Monetary policy comes of age: a 20th century odyssey.
Goodfriend, Marvin
In the early 1960s the Federal Reserve (Fed) was little known
outside of the financial services industry and university economics
departments. Twenty years later Fed Chairman Paul Volcker was one of the
most recognized names in American public life. Now hardly a week goes by
when the Fed is not featured prominently in the business news. The Fed
was thrust into the limelight in the intervening years when the public
came to associate it with inflation-fighting policy actions that raised
interest rates and weakened economic activity. Even though inflation has
been held in check since the mid-1980s, the public remains acutely aware
of Fed policy today.
Monetary economists and central bankers alike now understand that
effective in monetary policy must be built on a consistent commitment to
low inflation. That is why in recent years the Fed has made low
inflation a particularly high priority. The large fraction of the public
having first-hand experience with high inflation naturally supports the
view that inflation must be contained. As the collective memory of
inflation fades, however, public support for low inflation will become
increasingly difficult to sustain. A permanent national commitment to
price stability requires that citizens personally unfamiliar with the
trauma of high inflation understand the rationale for price stability
and the tactical policy actions needed to maintain it.
This article reviews the history of U.S. monetary policy in the
20th century with the aim of providing that understanding. It identifies
mistakes that led to high and volatile inflation, lessons learned from
the experience, and principles applied in the pursuit of low inflation
today. U.S. monetary policy came of age in the 20th century in the sense
that the country left the strict rules of the gold standard for the
freedom of an inconvertible paper standard, which the Fed only slowly
and painfully learned to manage. What follows is the story of that 20th
century odyssey.
Section 1 discusses monetary policy under the gold standard and
the circumstances that led to the founding of the Fed. Section 2
outlines the main conceptual obstacles that had to be overcome in order
to manage monetary policy under a paper standard. The causes and
disruptive consequences of inflationary policy at mid-century are
discussed in Section 3.
Certain key theoretical and practical developments paved the way
for the Fed to take responsibility for controlling inflation in the
early 1980s. Section 4 covers these developments. Progress in the theory
of the demand for and the supply of money as well as empirical evidence
supporting the theory played key roles here. The failure of nonmonetary
approaches to controlling inflation was also important. The recognition
that a credible Fed commitment to price stability could minimize the
unemployment cost of achieving low inflation also played a role.
Section 5 recommends that the Fed be given a legislative mandate
for low inflation. The case is based on lessons learned in the
inflationary 1960s, `70s, and early `80s, and on the principles that
have been applied successfully to maintain low inflation since then. The
closing section summarizes the monetary policy lessons learned on the
20th century odyssey.
1. MONETARY POLICY UNDER THE GOLD STANDARD
When the Federal Reserve was established in 1913, inflation was not
the problem it was to become in the latter part of the century. The
nation was on a gold standard and the purchasing power of money in 1913
was about what it had been 30 years before, or for that matter, 100
years before. The gold standard sharply restricted inflation by
requiring that money created by the U.S. Treasury be backed by gold.(1)
The classical gold standard yielded price stability only to the
extent that the Treasury's stock of monetary gold happened to
expand at a rate sufficient to satisfy the economy's demand for
money at stable prices. For instance, slow growth in the gold supply
caused the price level to decline at over 1 percent per year from 1879
to 1897, and gold discoveries and new mining techniques caused inflation
to average over 2 percent per year between 1897 and 1914. Nevertheless,
by the standard of what was to come, the variation of inflation was very
small.
Although the economy grew rapidly throughout the gold standard
years, the period was marked by a number of recessions associated with
temporary deflations and substantial interest rate movements. Sudden
sustained short-term interest rate spikes of over 10 percentage points
occurred on eight occasions between the Civil War and the founding of
the Federal Reserve. Five of these spikes were associated with bank runs
characterized by a demand to convert bank deposits into currency that
could not be satisfied by the fractional cash reserves held by banks.(2)
Finally, in response to the banking panic of 1907 and the ensuing
recession, the nation was no longer willing to run monetary policy
entirely according to the classical gold standard rules. The Federal
Reserve was established in the United States with the power to create
currency and bank reserves at least somewhat independently of the
nation's monetary gold. The Fed was given authority to create
currency and reserves by making loans to banks through its discount
window or by acquiring securities in the money market. The Fed's
mission was to provide an elastic supply of money to smooth short-term
interest rates against liquidity disturbances, while preserving the link
between money and gold in the long run in order to restrain
inflation.(3)
Through its dominant presence in the market for currency and bank
reserves, the Fed easily gained control of short-term interest rates and
eliminated the kind of interest rate spikes seen earlier.(4) By
smoothing short-term interest rates, however, the Fed was obliged to
substitute its discretionary management of short rates for the
impersonal market forces that had determined rates previously. The Bank
of England had successfully managed short rates for (5) decades in the
context of the classical gold standard. And the Fed could have followed
similar gold standard operating procedures. However, the classical gold
standard collapsed with World War I, and the nation was never willing to
support Fed procedures geared to defending the gold standard. The Fed
was left without clear operational procedures for positioning short-term
interest rates to stabilize economic activity around full employment
with stable prices.
2. THE OBSTACLES TO UNDERSTANDING MONETARY POLICY
Improvements in monetary policy that seemed within reach after the
founding of the Fed proved elusive. The 1930s saw the sharpest
deflation, the worst banking crisis, and the longest and deepest
economic depression in American history.(6) Then, beginning in the
mid-1960s there were two decades of unprecedented peacetime inflation
that tripled the general price level by the early 1980s.(7)
Why has it taken so long for the Fed to give price stability pride
of place?(8) Initially, there was a tendency to underestimate the
disruptive potential of inflation and a willingness to be tolerant of
each new burst of inflation in the hope that it would soon die down.
Such hope seemed reasonable since protracted peacetime inflation had
never before been a problem in the United States. Another difficulty was
that it took some time for economists to develop a framework capable of
understanding monetary policy in the absence of a link to gold. Prior to
the 20th century the world had little practical experience with monetary
regimes in which money was unbacked by a commodity such as gold or
silver. With some exceptions, mainly during wartime, there was little
empirical evidence on such regimes and little interest in analyzing
them.
