain more
favorable monetary terms or more stringent covenant conditions (a
partial control transfer). Renegotiation allows outcomes to vary with ex
post contingencies in ways that would be difficult to provide for ahead
of time in a formal contract (Huberman and Kahn 1988, Kahn and Huberman
1989). Strict covenant restrictions can be adopted, with the expectation
that in some circumstances they will be waived or loosened by the
lender. Although the borrower and the lender cannot precommit to refrain
from renegotiating, the loan agreement can influence outcomes by
ensuring that the allocation of property rights depends on future
circumstances.
It makes sense, from an ex ante point of view, for the allocation
of bargaining rights implied by loan covenants to depend on the
riskiness of increased lending. When covenants are violated, managerial
moral hazard is likely to be more pronounced. If further lending is to
take place, the lender must do as well as if it withdrew the credit line
and forced reorganization or liquidation. In this case covenants put the
lender in a position to insist on a higher markup or more collateral to
compensate for the heightened risk of continued lending. If the lender
cannot be satisfied--if no such terms or collateral exist--then further
lending is, presumably, ex post inefficient or infeasible, and the
borrower is insolvent. When covenants are fully satisfied, managerial
moral hazard is likely to be muted and so the lender does not need the
right to prevent further lending. The bargaining power rests with the
borrower, who is quite likely to be solvent in this case. Lending takes
place at the borrower's request at the pre-agreed rate. The ex post
self-interest of lenders, the ability to renegotiate, and the presence
of relatively strict loan covenants provide a contractual mechanism that
credibly commits the lender to limit lending when appropriate.
If given the choice ex post, the lender would never want to extend
new lending to an insolvent firm. A firm is insolvent when the present
discounted value of future cash flows falls short of the real current
value of liabilities. Without a positive gap between future receipts and
future obligations, the present value of anticipated future repayment
streams cannot possibly cover the value of additional loans. Lending in
such circumstances would represent subsidization, and a
profit-maximizing lender has no reason to subsidize customers under
competitive conditions. [7]
Collateral
The secured lender's ability to seize collateral for
nonpayment is an important contractual right. A lien on an asset that is
essential to the borrower's operations can provide the lender with
another means of forcing the borrower's liquidation. In addition,
collateral reduces the lender's risk by providing compensation when
the borrower cannot pay the obligation in cash, therefore allowing a
lower risk markup. Collateral also sharpens the borrower's
incentive to repay, which helps relax borrowing constraints by allowing
larger credible repayment obligations (Lacker 1998). Moreover, in
bankruptcy, secured debt has a priority claim on the pledged assets.
Collateral thus prevents dilution of the lender's position.
The lender's ability to take new assets as collateral later in
the lending relationship helps overcome the classic underinvestment
problem associated with debt overhang (Stulz and Johnson 1985). When the
value of the firm is below the nominal value of outstanding debt, part
of the return to any investment accrues to current debtholders; the real
value of their debt increases. By pledging collateral, the borrower and
the new lender can appropriate and share between them much of the gains
from the new investment. Junior lenders can prohibit financing new
projects with secured debt by including a "negative pledge
clause" that prohibits pledging collateral to other lenders. Many
junior creditors do not do so, however, since a negative pledge clause
has the potential to prevent value-enhancing investments. For many
publicly issued bonds, the firm retains the right to finance new
projects with secured debt. Note that the presence or absence of a
negative pledge clause for junior debt is a matter of contract. Note
also that the lender's decision to take additional collateral is
subject to ex post rationality constraints; it must be in the
lender's self-interest to do so.
It is important to recognize that collateralized lending is not
perfectly safe. The value realized by seizing and disposing of
collateral is uncertain, and in some circumstances can fall short of the
nominal obligation it backs. This feature is no accident, since
borrowers have a greater incentive to default and surrender collateral
when its value has fallen below the value of the debt. Why would lenders
agree to terms under which they may take a loss on collateral? As
previously noted, the key role of collateralized debt is to enhance the
repayment incentive of the borrower. Collateral that is worth more to
the borrower than to the lender, perhaps because of the transactions
costs associated with liquidating the collateral, can provide adequate
repayment incentives even though the lender suffers a loss when the
borrower defaults and transfers the collateral (Lacker 1998). Moreover,
collateralization alters ex post bargaining positions in any
renegotiation by the borrower and the lender.
Monitoring
As mentioned above, line-of-credit lending is accompanied by costly
information gathering. Banks assess the borrower's credit risk
prior to the contractual commitment in order to set contract prices
appropriately and to screen inappropriate risks. After the lending
commitment has been signed, ongoing monitoring takes place, partly in
the form of periodic financial statements required by covenant, and
partly through informal contacts. Note that any arbitrary information
gathering can, in principle, be negotiated as part of the commitment
agreement. For example, many agreements stipulate that the lender
receive audited financial reports. In other cases, particularly for
small firms, the burden of audited statements is judged too costly and
unaudited reports are accepted instead. When the borrower and the lender
negotiate the monitoring features of the contract, they presumably
balance the marginal value of gathering additional information against
the expected incremental joint cost.
Lenders have a strong incentive to gather information on an ongoing
basis in order to be able to assess the solvency of the borrower as
accurately as possible. Periodic monitoring thus helps prepare the
lender to make critical decisions when the borrower experiences
financial distress (Rajan and Winton 1995). What is learned about the
characteristics of the firm's cash flow can help the lender
interpret payment problems and more accurately assess the value of the
firm as a going concern. Such information will be useful when the lender
decides whether to extend or deny credit in response to covenant
violations. In comparison, a lender with no prior lending relationship
with the borrower will be at a distinct informational disadvantage.
