Can the Fed be a payment system innovator?
Lacker, Jeffrey M. ; Weinberg, John A.
We live in a time of rapid technological change, in which the arrival
of new ways of conducting business has become a commonplace occurrence.
One segment of the economy where these changes are having a particularly
significant effect is the payment system, the web of banks and other
institutions through which payments for goods and services are cleared
and settled. New mechanisms such as smart cards and internet-based
electronic money have captured the imagination of many payment system
observers and participants. While earlier predictions of the death of
paper money have proven premature, the unprecedented pace of
technological advance in the last decade has given new hope to the
prophets of the electronic age.
The Federal Reserve (the Fed) plays a prominent role in the payment
system, both as a provider of payment services and as a regulator. The
public interest in an economically efficient payment system has been at
the core of Fed payment system policy since the Fed's founding in
1914. With new electronic payment mechanisms apparently within grasp,
there has been renewed attention to the role of the Fed in the
innovative process. A committee headed by Federal Reserve Board Vice
Chair Alice Rivlin recently completed a study of the Fed's role in
the payment system, which gave special attention to how active a role
the Fed should play in guiding payment system innovation.(1)
Within the Federal Reserve System, electronic check presentment (ECP)
is seen as a potentially promising step in the evolution toward
electronic payments. With ECP, consumers and businesses continue to make
payments with paper checks, but banks and clearinghouses that clear and
settle payments use electronic information "captured" from the
checks shortly after they are first deposited in the banking system.
(See Appendix.) While some ECP services are now available, many
important aspects of full-scale implementation are still under
discussion. The Fed's role in developing and promoting ECP is
clearly aimed at the public interest objective of enhancing payment
system efficiency. In what follows, we ask whether the Fed can be a
payment system innovator while remaining loyal to its fundamental public
interest objective. In particular, how can we ensure that the Fed's
payment system leadership contributes to economic efficiency?
Our approach to this policy question is founded on the notion that
the payment system is a communications industry. Such industries involve
substantial common costs - costs that cannot be uniquely attributed to
any one user. This cost characteristic has important implications for
industry behavior. The critical issue in such industries is how common
costs are allocated across users.
Markets for communication services (including payment services) tend
to be heavily regulated and, in some instances, served by
government-owned enterprises, such as the U.S. Postal Service. Concerns
about "universal access" often motivate government
intervention. Here, universal access is usually interpreted as a concern
about the cost of services to a particular class of users: residential
phone customers, rural postal patrons, or small and remote depository institutions. Access has been provided through price regulation, as in
telecommunications, and by direct government provision, as in the U.S.
Postal Service.
We show that government involvement in other communications
industries offers lessons for the role of the Federal Reserve in the
payment system. In both the telecommunications and postal services
industries, legal barriers to competition historically have helped
sustain the provision of universal access. Barriers to competition allow
the shifting of common costs to be pushed to the point where some users
are subsidized, in a sense that we will make precise later. Such
subsidization is inconsistent with economic efficiency, and would be
impossible without barriers to competition. We point out that the
Federal Reserve Banks still benefit from some barriers to competition -
privileged treatment under current check presentment regulations - that
would allow them to subsidize should they choose to do so. Federal
Reserve policy explicitly seeks to prevent subsidization, and there is
no direct evidence that the Fed currently subsidizes any segment of the
check collection market. At the same time, however, it is clear that
available analytical methods for determining the absence of subsidies
are imperfect.
Barriers to competition impede technological progress by distorting
adoption choices. The contrasting experiences of the telecommunications
and postal services industries illustrate this fundamental conflict. In
telecommunications, the removal of barriers and a retreat from access
have been accompanied by rapid technological innovation. The U.S. Postal
Service has retained barriers to competition and in the view of some
observers has been relatively slow to adopt innovations. Barriers
provide the opportunity for cross-subsidies that distort the innovative
process. Against this background, we argue that the Fed should act to
preclude subsidization by removing remaining barriers to competition. As
we emphasize, however, this step may require some retreat from the goal
of providing universal access.
1. THE PAYMENT SYSTEM AS A COMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY
In the U.S. economy, roughly 220 million market transactions are made
without cash daily, with a total dollar value of $1.6 trillion.(2) These
transactions all involve credit. The seller receives a financial
instrument representing a claim on either the buyer or a third party.
For example, a check is the liability of the check writer and his or her
bank. A credit card sale results in a claim - a "sales slip" -
that entitles the merchant to good funds. Similarly, a debit card transaction gives the merchant a claim to good funds.
The clearing and settling of credit instruments used as means of
payment intrinsically requires communication. A vast web of bookkeeping
systems records the assets and liabilities of various economic entities
- bank accounts, loan balances, investment funds, and the like. Noncash
payment instruments are fundamentally bookkeeping instructions to debit
an account of the buyer and credit an account of the seller. Those
instructions must be communicated to the relevant bookkeeping systems in
order to carry out the necessary accounting entries.
The payment system bundles together communication and financial
services. Arrangements governing the use of payment instruments specify
the allocation of risks associated with payment failures. For example,
the merchant accepting a check bears the risk that the check writer may
fail to cover it, but the merchant does not bear the risk of a
fraudulent credit card purchase. While these risk-sharing arrangements
are an important feature of the evolution of the payment system, they do
not make the fundamental function of payment arrangements inherently
different from other communication services.
Every new development in communication technology brings with it a
new possibility for sending payment instructions. Improvements in
freight transportation increase the speed and reliability with which
checks can be delivered to a buyer's bank. Improvements in computer
and telecommunications technologies facilitate the sending of payment
instructions in electronic form directly to and from banks. Optimism
about the transition to electronic payment instruments is based on the
assessment that the technologies underlying electronic communications
systems are improving rapidly, while physical transportation
technologies are improving only slowly at the present time.(3)
2. SOME NOTEWORTHY CHARACTERISTICS OF COMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRIES
Economists have long noted that communications industries share
certain distinct characteristics that have, in turn, heavily influenced
industry behavior. The most salient of these is the prevalence of common
costs. The allocation of these costs among diverse users is fundamental
to the operation of communications industries. Governments tend to
intervene in such industries to allocate these common costs in such a
way as to promote access.
In what follows we employ a few technical terms that are necessary
for a clear understanding of the economics of communications industries.
While these terms are defined as they are introduced, they also appear
in a glossary at the end of the article.
Common Costs
Every communication benefits two parties, the sender and the
receiver. How should the costs of a message (a phone call, a letter, an
e-mail) be divided between the two beneficiaries? The answer is not
entirely obvious. While providers of communication services often
collect fees from the sender, services are provided jointly to both
parties. The costs of providing these services cannot be uniquely
attributed to either of the beneficiaries. We call such costs common
costs. Common costs also extend beyond the level of the individual
message. A large part of the infrastructure costs of a communication
system, such as phone lines and information processing resources, are
common to all users of the system.
