Investing in equities: can it help social security?
Dotsey, Michael
Social Security is in trouble. A recent report by the U.S. General
Accounting Office (1997) indicates that absent any changes to the
current system, payments to beneficiaries will exceed revenues from
payroll taxes in 2012, and by 2029 the Social Security Trust Fund will
be depleted. That Social Security is in trouble is not really news. The
system has a long history of being underfinanced, and the current
difficulties are not historically large. Recently, the 1994-1996
Advisory Council on Social Security issued its report with various
recommendations for putting the system on firm financial footing. From
an economic perspective, making the Social Security System sound is not
a difficult task. There exist a multitude of ways for doing so, but most
involve either increases in taxes, reductions in benefits, or both.
Thus, any plan inherently involves difficult political decisions.
However, one part of the solution that is included in each of the three
separate plans that were presented to the Commissioner of Social
Security was the recommendation that some portion of the current trust
fund be invested in the stock market. By taking advantage of the higher
returns earned by equities, this recommendation seemingly would reduce
the increases in taxes or the reduction in benefits that would be needed
to return the Social Security System to financial viability.
In this article I address the economic merits of this
recommendation. My analysis suggests that the ownership of the capital
stock has very few consequences for the government's budget. The
economic opportunities available to society are not increased by a
transfer of capital from the private sector to the government. In short,
there is no free lunch.
1. A BRIEF HISTORY
The Inception of Social Security
Social Security was created in 1935 as an intergenerational transfer
program from workers to retirees. Its design also provided for income
redistribution among the elderly, because replacement rates (the ratio
of the benefit paid in the first year of retirement to taxable earnings
in the preceding year) are higher for low-income workers than for
high-income workers. Social Security is a pay-as-you-go system. In years
when the revenue from Social Security taxes exceeds outlays, the U.S.
Treasury uses the proceeds to finance other expenditures, thereby
reducing the level of government debt from what it otherwise would have
been. There exists the accounting fiction of a trust fund, but from an
economic perspective no such fund exists. The lower level of government
debt makes it more likely that future claims will be honored, but there
is no dedicated set of securities belonging to the Social Security
Administration that has the same legal standing as a government bond
issued to a private citizen. Because it is a pay-as-you-go system, there
is the potential that, for a variety of reasons, promised payments could
become increasingly difficult to honor. This is what has happened
repeatedly to the Social Security System.
Despite its problems, the Social Security System has been
remarkably successful in terms of its growth and its economic
importance. At the time of its creation, the old age and survivors
insurance (OASI) part of the program was fairly small, with benefits
equaling 0.03 percent of GDP in 1940. By 1950 that percentage had risen
to only 0.33 percent of GDP, but by 1996 it had risen to over 4 percent
of GDP. In terms of taxable payrolls, benefits were 10.7 percent in
1994, which is very close to the 10 percent envisioned in the 1939 Act
(see Miron and Weil [1997]) and represented roughly 19 percent of all
federal outlays. Over time, the fraction of the labor force covered by
Social Security has risen from 63.7 percent in 1940 to 97.6 percent in
1993.
Social Security has also played a major role in reducing the
percent of those over 65 who live below the poverty line. In 1959, 35.2
percent of the elderly were characterized as poor. By 1994, that figure
had dropped to 11.7 percent. The increase in Social Security benefits is
in large part responsible for this decline. Expressed in terms of 1995
dollars, the average monthly benefit in 1950 was $269.30, in 1960 it was
$381.38, and in 1995 it was $719.80. Also, the number of beneficiaries
has risen substantially from 222,488 in 1940 to 37.5 million in 1995. In
terms of percentages of the population over 65, only 7 percent received
benefits in 1940, whereas 91.3 percent received benefits in 1995. More
importantly from the standpoint of helping the poor, Social Security
currently provides over 90 percent of income for half the seniors below
the poverty line and 50 percent of income for two-thirds of all
beneficiaries.
As the preceding figures show, the scope and amount of coverage
has increased greatly since the inception of Social Security. The
original act promised benefits only to those who contributed, but in
1939 benefits were extended to spouses and surviving widows. Over time,
various changes have expanded the scope of Social Security, with perhaps
the most important extension resulting from the 1950 Act that brought 10
million new workers into the system. Also, various changes in computing
benefits, coupled with high inflation and growth in wages, served to
increase benefits, which consequently grew much faster than the economy.