The main problem was confusion within the economics profession
about the determination of the general price level and the control of
inflation in a regime of inconvertible paper money.(9) There was also
little understanding of the role played by inflation expectations in the
wage- and price-setting process and in the determination of interest
rates. Finally, the relationship between unemployment and inflation was
seriously misunderstood. The resolution of these disputes provided the
foundation for today's monetary policy success.
3. INFLATIONARY MONETARY POLICY AT MID-CENTURY
Largely as a result of the nation's unfortunate experience with
inflation in the period from the mid-1960s through the early 1980s,
monetary economists and central bankers now understand that the costs of
inflationary monetary policy are significant and varied. First are the
costs that even a steady, perfectly anticipated inflation imposes on
society. Then there are the disruptive and destabilizing costs of
unstable inflation, more difficult to quantify but substantial
nonetheless. These latter costs stemmed from alternating expansionary and contractionary policy actions. Specifically, there was a
tendency-known as go-stop monetary policy--for the Fed to exacerbate the
cyclical volatility of inflation and unemployment. And there was a
related tendency to produce rising inflation and increasingly volatile
inflation expectations over time. The forces giving rise to these
tendencies are identified and described below together with their
disruptive consequences.
The Cost of Steady Inflation
The cost of steady inflation begins with the fact that a steadily
falling purchasing power of money causes people to hold less cash than
they would if prices were stable. Attempts to economize on money
holdings manifest themselves in several ways. Banks invest in teller
machines, people visit banks or teller machines more frequently,
businesses devote more time and effort to managing their cash balances,
etc.(10) Even more important, individuals and firms take steps to
protect the value of their savings and investments against loss due to
inflation. The effort and resources devoted to dealing with inflation
are wasted from society's point of view in the sense that they
could be better employed in producing goods and services.
Another major cost of steady inflation stems from the incomplete
indexation of the tax system. The biggest problem in this regard results
because taxes are assessed on nominal interest earnings and nominal
capital gains, that is, on investment returns in dollars. Inflation
causes nominal returns to rise because investors demand compensation for
the declining purchasing power of money. For instance, long-term bond
rates contain a premium for expected inflation over the life of the
bond. Since nominal returns are taxed as income, however, inflation
reduces the after-tax return to saving and investment and thereby tends
to inhibit capital accumulation and economic growth.(11)
Go-Stop Monetary Policy(12)
A central bank such as the Fed that is charged with conducting
monetary policy on a discretionary basis is naturally inclined to give
considerable weight to the public's mood. Go-stop monetary policy
was, in good part, a consequence of the Fed's inclination to be
responsive to the shifting balance of public concerns between inflation
and unemployment. Of course, difficulties in judging the strength of the
economy and in gauging inflationary pressures compounded the problem, as
did ignorance of the lags in the effect of policy.
For the most part the public tolerated inflation as long as it was
low, steady, and predictable. When labor markets were slack, the public
was even willing to risk higher inflation in order to stimulate
additional economic activity. Only when economic activity was strong and
inflation moved well above the prevailing trend did inflation top the
list of public concerns.
It is easy to understand why inflation need not greatly concern
the public when it is steady and predictable. Individuals and firms are
inconvenienced only slightly by steady inflation. As long as wages,
prices, and asset values move up in tandem, there are no big financial
consequences, especially when inflation is low. Likewise, a temporary
and modest increase of inflation around a low, well-established trend
need not immediately arouse concerns.
However, a persistent departure of inflation above trend causes
anxieties because people wonder where a new trend might be established.
Investors worry about how much of an inflation premium to demand in
interest rates; businesses worry about how aggressively to price in
order to cover rising costs; and workers worry about maintaining the
purchasing power of their wages.
In marked contrast to inflation, which affects all, unemployment
actually affects relatively few at a given time. The unemployment rate
in recent decades has risen at most to only about 10 percent of the
labor force. The public is concerned about unemployment not so much
because of those who are currently unemployed but because people are
afraid of becoming unemployed. It follows that the public is generally
more concerned about unemployment when the unemployment rate is rising,
even if it is still low, than when it is falling, even if it is already
high.
The above-mentioned reasoning helps explain why the Fed produced
go-stop monetary policy in the 1960s and `70s. In retrospect, one
observes the following pattern of events.
First, because inflation became a major concern only after it
clearly moved above its previous trend, the Fed did not tighten policy
early enough to preempt inflationary outbursts before they became a
problem.
Second, by the time the public became sufficiently concerned about
inflation for the Fed to act, pricing decisions had already begun to
embody higher inflation expectations. Thus delayed, a given degree of
restraint on inflation required a more aggressive increase in short-term
interest rates with greater risk of recession.
Third, in any cyclical episode there was a relatively narrow
window of broad public support for the Fed to tighten monetary policy.
The window opened after inflation was widely recognized as the major
concern and closed when tighter monetary policy caused the unemployment
rate to begin to rise. Often the Fed did not take full advantage of a
window of opportunity to raise short rates, because it wanted more
confirmation that higher short-term rates were required.
Fourth, it was probably easier for the Fed to maintain public
support for fighting inflation with prolonged rather than preemptive tightening. A more gradual lowering of interest rates in the later stage
of a recession was a less visible means of fighting inflation than
raising rates more sharply earlier. Once unemployment peaked and began
to fall, the public's anxiety about it diminished. Prolonged
tightening was attractive as an inflation-fighting measure in spite of
the fact that it probably lengthened the "stop" phase of the
policy cycle.
Rising Inflation and Unstable Inflation Expectations
Over time, deliberately expansionary monetary policy in the
"go" phase of the policy cycle came to be anticipated by
workers and firms. Workers learned to take advantage of tight labor
markets to make higher wage demands, and firms took advantage of tight
product markets to pass along higher costs in higher prices.