The significance of common costs distinguishes communications from
many other industries. For most other goods and services, a large part
of the costs of an individual's consumption can be uniquely
attributed to that individual. The time that a dentist, a barber, or a
mechanic spends serving a customer is a cost of serving that customer
exclusively. Costs that can be unambiguously associated with the
provision of goods or services to a particular individual are
attributable costs.
For some costs, specifying whether they are common or attributable is
not so simple. Costs that arise from a single message from a sender to a
receiver (a single phone call, for instance) are attributable to that
pair of users but are common between them. Similarly, the transportation
costs of a single shipment of mail between two points are attributable
to the group of people sending or receiving letters on that shipment but
are common among the members of that group. In communications
industries, there are very few costs that are attributable to individual
users, but there are many costs that are attributable to specific groups
of individuals. There are also substantial costs that are common to
entire communication systems.
Common costs are often fixed costs; they do not vary with the amount
of goods or services produced. An industry that has large fixed costs
and relatively small variable costs will exhibit economies of scale
(declining average costs) over some range of output levels. When there
are costs that are common to the production of multiple goods, then
production is said to exhibit economies of scope. Economies of scale and
scope are important characteristics of many communications markets
because many costs are common among all users of the network.
Another notable feature of communications markets is in the nature of
demand for such services. The economic value to an individual of having
access to a communication system depends on the individual's own
demands for connection to others and on the extent of the network of
individuals connected by the system. A consumer will be willing to pay
more for a communication service that allows communication with a larger
set of correspondents. This relationship between an individual's
valuation of a communication service and the extent of the network is
referred to by economists as a network effect. Note, however, that a
network effect is a consequence of both the interdependence of demand
for communication and the existence of common costs. The idea that an
individual "belongs to a network" is only meaningful if there
are common costs associated with linking people together.
The presence of common costs and network effects makes it difficult
to unambiguously specify the cost of serving a particular individual or
group. On the one hand, one can ask, "Given that services are
already being provided to others, what would it cost to extend service
to this particular group?" The answer to this question yields the
incremental cost of serving a group of users.(4) This definition
excludes costs that are common to the delivery of service to this group
and to others. On the other hand, one might ask, "What would it
cost to provide services to this group if no one else were being
served?" The answer to this question yields the group's
stand-alone cost, which includes all common costs. Clearly, when common
costs are substantial, incremental cost is much smaller than stand-alone
cost.
When there are no network effects, a group's incremental cost is
simply the attributable cost of extending service to that group. When
there are network effects, the addition of the new group also has the
effect of creating benefits for other users. These benefits work to
reduce the net cost of adding a new group of users. Hence, we need a
more general definition of incremental cost:
The incremental cost of extending service to a new group of users is
the cost of adding that group to the network, minus the benefits for
others created by that group's participation.
Some commentators have interpreted governmental concern for universal
access in communications industries as a necessary response to network
effects. Many believe reducing prices to some users may enhance
efficiency by compensating them for the network benefits they bring to
other participants. If the total benefits of an added participant, both
to himself and to others, however, are greater than the costs of adding
that participant, then a privately operated network will have an
incentive to compensate the added participant. This would be the case
even in the absence of government intervention. Network effects do not,
by themselves, induce market failures.(5)
Allocating Common Costs
In pricing a communication service, a provider must decide who should
bear the common costs. There are many possibilities. One could recover
all such costs from one small group of buyers, or try to spread the
burden evenly among all buyers. We can evaluate alternative cost
allocations according to two criteria. First, are they consistent with
efficient use of the service? Second, could they arise under competitive
market conditions?
While there are many dimensions to the efficiency of a communication
services market, one essential consideration is that the allocation of
costs must provide customers with the right incentives to participate in
the network. An individual's participation is economically
efficient if the resulting benefits exceed the additional costs
incurred. If the prospective customer is charged less than incremental
cost, his or her participation could be inefficient, creating benefits
smaller than the costs incurred. Hence, a minimal requirement for a cost
allocation to be consistent with efficient use of the service is that no
individual or group of users should pay less than its incremental cost.
Like prices that are too low, prices that are too high can also
interfere with efficient use of the service. In particular, suppose some
prices were greater than stand-alone cost. There might then be users
willing to pay this cost, but not willing to pay the higher cost imposed
by the seller's prices. Such users would be inefficiently excluded
by prices that exceed stand-alone cost. Efficiency also requires prices
below stand-alone costs.
There is a natural tendency for market forces to produce prices that
respect the bounds of incremental and stand-alone costs. If there are no
barriers to the entry of new competitors, then the threat of such entry
will serve to discipline the pricing and cost allocation practices of
incumbent suppliers. Suppose, for example, that a group of customers is
collectively paying more than its stand-alone costs. This market segment
would be particularly vulnerable to entry by an alternative provider.
The threat of such entry will limit the ability of the incumbent to
charge more than stand-alone cost.
The threat of competition, which prevents any individual or group
from bearing too large a share of common costs, also prevents anyone
from bearing too small a share. If a provider is to at least break even
on the sale of services and tries to charge some group less than their
full incremental cost, then the provider must recover from other users
all of the common costs plus the deficit created by undercharging the
favored group. Consequently, some set of buyers must pay more than their
stand-alone cost. With potential competition, however, this allocation
of costs is not sustainable. Potential competition therefore places both
an upper and a lower bound on how much a customer or group of customers
can bear. The lower bound is the incremental cost of serving those
users, while the upper bound is stand-alone cost or the incremental cost
of adding those users to a competing network. Note that these bounds are
the same as those that guard against inefficient use of a service. In
short, competitive pressures prevent inefficiency.
The evaluation of cost allocations on efficiency grounds is
complicated by the fact that incremental cost can be difficult to
measure. The categorization of costs as attributable and common is not
always straightforward. Even more difficult, however, is the
identification and measurement of the benefits that one
individual's or group's participation brings to others. On the
other hand, it is relatively easy to determine whether there are
significant barriers to competition. If one can guard against such
barriers, then market forces will tend to produce cost allocations that
respect the bounds of incremental and stand-alone cost.
Government Intervention
In the United States and other countries, communications industries
have typically been the object of substantial government intervention.
Government agencies or government-owned firms have typically provided
postal services and, in many countries, telecommunication services. In
other cases, such as telecommunications in the United States, provision
of services by private enterprises has been subject to substantial price
and product regulation.
The structural characteristics of communications industries drive
government intervention. There are, however, two distinct views about
how these characteristics motivate intervention. These industries are
conducive to relatively concentrated markets, which could give sellers
the ability to exercise monopoly (or near monopoly) power over prices.
One common view is that government intervention in communications
industries is motivated by a desire to limit anticompetitive behavior in
markets that have natural monopoly characteristics.
