Group lending and financial intermediation: an example.
Prescott, Edward S.
Imagine a small group of people, each of whom borrows money from a
financial intermediary. The intermediary does not require collateral
because the borrowers are relatively poor and do not own much property.
Instead, the intermediary requires group members to be jointly liable
for each other's loans. That is, if a member defaults on a loan,
the rest of the group is liable for the remainder of the loan. If the
group does not honor this joint obligation, then the entire group is cut
off from future access to credit.
The lending arrangement I just described is not fictitious. Two
million villagers, most of whom are female and poor, borrowed in this
way from the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh. In Bolivia, 75,000 urban
entrepreneurs, roughly one-third of the banking system clientele,
borrowed money via group loans from BancoSol. Even in nineteenth-century
Ireland, many rural residents took out loans similar to group loans.
Motivated in part by group lenders in less-developed countries,
organizations in the United States have developed similar programs. The
1996 Directory of U.S. Microenterprise Programs lists 51 organizations
that issue group loans. The programs operate in both rural and urban
areas. Often they are run by nonprofit organizations.
The underlying idea of group lending is to delegate monitoring and
enforcement activities to borrowers themselves. Borrowers who know a lot
about each other, such as those who live in close proximity or socialize in the same circles, are the most promising candidates for group
lending. For example, the rural villages that Grameen lends in would
seem ideally suited for group lending, because they are relatively
self-contained communities, and people live close to each other and
interact regularly. In such an environment, residents should be better
than outsiders at assessing and monitoring the creditworthiness of
fellow residents. They should also be better able to apply social
pressure on potential defaulters.
The first goal of this paper is to analyze group lending,
particularly as a potential method for lending to the poor in the United
States. Studying alternatives to traditional lending is important
because there is economic evidence that the poor in the United States
have an unmet demand for finance. Zeldes (1989) finds that the poor are
borrowing-constrained; that is, they would like to borrow more money at
existing rates than they can. Evans and Jovanovic (1989), even after
accounting for possible correlation between entrepreneurial ability and
wealth, find that the lack of wealth affected the poor's ability to
engage in self-employment activities. Bond and Townsend (1996),
reporting on the results of a survey of financial activity in a
low-income, primarily Mexican neighborhood in Chicago, find that bank
loans are not an important source of finance for business start-ups. In
their sample, only 11.5 percent of business owners financed their
start-up with a bank loan. Furthermore, 50 percent of the respondents
financed their start-up entirely out of their own funds.
Two services provided by financial intermediaries are delegated
monitoring and asset transformation. Banks provide both of these
services and, maybe surprisingly, groups do too. Group members monitor
each other and through joint liability, transform the state-contingent
returns of its members' loans into a security with a different
state-contingent payoff. Consequently, groups can be interpreted as
financial intermediaries, albeit small ones.
Interpreting groups as financial intermediaries is an important
part of my second goal: to place group lending in the context of the
rest of the financial intermediation sector. In this paper, groups have
a comparative advantage at some types of financial intermediation.
Understanding comparative advantage and specialization in financial
intermediation to the poor is important because it can help answer
questions such as: Which financial intermediary is best at what
activity? How are different intermediaries financially linked? Do legal
and regulatory restrictions, through their effect on the organization of
financial intermediation sector, change the services they offer? These
are the questions that underly the assessment of legislative acts aimed
towards lending to the poor, like the Community Development Financial
Institutions Act (CDFIA) and the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA).(1)
Theoretical Framework
The theoretical framework I use is the delegated monitoring model
developed in Diamond (1984, 1996). In his work, there are lots of small
lenders and a smaller number of borrowers. Lenders lend to borrowers
through a financial intermediary in order to economize on monitoring
costs.
My model makes two additions to this framework; the major one is
to allow some borrowers to monitor each other at a lower cost than
outsiders. The heterogeneity in monitoring costs drives the coexistence of two types of financial intermediaries, large ones like banks and
smaller ones like groups. Both types transform assets and provide
monitoring services. In my model, just like in Diamond's model,
lenders' funds flow through a large financial intermediary. But in
my model, the large financial intermediary does not directly lend to all
borrowers. Instead, for those borrowers who can monitor each other at a
low cost, it lends to groups that in turn lend to their members.
I use Diamond's framework for three reasons. First, delegated
monitoring is an important feature of group lending. Second, it allows
for the embedding of groups into the financial intermediation sector.
Finally, it demonstrates the similarities between groups and other
financial intermediaries.
There is a small economic literature on group lending. This
literature examine group versus individual lending but not in a model
designed to study the existence of financial intermediaries. Stiglitz
(1990) examines a problem where group members can assess whether other
members are shirking. Varian (1990) examines the important screening
role groups may provide, that is, their use of their prior knowledge
about others to form groups. He also examines learning from fellow
members as a potential advantage of groups. Besley and Coate (1995)
examine the potential enforcement advantages groups may have. For
example, social ostracism of defaulters is an option available to groups
but not to outsiders. These penalties can reduce incentives to default
but not in all cases. Sometimes, they increase the chance of default.
While all of these features of group lending are important, I abstract
from them.
In the following section, I provide background on group lending in
practice, after which my model is developed and analyzed. Then I analyze
the portability of group lending to the United States in the context of
the model.
1. GROUP LENDING IN PRACTICE
Microfinance is the provision of financial services to the poor. The
prefix micro is used because the amounts involved in transactions are
small. Often, microfinance is provided by nonprofit organizations; their
targets are people who have not participated in the formal financial
sector. The financial services that their clients do use tend to be
supplied by relatives, or in some parts of the world, by moneylenders.
Formal financial institutions have avoided this market because the loan
sizes are small, administrative costs per dollar lent are high, and they
perceive the risk of default to be significant. It is the absence of the
formal sector from these markets that has led nonprofit organizations,
often with the goal of poverty alleviation instead of profit
maximization, to supply financial services. It is also the
inappropriateness of traditional financial products that has led to the
introduction of financial products such as group lending.
Group lending is not the only tool used to provide microfinance.
Many microfinance organizations make loans only to individuals while
others make loans to both individuals and groups. Others provide savings
and insurance services. Much microfinance is provided informally, by
rotating savings and credit associations, or between friends and family.
While these issues are important, I do not discuss them because this
paper is a study of the narrower question of what conditions favor group
lending.
Group Lending in Less-Developed Countries
The most famous group lender is the Grameen Bank, which was founded
in Bangladesh in the mid-1970s. This bank makes loans to groups of five
unrelated individuals who are poor. Most groups consist of landless women from the same village. Loans are made sequentially with remaining
members not receiving their loans until other members repay their loans.
Loan size is increased after the group has successfully repaid earlier
small loans.(2)
The bank has grown tremendously. In 1992, it lent to 2 million
people at real interest rates of around 12 to 16 percent. Their
repayment rate is high, around 97 to 98 percent. The bank even shows a
profit, though it would not do so without the low-interest loans and
grants it has received (Morduch 1997).