Increasingly aggressive wage- and price-setting behavior tended to
neutralize the favorable employment effects of expansionary policy. And
the Fed became evermore expansionary on average in its pursuit of low
unemployment, causing correspondingly higher inflation and inflation
expectations. Lenders demanded unprecedented inflation premia in
long-term bond rates. And the absence of a long-run anchor for inflation
caused inflation expectations and long bond rates to fluctuate
widely.(13)
The breakdown of mutual understanding between the markets and the
Fed greatly inhibited the conduct of monetary policy. The Fed continued
to manage closely short-term nominal interest rates.(14) But the result
of an interest rate policy action is largely determined by its effect on
the real interest rate, which is the nominal rate minus the
public's expected rate of inflation. And the Fed found it
increasingly difficult to estimate the public's inflation
expectations and to predict how its policy actions might influence those
expectations. Compounding the problem, enormous increases in short-term
interest rates were required by the early 1980s to stabilize the
economy. Stabilization policy became more difficult because the public
could not predict what a given policy action implied for the future, and
consequently, the Fed could not predict how the economy would respond to
its policy actions.
4. THE CONTROL OF INFLATION: DISINFLATION IN THE 1980s
By the late 1970s, policymakers and monetary economists had come to
understand the costly and disruptive features of inflation discussed
above. With considerable public support, the Fed under the leadership of
Chairman Paul Volcker initiated the great disinflation in October 1979,
marking the beginning of the period in which the Fed would make lowering
inflation a priority. What followed was a tightening of monetary policy
that succeeded in bringing the inflation rate down permanently for the
first time in the post-Korean War period, first from over 10 percent to
around 4 percent by 1983, and then to around 3 percent by the mid-1990s.
This section reviews three developments that paved the way for the
Fed to take responsibility for price stability. Most important was the
progress that economists made in understanding money demand and supply.
Next was the failure of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation.
Finally, and to a lesser extent, was the idea advanced by monetary
economists that the unemployment cost of disinflation might be minimized
if the disinflation were credible.
The Central Bank's Responsibility for Inflation
The consensus among monetary economists that central banks are
responsible for inflation is built on both theory and evidence. Above
all, there is the substantial body of evidence from the inflationary
experiences of a great many nations, including the widespread inflation
in the industrialized world during the 1960s and '70s, showing that
sustained inflation is always associated with excessive money growth.
The evidence also clearly indicates that inflation is stopped by slowing
the growth of the money supply.(15)
The theory of money demand and supply supports the cross-country
evidence by illuminating the mechanics of the link between monetary
policy and inflation. The theory of money demand implies that control of
the money supply is necessary and sufficient to control the trend rate
of inflation. And the theory of money supply implies that a central bank
can control the trend rate of money growth. As will become clear below,
money demand may be thought of as the fulcrum by which a central bank
controls inflation, and the money supply may be thought of as the lever
by which it does so.
Money Demand
The theory of money demand asserts that individuals and businesses
choose to hold a target stock of money that is proportional to their
expenditures, a target that balances the convenience of holding money
against the foregone interest earnings.(16) The key implication of money
demand theory for monetary policy is that there is a reasonably stable
long-run relationship between a nation's demand for money and its
production and exchange of goods and services.
It follows that sustained inflation results when the growth of the
nation's money stock exceeds the rate of growth of the
nation's physical product.(17) Prices must rise in this case
because otherwise individuals and firms would spend their growing excess
money balances. Since one person's expenditure is another
person's receipts, the spending would put upward pressure on prices
until the inflation rate matched the rate of money growth in excess of
the growth of output. Only then would the ongoing increase in the stock
of money be willingly absorbed by the public.
The theory of money demand also implies that the overall price
level cannot move very much over the long run if the stock of money
grows in tandem with the growth of output.(18) If an inflation were to
start, it would reduce the purchasing power of a given nominal stock of
money and cause individuals and businesses to cut their spending in an
effort to maintain their inventory of monetary purchasing power. With no
additional money balances forthcoming in the aggregate, the downward
pressure on spending would stop the inflation.
Money Supply
The nation's basic money supply consists of currency and
checkable deposits held by households and businesses. A central bank can
control the former because it has a monopoly on the creation of
currency.(19) Checkable deposits are created by banks. A central bank
also has the power to control checkable deposits because banks must hold
reserves to service their deposits, and a central bank controls the
aggregate stock of bank reserves.(20)
The financial services industry has long been creating new
instruments in which the public can hold liquid balances, e.g.,
certificates of deposit and money market mutual funds. New financial
instruments usually do not add to the basic money supply since they are
only imperfect substitutes for currency or checkable deposits.(21)
Nevertheless, the introduction of money substitutes has adversely
affected the predictability of money demand in the short run. In
practice, however, money demand is sufficiently stable and money supply
sufficiently controllable over time, so that financial innovations do
not fundamentally alter a central bank's power over inflation.(22)
Failed Approaches to Controlling Inflation
A variety of nonmonetary approaches to controlling inflation were
tried in the 1960s and '70s. In the United States, for example, the
federal government published voluntary wage-price guidelines at various
times to persuade firms and workers to forego price and wage increases
deemed excessive.(23) Actual controls were imposed for a few years in
the early '70s but for the most part they were lifted by the
mid-'70s.(24) By the end of the period, both controls and
guidelines came to be regarded as arbitrary, unfair, and ineffective.
Moreover, where they were effective they often created allocative
disruptions, e.g., price controls in the energy sector created shortages
and long lines at gas stations.
In the early 1960s economists believed that budget policy might
play a key role in fighting inflation. In the United States, however, it
quickly became clear in the Vietnam War period that political concerns
would immobilize fiscal policy as a practical economic policy tool.
Moreover, it later became clear that the inflation of the 1970s was not
closely related to the government's fiscal situation.(25)
Even after the Fed under Chairman Volcker had begun its momentous
disinflation, the Carter administration imposed credit controls in early
1980 in an effort to foster the process. The credit control program
caused a sharp recession with little impact on inflation and was phased
out at midyear.(26)
Thus did policymakers learn the hard way that policies for
stopping inflation other than monetary control didn't work. As much
as anything else, the failure of nonmonetary approaches to disinflation
set the stage for the Fed to take responsibility for bringing inflation
down.