An alternative view states that government intervention is motivated
by a desire to place the cost allocation problem inherent in the pricing
of communication services under political control. In communications
industries, government intervention has tended to tilt the allocation of
common costs away from those buyers with high attributable costs. This
group of buyers often represents individuals in remote, rural locations.
For instance, postal rates are independent of the location to which mall
is sent, although delivery costs are clearly higher in rural areas.
Also, when there are scale economies associated with service to
individual buyers, the per-unit attributable costs of serving large
commercial and industrial users will be less than those of serving small
residential users.
When government intervenes to allocate service costs away from some
users and toward others, it might appear that the latter are subsidizing
the former. Intuitively, we might say that an individual buyer or a
market segment is subsidized if it is paying less than its share of
production costs. As emphasized earlier, however, common costs make it
difficult to unambiguously define the share of total costs borne by an
individual or group. Subsidization is less ambiguously defined with
reference to incremental costs. That is, an individual or group is
subsidized if it pays less than its incremental cost. If the provider
must cover all costs while subsidizing a set of buyers, payments
received from other buyers must be covering more than 100 percent of the
common costs. In this case (and only in this case) we say that some
buyers cross-subsidize others. As previously noted, competition or
potential competition will limit a seller's ability to engage in
pricing that results in such subsidies.
Government intervention that respects the bounds of incremental and
stand-alone costs can be consistent with the efficient provision of
services. The history of public sector intervention in communications
markets suggests that sometimes the beneficial treatment of groups has
gone further, resulting in prices that are below incremental cost.
First-class mail service to many hard-to-reach endpoints, for instance,
is widely believed to be subsidized. This sort of cross-subsidization,
however, is only possible if there are limits on competition. Prices in
a market segment in which the seller enjoys a legally protected monopoly
are not constrained to be below stand-alone cost. The seller might then
be able to raise enough revenues in the protected segment to cover any
losses incurred in selling to a subsidized segment.
When cost allocations are subject to political control, through
either the regulation of private providers or the public provision of
services, allocation choices are often justified in terms of access.
Governments have tended to view themselves as guarantors of widespread
access to communication systems. This interest in access has sometimes
been motivated by the view that the universality of a communication
network is an inherently worthy goal. In other instances, the motivation
arises from the concern for the consequences of market outcomes for
certain high-cost segments of users - rural postal customers, for
example. In either case, interest in access may result in cost
allocations in which some users subsidize others.
3. A LOOK AT OTHER COMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRIES
Communications industries, we have argued, are characterized by
common costs - costs that cannot be uniquely attributed to any
particular user or set of users. Government intervention in such
industries is often aimed at altering the allocation of common costs
across users. In the name of universal access, such intervention often
reduces the portion of common costs borne by some users. Legal barriers
to competition aid in cost shifting, but distort the decisions of
potential competitors.
The twentieth-century experience of two prominent communications
industries - telecommunications and postal services - offers valuable
insights. In both there are significant common costs and a tendency
toward few competitors. Both were subject to significant government
intervention that shifted the incidence of common costs and raised
barriers to competition, although in recent decades these barriers have
come under pressure. Public policy has responded very differently in
each industry with divergent results, particularly with regard to
technological innovation. The history of these two industries offers
revealing lessons for the Federal Reserve's role as a payment
system innovator.
Telecommunications
For many decades, the telecommunications industry. adhered to the
model of protected, regulated monopoly.(6) The prevailing industry
structure had its beginnings in the 1920s, when AT&T was allowed to
amass a virtual monopoly in phone services and operate free from the
threat of competition. In exchange, AT&T made large sunk investments
in infrastructure to extend the national network and subjected itself to
rate-of-return regulation that sought to keep charges to any buyers from
being "too high." This deal was supported by AT&T's
argument that telephone service was a natural monopoly and that it
(AT&T) could provide universal access at lower cost than could a
fragmented industry.
For basic local telephone services, buyer-specific fixed costs are
significant and variable costs are low. Hence, attributable costs per
call tend to fall with the number of calls over a wide range. Large
industrial and commercial users' average attributable costs are
likely to be lower than those for small business and residential users.
The public interest in widespread access has typically promoted price
structures that mute these cost differences by shifting common costs
away from small users and toward large business users. In addition, cost
allocations tended to favor local service at the expense of long
distance.
Through a series of moves by market participants and regulators, the
structure of the telecommunications industry has evolved from one of an
integrated, regulated monopolist to one of more open competition. The
Consent Decree of 1982, which settled a Justice Department antitrust
case against AT&T, brought competition to long distance markets,
while the regional Bell companies retained monopoly positions in local
telephony.
Regulated pricing of local service continued to attempt to shift
common costs away from high-cost residential and rural users in
particular. Such an allocation required higher recovery from large
commercial users and contributed to commercial customers' interest
in alternatives to the regional Bells' local service, particularly
with the proliferation of fax and data services. The longstanding status
of local service providers as protected, regulated monopolies was
increasingly unsustainable in the changing technological environment.
The 1996 Telecommunications Act opened all markets to competition, and
explicitly recognized that doing so would put pressure on the
industry's ability to provide inexpensive access to such high-cost
users as rural hospitals.
The dismantling of barriers to competition in telecommunications has
been accompanied by rapid adoption of new technologies. While the
by-pass services that hastened the arrival of competition were made
possible by technological progress, competition itself has accelerated
technological change by encouraging innovation. In the process, the
telecommunications industry and its regulators have retreated from the
goal of providing access through subsidized cost allocations.
Postal Services
The U.S. government has been involved in postal services since the
founding of the nation and has long made universal access the central
goal of federal postal policy. In the nineteenth century, the flow of
information arising from a universally accessible and affordable postal
service was seen as an important factor in the growth of a nation. The
U.S. Postal Service's legal monopoly status has been seen as
essential to the goal of universal access. With its protected position,
the Postal Service can deliver first-class mail to all locations in the
United States at a single price. Without this protection, competitors
would "skim the cream" by taking low-cost local business,
thereby raising the costs of serving the remaining markets. This view
suggests cross-subsidized pricing, since prices that are free of
subsidies would be immune to cream-skimming.
The Postal Service's legal monopoly on first-class mail appears
to have affected other markets in which the monopoly does not apply. In
parcel post and package delivery, for instance, private firms are
allowed to compete directly with the U.S. Postal Service, although they
are significantly constrained in their ability to do so.(7) Critics have
claimed that the Postal Service uses funds earned in the protected
first-class market to offer new services priced below incremental cost
in the more competitive package delivery business. A private,
profit-seeking provider might not have an incentive to engage in such
pricing of new products; unprofitable entry into a new market is not a
compelling goal by itself. As a public entity, however, the Postal
Service's motivations are less well defined. While a public entity
is charged with serving the public interest and may generally seek to do
so, it is hard to prevent at least some decisions from being motivated
by other goals. Entry into a new market, for instance, may enhance the
overall size and influence of the organization.