Initially a 2 percent tax rate, equally divided between employer
and employee, was levied on income up to $3,000. The first benefits to
contributing retirees were not to be paid until 1942, but the 1939 Act
moved that date forward to 1940. Further, no benefits were to be paid in
any month that a retiree earned more than $15. To put that figure in
perspective, the average annual wage in 1937 was $979. This feature of
the system indicates that Social Security was in part envisioned as
insurance against destitution. However, under the assumption of no
inflation and no wage growth, the replacement rate for a worker earning
$1,000 for 45 years, and retiring at age 65 in 2002, would have been
0.60 under the initial act. That means that this hypothetical worker
would have received $600 a year in perpetuity, implying that the initial
act also possessed features that went far beyond mere insurance. A
60-year-old worker earning the same salary ($1,000) and retiring in 1942
would have received benefits of $200 a year. With the extension of
benefit eligibility, the 1939 Act also reduced the replacement rate to
0.43. Thus, our hypothetical worker would receive only $430 upon
retirement, while his spouse would receive $215.
Under the 1939 Act, the combined tax rates on employer and
employee were 2 percent and were scheduled to rise to 6 percent by 1949
and remain fixed thereafter. Full benefits would not begin until 1991,
when workers with a full history of contributions would be retiring.
According to projections at the time, the internal real rate of return
for those retirees would be 3.9 percent, not much above the 3 percent
rate of return that was projected on the accumulated trust fund. Or, in
more relevant terms, the internal rate of return would not be too far
above the economy's growth rate and benefits could be paid by
issuing government debt without increasing the debt-to-GDP ratio. Thus
the initial planning attempted to create a sustainable system.
A History of Problems
Over its history the Social Security System probably has never been
sound. The chief reason is that Congress tended to make benefits more
generous than originally intended and refused to raise tax rates as fast
as the 1939 Act prescribed. Tax rates did not reach 6 percent until
1960. Also, economic factors such as usage growth interacted with the
methodology for calculating benefits, increased the level of benefits in
unintended ways during the 1970s, and placed the system under tremendous
strain. Corrections to the methodology were not made quickly enough, and
tax rates were not raised sufficiently, so that the system almost
defaulted in the early 1980s. Demographic changes also conspired to make
the system less sound than it would have b-Xeen under stable population
growth. Thus, under current law someone just entering the labor force
will earn a rate of return on Social Security contributions that is
probably negative, while the rate of return for those that have already
retired is significantly higher than was intended.
The 1950 Act, which brought in 10 million new workers, also
calculated their benefits in a way that provided them with large
transfers. Expansion in scope need not have been detrimental to the
soundness of the system, but these workers received benefits that were
based on their wage history after 1950 rather than on their entire wage
history. Thus, individuals from this group who retired soon after 1950
received full benefits and a large transfer from the existing system.
Basically for this group the link between the replacement rate and the
number of years of paying into the system was cut, and these new
retirees received the same benefits as those who had been in the system
since its inception. To accommodate this change, average benefits were
slightly reduced.
Perhaps the most severe problem for the system was created by the
1972 Act, which for the first time included automatic price adjustments.
Previously, such adjustments were made on an ad hoc basis. However, the
adjustment procedure ended up overcompensating workers and made
replacement rates unstable (for an excellent discussion see Munnell
[1977]). The cost-of-living adjustment for retirees did not present a
problem. Rather, the calculated replacement rates for newly retired
workers were overstated. In essence these workers received an increase
in their benefits that accounted not only for inflation but for wage
growth as well. Because wages tend to rise with inflation, new retirees
received a double counting. The amount of initial benefits also
increased with the disparity between real wage growth and inflation. In
this manner, the economic climate at the time, along with the unsound method of computing initial benefits, placed great stress on the system,
with replacement rates rising from 47.9 percent in 1970 to 66.7 percent
in 1980. As a result, the individual that retired in the 1970s received
the largest net transfer of any cohort under Social Security.
The mistakes in the 1972 Act led to the rescue package of 1977,
which constituted the largest peace-time tax increase in U.S. history.
The rescue package also stopped initial benefits from rising faster than
wage growth. The system was pronounced sound for the rest of the century
and well into the next one. Unfortunately, the pronouncement was wrong.
By 1981, there was a high probability that the system would not be able
to meet its promised benefits. A commission was appointed to deal with
the problem. Its lack of complete success is in part why Social Security
restructuring is currently receiving so much attention. The 1983 Act did
raise the schedule of tax rates and the annual maximum on taxable
earnings. It also effectively reduced benefits by taxing some portion of
Social Security payments. Finally, it gradually raised the age to 67 at
which full benefits were paid for the cohort born in 1960. Combined,
these changes averted a problem of failing to honor legislated benefits
but failed to solve the problem of long-term insolvency.