Credibility for Low Inflation and the Unemployment Cost of
Disinflation
In the early 1960s policymakers were inclined to accept the
inflationary consequences of policy actions taken to stimulate aggregate
demand and employment. That inclination was based to a great extent on
evidence of a century-long negative Phillips curve correlation between
unemployment and (wage) inflation in the United Kingdom that appeared to
offer a trade-off ia which the benefits of lower inflation would have to
be balanced against the costs of higher unemployment.(27)
When stimulative policy succeeded in driving down the unemployment
rate in the '60s, the resulting increase in inflation at first
seemed, consistent with a stable Phillips curve trade-off; and the
rising inflation was tolerated as a necessary evil.(28) In the 1970s,
however, the Phillips curve correlation broke down as inflation and
unemployment both moved higher, and it became clear that high inflation
could not buy permanently low unemployment.(29)
Even though protracted inflation was widely understood by the late
1970s to have costs with no offsetting benefits, it was recognized that
bringing inflation down would be costly too. Previous experience with
go-stop policy made it clear that there was a short-run trade-off
between unemployment and inflation.(30) Policymakers expected the
temporary unemployment cost of a large permanent disinflation to exceed
the costs of earlier disinflations that the Fed had produced in the
"stop" phase of its policy cycles.
To some degree a view then emerging in the academic community
might have encouraged the Fed to pursue the disinflation. The view holds
that the unemployment cost of disinflation can be minimized if a
disinflation policy is credible. The idea that credibility would govern
the costliness of disinflation has since become widely accepted in
theory.(31) The acquisition and maintenance of credibility for low
inflation have become major practical concerns of Fed policymakers and
central bankers around the world.
The idea underlying the role of credibility is that wage- and
price-setting behavior is geared to expectations of money growth. The
Fed supports the ongoing inflation as long as money grows in excess of
output. If the Fed's disinflation is credible, the Fed slows money
growth and wage and price inflation come down, too, with little effect
on employment. On the other hand, if the disinflation is not credible,
then wage and price inflation continues as before. If the Fed persists
in slowing money growth anyway, a deficiency of aggregate demand causes
unemployment as households and businesses cut spending in an attempt to
maintain their targeted monetary purchasing power.(32)
In practice, however, disinflation is nearly always costly because
credibility for low inflation is hard to acquire after it has been
compromised. Moreover, a central bank's commitment to low inflation
is only as credible as the public's support for it. The Fed
probably embarked on the disinflation in 1979, in part, because the
public finally seemed ready to accept it.
Although its discount rate changes often made the headlines prior
to 1979, the Fed rarely sought publicity for its monetary policy
actions. Chairman Volcker broke sharply with tradition by initiating the
period of disinflationary policy with a high-profile announcement
signaling that the Fed would take responsibility for inflation and bring
it down.(33) In so doing, Chairman Volcker built credibility by staking
his own reputation and the Fed's on achieving the low inflation
objective. The unprecedented increases in short-term interest rates that
followed further demonstrated the Fed's commitment to reducing
inflation.(34)
Nevertheless after two decades of rising inflation, a widespread
skepticism worked against Fed credibility.(35) Wage and price setters
doubted that there would-be sufficiently widespread public support for
the Fed's disinflation. Indeed, the inflation was not broken until
a sustained slowing of money growth beginning in 1981 created a serious
recession that tested the Fed's determination and the public's
support.(36) Although the recession was the worst since the 1930s, it
was less severe than might have been expected considering the size of
the accompanying disinflation. Most remarkable is that the roughly 6
percentage point disinflation occurred in just two years: 1981 and 1982.
The size and speed of the disinflation suggests that the acquisition of
credibility played a key role in making it happen.
5. MONETARY POLICY AT THE CLOSE OF THE CENTURY: MAINTAINING LOW
INFLATION
The Fed has succeeded in maintaining low inflation for almost 15
years now. With luck the United States should enter the 21st century
with inflation near what it was under the gold standard at the opening
of the 20th century. Macroeconomic performance during the low inflation
period has been good, especially when compared to the inflationary
period preceding it. The only recession during the period, in 1990-91,
was mild by recent standards. Over the period as a whole, employment
growth has been strong and productivity growth may have picked up
somewhat. Moreover, both short- and long-term interest rates are around
one-third of what they averaged in the early 1980s and are much less
volatile too.
The promise of low inflation is being fulfilled. The challenge
today is for the Fed to understand the secret of its success. In that
regard the low inflation period has as much to teach as the traumatic
period that preceded it. In reviewing below the lessons learned and
principles applied, we shall see that the best way of assuring our
continued monetary policy success would be for Congress to give the Fed
a legislative mandate for low inflation.
Lessons Learned and Principles Applied
One of the most important lessons learned from the last four decades
is that credibility for low inflation is the foundation of effective
monetary policy. The Fed has acquired credibility since the early 1980s
by consistently taking policy actions to hold inflation in check. In
effect, the Fed has reestablished a mutual understanding between itself
and the markets. From this perspective, wage and price setters keep
their part of an implicit bargain by not inflating as long as the Fed
demonstrates its commitment to low inflation. Ironically, the Fed has
learned from nearly a century of experience to pursue rule-like behavior
in order to fully achieve the gains from moving away from the gold
standard.
Experience shows that the guiding principle for monetary policy is
to preempt rising inflation. The go-stop policy experience teaches that
waiting until the public acknowledges rising inflation to be a problem
is to wait too long. At that point, the higher inflation becomes
entrenched and must be counteracted by corrective policy actions more
likely to depress economic activity.
The main tactical problem for the Fed is to decide when preemptive
policy actions are necessary and how aggressive they should be. In this
regard, the Fed must be careful to consider any adverse effect that a
poorly timed policy tightening could have on employment and output. For
that matter, the Fed must be prepared to ease monetary policy when a
weakening economy calls for it. The central bank's credibility
depends not only on its inflation-fighting credentials but also on its
perceived competence.