Information gathering gives rise to "relationship
lending" in which ties between lenders and borrowers are typically
long lasting (Berger and Udell 1995, Petersen and Rajan 1994, Petersen
and Rajan 1995, and Sharpe l990). [8] This effect is particularly acute
in times of distress, when outsiders are unable to acquire information
fast enough to assist the firm on the same terms. The informational
hurdles facing alternative lenders make the current lender's
decision to grant or deny credit all the more crucial. When the
informational advantage of a lending relationship enables a firm to
obtain funds at a low enough cost to continue operating, and that same
firm would have been unable to obtain funds cheaply enough without that
relationship, we can say that the firm is illiquid though solvent.
Withdrawing credit in this setting can effectively force reorganization
or liquidation.
Safeguards for the Borrower
From the borrower's point of view, the important feature of
loan covenants is that they define the limits of the lender's power
to abrogate the agreement and demand accelerated payment. If the
covenants are not violated, the lender is compelled to lend. As the
lending relationship matures over time, the quasi-rents associated with
the lender's informational advantage over competing lenders will
grow. If the lender had blanket authority to demand repayment, the
lender would be tempted to extort concessions from even a financially
healthy borrower. All the quasi-rents from the relationship would
inevitably accrue to the lender. To safeguard the borrower against such
opportunistic behavior, the line-of-credit agreement stipulates that the
lender is compelled to lend at a pre-agreed risk premium, absent any
violation of the covenant conditions.
To summarize, then, line-of-credit agreements are crafted to
address anticipated moral hazard problems that may arise if the borrower
later gets into trouble. In the presence of loan covenants and
collateral provisions, a lender's profit motive allows it to
credibly commit to making appropriate decisions to withdraw credit and
induce closure or reorganization. Costly periodic monitoring enhances
the lender's ability to gauge the borrower's situation.
2. CENTRAL BANK LENDING AS A LINE OF CREDIT
In this section we describe the similarities and differences
between central bank lending and lending under private loan commitments.
We consider central bank lending practices against the benchmark of
private lending mechanisms, without prejudging the usefulness of public
line-of-credit lending. [9] The critical difference is that the profit
motive provides private line-of-credit lenders with ample incentive to
limit lending ex post in the event of borrower adversity. The comparable
incentive for central banks is relatively weak. Indeed, the commitment
problem facing a central bank is the opposite of that facing a private
lender; a lender needs to commit to lend in situations in which it might
not want to lend, while a central bank needs to forego lending when it
might want to lend.
Central Bank Lending
At first glance, central bank lending would appear to be quite
different from private line-of-credit lending. Central banks do not
generally negotiate contractual terms with individual borrowers.
Instead, they are given statutory authority to lend to broad classes of
institutions. Central banks are publicly chartered institutions and,
unlike private lenders, profit maximization is not their primary
objective.
Despite these apparent differences, central bank lending functions
in fundamentally the same way as a private line of credit--by providing
guaranteed access to borrowed funds at a predetermined rate. The rate at
which central banks lend is generally posted in advance rather than
negotiated ex post with each individual borrower. Thus central bank
lending rates do not appear to vary much with the borrower's ex
post creditworthiness. At times, distressed borrowers turn to the
central bank because terms offered by private lenders would be
exorbitant, either in the cost of explicit financing or because the
terms would require surrender of control. Access to central bank credit
therefore appears to provide implicit insurance to those that qualify.
One difference between the pricing of central bank credit and private
lines of credit is that central banks generally do not charge explicit
ex ante fees for the service, although one could argue that the central
bank commitment is bundled together with an array of regul atory burdens
(and privileges). [10]
In its classic rationale, central bank lending is intended to help
illiquid but solvent financial institutions meet their maturing
short-term obligations. In the extreme case, central bank lending might
fund a run on demand deposits. Note that this function closely parallels
the role of bank lines of credit in backing up commercial paper
programs. The facility is designed to help a firm cope with an emergency
"run"--an inability to roll over its credits. As noted above,
a decision to withdraw credit can trigger default on the commercial
paper and closure or reorganization of a firm.
Compare private and central bank lending with respect to the
mechanism that links credit withdrawal and closure. A private lender
denies credit, causing a default, which leads creditors to seek remedies
by seizing assets. The borrower files for bankruptcy to obtain
protection from creditors so that a division of the losses can be
negotiated without destroying firm value. A central bank that denies
credit to a bank forces the hand of the chartering agency or the deposit
insurance fund. The central bank's critical role in bank closure
brings it face-to-face with the government agencies that have direct
responsibility for closing banks.
Agency Problems
A vast array of bank management decisions involves risk-return
trade-offs. Attitudes toward risk are to some degree distorted at any
leveraged entity, because some decisions affect the value of
debtholders' claims. Banks are among the most highly leveraged of
institutions. At well-capitalized banks, the value of future
control-rents is an asset that acts as an implicit performance bond that
offsets risk-taking incentives. When net worth falls, however, the value
of the implicit bond vanishes and incentives flip toward
risk-taking--little is left to lose. It is widely recognized that the
management of a poorly capitalized bank has incentives to take on
excessive risks in an attempt to gamble its way out of trouble. When
supervisory restraint is lax--as during the U.S. savings and loan
crisis, or in the recent emerging markets banking crises--moral hazard
steadily grows as the losses pile up (Calomiris 1998).
Private banks make explicit case-by-case decisions to grant lines
of credit. In contrast, central bank lending commitments are not usually
made on an individual basis. Often legislative and regulatory policies
delimit the set of institutions that have access to central bank credit.
Sometimes the set of institutions with access is quite large. [11] The
key difference is that private institutions are able to condition the
commitment on an examination of the prospective borrower's
financial health and then tailor the contractual terms to the individual
borrower. In contrast, access to central bank credit is granted to broad
categories of institutions. Also, the terms of central bank lending do
not reflect the competitive discipline of arm's-length bargaining.