The Current Problem
The Social Security System as currently constituted is not
actuarially sound. In this regard, the important date is 2012, because
that is when expenditures will exceed receipts. At that point the
federal government will have to raise taxes, reduce government spending,
or increase its borrowing in order to make the promised payments to
retirees. Beyond that date, the revenue shortfall will increase and the
necessary adjustments will be more dramatic. It is estimated that the
revenue shortfall will be $57 billion in 2015 and grow to $232 billion
in 2020. Put in perspective, current total OASI payments are
approximately $308 billion dollars. This deficit will occur in part
because there will be an estimated 50.4 million beneficiaries in 2015,
up from 37.5 million in 1995.
As mentioned earlier, the system's current troubles are a
consequence of increasing benefits, due both to the increased number of
retirees and the more generous benefits that each retiree receives. One
way to gauge the increase in the level of benefits is to compare them
with average wages. For example, in 1953 the maximum benefit was
equivalent to 30.5 percent of the average wage. By 1981 the
corresponding figure was greater than 50 percent, and in 1995 it equaled
60.5 percent (Marcks 1997). Unquestionably, retirees' benefits have
been rising relative to the tax base that can support those benefits.
The problem is also one of demographics. In 1945 there were 42
workers per retiree. In 1995 that number had shrunk to 3.3, and it is
projected that in 2030 there will only be 2 workers per retiree.
Furthermore, the life expectancy of individuals has increased since the
inception of the system, meaning that a greater fraction of contributors
have become beneficiaries. Also, the length of retirement has increased.
In 1940 a 65-year-old male and female had a life expectancy of 12 and 13
years, respectively. By 2015 the comparable numbers will be 16 and 20
years.
These demographic features imply that maintaining the current
level of benefits requires a significant increase in taxes. The Report
of the 1994-1996 Advisory Council on Social Security (Department of
Health and Human Services 1997) indicates that taxes would have to be
raised immediately by 2.13 percent to attain 75-year balance.(1) These
calculations explicitly take into account interest payments and payments
on principal from the fictitious trust fund. To make these payments, the
government would have to increase the level of the debt, reduce
spending, or increase tax revenue from other sources.(2) Thus, total tax
payments could be substantially higher if all forms of taxes are
considered. Waiting to adjust tax rates will only make the problem
worse.
2. THE STOCK MARKET TO THE RESCUE?
Over the period 1926 to 1993, the real return on the Standard &
Poor's 500 averaged 9 percent, while the real yield on
intermediate-term U.S. government bonds averaged only 2.2 percent. This
difference in yields is large. For example, earning 9 percent implies
that your investment doubles approximately every eight years as compared
to every 35 years with a 2.2 percent return. Furthermore, in every
22-year period since 1926, equities have outperformed bonds. These
considerations have spurred many observers to argue that investing at
least some portion of the Social Security Trust Fund in equities can
avert the financial difficulties facing the system.
In one sense the proposition is true. Increasing the yield on the
trust fund can make the Social Security System more viable in isolation.
However, it can only do so by making the rest of the government worse
off. On net, an individual taxpayer will be little affected by this
investment policy. In order for the government, or some part of it, to
take an equity position, the government as a whole must issue more
bonds. This swap of paper claims with the public affects the allocations
and the risk characteristics of the respective portfolios but
quantitatively does not have any appreciable effect on the
government's overall budget. The economy cannot produce any more
goods, and although the consumption profile of the representative
household may be somewhat altered, the effects of this alteration are
small. Since taxpayers are the ultimate receivers of any government
earnings or losses, it matters little who owns the capital stock.
A number of economists recognize this fairly simple notion.
Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan expressed the idea
cogently in his recent Remarks at the Abraham Lincoln Award Ceremony of
the Union League of Philadelphia (1996, p. 8), "Bonds and equities
are merely the paper claims to income earning assets, and the value of
the income stream is not determined by short-run changes in the supply
and demand for securities. Rather, equity prices must, in the long run,
reflect the underlying earnings of the corporations on which the
equities are a claim, as well as society's need to be compensated
for postponing consumption into the future and its perception and
attitudes toward risk as a consequence of uncertainty about the future.
Indeed, the total market value of debt plus equities is, to a first
approximation, likely to be unaffected by a shift in the balance of
paper claims." These sentiments are also reflected in the views of
Herbert Stein (1997, p. A18), "... privatizing the Social Security
funds would not add to national saving, private investment, or the
national income and would not allow the system to earn more income
without anyone earning less."
Others, however, have argued to the contrary and have made the
purchase of equities by the trust fund seem like a free lunch. For
example, editorial commentary in Barron's Online by Thomas G.
Donlan (1997) states that "Unless the system invests in private
enterprise and those investments continue to earn historically high
returns the Baby Boom generation will pay for its own retirement."
Investing in equities is a major component of all three plans presented
by the 1994-1996 Advisory Council on Social Security (Department of
Health and Human Services 1997).