Without the discipline of potential competition, the U.S. Postal
Service's incentives to maintain and enhance the cost efficiency of
its operations are muted. Some observers have noted the difficulties the
Postal Service has experienced in the automation of mail processing.(8)
At the same time, potential competitors incentives to develop innovative
products and processes may well be blunted by the Postal Service's
ability to subsidize its prices in competitive market segments.
In short, the postal services and telecommunications industries in
the United States have followed divergent paths. While the
telecommunications industry has placed increasing reliance on markets to
provide pricing discipline and incentives to innovate, the U.S. Postal
Service has retained a protected monopoly structure that may distort
competition and can stifle technological progress. And while in
telecommunications the pace of technological innovation has been quite
brisk, with the U.S. Postal Service the pace has been relatively slow.
4. FEDERAL RESERVE CHECK CLEARING
Check collection and other payment services share many features with
network communications industries like telecommunications and postal
services. From the earliest years Reserve Banks have enjoyed legal
privileges that have aided the Fed's entry into check collection
and have made the shifting of common costs in the pursuit of universal
access at least possible. Some competitive advantages remain today, most
notably the "six-hour monopoly," which we discuss below. These
privileges make it theoretically possible for the Fed to subsidize some
check-clearing services, in the specific sense that term was defined
above. If the Fed were engaged in subsidization, by our definition, the
Fed's presence could detract from economic efficiency. Moreover, as
demonstrated by the contrasting cases of telecommunications and postal
services, the capacity to subsidize would not bode well for the
Fed's ability to innovate in the public interest. The critical
question regarding Fed participation in check collection, then, is
whether under barriers to competition some check collection services are
in fact subsidized. If so, then the Fed's participation would not
only detract from economic efficiency but could also distort the
innovative process.
The Six-Hour Monopoly
The Federal Reserve Banks enjoy certain legal privileges in the check
collection business. The most important is the Reserve Banks' right
to present checks to a paying bank until 2:00 p.m. and receive payment
the same day; private-sector banks must present by 8:00 a.m. in order to
insist on same-day funds. In practice, private-sector banks can and
often do present after 8:00 a.m., but only after negotiating a voluntary
agreement with the paying bank, presumably offering the paying bank
compensation in the form of reciprocity or presentment fees. The Reserve
Banks need not obtain prior permission. Thus, the Reserve Banks enjoy a
six-hour monopoly on free par presentment for same-day funds. Other
advantages also exist but they appear to be of minor significance.(9)
The six-hour monopoly originated shortly after the founding of the
Federal Reserve System. The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 authorized the
Reserve Banks to offer check collection services to their member banks.
An amendment enacted on June 21, 1917, extended this authorization to
allow the Reserve Banks to clear checks for all banks. The amendment
also prohibited charging presentment fees against Reserve Banks, but
this provision only applied to banks that voluntarily joined the
Fed's collection system.(10) The prohibition codified and expanded
a stipulation the Federal Reserve Board had imposed earlier by
regulatory fiat on member banks.(11) Banks retained the right to charge
presentment fees to any other banks presenting by mail, however. Only
the Reserve Banks could mail checks to participating banks and demand
immediate par settlement.
The Fed's par presentment privilege was by all accounts
essential in the subsequent growth of the Reserve Bank check collection
system. The ability to present at par to member banks gave the Reserve
Banks a cost advantage over competitors. This advantage gave nonmember
banks an incentive to join the Fed's collection system to obtain
access to low-cost presentment at member banks. The Reserve Banks
required that banks joining the system also agree to accept presentment
at par. The upshot was that the more banks that joined the Fed
collection system, the greater the value of joining.(12)
From its founding in 1913, the Federal Reserve was eager to increase
participation in the Reserve Banks' check collection system. For
members of the Federal Reserve System, access to the system was a
benefit that offset, in part, the cost of stricter Fed reserve
requirements, while nonmembers gained the ability to present to
participating banks at par. Despite these benefits, the Fed never
completely monopolized interbank check collection. For some nonmember
banks the income from presentment fees was apparently worth more than
the net value of lower-cost clearing services available from the Reserve
Banks, so these "nonpar banks" continued to charge presentment
fees, a practice that persisted for decades.(13)
The Monetary Control Act (MCA) of 1980 dramatically changed the
nature of the Fed's check collection service. The MCA required
Reserve Banks to charge fees for their payment services which must, over
the long run, cover the direct and indirect costs of providing the
services, including imputed costs that would be incurred if the services
were provided by a private firm.(14) The MCA also imposed uniform
reserve requirements on all depository institutions and granted
nonmembers access to Reserve Bank payment services. Prior to the MCA,
free check clearing was one of the benefits of membership. Access to Fed
services was now divorced from membership and was explicitly priced.
By forcing the Reserve Banks to charge prices that cover actual and
imputed costs, the MCA went a long way toward leveling the competitive
playing field. The Fed retained presentment privileges nonetheless.
Private collecting banks had no practical means of obtaining same-day
funds.(15) In response to public concerns about the remaining asymmetry,
the Board sought public comment in 1988 on a proposal to extend Reserve
Bank presentment rights to private-sector banks, allowing them to
present until 2:00 p.m. for settlement the same day. Corporations
objected to the proposal, however, because it would hamper their ability
to manage their accounts within the day.(16) The compromise that was
finally adopted, effective January 1994, established the current regime
in which all banks have the right to same-day settlement for checks
presented by 8:00 a.m. The Reserve Banks retained the privilege of
presenting until 2:00 p.m. for same-day funds.(17)
The six-hour monopoly could give the Reserve Banks an advantage over
competitors in some market segments. It means that the Reserve Banks can
collect a given set of checks on better terms than a private provider:
for example, by offering a later deposit deadline or better availability
(less check float). A private-sector competitor would have to incur
additional costs to clear the same checks with the same availability. In
some markets, particularly for small and remote depository institutions
where transportation time can be significant, this advantage has given
the Reserve Banks a dominant market share. Indeed, in some locations
only the Fed presents checks. In more geographically concentrated
markets - large cities, for example - the six-hour monopoly provides
little or no competitive advantage and the market share of the Reserve
Banks is correspondingly low.
The Allocation of Common Costs
How do the Fed's check collection activities affect the
allocation of the common costs? Since implementation of the MCA in the
early 1980s, the Reserve Banks price structure has determined the
allocation of common costs. Early on, Reserve Bank pricing under the MCA
was relatively uniform, although prices varied according to the
destination of the check. At first, prices at various Fed offices
depended only on whether the item was bound for a city or a remote
location. More recently, the price structure has become increasingly
complex with finer geographical differentiation.
The increasing complexity of the Reserve Banks' pricing has been
a response to competitive pressures. Initially, alternatives to Fed
check clearing were not well established. As private-sector clearing has
grown over time, increased price differentiation has lowered margins in
market segments in which alternative providers can compete effectively
with the Fed. Maintaining full cost recovery then requires higher
margins in market segments where customers have relatively few viable
alternatives. Such markets are generally those in which the Fed's
six-hour monopoly supports a dominant market share - presentment to
remote banks. Accordingly, common costs have shifted away from market
segments in which the six-hour monopoly yields no significant
competitive advantage for the Fed - presentment to city endpoints.