Central bank supervision of institutions with access to central
bank credit is a direct counterpart to the ongoing monitoring performed
by banks. Supervisory reports, like the periodic financial statements
provided to line-of-credit lenders, keep authorities apprised of changes
in the creditworthiness of the prospective borrower. Even for central
banks without a direct supervisory role, access to such information
performs the same function. Supervisory information is generally far
more detailed than the reporting required of private line-of-credit
customers. As noted earlier, private contracts can, in principle,
mandate stricter disclosure, but there are impediments to doing so. In
the United States, provisions of bankruptcy law discourage lenders from
becoming so intimate with the management of the firm as to be deemed an
"insider" (Baird 1993).
Like private line-of-credit lending, central bank lending is
generally collateralized. Specific assets can be documented and
evaluated in advance, drawing on the central bank's supervisory
knowledge. In addition, the security interests of central banks are
generally favored in bank failure resolutions. This fact tends to make
central bank lending relatively safe, although, as noted above,
collateralized lending is not risk-free in general.
When central banks lend to government-insured institutions,
collateral plays a crucial role in the loan's effect on the
insurance fund in the event of a failure. Collateralized lending dilutes
junior claimants, which in the case of an insured bank includes
depositors. The insurance fund stands in for the depositors in the event
of closure, however, so central bank lending effectively dilutes the
deposit insurance fund. For example, in the United States, the FDIC
assumes the failed bank's indebtedness to the Federal Reserve and
in exchange retains the pledged assets. When the Fed lends to allow a
failing bank to pay maturing short-term obligations the insurance fund
retains the collateral, but the maturing short-term obligations have
been replaced by a fixed obligation to the Fed. If the short-term
claimants whose funds were withdrawn are insured depositors, the
operation has merely replaced one fixed obligation for another. It is a
different matter, however, if some short-term claimants are uninsured.
The sh ort-term claimants would have shared in the losses with the FDIC
had the central bank not lent. [12] Instead, the insurance fund inherits
a bank in which an uninsured claim held by the private sector is
replaced by a fixed senior claim held by the Federal Reserve. In the
process, closure is delayed and private uninsured creditors are spared.
The Commitment Problem
With private lines of credit, lender profit maximization provides
an incentive to advance credit only when it is ex post efficient to do
so. The environment surrounding central bank lending is quite different.
A central bank has a legislated responsibility for the stability of the
financial system as a whole: it could be blamed for any negative
consequences of not lending. A central bank that precipitates the demise
of one or more financial institutions may be subject to direct action
through the legal system or indirect action through the legislature. It
is impossible to prove the counterfactual, i.e., that not lending and
letting a troubled firm fail would not seriously disrupt markets.
Furthermore, it is difficult for outsiders to question, after the fact,
a central bank's judgment on such matters. For all of these
reasons, central banks are inclined to lend whenever financial stability
is at all threatened.
Central banks are careful to protect their loans by taking
collateral. In fact, some central banks lend only on terms that
virtually guarantee repayment in full. In the United States, for
example, discount window loans are virtually always collateralized,
assuring priority in closure (Hackley 1973). Moreover, the FDIC
generally assumes the debt that the borrowing bank owes the Fed in
exchange for the collateral, relieving the Fed of the risk of falling
collateral value. This arrangement allows the Reserve Banks to avoid
loan losses but has the effect of shifting losses to the deposit
insurance agency (Marino and Bennett 1999).
Implicitly restricting central bank lending to be risk-free by
taking collateral is a "bright line" policy that is easy to
verify ex post. Such a policy is one way to limit central bank
involvement in the allocation of credit and to restrict the scope for
subsidization. Limits to the central bank's involvement in credit
allocation can help buttress the central bank's independence and
bolster the fiscal discipline of the deposit insurance fund (Goodfriend
1994). One might think that such a bright-line no-loss policy would
sharpen the central bank's incentives, bringing them more closely
in line with those of a private line-of-credit provider. By itself,
however, taking collateral is not enough, because the central bank then
has no pecuniary reason not to lend.
Lending by the central bank creates a potentially severe moral
hazard problem. Markets expect the central bank to provide the bank with
the funds to allow the exit of uninsured liquid claimholders. Thus,
lending by central banks facilitates a reallocation of wealth among the
creditors of a failing bank that the deposit insurance fund has neither
the capability nor the legal authority to perform by itself. Private
lending to a failing firm is subject to the safeguards of bankruptcy
law. This includes the fraudulent conveyance provision, which under
certain conditions allows the court to unwind transactions, including
loan agreements, that occurred immediately prior to bankruptcy if such
agreements disadvantaged the bankrupt firm's estate. Collateralized
central bank lending accompanied by indemnification from the deposit
insurance fund is subject to no such formal discipline, only the
vagaries of the political system. [13]
The financial stability mandate can create pressure to expand the
scope of central bank lending to nonbank financial institutions. Nonbank
financial intermediaries are capable of amassing sizable financial
market positions. The liquidation of these positions could be seen as a
threat to the stability of asset prices and the solvency of many other
financial institutions, including insured banks. A central bank with no
formal authority to lend outside a narrowly defined set of institutions
is, of course, well positioned to resist influence. Otherwise, we might
see a tendency to expand the range of institutions receiving central
bank line-of-credit assistance. [14]
We conclude that the incentives for a central bank to limit lending
are relatively weak. As a result, we should expect to see a tendency for
central banks to overextend lending, creating moral hazard problems
among institutions deemed likely to qualify for central bank credit.
Moreover, the rate of incidence of financial distress that calls for
central bank lending should tend to increase over time as market
participants come to understand the range of the central bank's
actual (implicit) commitment to lend and adjust expectations
accordingly.
3. COPING WITH THE COMMITMENT PROBLEM
To summarize the argument so far, we have seen how commercial banks
efficiently and profitably structure contracts to support private lines
of credit. They do so because (1) their own money is at stake, (2) they
can choose their borrower relationships, (3) the conditions include the
right to monitor the value of assets on an ex ante (ongoing) basis to
distinguish illiquid from insolvent borrowers in the event of a request
for funds, (4) loan covenants give the lender the right to withdraw
credit when the borrower's financial condition has deteriorated,
and (5) competition and profit maximization induce private providers to
balance the risks of accommodating a request for funds against the costs
of not lending. To be competitive, the terms of the line-of-credit
product must not exploit borrowers; and to be profitable, the credit
line must provide a risk-adjusted return comparable to products offered
by other banks.