The Grameen Bank is far from the only institution to make group
loans. Even in Bangladesh, there are at least two other organizations,
Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC) and Thana Resource
Development and Employment Programme (TRDEP), that make group loans
(Montgomery, Bhattacharya, and Hulme 1996). Like Grameen, BRAC is a
sizable institution, lending to over 600,000 borrowers in 1992. Other
countries with lending institutions that make group loans include Kenya
(Mutua 1994), Malawi (Buckley 1996), Costa Rica (Wenner 1995), Columbia,
and Peru, just to name a few.
One of the most successful group lenders is BancoSol, located in
Bolivia. It is a chartered bank, subject to the supervision of SIB, the
Bolivian bank regulatory agency. It makes uncollateralized loans for
periods of 12 to 24 weeks. Repayments are made frequently, every week or
two. Loans are made to what they call solidarity groups, each of which
can have four to ten members. The group takes a loan from the bank and
apportions it among its members. Like Grameen's groups, group
members are jointly liable for each other's debts. Loans are
usually made to provide working capital for small-scale commercial
activities. Also like Grameen, the majority (77 percent) of clients are
women. But unlike the Bangladesh bank, most of the borrowers are located
in urban areas. Nonetheless, borrowers still have good information about
each other because BancoSol requires all members of a solidarity group
to work within a few blocks of each other. Most borrowers are market
vendors, though half of the portfolio is lent to small-scale producers
like shoemakers, bakers, and tailors (Glosser 1994). Lending is not the
only financial service provided by BancoSol. It also offers deposit
services in both boliviano and U.S. dollar-denominated accounts.(3)
BancoSol's growth has been extraordinary. In 1996, it lent to
about 75,000 people, roughly one-third of the people who use the
Bolivian banking sector. In 1996, BancoSol had a loan portfolio of $47.5
million. It also earned $1.1 million on revenues of $13 million
(Friedland 1997). Two important reasons for this success is that the
bank charges real interest rates of 34 percent and has a default rate of
less than 1 percent (Agafonoff 1994). The high interest rates are no
doubt required to cover the high administrative costs required by its
lending strategy. As a basis of comparison, 80 percent of
BancoSol's costs are administrative, while the comparable number
for the rest of the Bolivian banking industry is only 20 percent
(Glosser 1994).
Group Lending in the United States
Recently, several lenders have tried group lending in the United
States. These lenders are nonprofit organizations whose main goal is to
assist the poor--in particular, women and minorities--by financing
self-employment. Since these efforts have started relatively recently,
published information is still limited.
One source of information is a study by Edgcomb, Klein, and Clark
(1996), who examine seven microenterprise programs. Of the seven, four
make group loans.(4) Each program provides services other than group
lending. Several lend to individuals, others provide training, and some
provide all three services.
All four programs followed Grameen's example but with
modifications. Each agency started with groups of five members. However,
the agencies found that if an individual dropped out of the group, the
rest of the group would disband. Currently, three of the agencies allow
more flexibility in group size. One program allows four to ten members,
while another allows four to six businesses per group.
The scale of the agencies' operations are still small. For
example, the number of loans made by the programs in 1994 ranged from 27
to 103, and average loan sizes ranged from about $2,100 to $4,900.
Making these loans is expensive. The average cost per loan varied from
$4,500 to $15,300, so these programs are far from self-sufficient.
However, when compared with job training and other assistance programs,
their costs seem more reasonable. I discuss possible reasons for the
high costs after I describe the model.
Historical Group Lending
Group lending is often considered a recent innovation, and its recent
popularity certainly is connected with the success of the Grameen Bank.
There are, however, at least two types of institutions that existed long
before the Grameen Bank and that used variants on group lending.
To the best of the author's knowledge the earliest
institutions that used a form of group lending were the Irish Loan Funds
(Hollis and Sweetman 1997a, b).(5) The funds developed in the early
1700s, peaked in size in the early 1800s, and then slowly declined
throughout the rest of the nineteenth century. Interestingly, Hollis and
Sweetman trace their development to Jonathan Swift, the Anglican priest
best known for writing Gulliver's Travels.
The Irish Loan Funds were usually located in rural areas, took
deposits, and made small loans. The institutions generally made
uncollateralized loans to finance a small investment project, such as
the purchase of an animal. As a rule, the loans were repaid on a weekly
basis. These loans most resembled present-day group loans in that all
borrowers were required to obtain two cosigners for each loan, and both
cosigners were liable for repayment.(6) While each fund was independent,
the funds were regulated by a Central Loan Fund Board.
Another historical example of European group lenders was that of
the German credit cooperatives that developed in the late nineteenth
century (Guinnane 1993; Banerjee, Besley, and Guinnane 1994). They were
often located in rural areas where individuals knew each other well.
These cooperatives provided credit services, and importantly, many had a
policy of unlimited liability. That is, if the cooperative failed, any
member could be sued for the entire amount owed by the cooperative.
Interestingly, these credit cooperatives were the inspiration for the
credit union movement in the United States.
2. THE MODEL
The model in this paper is designed to study the following three
features of group lending and the financial intermediation sector:
* the existence of joint liability groups
* the existence of more traditional financial intermediaries
* large financial intermediaries lending to the groups
Analysis of these issues requires a model in which it is possible to
lend funds either directly to an individual or indirectly through a
financial intermediary. With two additions, the framework in Diamond
(1984, 1996) provides an environment that satisfies these conditions.
Diamond considered an economy where there are borrowers and
lenders, and funding each borrower's project requires the resources
of several lenders. Borrowers' returns are unobserved by a lender
unless he spends resources to monitor the borrower. Lenders face the
choice of whether to lend directly to borrowers or to lend to them
indirectly through the financial intermediary. In equilibrium, lenders
lend to the financial intermediary and the intermediary in turn lends to
the borrowers. The reason that lenders lend through the financial
intermediary is that it avoids costly duplicative monitoring.
This paper operates in the same framework but with two additions,
heterogeneous monitoring costs and screening costs. The important
addition is the former. In particular, some borrowers are given the
ability to form small groups, and in these groups they can monitor their
fellow members. This ability is potentially valuable because group
members monitor each other at a lower cost than a more traditional
financial intermediary. People who live close to each other, those who
work near each other, or those who socialize together would be most
likely to satisfy these conditions. As in Diamond's model, it is
optimal for lenders to lend to a traditional financial intermediary, but
in this paper the financial intermediary lends to groups that in turn
lend to their members. As we will see, the incentive problem underlying
the contract between lenders and the large financial intermediary is the
same as the incentive problem underlying the contract between the large
financial intermediary and the groups. It is in this sense that groups
and institutions, such as banks, are financial intermediaries for the
same reason.
Environment
The model in this section is really a numerical example that closely
follows Diamond (1996). In this economy, there are two main types of
people, lenders and borrowers. Both types are risk-neutral, and
consumption cannot go below zero. Each lender is endowed with l/m, m [is
greater than] 1, units of the investment good. The investment good
cannot be consumed, but it can be used to create the consumption good.