A natural starting point to balance these concerns is to use a
policy rule-of-thumb based on historical data to benchmark Fed policy.
The stance and direction of monetary policy can then be chosen in light
of historical experience conditioned on any special current
circumstances. The most relevant historical experience is, of course,
the relatively brief low inflation period since the mid-1980s. As the
Fed extends low inflation over time, the nation will build up a richer
relevant history against which to benchmark policy.(37)
However, even our brief experience with low inflation contains
useful insights such as this. In some years, such as 1994, inflationary
pressures might be judged to call for a particularly aggressive
preemptive tightening. At other times, such as in 1996, there might be
some concern about the potential for rising inflation but enough doubt
to adopt a wait-and-see attitude. The Fed's success in 1994 and
1996 suggests that the key to effective management of short-term
interest rates over the business cycle is to move rates up decisively
and preemptively when warranted in order to build credibility for low
inflation. With credibility "in the bank," so to speak, the
Fed can hold rates steady or move them down out of concern for
unemployment at other times.(38) The lesson is that credibility enhances
flexibility.
A Legislative Mandate for Price Stability
Largely as a result of the common understanding of the theory and
history of monetary policy reviewed above, there is today a consensus
among monetary economists and central bankers that maintaining low
inflation is the foundation of effective monetary policy. Moreover,
there is an emerging consensus that a central bank's commitment to
price stability should be strengthened by legislation making low
inflation the primary goal of monetary policy.(39)
The recommended priority for price stability derives not from any
belief in its intrinsic value relative to other goals such as full
employment and economic growth. Price stability should take priority for
two reasons: first, the Fed actually has the power to guarantee it over
the long run, and second, monetary policy encourages employment and
economic growth in the long run mostly by controlling inflation.(40)
Also, and this is very important, a mandate for price stability would
not prevent the Fed from taking the kinds of policy actions it takes
today to stabilize employment and output in the short run. What it would
do is discipline the Fed to justify these actions against a commitment
to protect the purchasing power of money.
Two often-repeated objections to a mandate for low inflation
deserve mention here. One is the notion that low inflation targeting is
largely irrelevant because two enormous oil price increases in the
1970s--in 1973/74 and 1979/80--were responsible for the worst inflation
of that period.(41) The claim continues that our success in controlling
inflation will be determined by whether we have large oil price shocks
in the future or not. Clearly, oil price increases create a problem for
the economy: the higher price of oil diverts expenditure to oil products
and raises real costs throughout the economy, with adverse consequences
for demand and employment in non-oil sectors.
The economy must adjust to the higher real cost of oil in any
case. The problem for a central bank is to make sure that the adjustment
problem is not compounded with monetary instability. A central bank with
a mandate for low inflation is more likely to resist excessive monetary
accommodation than one with a weaker commitment to price stability. This
is because an oil price shock will be less likely to set in motion wage
and price increases that the central bank will be inclined to
accommodate. The Fed was in just this predicament when the 1970s oil
price shocks hit, since rising inflation trends were already well
established before each oil shock. The destabilizing effects on
inflation, inflation expectations, and employment and output would
almost surely have been less troublesome in a climate of stable
inflation.
A second objection to a mandate for low inflation is that it would
hold back economic growth. In fact, the opposite is more nearly true. In
terms of the earlier discussion of money demand and supply, trend growth
of national output continually raises the demand for money, and the Fed
accommodates the growing demand for money at stable prices.
Would monetary policy prevent the economy from growing faster if
labor productivity unexpectedly surged? Not for long, because
unemployment would begin to rise as businesses found that they could
meet demand with less labor input. And the Fed would resist rising
unemployment by easing monetary policy to encourage faster growth in
aggregate demand. In short, the Fed's policy procedures do not
"target growth." A mandate for price stability would allow the
Fed to naturally and automatically accommodate an increase in
productivity growth over time.
Ultimately the Fed can only secure full credibility for low
inflation with the backing of the public. The public's
misunderstanding of the tactics of monetary policy is particularly
troublesome. For instance, accusations that the Fed was "busting
ghosts" when it ran short-term interest rates up in 1994 threatened
to undermine support for policy actions that, were clearly called
for.(42) Preemptive policy actions in 1994 laid the foundation for
continued economic expansion. The task ahead must be to broaden and
deepen the public's understanding and support for the strategy and
tactics of monetary policy and to lock in credibility for low inflation
with a legislative mandate.
6. CONCLUSION
American monetary policy has come full circle in the 20th century.
Early in the century the nation overcame a long-standing distrust of
government intervention in the monetary system to establish a central
bank. The Federal Reserve embodied the idea that discretionary monetary
policy could improve on the rules of the gold standard, rules that were
seen as unduly restrictive. We now know that the faith then placed in
discretion over rules was somewhat misplaced. Today, monetary economists
and central bankers alike understand that effective monetary policy must
be built on a consistent commitment to low inflation.
Numerous lessons were learned on the 20th century odyssey. The
most important is that the Federal Reserve, through its management of
monetary policy, is responsible for inflation. This became clear partly
as a result of advances in monetary theory and partly as a result of
evidence on money demand and money supply. It was also the result of a
learning process in which nonmonetary approaches to controlling
inflation were seen to fall, and the monetary approach succeeded.
Discretionary monetary policy actions can be invaluable in
fighting a financial crisis or a weak economy. But we learned that the
promise of discretion can be realized fully only in the context of a
monetary policy that makes price stability a priority. Otherwise
discretion leads inexorably to go-stop policy that brings rising and
unstable inflation and inflation expectations, with adverse consequences
for interest rates and employment.
The go-stop experience taught that the Fed should fight inflation
by tightening monetary policy before price pressures break out into the
open. Waiting until inflation has begun to rise may better assure public
support for higher short-term interest rates. But delayed tightening
allows higher inflation to become more firmly established, requiring
even higher rates to choke it off, with a greater risk of recession.