The six-hour monopoly could allow the Fed to set prices below
incremental costs so that subsidization results. We previously noted
that in industries which have substantial common costs (like
communications), competitive pressures constrain the way those costs can
be allocated across market segments; market discipline generally
prevents subsidization. Governmental barriers to competition can loosen
the constraints of competitive pressure, however, because they allow
over-recovery of costs in protected market segments in order to fund
prices below incremental costs in other market segments. The six-hour
monopoly is exactly this type of barrier to competition. By raising the
costs of competitors, this advantage could allow the Reserve Banks to
charge more than stand-alone cost in the protected market segment
(checks drawn on remote banks) in order to price below incremental cost
in contested market segments (checks drawn on city banks). While these
prices could further the goal of universal access, they would be
detrimental to economic efficiency, since some users would face prices
below incremental social cost.
Reserve Bank price setting is constrained by a specific methodology
designed to prevent cross-subsidies. Per-item fees must be above
"floor cost," which is defined essentially as average
(attributable) variable cost. The individual check is not the only
relevant increment, however. There are often significant costs that are
attributable to a group of checks but not specifically attributable to
individual checks. For example, local transportation costs are
attributable to the collection of checks drawn on a particular group of
banks, though not to an individual customer or item. The total floor
cost for a group of checks is an underestimate of incremental cost if it
excludes costs that are attributable to that group of checks but not to
any individual item.(18) It is also possible that floor costs overstate
incremental costs, since network effects, if they exist, reduce the true
incremental cost of serving a market segment.
We need to entertain two alternative hypotheses, therefore, about the
Fed's allocation of common costs. One hypothesis is that the
Reserve Banks generally do not set fees below incremental costs or above
the stand-alone costs. The other is that in some market segments the
Reserve Banks set some fees below incremental costs and thus set fees
above stand-alone costs elsewhere.(19) These two hypotheses have
different implications, as we will see, for how we approach questions
about the Fed's role in payment system innovation.
Access
As noted earlier, the Federal Reserve lists payment system
accessibility as an important policy goal.(20) The usual articulation of
this goal speaks of the Fed providing payment services to all depository
institutions, particularly "smaller institutions in remote
locations that other providers might choose not to serve."(21)
Since there is undoubtedly some price at which alternative providers
would choose to serve a given location, access to the payment system
must be interpreted in terms of the cost of payment system services to
small and remote banks. Enhancing access to the payment system must mean
lowering the cost to small and remote banks.
Does the Fed lower the costs of check clearing for small and remote
banks? We have argued that the Fed's presence tends to shift common
costs toward checks drawn on remote banks. Hence, cost allocation among
banks is determined by whether checks drawn on remote banks make up a
smaller portion of the checks collected by remote banks than they do of
checks collected by city banks. If so, the Fed's presence tends to
favor small and remote banks. Although to our knowledge no formal data
is available, anecdotal evidence suggests that the difference, if there
is one, is not large. The shift of common costs toward checks drawn on
remote banks does not appear to alter appreciably the relative burden
imposed on small and remote banks. There are, however, other dimensions of pricing along which the Federal Reserve may still be able to pursue a
goal of moderating costs for small and remote banks, although direct
quantitative evidence is unavailable.(22)
While we lack direct evidence on the extent to which the Fed shifts
common costs away from small and remote banks, some indirect evidence is
available. Last year Federal Reserve Board Vice Chair Alice Rivlin
headed a committee that examined the role of the Federal Reserve in the
payment system.(23) As part of its work, the committee held a series of
public forums. Many participants at these forums expressed the widely
shared belief that the Fed's exit from check clearing would raise
the cost of check collection to small and remote banks. Thus according
to many people intimately involved in the check collection industry, the
Fed's cost allocation does have the effect of enhancing universal
access. A reasonable working hypothesis is that the Fed's presence
does shift at least some common costs away from small and remote
banks.(24)
5. THE FED AS A PAYMENT SYSTEM INNOVATOR: ELECTRONIC CHECK
PRESENTMENT
We have argued that the Federal Reserve's involvement in the
check collection industry closely parallels government involvement in
the telecommunications and postal services industries. Under this view,
the Fed promotes universal access by shifting common costs in the
presence of legal barriers to competition. Rapid technological change is
currently creating new opportunities for innovation in payment services.
As a major provider of payment services, the Federal Reserve must
determine its appropriate role in pursuing and promoting innovations.
Our reading of the history of communications industries strongly
suggests that barriers to competition are fundamentally incompatible
with the efficient adoption of new technologies. Barriers weaken the
effectiveness of an organization's innovative efforts, and they
create opportunities for subsidies that can distort the choices users
make with respect to new technologies. For both reasons, truly good
innovations may fail to reach the market, while unworthy ones may
actually take hold. Without barriers to competition, cross-subsidization
would not be sustainable, and so we can have confidence that the
innovative process is genuinely beneficial.
How does one resolve the conflict between cross-subsidization and
innovation? One approach is to measure incremental costs rigorously in
order to prevent subsidization. This approach, in essence, is the
Federal Reserve's current practice. Earlier, however, we pointed
out that the need to gauge incremental costs and network effects across
a wide assortment of user subgroups is likely to make comprehensive
measures of incremental costs difficult to obtain. Accounting data alone
are not likely to convince a skeptic of the absence of cross-subsidies.
An alternative approach to the conflict between cross-subsidization
and innovation as it pertains to Reserve Banks is to remove the
conditions that might lead to cross-subsidization. In the absence of
special legal privileges, competitive pressures will preclude
cross-subsidization, as we defined it earlier. Removing the remaining
barriers to competition would clearly demonstrate the Fed's
commitment to efficient innovation.
These principles apply to the Fed's current efforts to implement
ECP. As with any innovation, the near-term prospects of ECP are
uncertain. A recent study by Joanna Stavins (1997), an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, attempts to quantify the overall costs
and benefits to society of a transition to ECP. One advantage would come
from replacing the resource cost of transporting and processing paper
checks with the lower cost of sending electronic messages. On the other
hand, some people prefer to get their checks back. Further, under a
variety of state laws, certain check writers are either entitled or
required to receive their canceled checks. While the estimates reported
by Stavins favor ECP, the results are sensitive to reasonable
alternative assumptions, particularly with regard to the intrinsic value of canceled checks to consumers. As with other recently proposed payment
innovations, such as stored-value ("smart") cards, it is
probably too early to tell whether ECP will make society better off or
not.