Lenders have access to a safe but low-return investment technology.
Their investment technology takes x units of the investment good and
turns it into 1.05x units of the good, receiving an interest rate of 5
percent.
The borrowers are better at producing the consumption good, but
they start without any units of the investment good. Each
borrower's investment technology requires an input of exactly 1.0
unit of the investment good. An investment of less than 1.0 produces an
output of zero and any investment over 1.0 unit is wasted. The former
assumption means that for each borrower it takes the funds of at least m
lenders to finance his investment. Their investment technology is also
riskier than that of lenders. In this example, an investment of 1.0 unit
produces an output of 1.0 with a probability of 0.2 and an output of 1.4
with a probability of 0.8. Expected output for a borrower is (0.2) 1.0 +
(0.8) 1.4 = 1.32, which is greater than 1.05, the return on the safe
investment. However, 20 percent of the time output is less than what it
would have been if the lender's investment technology had been
used. Finally, I assume that each borrower's return is independent
of other borrowers' returns.
In this model, the owners and the productive users of the
investment good are different people. As the problem presently stands,
the initial mismatch between owners and users is easily rectified through simple loan contracts. Lenders would lend to borrowers as long
as their expected repayment was equal to 1.05. There is no role for
intermediaries.
To introduce intermediaries requires the addition of complications
to writing and enforcing contracts, complications that intermediaries
are better able to overcome than lenders. I now describe four features
to the model that affect the feasibility and desirability of various
contracts and ultimately lead to a role for financial intermediaries,
both large ones like banks and smaller ones like groups. The four
features are private information on borrowers' returns, liquidation costs, costly monitoring, and costly screening.
Private Information
It is assumed that borrowers' returns are private information.
That is, a borrower is the only person who knows the success of his
project; lenders do not observe it, nor do other borrowers. Private
information makes some contracts infeasible. For example, consider a
contract where lenders receive 1.0 if the low output is produced and
1.0625 if the high output is produced. If lenders knew that the
contractual terms would be honored by the borrower, they would make the
loan because their expected return is 0.2(1.0) + 0.8(1.0625) = 1.05.
Under private information, however, they cannot be sure that this
contract would be honored. The reason is that lenders do not know the
true value of the output so the borrower could always claim that he
received a low output. That is, if the lender received the high output
the borrower could claim he received the low output, pay 1.0 to the
lender, and keep the difference. Lenders would be powerless to stop this
deception; they cannot find out if he is telling the truth, and as
things are presently specified, they cannot punish him. All they can do
is refuse to lend, despite the acknowledged quality of his project.
Liquidation Costs
A contract with the option of liquidation is one way out of this
dilemma. In this model, a liquidation cost serves as an ex post penalty
imposed by the lender on the borrower. If the borrower does not meet the
terms of his agreement, the lender can liquidate the borrower's
assets. In this model, I interpret liquidating as meaning that the
borrower and the lender receive zero. This means, among other things,
that there are no assets that the lender can seize and sell. (In
microfinance, projects are so small that one would gain very little from
seizing and selling physical assets.)
The penalty imposed on the borrower by liquidation is important
because it prevents him from always claiming he received the low output,
as in the contract described above. For example, consider a debt
contract with a face value F of 1.3125. If the borrower does not repay
1.3125, he has defaulted. When the output is 1.4, the borrower pays
1.3125. When the output is 1.0, the borrower cannot pay the full amount,
so the lender liquidates, giving the borrower (and the lender) zero. The
expected return to the lender is (0.8)(1.3125) = 1.05, so the loan is
made and the borrower receives zero in the low-return state and 0.0875
in the high-return state. The threat of liquidation is enough to force
repayment in the high-return state. The cost of liquidation is that
output, which is 0.2 in expected value terms, is destroyed. But in this
example, the benefits of financing the loan outweigh the liquidation
costs.(7)
Costly Monitoring
Costly monitoring is the other way to make lending feasible. In this
paper there are two types of monitoring: costly monitoring by a lender
and mutual monitoring within a group. Monitoring by a lender is
identical to monitoring in Diamond's model; the lender pays an ex
ante cost that allows him to observe a borrower's output. In
essence, the lender uses resources to observe the private information.
The resource costs could be as simple as spending time with the borrower
or as complex as receiving regular reports on the project's
financial status.
Observing output is valuable because then repayment can be made
dependent on output, which avoids the need for liquidation. For example,
consider the following contract: the lender monitors and the borrower
pays 1.0 if the low output is realized, and 1.2 if the high output is
realized. The expected return for the lender is 0.2 + 0.96 - K, where K
is the cost of monitoring. If the cost of monitoring is K [is less than
or equal to] 0.11, then a lender's expected return (assume for the
moment there is only one lender) is greater than 1.05, making monitoring
worthwhile. Furthermore, this contract with monitoring is better for the
borrower than the liquidation contract. (In both cases the borrower
keeps zero in the low state, but under the monitoring contract, he keeps
more in the high state.)
The second type of monitoring, mutual monitoring within a group,
is the main departure from Diamond's model. I assume that within a
subset of borrowers there are pairs of borrowers who know each other
well, maybe because they live near each other or maybe because they are
in the same social or ethnic circles.(8) Each one of these pairs may
form a group at a per-person cost of [K.sub.g]. Membership in a group
allows a group member to observe the other group member's output.
Furthermore, because of the close social ties within a group, or maybe
even because their time is less valuable than a loan officer's, I
assume that the cost of being in a group is lower than the cost of
anyone else monitoring them, that is, [K.sub.g] [is less than] K.
At this point I should say more about what it means to be a group
and how that affects the group's interaction with nongroup members.
I am assuming that group members observe each other's outputs and
act cooperatively or collude. In many models where people can collude,
their interaction is complicated and even disadvantageous.(9) In this
model, there are no such disadvantageous effects. Furthermore, the
analysis is simple because the borrowers are risk neutral and thus
utility is transferable. In this model, transferable utility eases the
analysis because it means that the division of output between the group
members does not affect the group's decisions. That is, regardless
of how the group shares their returns, the group acts as if it is
maximizing total expected output. In this paper, I assume that they
share the returns equally. Besley and Coate (1995) examine a
group-lending arrangement where there is an element of strategic play
between group members, and they show that this can be a problem in some
cases. I abstract from this consideration.
Screening Costs
The last element, and the remaining addition to Diamond's setup,
is the addition of a screening cost. What I have in mind is a
preliminary form of monitoring. A lender needs to meet with the
borrower, discuss his project, and record and verify information about
the borrower. In contrast with the previously discussed monitoring
costs, screening costs do not reveal the final output. They only
represent the effort that goes into ensuring that file project has a
chance of success. To model these ideas, I assume that there is a fixed
cost of [K.sub.s] per lender to screen a borrower. I do not model what
happens if the lender or lenders do not screen a borrower; I simply
assume that they must screen a borrower before they make a loan.