Central banks provide lines of credit under such different
circumstances that we cannot presume they will make lending decisions
appropriately. First, financial losses are not borne by the central bank
but by the Treasury, and, ultimately, taxpayers. Second, a central bank
cannot offer "take-it-or-leave-it" conditions because it is
responsible for protecting financial markets as a whole and may not be
able to refuse to lend to an institution whose failure might threaten
the system. Third, for the reason mentioned above, a central bank might
feel pressure to lend to an institution that it does not examine
thoroughly, or at all. Fourth, a central bank is not disciplined by
competition or profit maximization.
At any point in time, then, a central bank will be more inclined to
lend whenever not lending could threaten the entire financial system.
Such incentives ensure that the central bank carries out its legislative
mandate to stabilize financial markets. The problem is that the
inclination to lend creates in the public's mind an expectation
that a financial institution in a protected class can count on credit
assistance from the central bank in certain adverse future
circumstances. Private lenders will take advantage of central bank
assistance by monitoring less and accepting greater credit risks when
lending to implicitly protected firms. Further, borrowing firms in the
protected class will take advantage, too, by taking on increasingly
risky assets. Over time, the central bank will be inclined to expand the
class of firms perceived to be protected and the extent of protection.
The fundamental problem is to find a way to credibly commit to
limit lending. [15] It is a difficult problem and there are no easy
solutions. In what follows we consider the practical effectiveness of
five broad approaches to the commitment problem.
Good Offices Only
In lieu of establishing a practical means of committing a central
bank to refrain from lending except in deserving circumstances, we could
imagine legislation precluding a central bank from extending its own
credit under any circumstances. This possibility is worth considering
because a central bank could still play a useful and effective role in
facilitating private credit transactions or those of other national or
international agencies. A central bank has three institutional strengths
in this regard. First, its financial independence and independence from
the budget process makes it impartial with respect to financial matters,
unlike most other government agencies, or, for that matter, firms in the
private sector. Second, a central bank has a large staff with practical
experience in economics, supervision and regulation, payments system
operations, and financial law. Third, in the course of carrying out
their normal duties, high central bank officials develop personal
relationships with their counterparts in the private sector.
Thus, a central bank could offer its "good offices" to
help private creditors negotiate a troubled financial firm's
recapitalization. The central bank might have knowledge of the troubled
firm through existing supervisory relationships. Also it might be in a
position to "certify" the solvency of the firm to others,
essentially facilitating "due diligence" efforts. Even in the
absence of ex ante central bank knowledge of the institution, the
central bank might inspect the portfolio for others, acting as a trusted
third party. Furthermore, in negotiations among members of a potential
lending consortium, the central bank might play the role of neutral
arbitrator.
In principle, the extension of good offices need not involve
pressure or sweeteners from the central bank. In practice, however, as
long as a central bank retains supervisory and regulatory powers, one
could not be sure whether private parties to the agreement were
influenced implicitly by a concern about punishment should they not sign
on to a deal. In effect, then, a deal could have been facilitated by
implicitly directed credit allocation because of the central bank's
involvement. The parties could also believe that regulatory authorities,
including the central bank, would forbear if the institutions that lent
became troubled themselves. Of course, a deal could very well involve a
considerable transfer of equity from the original owners to the new
owners of the troubled firm. If a central bank presides over a deal more
favorable to the original owners than they would have received without
its help, moral hazard has increased.
One way to ensure that no implicit pressure or sweeteners are
involved when a central bank uses its good offices would be to take the
central bank out of bank supervision and regulation. But then the
central bank would lose the professional and personal connections that
make it a good facilitator in the first place. The upshot is that even
limiting a central bank's role to one of facilitator tends to
create in the public's mind the possibility of assistance of one
kind or another.
Lending Hurdles
Recognizing that there are circumstances when central bank lending
would be desirable in order to protect the financial system, we consider
various hurdles designed to limit the central bank's inclination to
lend except in extreme circumstances and to limit its own exposure if it
does lend. We deal with these issues in reverse order. First, we
consider the taking of collateral. After that, we consider the
effectiveness of hurdles that a central bank might be made to clear
before it is authorized to lend in the first place.
Collateral
Some central banks lend only on good collateral to fully protect
their funds in the event that the borrower cannot repay. The taking of
good collateral certainly protects the financial integrity of central
banks themselves. As discussed above, however, collateralized lending
does not limit the exposure of the insurance fund and taxpayers.
Its lending well protected, a central bank would have little
incentive to precipitate a borrower's insolvency by refusing to
lend. When a central bank supervises a borrowing bank, it is in a good
position to evaluate the illiquid portions of a portfolio for purposes
of collateral and can keep a bank operating for some time. In effect,
central bank lending provides uninsured creditors of a troubled bank
with free insurance (which encourages uninsured creditors to invest at
shorter maturities) and delays the time when a troubled bank would
default to one of its creditors and trigger its closing and
reorganization. Assets that could have remained in the bank, if it had
been closed sooner, are pledged to the central bank and are unavailable
to help the deposit insurance fund and the taxpayers pay off insured
deposits. Full collateralization of central bank lending conceals the
fact that such lending exposes the insurance fund and the taxpayer to a
risk of loss.
Early Intervention
One option for better protecting the deposit insurance fund and the
taxpayer is to require bank regulators to close a failing bank when its
book value equity capital falls to, say, 2 percent rather than to the
point of book insolvency. A deterioration of book capital could trigger
progressively heavier regulatory restrictions. Such restrictions might
prohibit additional central bank lending at some point, unless the
highest officials in the government grant written permission to lend.