Ideally, innovations would succeed in the marketplace if and only if
they were truly beneficial to society. Accordingly, the Fed should
introduce ECP in such a way that we can be assured it will succeed if
and only if it improves payment system efficiency. In the absence of
impediments to competition, a new product or service generally will be
profitable if its value to customers, as measured by willingness to pay,
exceeds the cost at which providers are willing to supply it.(25) The
usual presumption is that innovation in competitive settings yields
outcomes that are beneficial to society as a whole. A necessary
condition is that prices are not inefficient, that is, they do not
embody cross-subsidies. Barriers to competition allow inefficient
pricing. One way to ensure that the Fed's implementation of payment
system innovations contributes to payment system efficiency, therefore,
is to remove artificial barriers to competition like the six-hour
monopoly.
Removing barriers to competition would help avoid some of the
potential pitfalls that face a public entity participating in a
commercial enterprise. The Reserve Banks' special legal status as
public institutions, as opposed to private, profit-seeking businesses,
could inhibit their pursuit of improvements in products and processes.
The structure of Federal Reserve decisionmaking could result in
unnecessarily high costs of research and development. It is often
difficult for large organizations, particularly public institutions, to
respond nimbly to new technological opportunities. The difficulties
experienced by the U.S. Postal Service in implementing automation
illustrate the challenge of innovating at large, public-sector
institutions.
An even more worrisome possibility is that an organization that is
not fully subject to market discipline could make wasteful investments
designed to hold on to market share. Many observers expect electronic
payment instruments, such as debit cards, credit cards, or smart cards,
increasingly to displace checks. In this context, ECP could be viewed as
an attempt to stem the expected decline in check use. By reducing the
cost of paper checks, ECP could slow the transition to fully electronic
payment instruments that are even more beneficial. As long as barriers
shield the Fed from competitive pressures, there is the potential for
the Fed's pursuit of payment system innovations to conflict with
payment system efficiency.
Yet there are good reasons for the Fed to pursue ECP research and
development. The Fed, the largest processor of paper checks in the
economy, maintains a substantial capital stock dedicated to that
activity. The Fed would need to integrate ECP investments into its
current check collection infrastructure. As a result, the Fed is likely
to have a comparative advantage in evaluating the technical
characteristics of ECP investments. In addition, the Reserve Banks have
strong incentives to pursue innovations that, if successful, would
enhance the value of their existing check infrastructure. To the extent
that the Fed's decisionmaking mimics that of a private business,
the interdependence of paper and electronic check collection gives the
Fed appropriate incentives regarding ECP research and development.
Implementing ECP
What does all this mean for the implementation of ECP? Because it is
uncertain whether ECP will actually contribute to economic efficiency,
the Fed should do everything possible to ensure that ECP flourishes only
if genuinely warranted. If ECP truly is to enhance economic efficiency,
it ought to be possible to offer it in a competitive market at prices
that cover costs and attract users voluntarily. Any implicit
cross-subsidy could distort outcomes by driving some prices below costs,
so that users find ECP attractive even if social costs exceeded
benefits. Similarly, a legal privilege that dampens competitive
pressures could artificially tilt users through nonprice incentives
toward an ECP service offered by the Fed.
Because the paying bank has the right to insist on presentment of the
paper check, a key issue for ECP is inducing the paying bank to accept
electronic presentment. Stavins' (1997) estimates indicate that
while paying banks realize significant cost savings from ECP, check
writers incur increased costs and lose the benefits of receiving
canceled checks. Although her estimates suggest a small net gain to
paying banks and their customers, there will undoubtedly be some
instances in which ECP would raise the net cost to paying banks and
their customers. If the total benefits of ECP exceed the total cost for
payors and payees combined, then it ought to be possible for paying
banks and their customers to be compensated by other participants. Such
compensation could take the form of fees for checks presented
electronically, or alternatively, charges to paying banks that wish to
receive paper checks.
Net revenues from ECP services should cover the full incremental cost
of ECP if it is to be implemented without subsidization. In the absence
of barriers to competition, the Fed could not systematically violate
this bound. Theoretically, the six-hour monopoly gives the Fed the
capability to subsidize ECP; paying banks could be induced to adopt ECP
before it is efficient to do so. Eliminating barriers to competition
like the six-hour monopoly would help ensure that ECP will succeed if
and only if it is truly beneficial to society.
One frequent suggestion by ECP advocates is that the Federal Reserve
alter its check presentment regulations so that paying banks are
required to accept presentment in electronic form as well as paper.
Paying banks could no longer insist on presentment of the paper check.
This change is consistent with a competitive market approach as long as
paying banks who prefer to receive paper presentment are able to
compensate collecting banks. If the paying bank's willingness to
pay to receive paper exceeds the cost to collecting banks of presenting
paper, then the paying bank ought to be able to stay with paper.
Otherwise, the paying bank will receive presentment electronically.(26)
Simply mandating participation by paying banks would short-circuit
the competitive discipline imposed by the need to enlist voluntary
cooperation. Then an ECP plan that marginally lowers the costs of
collecting banks as a whole might succeed, even though it imposes
greater additional costs on paying banks and their customers. Such a
scheme would not be in society's interests, and yet it might be
adopted if acceptance by paying banks of electronic presentment were
mandated with no opt-out provision.
What about Access?
We have interpreted access in terms of the costs of check collection
to small and remote banks. Fed participation in the check collection
system is intended, in part, to make the cost to these banks lower than
it otherwise would be. This interpretation is consistent with two
alternative hypotheses. First, the Fed's priced services could be
free of cross-subsidies, and therefore efficient, even though its
allocation of common costs might favor small and remote banks. Second,
the Fed's pricing could involve cross-subsidies. In order to
maintain prices below incremental costs, the Fed would need to rely on
market privileges such as the six-hour monopoly.
If the six-hour monopoly is essential to achieving the Fed's
access goals, then its continued presence could distort the
implementation of ECP or other innovations in check clearing. If current
pricing involves cross-subsidies, then the revenue from customers paying
more than their stand-alone costs could be used to push ECP prices below
incremental cost. If the Fed's current pricing does not involve
cross-subsidization, then the six-hour monopoly is not essential to the
status quo price structure. In this last case it should be possible for
the Fed to implement ECP efficiently without sacrificing universal
access.
Which of these two hypotheses is correct? As we noted above,
available data cannot discriminate between the two, and the Fed's
floor-cost methodology may not guarantee the absence of subsidies.
Moreover, it will always be difficult to objectively verify the absence
of cross-subsidies. As long as cross-subsidies are possible, there will
be those who question the Fed's actions, particularly with regard
to new product offerings. How can the public be confident that the
Fed's innovative efforts in the payment system enhance efficiency?
The simplest and most transparent measure would be to eliminate
artificial barriers to competition like the six-hour monopoly.
6. CONCLUSION
We have drawn lessons for Federal Reserve payment system policy from
the history of other communications industries. Government intervention
in these industries has been driven largely by the desire to allocate
common costs in order to enhance access for some users. We have argued
that Federal Reserve Banks' provision of check collection services
fits the same pattern.