An emerging consensus among monetary economists and central
bankers supports the need for a legislative mandate to make low
inflation the primary goal of monetary policy. That recommendation has
broad backing for three reasons. A central bank can guarantee low
inflation over time. Monetary policy most effectively stabilizes
employment over the business cycle when it has credibility for low
inflation. And full credibility for low inflation needs the support of a
legislative mandate.
Monetary policy has come of age in the 20th century in the sense
that monetary economists and central bankers have come to terms with the
past--lessons have been learned and principles have been applied
successfully. The country should build on that professional consensus to
broaden the public's understanding and support for price stability
and the preemptive policy procedures to sustain low inflation. The
nation has the opportunity to bring a tumultuous chapter in its monetary
history to a close. It should grasp that opportunity and enjoy the
benefits that sustained price stability would bring.
(1) Technically, the United States was on a bimetallic (gold and
silver) standard until 1900. Though it is true that the money supply was
limited by the size of the Treasury's gold and silver holdings,
there was considerable short-run variability in the money multiplier.
See Cagan (1965) and Freidman and Schwartz (1963).
(2) Major banking panics occurred in 1873, 1884, 1890, 1893, and
1907.
(3) This latter understanding was viewed as part of the Fed's
mission, although it is only implicitly, not explicitly, stated in the
Federal Reserve Act of 1913 itself.
(4) See Goodfriend (1988).
(5) See Hawtrey (1938).
(6) According to Friedman and Schwartz (1963) U.S. real net national
product fell by more than one-third from 1929 to 1933, implicit prices
of goods and services fell by more than one-quarter, and wholesale
prices by more than one-third. More than one-fifth of the commercial
banks in the United States holding nearly one-tenth of the deposits
closed because of financial difficulties. As a result of the sharp
contraction in economic activity, the unemployment rate peaked at over
20 percent in 1932-33, and remained above 10 percent for the remainder
of the decade.
(7) The Fed had already recognized inflation as a problem on three
occasions prior to the mid-1960s: in the aftermath of World War II,
during the Korean War and the period of the 1951 Fed-Treasury Accord,
and again in the mid-1950s. See footnote 12.
(8) Under the leadership of Benjamin Strong, Governor of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, the Fed made price stability a priority
briefly in the 1920s. See Hetzel (1985).
(9) See, for example, Bronfenbrenner and Holzman (1963) and Friedman
(1987).
(10) Estimates in Lucas (1994) imply that the economization of money
balances that occurred at a rate of inflation of 5 percent per year
(associated with a short-term nominal interest rate of about 6 percent)
wasted about 1 percent of U.S. GDP. The payment of interest on
transactions deposits in recent years raises money balances and reduces
this welfare cost somewhat. The bulk of the welfare gain to reducing
inflation is probably realized at a slightly positive inflation rate.
See Wolman (1997).
(11) Feldstein (1996) reports that the net present value of the
welfare gain of shifting from 2 percent inflation per year to price
stability forever is about 30 percent of the current level of GDP.
(12) Friedman (1964, 1972, and 1984) discusses go-stop policy. Romer
and Romer (1989) document that since World War II the Fed tightened
monetary policy decisively to fight inflation on six occasions
beginning, respectively, in October 1947, September 1955, December 1968,
April 1974, August 1978, and October 1979. The unemployment rate rose
sharply after each policy shock. Only two significant increases in
unemployment were not preceded by Fed action to fight inflation. One
occurred in 1954 after the Korean War and the second occurred in 1961,
after the Fed tightened monetary policy to improve the international
balance of payments.
(13) The monthly average 30-year bond rate rose from around 8 percent
in early 1978 to peak above 14 percent in the fall of 1981. The long
bond rate was near 13 percent as late as the summer of 1984.
(14) See Cook (1989).
(15) See, for instance, Friedman (1987), Poole (1978), and Sargent
(1986).
(16) See McCallum and Goodfriend (1987).
(17) The public's target ratio of money to expenditure may
exhibit a trend at times in response to, say, rising interest rates or
technical progress in the payments system. For instance, the ratio of
money to expenditure will trend downward if money provides transaction
services more efficiently over time. In that case, the money growth rate
consistent with price stability will be below the growth of physical
product.
(18) See the preceding note.
(19) Electronic private substitutes for government currency have
become feasible recently. See Lacker (1996).
(20) See Cagan (1965).
(21) There have been exceptions, however. For instance, a new deposit
type known as the negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW) account was
introduced in the late '70s and early '80s as part of the
deregulation of the prohibition of interest on checkable deposits. NOW
accounts were interest-earning substitutes for demand deposits and so
were immediately included in the Fed's M1 measure of the basic
money supply for purposes of targeting and control. See Broaddus and
Goodfriend (1984).
(22) For instance, see Lucas (1988) and Meltzer (1963) on the
long-run stability of the demand for M1.
(23) See Heller (1966) and Shultz and Aliber (1966).
(24) See Kosters (1975).
(25) Government fiscal concerns are the driving force behind high
inflations. See Sargent (1986).
(26) See Schreft (1990).
(27) See Phillips (1958).
(28) See Heller (1966) and Tobin (1972).
(29) See Fischer (1994), pp. 267-68.
(30) King and Watson (1994), for example, report a significant
negative correlation between unemployment and inflation over the
business cycle.
(31) Barro and Gordon (1983), Fellner (1976), Sargent (1986), and
Taylor (1982) contain early discussions of credibility as it relates to
monetary policy. Persson and Tabellini (1994) contains a recent survey
of research on the role of credibility in monetary and fiscal policy.
The new large-scale Federal Reserve Board macroeconomic model is
designed to take account of different degrees of credibility in policy
simulations. See "A Guide to FRB/US" (1996).
(32) What happens is this: In the first instance households and
businesses attempt to exchange financial assets for money. Such actions,
however, cannot satisfy the aggregate excess demand for money directly.
They drive asset prices down and interest rates up until the interest
sensitive components of aggregate expenditure grow slowly enough to
eliminate the excess demand for money. As the disinflation gains
credibility, wage and price inflation slows, and real aggregate demand
rebounds until the higher unemployment is eliminated.