I also assume that screening is only necessary for lending to
borrowers. By borrowers I mean the second type of people, those who have
access to the high return and risky technology, and not any entity that
receives funds for investment. In particular, there is no need to screen
a financial intermediary, though the financial intermediary still needs
to screen any borrowers to whom it lends. This assumption is admittedly
strong but not without merit. It seems reasonable to assume that it is
harder to do a preliminary evaluation on small, idiosyncratic investment
projects than on a large, well-known institution such as a bank. The
only role of this assumption is to ensure that lending to groups is done
by the financial intermediary and nor directly by lenders.(10)
Where I am going ...
In this economy there are lenders who have funds and borrowers who do
not. The productivity of borrowers' investment projects creates a
demand for finance. Private information, however, precludes lending
unless there is monitoring or the penalty of liquidation. Before
describing how these elements create a demand for financial
intermediation, it is helpful to show what the lending flows will be and
where each type of financial intermediary fits into the flow pattern.
Figure 1 describes the direction of lending flows in the model.
Arrows indicate the direction of lending and an M indicates whether or
not there is monitoring. The lenders, who start with the investment
good, make unmonitored loans to the large financial intermediary.(11)
This financial intermediary makes two types of loans, monitored loans to
individuals and unmonitored loans to groups. Groups, the smaller
financial intermediary, in turn make monitored loans to its members.
[Figure 1 ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
My strategy for analyzing the model is to split the analysis into two
sections. In the first section, I take as given that there is one large
financial intermediary and analyze its decision of whether to make a
loan to an individual or to a group. To do this analysis, I consider
each type of loan the financial intermediary may make to the borrowers
and enumerate the trade-offs of lending to a group versus lending to
individuals and also whether or not it is beneficial to monitor the
loans. Next, I consider the lending decisions for lenders and show that
it is indeed optimal for them to lend to borrowers through the financial
intermediary rather than to lend to them directly.
Lending by the Financial Intermediary
The large financial intermediary has three options for lending funds:
* It can lend to borrowers, not monitor them, and use the threat of
liquidation;
* It can lend to borrowers and monitor them; or
* It can lend to borrowers through groups.
For this last case, we need only concern ourselves with unmonitored
loans to the groups, since if the bank monitored them, it might as well
bypass the groups altogether.
Recall that for each borrower who invests 1.0 unit of capital, he
produces the low output of 1.0 with a probability of 0.2 and the high
output of 1.4 with a probability of 0.8. Also, borrowers need 1.0 unit
of the good to invest and for reasons explained later, the large
intermediary requires an expected return of 1.05.
The expected returns to a project can be broken into five
components: the expected payment to the financial intermediary R, the
expected utility (return) of the borrower U, the liquidation costs L,
the monitoring costs M, and the screening costs S. These will sum to
1.32, the project's expected output. In the following sections,
when each contract is analyzed, I will list the values of the five
components for each contract. Also, I assume that the financial
intermediary receives 1.05, the opportunity cost of the lenders'
funds. Thus, any excess accrues to the borrower. Under this
(unimportant) assumption, maximizing social welfare is equivalent to
maximizing the utility to the borrower.
Individual Lending with Liquidation but No Monitoring
The enforcement device used for this contract is liquidation. Since
there is no monitoring, a state-contingent contract without liquidation
cannot be offered. Instead, a debt contract with a face value of F is
written. Under this contract the borrower must pay F, or his project is
liquidated. To make the problem interesting I assume that the parameters
are such that 1.0 [is less than] F [is less than] 1.4. This means that
if the borrower receives the high return he pays F, but if he receives
the lower return, his project is liquidated, and both he and the
intermediary receive zero. An F guaranteeing that the intermediary
receives 1.05 in expected return is the solution to the following
equation:
1.05 = (0.2)0 + (0.8)F- [K.sub.s].
The intermediary receives a zero payment 20 percent of the time, it
receives a payment of F 80 percent of the time, and this return has to
be high enough to cover the screening costs [K.sub.s] and the
opportunity cost of the funds 1.05. The solution to the equation is F =
1.3125 + [K.sub.s]/(0.8). The borrower's expected utility is U =
(0.2)0 + (0.8)(1.4 - F). Calculations for utility and the other
variables of interest are as follows:
U = 0.07 - [K.sub.s], R = 1.05, L = 0.20, M = 0, and S = [K.sub.s].
Notice that these values sum to 1.32, the project's expected
return.
Individual Lending with Monitoring
There is no need to liquidate when monitoring because output is
observed by the financial intermediary. For simplicity, I assume that
1.0 is paid out if the low return occurs, and F is paid out if the high
return occurs. A face value of debt F that gives the intermediary a
return of 1.05 is the solution to the following equation:
1.05 = (0.2)(1.0) + (0.8)F - K - [K.sub.s].
Compared with the previous contract, the intermediary now receives
1.0 if the low output is observed but must also bear the, monitoring
cost K. The solution to this equation is F = 1.0625
+(K+[K.sub.s])/(0.8). The borrower's expected utility is again U =
(0.2)0 + (0.8)(1.4 - F). Carrying out the calculations for the variables
produces the following numbers:
U = 0.27 - K - [K.sub.s], R = 1.05, L = 0, M = K, and S = [K.sub.s].
Comparing the utilities from a loan with monitoring and a loan using
liquidation shows that the former is preferred when 0.27 - K - [K.sub.s]
[is greater than] 0.07 - [K.sub.s], or equivalently, K [is less than]
0.20.
Group Lending
The group-lending contract includes elements of monitoring and
liquidation. The group members monitor each other, but since the large
financial intermediary does not know the results of their monitoring, it
needs to include a liquidation provision in the contract. As I mentioned
earlier, the two members of a group pool their resources so the
group's distribution of returns is
return probability
2.0 0.04
2.4 0.32
2.8 0.64
The assumptions made concerning group membership are that group
members observe each other's output and act cooperatively. In this
context, acting cooperatively means they maximize the expected value of
the group's return. Thus, the contract needs to be written in terms
of the total returns to the group, since the group can always move funds
around to pay off a debt. Therefore, the optimal contract will again be
a debt contract, with liquidation if the face value of the debt is not
repaid. To facilitate comparison with the other contracts, we put the
face value of the debt in per-group-member terms, that is, the face
value of the group's debt is 2F.
For the intermediary to receive an expected payment of 2.10 (1.05
per group member), F needs to solve the following equation:
2.10 = (0.04)0 + (0.32)(2/2) + (0.64)(2F) - 2[K.sub.s].
I assume that the large intermediary rather than the group bears the
screening cost. This assumption is not important.
At this point, it is necessary to make one more assumption. I
assume that 2.4 units of output is enough to pay off the face value of
the group's debt, 2F. The value of 2F will depend on the other
parameters, so I am assuming their values are such that this condition
holds. Under these assumptions, the solution to the equation is F =
1.09375 + [K.sub.s]/(0.96). Each borrower's utility, assuming equal
division of returns, is calculated from U = (0.04)0 + (0.32)(2.4 - 2F -
2Kg)/2 + (0.64)(2.8- 2F-2[K.sub.g])/2. I include the monitoring cost in
this equation because the group pays it themselves. The values of the
variables in per-group-member terms are
U = 0.23 - (0.96)[K.sub.g] - [K.sub.s], R = 1.05, L = 0.04, M =
(0.96)[K.sub.g], and S = [K.sub.s].