[16]
The problem with this hurdle is that it is based on book rather
than market value capital. When depository institutions have assets that
are in large part illiquid non-traded loans, they could become insolvent
on a market value basis well before they are declared insolvent on a
book value basis. For example, consider the Bank of New England which
was declared insolvent in January 1991. Soon after, the FDIC released
estimates that the deposit insurance claim would cost the taxpayer
around $2 billion. Why didn't the regulators act sooner?
The Bank of New England's problems began when the mortgage
loans it made in the mid-1980s turned bad. Real estate proved unable to
earn a sufficient return to cover the loan payments. The bank, however,
still had to pay competitive interest on deposits. So the bank had to
divert to depositors a portion of the return on assets that had been
going to equity holders. The cut in dividends caused the stock price to
fall precipitously, and the bank could not meet the competitive deposit
rate payments by reducing dividends alone. The bank had to sell off
securities, pledge assets to the Federal Reserve's discount window,
and obtain Treasury deposits in order to fund withdrawals of uninsured
deposits and pay interest to the remaining depositors. The negative cash
flow eventually reduced the book value net worth enough for regulators
to seize the bank.
In this case it may be said that regulators were too slow in
writing down the value of loans. It is well to remember, however, that
there are often good reasons to be cautious. The market value of a loan
is the present discounted value of future cash flows. Although current
cash flows may be small, there is usually room for disagreement among
analysts concerning future cash flows. Therefore, any write-down by a
regulator is subjective and subject to challenge ex post by high
government officials or by the bank in question itself. As a result,
hurdles based on measured capital deficiencies that are designed to
protect the deposit insurance fund and the taxpayer against losses due
to excessive central bank lending might not work very well in practice.
Constructive Ambiguity
The above argument suggests that one cannot count on simple
mechanistic hurdles to limit a central bank's inclination to lend.
The problem is that financial markets know that there are circumstances
in which a central bank would not refuse to lend to troubled
institutions. Thus, owners of institutions that are big enough or
central enough to the payments system or to financial markets more
generally have an incentive to increase their risk exposure in just
those circumstances. Owners know that they keep the upside returns if
things go well, but share any losses more broadly, i.e., with the
central bank, an insurance fund, or the taxpayer, if things go badly.
This sort of logic puts a central bank in a box. A central
banker's willingness to support the financial system in times of
potential crisis (to maintain the confidence necessary to facilitate the
functioning of financial markets and the economy more broadly) actually
causes risks in the system to grow. For this reason, a central bank
might be inclined to keep markets guessing about the exact circumstances
in which it would be willing to lend. By creating uncertainty in the
minds of potential borrowers, such ambiguity might be thought to be
constructive because it causes potential borrowers to take on less risk.
Constructive ambiguity, under this interpretation, attempts to reduce
market participants' perception of the probability of central bank
lending while reserving the central bank's option to lend when
systemic concerns seem to require it.
Some ambiguity is unavoidable in any attempt to state the precise
contingencies in which a central bank might lend. The true policy would
depend on information available to the central bank at a future date,
some of which might be private information about specific firms known
only to the central bank. A policy that needs to be based on private
unpublishable information would not be verifiable and so could not be
made completely free of uncertainty and ambiguity. Moreover, lending
policies that depend on future circumstances in complicated ways might
be difficult to state with clarity in advance.
That said, one might ask whether a central bank might want to
deliberately increase the uncertainty surrounding its lending
intentions. At one level, ambiguity can be enhanced by not attempting to
sharpen or clarify the broad principles of central bank lending in
internal discussions or external speeches of high central bank
officials. Over time, however, markets will learn the central
bank's actual lending policy. If the central bank does not follow
through with actions that ratify the announced ambiguity, its rhetoric
will ultimately be disregarded. Market expectations will converge on the
central bank's actual policy. To be sustainable, therefore, a
policy of constructive ambiguity has to be demonstrated in a central
bank's lending actions themselves.
In order to increase ambiguity, a central bank would have to add
extraneous variability to its lending policy--it would have to play a
"mixed strategy" in game-theoretic terms. In effect, a central
bank would have to couple each lending decision with a spin of a
roulette wheel that would randomly point to "follow through"
or "not follow through." The central bank would need to be
willing to abide by the wheel. That is, with some probability the
central bank would lend when its better judgment said the situation did
not call for it; and with some probability the central bank would have
to follow the wheel and not lend when it would otherwise wish to do so.
Randomization can be economically useful. For example, tax
authorities audit randomly, with audit probabilities that vary with some
basic features of the return. Randomization balances the beneficial
incentive effects on taxpayer behavior against the expected resource
cost of the audits. Tax authorities are able to implement mixed
strategies credibly because they have learned over time that failing to
audit eventually leads to increased tax evasion.
The problem with adding variability to central bank lending policy
is that the central bank would have trouble sticking to it, for the same
reason that central banks tend to overextend lending to begin with. An
announced policy of constructive ambiguity does nothing to alter the ex
post incentives that cause central banks to lend in the first place. In
any particular instance the central bank would want to ignore the spin
of the wheel.
Constructive ambiguity in the absence of an ability to precommit
may actually increase the drift toward expansion. The greater the
perceived probability of lending by the central bank in various
circumstances, the greater the risk-taking incentive for eligible
institutions. Whenever the central bank is seen to lend in a situation
in which it had not lent before, perceived probabilities will be revised
upward, inducing greater risk-taking. [17]
Extended Supervisory and Regulatory Reach
A central bank could consider extending its supervisory and
regulatory authority, or the authority of other government agencies, to
all institutions to which it might possibly wish to lend. In principle,
such authority would enable the central bank to limit risk-taking
directly. A central bank might extend its regulatory authority to
financial institutions, banking or otherwise, big enough or central
enough to threaten the financial system if they failed.
There are many problems with attempting to control risks by
extending regulatory authority. First, regulatory reach does not extend
across international borders. An attempt to regulate financial firms too
heavily may cause them to locate in those countries willing to impose
little regulation in order to attract the business. Second, an attempt
to extend regulation within a country causes new institutional forms to
develop to escape regulation. Third, the proliferation of new financial
instruments associated with derivatives enables institutions to
synthesize financial positions in many ways. Sophisticated financial
engineering has made circumventing regulatory restrictions much easier.