Providing access conflicts with technological progress when access is
supported by subsidized prices and barriers to competition. In the
telecommunications industry rapid innovation was stimulated by
deregulation that required a retreat from universal access. The U.S.
Postal Service provides a contrasting example in which protected markets
were maintained but at an apparent cost in foregone efficiency-enhancing
innovation. The lesson for the Federal Reserve seems clear: a pursuit of
access that makes use of cross-subsidization interferes with the
efficient implementation of payment system innovations. Subsidies erode market discipline and distort choices among competing technologies.
Let us emphasize that it is not at all clear that the Fed currently
subsidizes any segment of the check collection market. Federal Reserve
policy explicitly seeks to prevent subsidization and promote payment
system efficiency. With its efforts to promote ECP, the Fed seeks to
establish itself as a leader in payment system innovation. The Fed is
well suited to understand, evaluate, and help implement new technologies
in this area. For the Fed to be an effective leader, however, the public
must be confident that its choices are in the public interest.
Eliminating any remaining competitive advantages would deny the Fed the
capacity to subsidize and thus would enhance the credibility of the
Federal Reserve's commitment to payment system efficiency.
GLOSSARY OF COST-RELATED TERMS
Common costs: Costs that cannot be attributed to a particular
individual or group. Note that there can be costs that are attributable
to a group but common among the members of the group.
Attributable costs: Costs that arise directly from the provision of
services to a particular individual, group, or market segment.
Fixed costs: Costs that do not vary with the quantity of a service
produced. Fixed costs can be common among all users or attributable to a
subset of users.
Network effects: The benefits that one group's participation
creates for other users of a communication service.
Incremental costs: The additional cost of extending a given amount of
a service to a particular individual, group, or market segment, given
that others are already being served. Incremental costs are attributable
costs (fixed and variable) less any network benefits created for others
by extending service to the particular individual or group.
Stand-alone costs: The cost of providing a free-standing service to
an individual or group, in isolation from other users. Stand-alone costs
include the value of the network benefits that the group loses by not
sharing joint services with other users.
Subsidization: When the payments received from a group are less than
the incremental cost of providing service to that group.
Cross-subsidization: When the deficit created by subsidizing one
group is made up for by charging another group more than its stand-alone
cost.
APPENDIX
Electronic Check Presentment
While many payment system innovations take the form of new payment
instruments, electronic check presentment (ECP) is simply a means of
bringing modern information technology to bear on the clearing and
settlement of a very old payment instrument. The standard method of
clearing and settlement begins when the person or firm receiving a check
deposits the check in his or her bank. If the check is drawn on a
different account at the same bank, the check stays there and is paid
with a bookkeeping transfer. Otherwise, the check is physically
transported to the bank on which it is drawn (the paying bank). After
physical presentment of the check takes place, funds are sent from the
paying bank to the collecting bank. Often this process is intermediated
by other banks (correspondents), Federal Reserve Banks, or by private
contractors (courier services, for example). A check that is not honored
for some reason - because of insufficient funds in the check
writers' account, for example - is returned to the bank at which it
was initially deposited.
With electronic check presentment, consumers and businesses still
conduct transactions using paper checks. At some point in the process of
clearing the check, the relevant payment information is transferred into
electronic form and then sent on to the paying bank. The check itself
may or may not continue on its path to the paying bank. If the check is
not sent to the paying bank, it is called check truncation. Although
truncation is not a necessary part of ECP, many proponents believe that
ECP can make its greatest contribution to payment system efficiency in
combination with truncation. Indeed, to the extent that there are
savings associated with substituting the flow of electronic information
for a paper flow, it would seem to make sense to have paper items
truncated as early as possible in the clearing process. On the other
hand, the occasional need to inspect the physical check suggests that it
might be economical for truncation to occur at a more central point in
the process in order to concentrate the storage of paper items.
All Reserve Bank offices currently offer paying banks the option of
receiving electronic check presentment. Slightly less than 14 percent of
the checks processed by the Fed in 1997 were presented electronically.
For about another 9 percent, information was sent electronically to the
paying bank, although actual presentment was made with paper checks.
Reserve Bank representatives are actively involved in several
collaborative efforts with industry representatives aimed at finding
ways of increasing the use of ECP.
1 Federal Reserve System (1998).
2 Bank for International Settlements (1996).
3 federal Reserve System (1998).
4 It is important to distinguish between incremental and marginal
costs. Marginal cost is the added cost of the last unit of a good
produced. Incremental cost is all of the additional costs that arise
from extending a particular set of services to a particular set of
users. This may include costs that are fixed with regard to the quantity
of services provided, such as the costs of connecting a group of users
to an existing network.
5 For alternative discussions of network effects as a source of
market failure, see Economides (1996) and Weinberg (1997).
6 For further resources on the history of the U.S. telecommunications
industry, see Brock (1986) or Bornholz and Evans (1983).
7 Sidak and Spulber (1996) give a detailed account on the
restrictions facing private carriers.
8 Sidak and Spulber (1996).
9 The Reserve Banks voluntarily refrain from presenting between noon
and 2:00 p.m. in most markets. The six-hour monopoly is not the only
legal presentment privilege enjoyed by the Reserve Banks. For example,
private-sector banks do not have as much flexibility as Reserve Banks in
choosing where to present checks to paying banks. In addition, the
paying bank controls the intraday timing of payment to a private-sector
presenting bank, while the Reserve Banks have the right to debit the
paying bank's account within a specified time period. Because the
other legal privileges appear to be of minor significance relative to
the six-hour presentment monopoly, we will focus on the latter, although
what we have to say will apply equally well to these other privileges.
See Board of Governors (1998) and General Accounting Office (1989) for
more details.
10 The amendment provided that any bank could make "reasonable
charges, to be determined by the Federal Reserve Board, but in no case
to exceed 10 cents per $100," but that "no such charges shall
be made against the Federal Reserve Banks." An opinion of the U.S.
Attorney General established that this latter provision applied only to
banks that voluntarily joined the Fed's clearing system. Note that
a state-chartered bank did not have to become a member of the Federal
Reserve System in order to participate in the Fed's check
collection plan.
11 The first Reserve Bank check-clearing arrangement, the so-called
"voluntary plan" adopted in 1915, required that member banks
joining the plan accept checks at par from the Reserve Banks. The
"compulsory plan" adopted in May 1916 also included the same
requirement but had the Reserve Banks covering the expense of shipping
notes or lawful money from the bank to the Reserve Bank in payment. Such
expenses were obviously not the only paying bank costs attributable to
check collection. Note that because nonmembers had to agree voluntarily
to join the Fed clearing plan, the amendment gave the Reserve Banks no
real advantage over private banks, since both needed to offer
inducements to obtain par presentment rights. The amendment's
effect was to codify the Reserve Bank's right to present to member
banks at par, by mail, without prior permission. For discussions of the
Fed's entry into check clearing see the classic account of Warren
Spahr (1926), or more recently, Ed Stevens (1996, 1998) and Alton
Gilbert (1998).