Ball (1994) shows that a perfectly credible disinflation need have
no adverse effects on employment even in a model with considerable
contractual inertia in the price level.
(33) The Fed did not explicitly assert its responsibility for
inflation in the initial announcements of its disinflationary policy.
However, by emphasizing the key role played by money growth in the
inflation process, and by announcing a change in operating procedures to
emphasize the control of money, the Fed implicitly acknowledged its
responsibility for inflation. See Federal Reserve Bulletin (November
1979), pp. 830-32.
(34) The Fed took short-term rates from around 11 percent in
September 1979 to around 17 percent in April 1980. This was the most
aggressive series of actions the Fed has ever taken in so short a time,
although the roughly 5 percent increase in short rates from January to
September of 1973 was almost as large. See Goodfriend (1993).
(35) The collapse of confidence in U.S. monetary policy in 1979 and
1980 was extraordinary. The price of gold rose from around $275 per
ounce in June 1979 to peak at about $850 per ounce in January 1980, and
it averaged over $600 per ounce as late as November 1980. Evidence of a
weakening economy caused the Fed to pause in its aggressive tightening
in early 1980. But with short rates relatively steady, the 30-year rate
jumped sharply by around 2 percentage points between December and
February, signaling a huge jump in long-term inflation expectations. The
collapse of confidence in early 1980 was caused in part by the ongoing
oil price shock and the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan in December 1979.
But the Fed's hesitation to proceed with its tightening at the
first sign of a weakening economy probably also played a role. In any
case, the Fed responded with an unprecedented 3 percentage point
increase in short rates in March, taking them to around 17 percent. See
Goodfriend (1993).
(36) After making its disinflationary policy commitment in October
1979, the Fed let the growth of effective M1 overshoot its target range
in 1980 and the inflation rate continued to rise, peaking at over 10
percent in the fourth quarter. Then, in sharp contrast to the preceding
four years, effective MI actually undershot its target range in 1981.
Effective M1 grew around 4.6 percentage points slower in 1981 than its
average annual growth over the preceding five years. Further, the actual
2 percent shortfall in M1 from the midpoint of its 1981 target was built
into the 1982 target path. See Broaddus and Goodfriend (1984).
The unemployment rate rose from around 6 percent in 1978 to
average nearly 10 percent in the recession year of 1982.
(37) Simple policy rule specifications studied with models estimated
on historical data can be of great practical value in benchmarking
actual policy decisions. McCallum (1988) and Taylor (1993) present two
rules, respectively, that are particularly useful in this regard.
McCallum models the monetary base (currency plus bank reserves) as the
Fed's policy instrument, and has it responding to a moving average
of base velocity and departures of nominal GDP from a target path.
Taylor models the real short-term interest rate (the market interest
rate minus expected inflation) as the policy instrument, and has it
responding to inflation and the gap between actual and potential GDP.
Each specification has advantages and disadvantages. Taylor's
rule matches more closely the way the Fed thinks of itself as operating.
But McCallum's rule makes clear that the ultimate power of the Fed
over the economy derives from its monopoly on the monetary base.
McCallum's rule has the advantage that it could still be used if
disinflation happened to push the market short rate to zero, or if
inflation expectations became excessively volatile. In either situation
the Fed might be unable to use the real short rate as its policy
instrument.
(38) See Board of Governors "Monetary Policy Report to
Congress" (1994, 1995, and 1996).
(39) In 1995, Senator Connie Mack introduced a bill that would make
low inflation the primary goal of monetary policy. In 1989, Fed Chairman
Alan Greenspan testified in favor of a prior resolution that would have
mandated a price stability objective for the Fed. Academics as diverse
as Blinder (1995), Fischer (1994), and Friedman (1962) all agree that
the Fed should be given some sort of mandate for low inflation. The
remarkable convergence of professional thinking in favor of a mandate
was evident at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City's August
1996 conference on price stability. See Achieving Price Stability
(1996).
Inflation targeting is employed by a number of central banks
around the world. See Leiderman and Svensson (1995).
(40) Rudebusch and Wilcox (1994) report empirical evidence on
inflation and productivity growth. Dotsey and Ireland (1996) study the
question in a quantitative, theoretical model.
(41) Oil prices rose from around $3 to $12 a barrel during the
1973/74 oil price shock, and from about $15 to over $35 in 1979/80.
(42) See Thurow (1994). By successfully keeping inflation in check,
preemptive policy actions necessarily appear to be busting ghosts. So
the appearance of ghost busting is a consequence of good monetary
policy.
REFERENCES
Achieving Price Stability. A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 1996.
"A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United
States." Manuscript. Macroeconomic and Quantitative Studies,
Division of Research and Statistics, Federal Reserve Board: July 1996.
Ball, Laurence. "Credible Disinflation with Staggered
Price-Setting," American Economic Review, vol. 84 (March 1994), pp.
282-89.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Gordon. "Rules, Discretion and
Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy," Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 12 (July 1983), pp. 101-21.
Blinder, Alan. "Central Banking in Theory and Practice,"
The Marshall Lecture, Cambridge University, Federal Reserve Board,
processed May 1995.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Monetary
Policy Report to Congress," Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1994,
February 1995, and August 1996.
--. "Announcements," Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 65
(November 1979), pp. 830-32.
Broaddus, Alfred, and Marvin Goodfriend. "Base Drift and the
Longer Run Growth of M1: Experience from a Decade of Monetary
Targeting," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol.
70 (November/December 1984), pp. 3-14.
Bronfenbrenner, Martin, and Franklyn D. Holzman. "Survey of
Inflation Theory," American Economic Review, vol. 53 (September
1963), pp. 593-661.
Cagan, Phillip. Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of
Money, 1875-1960. New York: Columbia University Press, 1965.
Cook, Timothy. "Determinants of the Federal Funds Rate:
1979-1982," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol.
75 (January/February 1989), pp. 3-19.