It has become very difficult for regulators to monitor and regulate
transactions, i.e., balance sheet and off-balance-sheet positions of a
firm. This development prompted the movement from direct supervision of
balance sheet items toward a supervisory philosophy focused on
institutions' risk management and control processes.
If central banks extend supervisory and regulatory authority to a
broader array of financial institutions, they risk a positive feedback
effect on central bank lending policy. Supervisory involvement in a
financial sector can "taint" government authorities with
implicit responsibility for the health of institutions in that sector,
heightening the perception that the central bank is willing to lend to
them in the event of liquidity problems. A central bank might find it
costly to disappoint such expectations. In other words, extending the
breadth of supervision and regulation could induce a commensurate
extension of the perceived central bank lending commitment.
Supervision and regulation has its place as part of a
line-of-credit package, but it is oversold as a means of controlling
risk-taking by firms that could potentially benefit from having access
to central bank lending on favorable terms.
Reputation Building
In our view, none of the above institutional mechanisms can
credibly commit a central bank to limit its lending or prevent increased
risk-taking induced by a central bank's inability to limit its
lending commitment. However, we believe that a central bank could
credibly commit to limit its lending by building a reputation for doing
so. Given the pressures that a central bank faces, there might seem to
be little hope that it could ever build a reputation for lending
restraint. It is difficult to imagine how a central bank would begin to
do so. Yet, we think that the experience by which central banks around
the world have built a reputation for maintaining low inflation provides
a road map for how they might credibly commit to limit lending.
Building A Reputation for Low inflation [18]
In the 1960s, the inflation that accompanied stimulative monetary
policy was tolerated as a necessary evil in the United States because it
seemed consistent with a stable Phillips curve tradeoff between
unemployment and inflation. In retrospect, however, we see that workers
and firms came to anticipate deliberately expansionary monetary policy.
Workers learned to take advantage of tight labor markets to make higher
wage demands, and firms took advantage of tight product markets to pass
along higher costs in higher prices. Increasingly aggressive wage and
price behavior tended to neutralize the favorable employment effects of
expansionary monetary policy, and the Federal Reserve became evermore expansionary in pursuit of low unemployment.
In the 1970s, disaffection with inflationary policy arose as the
Phillips curve correlation broke down and both inflation and
unemployment moved higher. In the late 1960s, the Fed began periodically
to try to brake the acceleration of inflation with tight monetary
policy, well aware that such policy actions caused unemployment to rise.
The resulting stop/go monetary policy characterized the period from the
mid-'60s until the early 1980s. Finally, the great disinflation introduced a period in which the Federal Reserve gradually acquired
credibility for low inflation.
Two developments paved the way for the great disinflation. First
was the progress that economists made in understanding the causes of
inflation. This professional understanding reinforced the Fed's
confidence that monetary policy could bring inflation down. Second, two
decades of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation--for example,
wage/price guidelines and controls, fiscal budget policy, and credit
controls--had been tried and had failed.
By the time Paul Volcker became Federal Reserve Chairman in 1979,
inflationary policy was widely recognized to have costs with no
offsetting benefits. Previous experience with stop/go policy made clear
that bringing inflation down would be costly too. Indeed, the inflation
was not broken until a sustained tightening of monetary policy that
began in 1981 created a serious recession that tested the Federal
Reserve's determination and the public's support. With
widespread public support, the Federal Reserve has maintained low
inflation for almost two decades. Macroeconomic performance has been
good compared to that of the inflationary period, and only one mild
recession has occurred thus far--in 1990 to 1991.
Building a Reputation for Limited Lending
The analogy to the historical reduction of inflation provides a
road map for a central bank that seeks to acquire a reputation for
lending restraint. We might imagine the following sequence of events.
Initially, the central bank and the public alike recognize only the
short-term benefits of central bank lending. Central banks are inclined
to extend emergency credit assistance to any institution whose possible
failure could present even the most remote risk of disruption to the
financial system. The liberal lending policy encourages potential
beneficiary firms to take on more risks. Greater risk-taking, in turn,
creates more frequent crises and causes the central bank to extend the
scope of its lending even further. Policymakers and the public see the
frequency and magnitude of financial crises grow even as the willingness
of the central bank to lend increases.
Gradually, under this scenario, an understanding might emerge among
policymakers and the public that excessively liberal central bank
lending is counterproductive. The view would be supported by
economists' improved understanding of the causes of increasing risk
in the financial system and its relation to excessive central bank
lending. As central bankers come to feel overextended, they might be
more inclined to incur the risk of short-run disruptions in financial
markets by disappointing expectations and by not lending as freely as
before. The central bank might backtrack on its initial attempts to
disappoint lending expectations. Eventually, the public might decide
that the increased financial crises were, in part, due to excessively
liberal central bank lending. The public would want the central bank to
become more restrictive, even at the cost of precipitating a financial
disruption by refusing to lend in a particular crisis. Ultimately, with
the public's support and a consistent willingness to risk the
consequences, a central bank would acquire a reputation for more limited
lending. Financial firms might then take on less risk, and financial
market crises might become less common.
One might wonder where we are in this process today. The parallel
with monetary policy is again instructive. During the 20 years of great
inflation there were four major episodes (1966, 1968, 1973-74, 1979-82)
in which the Federal Reserve tightened monetary policy to restrain
inflation with adverse consequences for employment. It was not until the
savings and loan crisis of the mid-1980s that the public became aware of
the greater risk-taking engendered by the government financial safety
net, e.g., deposit insurance and central bank lending. To date, there
are no instances in which a financial crisis has followed a refusal by
the Federal Reserve to extend emergency credit assistance. Granted,
provisions of the FDICIA of 1991 impose some constraints on Federal
Reserve lending to failing institutions: lending to undercapitalized
depository institutions is limited, except in circumstances involving
"systemic risk" (requiring high-level certification), and the
Fed is exposed to minor losses. These provisions, ho wever, hardly
constrain discount window lending; for example, it appears that Fed
lending to Continental Illinois in 1984 would have met the requirements
of the 1991 Act.