Special attention should be paid to the liquidation cost, L. Under
group lending, L = 0.04, which is dramatically lower than the case where
the intermediary lends but does not monitor. (Recall that the
liquidation cost in that case was 0.20.) The reason for the dramatic
reduction is that the distribution of the group's output is
different from the distribution of the individual's output. In
particular, the group's distribution has less variance. The
decreased dispersion of group returns reduces the incentive problem
caused by the private information. In turn, a weakened incentive problem
means that liquidation is invoked less often than a liquidation contract
between the intermediary and an individual.
The argument is easier to understand if we compare two borrowers
borrowing F each as a group with the same borrowers borrowing F each as
individuals under the unmonitored liquidation contract. Also, assume
that 1.0 [is less than] F [is less than] 1.2. When the funds are lent to
the individuals, each borrower's project is liquidated 20 percent
of the time. This means that 4 percent of the time both are liquidated,
32 percent of the time one is liquidated, and 64 percent of the time
neither is liquidated. Now compare these liquidation probabilities with
those of the group. Under the group contract, 4 percent of the time both
are liquidated, but 96 percent of the time neither is liquidated. The
reason is that if one borrower gets a bad return and the other gets a
good return, then the latter bails out the former. The transfers between
the group members, in effect, alter their distribution of returns. This
change reduces the probability of liquidation, which is beneficial.
One more way to view this problem, and an argument I will return
to when discussing the large intermediary, is to consider a group
consisting of a very large number of borrowers. (More formally, assume
there is a continuum of them.) Because there are so many group members,
the law of large numbers means that the group's total return is
1.32-[K.sub.g] with probability 1.0. All idiosyncratic risk averages
out. In this case, there is never a need to liquidate since any claim
that total output was less than 1.32-[K.sub.g] would not be credible.
To reiterate, groups greatly reduce the probability of being
liquidated. Still, they have to pay a monitoring cost, and the relative
size of these two costs (along with the intermediary's monitoring
cost) determine whether group lending is better than the other types of
lending. In this example, group monitoring is better than individual
lending with monitoring if 0.23-(0.96)[K.sub.g]- [K.sub.s] [is greater
than] 0.27 - K - [K.sub.s]; that is, the utility accruing to a borrower
from group monitoring is greater than the utility accruing to a borrower
from an individual lending with monitoring contract. Rearranging terms,
the condition is
(1) (0.96)[K.sub.g] + 0.04 [is less than] g.
Equation (1) says that group monitoring is better if the sum of the
group monitoring cost [K.sub.g] and the liquidation cost of 0.04 is less
than the intermediaries monitoring cost K. This is not strictly true
because [K.sub.g] is multiplied by 0.96. That number, however, is only
in the equation because groups bear the cost of monitoring; if their
projects are liquidated, they receive zero and do not have to bear the
monitoring cost.
I can now provide conditions under which the large financial
intermediary will lend according to the pattern described by Figure 1.
First, I assume that monitoring by the intermediary satisfies K [is less
than] 0.20 (so individual lending with monitoring is better than
individual lending without monitoring). Second, I assume that for some
pairs of borrowers [K.sub.g] is small enough to satisfy equation (1) and
for other pairs of borrowers it is not. The former borrowers could be
those who live near each other like Grameen's clients or work near
each other like BancoSol's clients. For parameter values satisfying
these conditions, borrowers who cannot form a group borrow as
individuals with a monitored loan, while other borrowers who can form a
group do so and borrow from the intermediary as a group, using the
liquidation contract.
Lending to the Large Financial Intermediary
Now return to the lenders' lending decision. In equilibrium, as
indicated by Figure 1, lenders lend to the large financial intermediary
rather than directly to individuals or groups. Most of the pieces are
already in place to demonstrate why this is the case. Lenders can either
transform the asset themselves by using the low return but riskless
technology, or they can choose one of the following four lending
options:
* Lend directly to borrowers and use a liquidation contract;
* Lend directly to borrowers and monitor them;
* Lend directly to the group and use a liquidation contract; or
* Lend to the large financial intermediary.
The last option, lending to the large financial intermediary, is
the optimal arrangement. I will demonstrate this by first showing that
the costs to lenders of lending directly is greater than the same costs
faced by the large financial intermediary making the same loans. Then, I
will show that the lenders can lend to the large financial intermediary
at no cost. This will mean that lending through the large financial
intermediary is better than direct lending. Finally, if the large
intermediary receives a return of 1.05, as was assumed in the previous
analysis, and the intermediary adds no cost,,; to lending, then it is
optimal for lenders to lend to the large intermediary.(12)
The first three cases listed above are the direct-lending options
available to lenders. Each one of these options corresponds to one of
the cases worked through earlier in the section. The difference is that
now monitoring and screening costs have to be borne by m [is greater
than] 1 lenders rather than just the large financial intermediary. The
algebra is easy enough to work through but it is simpler to use the
following observations. The incentives faced by a borrower do not depend
on whether his funds are obtained from lenders or via the large
financial intermediary. Consequently, the problem is unchanged from the
earlier analysis except that screening costs (in all three cases) and
monitoring costs (in the second case) are m [is greater than] 1 times as
much under direct lending. Therefore, it is cheaper for lenders to lend
through the large financial intermediary rather than directly.
However, there still remains the issue of whether or not lenders
need to monitor and screen the financial intermediary. If they do not,
they can lend to the intermediary, which in turn lends to borrowers
(either directly or indirectly through groups). This flow of funds will
economize on monitoring and screening costs relative to direct lending.
By assumption, there is no need to screen the intermediary.
However, some work is needed to demonstrate that lenders do not need to
monitor the large financial intermediary. How do lenders know that the
intermediary actually monitors the borrowers? How do they know the
return of the intermediary? (At this point, it is helpful to think of
the large intermediary as a person, possibly a lender, who if he did not
monitor would save himself monitoring costs.)
In the previous section's analysis of lending to the group,
the increased size of the group made the liquidation contract more
effective. The larger the group, the more effective a liquidation
contract was. If the group consisted of a continuum of members, then
there was no need to monitor because the group's return is certain.
The same logic applies to the problem facing the lenders lending
to the intermediary. If the intermediary lends to a continuum of
borrowers, then the intermediary's return is certain. Thus, the
optimal contract between lenders and the large financial intermediary is
an unmonitored debt contract of face value F = 1.05. As part of the debt
contract, the lenders liquidate the intermediary's assets if it
claims its return is less than 1.05. But in equilibrium, the
intermediary's portfolio is so diversified that its assets are
never liquidated. Thus, there is no liquidation cost to lending through
the financial intermediary, and there is no need to monitor it. The
entire return of 1.05 that the intermediary receives from borrowers can
be passed to the lenders. Lending through the large financial
intermediary is better than direct lending.