12 Note that the effect of the size of the Fed check collection
system on the value of joining did not necessarily reflect a network
effect. Federal Reserve policy deliberately tied the service of
collecting a bank's outgoing checks to that bank's willingness
to pay par on its incoming checks. There was no technological link
between the number of banks sending checks to the Fed and the number of
banks to which the Fed could send checks.
13 See Jessup (1967) and Stevens (1998).
14 The Federal Reserve's cost recovery requirement includes a
"private sector adjustment factor" that consists of the taxes,
fees, and return on capital applicable to a comparable private-sector
provider.
15 The rights of private collecting banks were governed by provisions
of the Uniform Commercial Code. For a description, see General
Accounting Office (1989), p. 28.
16 In arrangements called "controlled disbursements," banks
notify their corporate customers early in the day of the value of the
corporation's checks presented that day, allowing the customers to
fund their accounts by selling money market securities. Later
presentment makes such arrangements more difficult because money markets
become progressively less liquid in the afternoon. These costly efforts
effectively skirt the prohibition on interest on corporate demand
deposits and are wasteful from society's point of view. Note that
corporate objections to extending private presentment time to 2:00 p.m.
are not directly relevant to the question of whether private and Reserve
Bank presentment times should be equalized; presumably they would also
object if asked whether the Reserve Banks should be able to present at
2:00 p.m. The objections might suggest that, without interest on
corporate checking accounts, equalization should take place at a time
earlier in the day rather than later. See Board of Governors (1991), p.
4747, for discussion of public comments on the 1988 proposal.
17 The Board of Governors has recently requested public comment on
the effect of the January 1994 same-day settlement role. In addition,
the Board is considering reducing or eliminating legal disparities
between Reserve Banks and private-sector collecting banks in the check
collection process, including the six-hour monopoly (Board of Governors
1998).
18 Critics who have charged the Fed with unfairly subsidizing check
collection have focused on whether the Fed's cost accounting
methodology understates the overall cost of Fed check collection. This
question is separate from the question we discuss: cross-subsidization
within Fed check processing. The Board of Governors requires that the
Reserve Banks annually recover the full cost of check collection
services from check collection fees.
19 Our reasonable hypothesis is that the Reserve Banks recover the
full costs of check collection in the aggregate.
20 The Monetary Control Act states that prices for Federal Reserve
services "shall give due regard to competitive factors and the
provision of an adequate level of such services nationwide."
21 Board of Governors (1990), p. 295.
22 For instance, Reserve Banks' prices depend on the amount of
sorting done by depositing banks prior to depositing checks with the
Fed. Small, remote banks are more likely to make unsorted deposits than
are large, city banks. The Fed could pursue its interest in access by
setting lower price-cost margins for unsorted than for sorted deposits,
thereby lowering the cost of check collection for small, remote banks.
23 Federal Reserve System (1998).
24 The shift of common costs away from small and remote banks might
be independent of the six-hour monopoly. Some participants in the Rivlin
Committee Forums believe that the Federal Reserve accepts a lower rate
of return than would be required by commercial providers or that the Fed
does not account for the full costs of providing service.
25 We mean profitability in the sense that the expected present
discounted value of net cash flows from the introduction of an
innovation are positive. The Board of Governors imposes a tighter
constraint on Reserve Banks; net cash flows must be positive each year
in each priced service line (check collection, automated clearing house,
and so on).
26 ECP was implemented quite rapidly in Switzerland under just such a
scheme. Paying banks must pay a substantially higher fee to receive
paper checks.
REFERENCES
Bank for International Settlements. Statistics on Payment Systems in
the Group of Ten Countries. Basle, Switzerland: Bank for International
Settlements, 1996.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Collection of
Checks and Other Items by Federal Reserve Banks and Availability of
Funds and Collection of Checks" (Docket No. R-1009), Federal
Register, vol. 63 (March 16, 1998), pp. 12700-06.
-----. "Proposed Rule" (Docket No. R-0723), Federal
Register, vol. 56 (February 6, 1991), pp. 4743-57.
-----. "The Federal Reserve in the Payments System,"
Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 76 (May 1990), pp. 293-98.
Bornholz, Robert, and David S. Evans. "The Early History of
Competition in the Telephone Industry," in David S. Evans, ed.,
Breaking Up Bell. New York: North-Holland, 1983.
Brock, Gerald W. "The Regulatory Change in Telecommunications:
The Dissolution of AT&T," in Leonard W. Weiss and Michael W.
Klass, eds., Regulatory Reform: What Actually Happened. Boston: Little,
Brown and Company, 1986.
Committee on the Federal Reserve in the Payments Mechanism. The
Federal Reserve in the Payments Mechanism. Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, January 1998.
Economides, Nicholas. "The Economics of Networks,"
International Journal of Industrial Organization, vol. 14 (October
1996), pp. 673-99.
Gilbert, R. Alton. "Did the Fed's Founding Improve the
Efficiency of the United States Payments System?" Manuscript.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, January 1998.
Jessup, Paul F. The Theory and Practice of Nonpar Banking. Evanston,
Ill.: Northwestern University Press, 1967.
Sidak, Gregory J., and Daniel F. Spulber. Protecting Competition from
the Postal Monopoly. Washington: AEI Press, 1996.
Spahr, Walter Earl. The Clearing and Collection of Checks. New York:
Bankers Publishing Company, 1926.
Stavins, Joanna. "A Comparison of Social Costs and Benefits of
Paper Check Presentment and ECP with Truncation," Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston New England Economic Review (July/August 1997), pp.
27-44.
Stevens, Ed. "Non Par Banking: Competition and Monopoly in
Markets for Payments Services." Manuscript. Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Financial Services Research Group, January 14, 1998.
-----. "The Founders' Intentions: Sources of the Payments
Services Franchise of the Federal Reserve Banks," Working Paper No.
0396. Cleveland: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Financial Services
Research Group, December 1996.
U.S. General Accounting Office. Check Collection: Competitive
Fairness is an Elusive Goal. Washington: U.S. General Accounting Office,
1989.
Weinberg, John A. "The Organization of Private Payment
Networks," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
vol. 83 (Spring 1997), pp. 25-43.
Jeffrey M. Lacker is a vice president and economist in the Research
Department. John A. Weinberg is a research officer and economist in the
Research Department. This article originally appeared in this
Bank's 1997 Annual Report. The authors wish to thank Ed Green, Tom
Humphrey, Ned Prescott, Marsha Shuler, John Walter, Marvin Goodfriend,
Walter Varvel, and A1 Broaddus for helpful comments and discussions. The
views expressed do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve
System. The authors remain solely responsible for the contents of this
article.