There is little evidence yet that the general public in the United
States favors a significantly more restrictive lending policy for the
central bank. One might regard the Bank of England's handling of
the Barings closure as an instance of a move toward a more restrictive
lending policy. But the parallel with monetary policy suggests that
episodes of increasing severity may be necessary before central banks
definitively alter course in the direction of lending restraint.
4. CONCLUSION
We have presented some guiding principles for central bank lending.
Central bank lending should be regarded as a line of credit, and should
be expected to exhibit the tensions inherent in private line-of-credit
products. The most serious problem is managerial moral hazard, the
borrower's incentive to take on more risk after arranging a credit
line. We discussed in some detail contractual provisions (loan
covenants, collateral, and monitoring) designed to control moral hazard.
The key point is that contractual provisions enable profit-maximizing
lenders to credibly commit to withdraw credit and induce the closure or
reorganization of a borrowing firm when appropriate.
The contractual mechanisms utilized by private line-of-credit
providers are less effective for a central bank whose primary
mission--to maintain financial system stability--can override its
obligation to protect public funds and undercut its ability to limit
lending. We considered in some detail five broad approaches to a central
bank's commitment problem: offering good offices only, intervening
early and taking collateral, adopting a strategy of constructive
ambiguity, extending supervisory and regulatory reach, and building a
reputation. Our analysis suggested that the first four institutional
approaches cannot be counted on to overcome the fundamental forces
causing a central bank to lend.
On the other hand, we believe that it should be possible for a
central bank to build a reputation for limiting its lending commitment,
just as central banks around the world acquired credibility for low
inflation. In fact, we view the forces operating on central bank lending
policy as analogous to those influencing the path of inflation. Liberal
lending policy initially raises expectations of lending. There is more
frequent lending, increased moral hazard, and greater financial
instability. Gradually, policymakers and the public become willing to
disappoint lending expectations. The economy then experiences a
temporary period of heightened financial instability associated with
increasingly restrictive lending, which is followed by less financial
instability and little central bank lending. It would appear that we are
still at the initial stages of what could be a lengthy process.
We are agnostic about whether central bank lending is beneficial.
We put off consideration of that difficult question until central bank
lending is more restrained, just as the debate on the desirability of
low or zero inflation in the steady state was deferred until inflation
was brought down sufficiently. Currently, the critical policy question
is how to reverse perceptions that central banks are increasingly
willing to lend, which increases risk-taking and the likelihood that
central banks will feel compelled to lend. Just as monetary policymakers
looked for opportunities to disinflate, we think that financial
economists and central bankers should look for opportunities to restrain
central bank lending.
This article was prepared for the Second Joint Central Bank
Research Conference on Risk Measurement and Systemic Risk at the Bank of
Japan, Tokyo, November 16-17, 1998. The authors are grateful for the
comments of Urs Birchler and Doug Diamond on an earlier draft and the
comments of Tom Humphrey, Bob Hetzel, John Walter, and John Weinberg on
this version. The article also benefitted from presentations at the
Konstanz Seminar on Monetary Theory and Policy, Konstanz, Germany; the
Center for Financial Studies Conference on Systemic Risk and Lender of
Last Resort Facilities, Frankfort, Germany; and the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland's Payments System Workshop. The authors' views do
not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1.) Because a central bank can create money, it has the option of
financing lending with an increase in the money supply. We would call
such lending a combination of monetary policy and credit policy. When we
speak of central bank lending in this article, however, we confine
ourselves to pure credit policy. Pure central bank credit policy
finances loans with proceeds from the sale of securities (Goodfriend and
King 1988).
(2.) See Humphrey and Keleher (1984).
(3.) Strictly speaking the International Monetary Fund is not a
central bank since it does not have the power to create money.
Nevertheless, it is financially a relatively independent governmental
organization, and it does make large loans on relatively short notice to
countries in financial distress (Masson and Mussa 1995).
(4.) Some dilution of long-term claimants is desirable, however, to
avoid socially inefficient liquidation (Diamond 1993).
(5.) See Harris and Raviv (1991, 1992) for surveys of the financial
contracting literature.
(6.) Not all control changes are instigated by lenders; they can
also take place at the initiative of the firm's governing board,
presumably representing the interests of shareholders.
(7.) The control rents enjoyed by the manager should, strictly
speaking, be counted as part of the total value of the firm as a going
concern, but since (by definition) these rents cannot be pledged to
outsiders, they are irrelevant to financing decisions.
(8.) Relationship lending can also arise outside of formal
line-of-credit lending.
(9.) See Goodhart (1988) and Schwartz (1992) for alternative views
on the desirability of central bank lending.
(10.) See Kwast and Passmore (1997) for evidence on the net subsidy
provided by the financial safety net in the United States.
(11.) In the United States, for example, all depository
institutions that are subject to reserve requirements are eligible to
borrow at the Federal Reserve's discount window. In addition,
Section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act allows the Board of Governors to
authorize the Reserve Banks "in unusual and exigent circumstances" to extend credit to any individual, partnership, or
corporation, provided the Reserve Bank obtains evidence that such entity
"is unable to secure adequate credit accommodations from other
banking institutions."
(12.) This presumes the current depositor preference regime. In the
absence of a depositor preference law, the short-term claimants would
have been junior to the FDIC's claim. See Birchler (forthcoming)
and Marino and Bennett (1999) for discussion of depositor preference
law. Marino and Bennett also discuss the role of Federal Reserve lending
in delaying closure of failed banks.
(13.) For an account of Federal Reserve lending to depository
institutions, see U. S. Congress (1991). See also Marino and Bennett
(1999).