To summarize, the large financial intermediary economizes on
monitoring and screening costs while the groups economize only on
monitoring costs. Relative to direct lending, both types of
intermediaries economize on monitoring costs in the same way. Lending
through the intermediaries avoids the duplicative monitoring of
borrowers by lenders while the intermediary's diversification
reduces the need for lenders to monitor it. Thus, total monitoring is
lowered in the economy. The reduction of these costs is the financial
intermediary's special role in transforming assets.
There is, however, one way in which the two types of
intermediaries differ in how they economize on monitoring costs Compared
with monitoring by the large financial intermediary, the groups save on
monitoring costs because they have a cost advantage. It is efficient for
the large financial intermediary to lend through groups if this cost
saving outweighs the liquidation cost from using the group. The
remaining observation--that lenders lend to groups through the large
financial intermediary--occurs to economize on screening costs.(13)
3. ANALYSIS
Ideally, the model would be used in the following way. We would start
with measurements of parameters in the model, such as distribution of
returns, costs of monitoring, etc. These measurements would come from
economies, like villages in Bangladesh or urban areas in Bolivia, where
group lending is successfully used. Using these measurements we would
evaluate the model on the criterion of whether or not it predicts there
will be groups. If it does predict groups, the experiment proceeds by
solving the model using parameter values taken from low-income U.S.
communities. Then, the model could be used to evaluate the potential of
group lending in the United States.
Precise measurement of many of these values is beyond the scope of
this paper. Indeed, measurement of a concept like monitoring is a
research project in and of itself. Consequently, the following
discussion is necessarily sketchy, guided by what little information is
available. Still, it is valuable, and one can gain some broad ideas
about the role group lending and financial structure may play in
channeling credit to the poor. The discussion should be considered a
starting point, particularly for researchers and practitioners who are
looking for guidance as to what variables to measure.
Business Opportunities
The model analyzes the problem of financing investment projects. It
takes as given that potentially profitable investment projects exist.
The financing problem, however, is irrelevant if there are no profitable
microenterprise projects to finance.
The evidence presented in the introduction suggests that there are
profitable investment projects in the United States that would be
financed in the absence of information constraints. There are, however,
reasons to think that there may be less of these opportunities in the
United States than in Bangladesh or Bolivia. For example, in
less-developed countries 60 to 80 percent of the labor force is engaged
in self-employment (Edgcomb, Klein, and Clark 1996), while in the United
States only about 12 percent of the labor force is self-employed (Segal
1995). Ultimately, of course, the existence of profitable
self-employment opportunities must be determined by empirical
investigation.
A related issue, applicable to most microfinance programs, is what
type of investments can be financed with group lending or any other
microfinance program. For example, one key feature of the studied
lending programs is the required frequency of repayments. Frequent
repayment requires that an investment produce cash flow for the entire
course of the loan. If it does not, then the borrower will default. This
time path would seem to preclude loans for investments that pay off
sometime in the future. For example, a planting loan to a farmer is
poorly suited for frequent repayment because planting does not generate
income until harvest.
A cursory examination of the type of loans made by Grameen,
BancoSol, or the Irish Loan Funds bears out this observation. Despite
their rural location, planting loans are not made by Grameen nor were
they frequently made by the Irish Loan Funds. Many loans tend to be for
investments that produce a flow of income. The purchases of a cow that
produces milk or a chicken that lays eggs are examples of such an
investment. BancoSol's loans, while in a different context, serve a
similar purpose. They tend to be made for working capital.
Conceivably, there are many valuable investments that do not
produce the steady cash flow demanded by group and other microfinance
lending schemes. The important question here is why are the loans made
with these terms? Are frequent repayments an important part of
monitoring? The answers to these questions are important not just to the
evaluation of group lending in the United States but also for the
evaluation of lending in less-developed countries.
Source of Funding and Comparative Advantage in Lending
The source of funding is important because it can limit the
activities of a financial intermediary, and it can influence the optimal
structure of the financial intermediation structure. In the model, there
were many lenders per borrower. This ratio was responsible for the
existence of the large financial intermediary since the number of
lenders needed to finance a borrower determines the costs of direct
lending, and consequently the savings in monitoring and screening costs
from intermediation. For microfinance programs it is reasonable to ask
if there are lots of lenders per borrower. First, the loans are for
small amounts, and second, many lenders are donors with large amounts to
lend.
BancoSol receives some of its funding: from deposits. Agafonoff
(1994) reports that in 1994 BancoSol's average loan was $499 and
its average deposit was $225. (The majority of the bank's loans and
deposits are denominated in U.S. dollars rather than Bolivian
bolivianos.) These numbers are consistent with the model's
assumption.
Still, many investors are large organizations whose investments
are much higher than the amount any single individual borrows. In terms
of the model some modifications would need to be made to ensure that
donors lend through an intermediary rather than directly. The simplest,
and most obvious, would be to assume that donors do not have the
expertise to lend themselves. Consequently, K and [K.sub.s] are much
higher if they hind themselves rather than through an intermediary.
Another possibility is that donors, particularly those overseas, find it
expensive to monitor because of physical, linguistic, and even cultural
distance from the borrowers. (See Boyd and Smith [1992] for a model in
which people at different locations have a comparative advantage in
lending in their home location.)
A comparison of the United States and Bolivia suggests that a
group lender may desire different sources of funds in the two countries.
In Bolivia, BancoSol raises some of its funds from deposits, but it is a
country where a large fraction of the population does not use the
banking sector. The banking sector, and more generally the financial
structure, is much more extensive in the United States. Consequently,
raising deposits might not be a group lender's comparative
advantage. Instead, debt or equity might be a better source of capital
for a group lender in the United States.
In the United States, group lenders' comparative advantage
should be in lending rather than in collecting deposits. [,ending to the
poor likely requires a different set of skills than other types of
lending. BancoSol's high administrative costs relative to the rest
of the Bolivian banking sector is supportive of the latter
conjecture.(14)
Indeed, it is not difficult to imagine a highly specialized
financial system where traditional financial intermediaries collect
deposits and then direct funds to specialists in microfinance, who in
turn lend to groups (or individuals). There is no reason to think that
traditional financial intermediaries are the best institutional vehicles
for delivering credit to the poor.
Costs to the Large Intermediary
In the model, for some parameter values the large intermediary saved
costs relative to direct lending. In practice, monitoring and screening
costs may be so high as to make any form of financing unprofitable. The
problem is particularly acute for microfinance because loans are for
small amounts, and they require frequent repayments. In the context of
the model's parameters, K and [K.sub.s] might be much higher in the
United States than in less-developed countries.
The data bears out the importance of these costs. Eighty percent
of BancoSol's costs are administrative while the cost figures for
the U.S. agencies exceed the face value of the loans. BancoSol has
surmounted these problems through a combination of a low default rate
and a high interest rate (about 34 percent per year). In 1994, their
average cost per dollar lent was 0.16; their borrower-to-loan-officer
ratio was about 320.