Dotsey, Michael, and Peter Ireland. "The Welfare Cost of
Inflation in General Equilibrium," Journal of Monetary Economics,
vol. 37 (February 1996), pp. 29-47.
Economic Report of the President. Washington: Government Printing
Office, 1996.
Feldstein, Martin. "The Costs and Benefits of Going from Low
Inflation to Price Stability," NBER Working Paper 5469. Forthcoming
in C. Romer and D. Romer, eds., Monetary Policy and Inflation. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1997.
Fellner, William. Towards a Reconstruction of Macroeconomics:
Problems of Theory and Policy. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise
Institute for Public Policy Research, 1976.
Fischer, Stanley. "Modern Central Banking," in Forrest
Capie, Stanley Fischer, Charles Goodhart, and Norbert Schnadt, eds., The
Future of Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of
England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Friedman, Milton. "The Quantity Theory of Money," in John
Eatwell, Peter Newman, and Murray Milgate, eds., The New Palgrave
Dictionary of Money and Finance. New York: The Stockton Press, 1987.
--. "Monetary Policy for the 1980s," in John H. Moore, ed.,
To Promote Prosperity: U.S. Domestic Policy in the Mid-1980s. Stanford:
Hoover Institution Press, 1984.
--. An Economist's Protest: Columns in Political Economy. New
Jersey: Thomas Horton and Company, 1972.
--. Statement before U.S. Congress, House of Representatives,
Committee on Banking and Currency in The Federal Reserve System After
Fifty Years. Subcommittee on Domestic Finance. Hearings, 88 Cong. 2
Sess. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1964.
--. "Should There Be an Independent Monetary Authority?" in
Leland. Yeager, ed., In Search of a Monetary Constitution. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1962.
--, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United
States, 1867-1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Goodfriend, Marvin. "Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation
Scare Problem: 1979-1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly, vol. 79 (Winter 1993), pp. 1-24.
--. "Central Banking Under the Gold Standard,"
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 29 (Autumn
1988), pp. 85-124.
--, and William Whelpley. "Federal Funds: Instrument of Federal
Reserve Policy," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review,
vol. 72 (September/October 1986), pp. 3-11.
Greenspan, Alan. Statement before the U.S. Congress, House of
Representatives, Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of the
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, Zero Inflation.
Hearing, 101 Cong. 1 Sess. Washington: Government Printing Office, 1989.
Hawtrey, R. G. A Century of Bank Rate. London: Longran, 1938.
Heller, Walter W. New Dimensions of Political Economy. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1966.
Hetzel, Robert L. "The Rules versus Discretion Debate over
Monetary Policy in the 1920s," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review, vol. 71 (November/December 1985), pp. 3-14.
King, Robert G., and Mark W. Watson. "The Post-War U.S. Phillips
Curve: A Revisionist Econometric History," Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 41 (December 1994), pp.
157-219.
Kosters, Marvin H. Controls and Inflation: The Economic Stabilization
Program in Retrospect. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute
for Public Policy Research, 1975.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. "Stored Value Cards: Costly Private
Substitutes for Government Currency," Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Quarterly, vol. 82 (Summer 1996), pp. 1-25.
Leiderman, Leonardo, and Lars Svensson, eds. Inflation Targets.
London: Center for Economic Policy Research, 1995.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "On the Welfare Cost of Inflation,"
Center for Economic Policy Research, Stanford University, February 1994.
--. "Money Demand in the United States: A Quantitative
Review," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
vol. 29 (Autumn 1988), pp. 137-69.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Robustness Properties of a Rule for
Monetary Policy," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy, vol. 29 (Autumn 1988), pp. 173-204.
--, and Marvin S. Goodfriend. "Demand for Money: Theoretical
Analysis," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London:
Macmillan Press, 1987, reprinted in Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review, vol. 74 (January/February 1988), pp. 16-24.
Meltzer, Allan. "The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the
Time Series," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 71 (June 1963),
pp. 219-46.
Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, eds. Monetary and Fiscal
Policy, Vol. 1: Credibility. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1994.
Phillips, A. W. "The Relation Between Unemployment and the Rate
of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957,"
Economica, vol. 25 (November 1958), pp. 283-99.
Poole, William. Money and the Economy: A Monetarist View. United
States: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1978.
Romer, Christina D., and David H. Romer. "Does Monetary Policy
Matter? A New Test in the Spirit of Friedman and Schwartz," NBER
Macroeconomics Annual, vol. 4 (1989), pp. 121-70.
Rudebusch, Glenn, and David Wilcox. "Productivity and Inflation:
Evidence and Interpretations," Federal Reserve Board, Washington,
D.C., 1994.
Sargent, Thomas J. Rational Expectations and Inflation. New York:
Harper and Row, 1986.
Schreft, Stacey L. "Credit Controls: 1980," Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol. 76 (November/December 1990), pp.
25-55.
Schultz, George P., and Robert Z. Aliber, eds. Guidelines: Informal
Controls and the Market Place. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1966.
Taylor, John B. "Discretion Versus Policy Rules in
Practice," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
vol. 39 (December 1993), pp. 195-214.
--. "Establishing Credibility: A Rational Expectations
Viewpoint," American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol.
72 (May 1982), pp. 81-85.
Thurow, Lester C. "The Fed Goes Ghostbusting," The New York
Times, May 6, 1994.
Tobin, James. "The Cruel Dilemma," in Arthur M. Okun, ed.,
Problems of the Modern Economy: The Battle Against Unemployment.
Revised. New York: W. W. Norton and Company, Inc., 1972.
Wolman, Alexander. "Zero Inflation and the Friedman Rule: A
Welfare Analysis," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Quarterly (forthcoming 1997).
The author is senior vice president and director of research. This
article, which originally appeared in this Bank's 1996 Annual
Report, benefited greatly from the comments of Doug Diamond, Mike
Dotsey, Bob Hetzel, Tom Humphrey, Bob King, Ben McCallum, Alan Stockman,
and Alex Wolman. It should be emphasized that the views expressed are
the author's alone and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
System.