(14.) For an account of Federal Reserve lending to nonbanks, see
Garcia (1990).
(15.) Some question the need for any discount window lending at
all. See Goodfriend and King (1988) and Schwartz (1992). Adherents of
this view can interpret our analysis as an exploration of the means by
which a central bank might limit its lending in practice.
(16.) The "prompt corrective action" provisions of the
FDICIA encourage early closure and help to restrict central bank lending
in this way.
(17.) Note that for the tax authority, the fraction of returns that
are audited is published and may have far more impact on perceived audit
probabilities than an individual audit. In contrast, because the
frequency of central bank lending is much lower, individual instances
may have a far greater effect on market expectations of future lending.
(18.) This account is drawn from Goodfriend (1997).
REFERENCES
Aghion, Philippe, and Patrick Bolton. "An Incomplete Contracts
Approach to Financial Contracting," Review of Economic Studies,
vol. 59 (1992), pp. 473-94.
Baird, Douglas G. The Elements of Bankruptcy. Westbury, N.Y: The
Foundation Press, 1993.
Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell. "Relationship Lending
and Lines of Credit in Small Business Finance," Journal of
Business, vol. 68 (July 1995), pp. 351-81.
Berlin, Mitchell, and Loretta Mester. "Debt Covenants and
Renegotiation," Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol. 2 (June
1992), pp. 95-133.
Birchler, Urs. "Bankruptcy Priority for Bank Deposits: a
Contract Theoretic Explanation," Review of Financial Studies
(forthcoming).
Calomiris, Charles W. "The IMF as Imprudent Lender of Last
Resort," Cato Journal, vol. 17 (Winter 1998), pp. 275-94.
Crane, Dwight B. Managing Credit Lines and Commitments. Chicago:
Trustees of the Banking Research Fund, Association of Reserve City
Bankers, 1973.
Diamond, Douglas W. "Seniority and Maturity of Debt
Contracts," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 33 (1993), pp.
341-68.
Garcia, G. "The Lender of Last Resort: Recent Development and
Nontraditional Examples." Manuscript. Washington: The Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs of the United States Senate,
December, 1990.
Goodfriend, Marvin, and Robert G. King. "Financial
Deregulation, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking," Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol. 74 (May/June 1988), pp.
3-22.
Goodfriend, Marvin. "Monetary Policy Comes of Age: A 20th
Century Odyssey," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly, vol. 83 (Winter 1997), pp. 1-22.
_____. "Why We Need an Accord for Federal Reserve Credit
Policy," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 26 (August
1994, Part 2), pp. 572-80.
_____. "Money, Credit, Banking and Payments System
Policy," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol. 77
(January/February 1991), pp. 7-23.
Goodhart, Charles. The Evolution of Central Banks. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1988.
Hackley, Howard H. Lending Functions of the Federal Reserve Banks:
A History. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
1973.
Harris, Milton, and Artur Raviv. "Financial contracting
theory," in Jean-Jacques Laffont, ed., Advances in Economic Theory,
Sixth World Congress, II. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1992.
_____, and _____. "The Theory of Capital Structure,"
Journal of Finance, vol. 46 (March 1991), pp. 297-355.
Huberman, Gur, and Charles Kahn. "Limited Contract Enforcement
and Strategic Negotiation," American Economic Review, vol. 78 (June
1988), pp. 471-84.
Humphrey, Thomas M., and Robert E. Keleher. "The Lender of
Last Resort: A Historical Perspective," The Cato Journal, vol. 4
(Spring/Summer 1984), pp. 275-318.
Kahn, Charles, and Gur Huberman. "Default, Foreclosure, and
Strategic Renegotiation," Law and Contemporary Problems, vol. 52
(Winter 1989), pp. 49-61.
Kwast, Myron L., and S. Wayne Passmore. "The Subsidy Provided
by the Federal Safety Net: Theory, Measurement and Containment,"
Working Paper 1997-58, Finance and Economics Discussion Series.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Divisions
of Research and Statistics and Monetary Affairs, December 1997.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. "Collateralized Debt as the Optimal
Contract," Working Paper 98-4. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
May 1998.
Marino, James A., and Rosalind L. Bennett. "The Consequences
of National Depositor Preference," FDIC Banking Review, vol. 12
(1999), pp. 19-37.
Masson, Paul R., and Michael Mussa. "The Role of the
IMF," Working Paper 50, Pamphlet Series. Washington, D.C.:
International Monetary Fund, 1995.
Nakamura, Leonard I. "Recent Research in Commercial Banking:
Information and Lending," Financial Markets, Institutions &
Instruments, vol. 2 (December 1993), PP. 73-88.
Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghurajan G. Rajan. "The Effect of
Credit Market Competition on Lending Relationships," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, vol. 110 (1995), pp. 407-43.
_____, and _____. "The Benefits of Firm-Creditor
Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data," Journal of
Finance, vol. 49 (March 1994), pp. 3-47.
Rajan, Raghurajan G., and Andrew Winton. "Covenants and
Collateral as Incentives to Monitor," Journal of Finance, vol. 50
(September 1995), pp. 1113-46.
Schockley, Richard L. "Bank Loan Commitments and Corporate
Leverage," Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol. 4 (July 1995),
pp. 272-301.
Schwartz, Anna J. "The Misuse of the Fed's Discount
Window," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 74
(September/October 1992), pp. 58-69.
Sharpe, Steven A. "Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending, and
Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of Customer Relationships,"
Journal of Finance, vol. 45 (September 1990), pp. 1069-85.
Stulz, Rene M., and Herb Johnson. "An Analysis of Secured
Debt," Journal of Finance, vol. 14 (1985), pp. 501-21.
U.S. Congress, House of Representatives, Committee on Banking,
Finance, and Urban Affairs. An Analysis of Federal Reserve Discount
Window Loans to Failed Institutions. 102 Cong. 2 Sess. Washington:
Government Printing Office, 1991.