Any microfinance program in the United States that desires to even
approach self-sufficiency will need a similar strategy and results. None
of the four agencies have reached BancoSol's scale. No agency made
more than 107 loans in 1994. Their loan-loss ratios vary from about 2 to
17 percent, and their costs per dollar lent uniformly exceed one. These
programs are far from self-sufficient. Of course, these programs are
relatively new and any activity takes time to learn, not to mention the
time needed to obtain economies of scale. It would be interesting to
compare these agencies' default rates with those of Grameen or
BancoSol in their early years of operation.(15)
Still, self-sufficiency may be too strong an evaluative criterion.
Many services and transfers are distributed through the social welfare
system and these programs are the right basis for comparison. Under this
interpretation, microfinance is unusual in that it directs aid to
specific people in the population; those who are willing to start
businesses. Furthermore, unlike most social welfare programs, the
recipients face the explicit incentive to perform or lose their aid.
Under this criterion, group lending may very well be an effective method
for targeting aid to the poor, particularly since these agencies'
costs are comparable with those of job-training programs.
Monitoring within Groups
One of the most critical issues concerning group lending is how high
is [K.sub.g], the cost of group monitoring?(16) There are reasons to
think that [K.sub.g] is higher in the United States than in developing
countries. There is more anonymity, the costs of being excluded from a
group are smaller in a rich country, and people do not necessarily work
in such close quarters.
Edgcomb, Klein, and Clark (1996) provide some indirect evidence in
support of this view. They conclude that the group-lending programs have
had the most trouble in rural areas. The programs found that rural
residents do not tend to know each other well enough to be able to
support groups, in part because of the low density of the population and
in part because of the low number of self-employed people in rural
areas. One agency has even resorted to purchasing credit reports on
fellow members for potential groups.
Another complication is that self-employment opportunities are
more diverse in the United States than in less-developed countries
(Edgcomb, Klein, and Clark 1996).(17) Group members engaged in similar
activities can learn from each other and can evaluate the borrowing
proposals of fellow group members. It probably also makes monitoring
easier. This is another reason [K.sub.g] may be higher in the United
States. Some of the resources used on training by the U.S. programs may
be designed to compensate for this.
4. CONCLUSION
Lending groups are financial intermediaries, albeit small ones. The
model shows how groups, as well as larger financial intermediaries,
economize on monitoring costs and transform assets. Through
diversification, financial intermediaries alleviate incentive problems
and reduce the costs of monitoring and screening.
Throughout the paper, I provide extensive description of existing
grouplending programs to demonstrate that group lending is a type of
intermediation that is viable in at least several environments,
including some of older origin than many probably realized. Whether it
is viable in the United States is an open question, though the
conditions here appear to be less favorable for it than in
less-developed countries. Still, while the narrow focus of this paper is
on the relative merits of group lending, the broader goal is to study
financial structure. Understanding financial structure is a necessary
prerequisite to the proper formulation of policy involving financial
intermediation and low-income communities.
I would like to thank Hiroshi Fujiki, Tim Harman, John Walter, Roy
Webb, and John Weinberg for helpful comments. The views expressed in
this paper do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
(1) The two acts take different views on the importance of the
structure of the financial intermediation sector for lending to the
poor. The recently enacted CDFIA seems to take the view that
alternatives to traditional financial institutions are needed to provide
financial services to low-income communities. (See Townsend [1994] for a
critical discussion of the act.) It funds institutions that specialize
in providing financial services to low-income communities. In contrast,
the CRA seems based on the premise that lending to low-income people is
best done by existing financial institutions but that these institutions
underserve low-income communities because of neglect, or even
discrimination in the most egregious cases. The CRA works by requiring
regulators to evaluate banks on criteria such as financial services
provided to low-income communities. Banks that score poorly are subject
to sanctions such as limits on merger activities.
(2) There are several other interesting features of the bank's
organization. For example, collections of six groups are formed into
Centres. All payments are made at Centre meetings in public view of
other Centre members. Savings funds are also developed to provide for
contingencies like death or disability. See Rashid and Townsend (1993)
and Fuglesang and Chandler (1987) for more details.
(3) BancoSol is a chartered bank because Bolivian law requires
deposit-taking institutions to be chartered banks subject to
governmental supervision. BancoSol was created by PRODEM, a nonprofit
organization that specialized in making loans. Its operations were
financed mainly by grants, usually from foundations and USAID. The
organization felt that grants were an insufficient source of capital, so
it decided to create a regulated bank in order to have the legal right
to collect deposits. Interestingly, the bank's nontraditional
activities complicated the granting of the charter. For example,
existing Bolivian banking law required that uncollateralized credit be
less than twice paid-up capital. Unfortunately, for BancoSol,
uncollateralized credit is all they supply! The bank negotiated a
compromise in which loans under $2,000 do not count towards this total.
The costs of the conversion were not trivial. They exceeded $500,000,
according to one estimate (Glosser 1994).
(4) The four that made group loans were the Coalition for
Women's Economic Development (CWED), based in Los Angeles; the Good
Faith Fund (GFF), located in Pine Bluff, Arkansas; the Rural Economic
Development Center (REDC), which lends throughout North Carolina; and
the Women's Self-Employment Project (WSEP), based in Chicago.
(5) All reported information about the Irish Loan Funds is taken from
Hollis and Sweetman (1997a, b).
(6) The loans are much like the ones Swift made. Using his own money,
he made small uncollateralized loans, required cosigners on loans, and
required frequent repayments.
(7) There is no advantage from a contract that liquidates for the
high output but not for the low output. Under such a contract, the
borrower would always claim the low output, avoiding liquidation and
keeping the difference between the high-output and the low-output
payment. More generally, if the technology allows for more than two
realizations of the output, even a continuum, then the optimal contract
will still be a debt contract. The optimal contract will require a
constant payment and liquidation if that payment is not made.
(8) For simplicity, I assume that groups consist of only two people.
(9) See, for example, Holmstrom and Milgrom (1990), Itoh (1993),
Ramakrishnan and Thakor (1991), or Prescott and Townsend (1996).
(10) There are other ways to ensure that lending to groups goes
through the large financial intermediary, though they add additional
issues that complicate the analysis. For example, making lenders
risk-averse would be sufficient, since then each lender would want to
lend directly to more than one group. Consequently, each lender would
screen several groups, raising screening costs.
(11) There can be more than one large financial intermediary as long
as each one has a sufficiently large portfolio. For our purposes, it is
simplest to assume there is only one.
(12) Technically, lenders are indifferent between this option and
using the safe investment technology. Among these two choices, I assume
that the lenders choose the socially optimal one, which is to lend to
the large financial intermediary.
(13) One difference from the Diamond (1984, 1996) setup is worth
mentioning. In his paper, financial intermediaries exist only to
economize on monitoring costs. In this paper, the large financial
intermediary economizes on monitoring costs, but it also economizes on
screening costs. The latter costs, in fact, are sufficient in this model
for the large intermediary to exist. In this paper, monitoring costs
serve the role of obtaining a nontrivial trade-off between individual
and group lending. They are necessary to generate the existence of the
small financial intermediaries, that is, the groups.
(14) In the model, groups save on monitoring costs, yet in the data,
group lenders spend a lot of resources on monitoring. This is not a
contradiction. The issue is how much more resources would have to be
used to monitor in the absence of groups. That is what the model
captures.
(15) A potential problem for any program with the goal of
self-sufficiency is that the interest rates necessary to cover costs may
be illegal, violating usury laws in many states of the union.
(16) In the model, monitoring was an either-or proposition. The only
options available were to pay the monitoring costs and observe fellow
members' output or to not pay the cost and not see the output. In
practice, there are degrees of monitoring. Still, for the purposes of
our discussion, [K.sub.g], provides a useful way to summarize these
degrees.
(17) However, different activities may have less-correlated returns.
In my model, group lending is more valuable when returns are less
correlated.
REFERENCES
Agafonoff, Alexander. "Banco Solidario S.A.: Microenterprise
Financing on a Commercial Scale in Bolivia," Economics Division
Working Paper 94/5. Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, The
Australian National University, 1994.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., Timothy Besley, and Timothy W. Guinnane.
"Thy Neighbor's Keeper: The Design of a Credit Cooperative
with Theory and a Test," Quarterly' Journal of Economics, vol.
109 (May 1994), pp. 491-516.
Berenbach, Shaft, and Digo Guzman. "The Solidarity Group
Experience Worldwide," in Maria Otero and Elisabeth Rhyne, eds.,
The New World of Microenterprise Finance. West Hartford, Conn.: Kumarian
Press, 1994.
Besley, Timothy. "Savings Credit and Insurance," in J.
Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Handbook of Development Economics,
Vol. III. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1995.
--, and Stephen Coate. "Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and
Social Collateral," Journal of Development Economics, vol. 46
(February 1995), pp. 1-18.
Bond, Philip, and Robert M. Townsend. "Formal and Informal
Financing in a Chicago Ethnic Neighborhood," Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago Economic Perspectives, vol. 20 (July/August 1996), pp. 3-27.
Boyd, John H., and Bruce D. Smith. "Intermediation and the
Equilibrium Allocation of Investment Capital: Implications for Economic
Development," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 30 (December
1992), pp. 409-32.
Buckley, Graeme. "A Study of the Malawi Mudzi Fund and the
Smallholder Agricultural Credit Administration," in David Hulme and
Paul Mosley, eds., Finance Against Poverty, Vol II. London: Routledge,
1996.
Diamond, Douglas W. "Financial Intermediation as Delegated
Monitoring: A Simple Example," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly, vol. 82 (Summer 1996), pp. 51-66.
--. "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring,"
Review of Economic Studies, vol. 51 (July 1984), pp. 393-414.
Edgcomb, Elaine, Joyce Klein, and Peggy Clark. The Practice of
Microenterprise in the U.S.: Strategies, Costs and Effectiveness.
Washington: The Aspen Institute, July 1996.
Evans, David S., and Boyan Jovanovic. "An Estimated Model of
Entrepreneurial Choice under Liquidity Constraints," Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 97 (August 1989), pp. 808-27.
Friedland, Jonathan. "Bolivian Bank Thrives with Little
Loans," Wall Street Journal, July 15, 1997.
Fuglesang, A., and D. Chandler. "Participation as Process: What
We Can Learn from the Grameen Bank, Bangladesh." Norwegian Ministry
of Development, 1987.
Glosser, Amy J. "The Creation of BancoSol in Bolivia," in
Maria Otero and Elisabeth Rhyne, eds., The New World of Microenterprise
Finance. West Hartford, Conn.: Kumarian Press, 1994.
Guinnane, Timothy W. "Cooperatives as Information Machines: The
Lending Practices of German Agricultural Credit Cooperatives,
1883-1914," Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 699. Yale
University, August 1993.
Hollis, Aidan, and Arthur Sweetman. "Microcredit in Pre-Famine
Ireland." Economics Working Paper Archives, ewp-eh/9704002. April
1997a.
--. "Complementarity, Competition and Institutional Development:
The Irish Loan Funds through Three Centuries." Economics Working
Paper Archives, ewp-eh/9704003. March 1997b.
Holmstrom, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom. "Regulating Trade among
Agents," Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol.
146 (March 1990), pp. 85-105.
Itoh, Hideshi. "Coalitions, Incentives, and Risk Sharing,"
Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 60 (August 1993), pp. 410-27.
Krasa, Stefan, and Anne P. Villamil. "A Theory of Optimal Bank
Size," Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 44 (October 1992), pp. 725-49.
Montgomery, Richard, Debapriya Bhattacharya, and David Hulme.
"Credit for the Poor in Bangladesh," in David Hulme and Paul
Mosley, eds., Finance Against Poverty, Vol. II. London: Routledge, 1996.
Morduch, Jonathan. "The Microfinance Revolution."
Manuscript. 1997.
Mutua, Alvert Kimanthi. "The Juhudi Credit Scheme: From a
Traditional Integrated Method to a Financial Systems Approach," in
Maria Otero and Elisabeth Rhyne, eds., The New World of Microenterprise
Finance. West Hartford, Conn.: Kumarian Press, 1994.
1996 Directory of U.S. Microenterprise Programs. Self-Employment
Learning Project. Washington: The Aspen Institute, 1997.
Prescott, Edward Simpson, and Robert M. Townsend. "Theory of the
Firm: Applied Mechanism Design," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Working Paper No. 96-2. June 1996.
Ramakrishnan, R. T. S., and A. V. Thakor. "Cooperation versus
Competition in Agency," Journal of Law, Economics, &
Organization, vol. 7 (Fall 1991), pp. 248-83.
Rashid, Mansoora, and Robert M. Townsend. "Targeting Credit and
Insurance: Efficiency, Mechanism Design, and Program Evaluation."
Manuscript. 1993.
Segal, Lewis M. "Flexible Employment: Composition and
Trends," Working Paper 95-19. Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, December 1995.
Srinivasan, Aruna. "Intervention in Credit Markets and
Development Lending," Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic
Review, vol. 79 (May/June 1994), pp. 13-27.
Stiglitz, Joseph E. "Peer Monitoring and Credit Markets,"
World Bank Economic Review, vol. 4 (September 1990), pp. 351-66.
Townsend, Robert M. "Community Development Banking and Financial
Institutions Act: A Critique with Recommendations," in Proceedings
of the 30th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition (Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 11-13, 1994), pp. 538-46.
Varian, Hal R. "Monitoring Agents with Other Agents,"
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, vol. 146 (March
1990), pp. 153-74.
Wenner, Mark D. "Group Credit: A Means to Improve Information
Transfer and Loan Repayment Performance," Journal of Development
Studies, vol. 32 (December 1995), pp. 263-81.
Zeldes, Stephen. "Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An
Empirical Investigation," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 97
(April 1989), pp. 305-46.