The Trust Fund
The Social Security System is but one part of the government. It is
the largest part, with transfers amounting to 22 percent of government
expenditures in 1995. The system's trust fund is really a myth.
Social Security receives contributions or taxes from workers and their
employers and pays out benefits to retirees, their dependents, and those
on disability. Excesses in receipts over expenditures are handed over to
the U.S. Treasury to be used in financing other governmental activities.
Employing an accounting fiction, the Social Security System treats these
transfers as investment in government securities and adds them to an
imaginary portfolio that also collects fictitious interest payments.
From the perspective of the government's total budget, this
practice implies that the Treasury issues fewer bonds to thc,, public
than it would if there were no surplus received from Social Security.
Unlike Treasury bills issued to the public, however, the IOUs from the
Treasury to Social Security are not counted as government debt.
What would happen if the Social Security System invested in
equities? The system would currently turn over less surplus to the
Treasury, and the Treasury would have to issue more bonds to the public.
Again, from the perspective of the government as a whole, this
transaction amounts to a trade of bonds for equities with the public.
Can such a trade, benefit the public? Since equities are a claim on
firms, government ownership of stock amounts to government ownership of
some portion of the country's capital stock. So the preceding
question can be rephrased. Does it matter who owns the capital stock?
The analysis presented below attempts to shed light on that question. It
turns out that the policy of government investment in equities has
either only minor or no effects on the government's budget and the
saving rate of the economy. Whether the government's financing
decisions have any economic effect depends on its ability to transfer
risk across individuals. In the models considered in Section 3, that
ability is absent, and hence government portfolio decisions are
irrelevant. The overlapping generations model of Section 4 allows some
scope for more efficient risk-sharing and the government's
portfolio decision does affect economic behavior. Quantitatively, this
effect turns out to be small.
3. A MODEL WITH INFINITELY LIVED AGENTS
In this section I use a model populated by infinitely lived agents
(or more generally, the dynastic families possessing bequest motives as
in Barro [1974]) to explore whether government investment in private
capital affects the amount of tax revenue needed to support a given
stream of transfer payments. Answering this question is analogous to
answering the question of whether investment by the Social Security
Administration in the stock market would have any impact on the
financing of a given stream of Social Security payments. I analyze this
question in a sequence of models that highlight the key issue, namely
that equity premium considerations are unimportant and it is only the
transferring of risk across generations that has any effect on economic
outcomes.(3) The model with infinitely lived agents clearly makes the
point that when there is no possibility of transferring risk among
agents, because all agents are essentially the same, the existence of an
equity premium does not in any way allow government ownership of capital
to influence economic outcomes.
To begin, I shall consider a world in which all transfers and
taxes are lump sum. Private agents own some portion of the capital stock
and the government owns the rest. The government may also issue debt. It
finances transfer payments and the interest payments on debt through its
earnings on capital and through taxes. I will show that in such a world
the behavior of individuals is unaffected by the portion of the capital
stock owned by the government. Essentially, any distribution of
ownership of the capital stock is consistent with the initial path of
transfers and taxes and has no effect on the consumption or saving
decisions of individuals. In other words, the government's
portfolio decision is irrelevant. I shall then extend this model to
include distortionary taxes and show that the results are unchanged.
The Model with Lump Sum Taxes
This model economy is populated by people who live forever or, more
generally, by the dynastic families in Barro (1974). Output is
stochastic and is produced via a standard neoclassical production
function using capital and labor. The government finances lump sum
transfers through lump sum taxes, the issuance of debt, and the return
from its ownership of capital.
Individual Decisions
To start the analysis, consider the problem of the individual agent
who wishes to maximize lifetime well-being or utility subject to a
budget constraint. The individual owns some capital that earns
[Rho]([s.sub.t]) in state s at time t. That is, the return to capital is
stochastic and, while one observes the actual return in any given
period, future returns are uncertain and depend on the state of the
economy in that period. Individuals also receive transfer payments from
the government Tr([s.sub.t]) and pay taxes T([s.sub.t]). These transfers
and taxes may, but need not, depend on the state of the economy.
Individuals also own government bonds, b([s.sub.t]), that pay
r([s.sub.t]) units of consumption in all states in period t + 1.
Finally, given a capital stock at the beginning of period t, agents
choose how much capital to bring into the next period, k([s.sub.t]), and
how much to consume this period, c([s.sub.t]).
Formally, the representative agent maximizes discounted expected
lifetime utility
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to per-period budget constraints in each possible state
[s.sub.t].
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where w is the real wage rate, n is exogenous labor supply, and [Rho]
is the rate of return on capital. For simplicity, I assume that capital
fully depreciates each period. Thus, agents are maximizing their
utility, taking into account expectations of all possible future events.
In the notation above, [s.sub.t] is the realization of one of finitely
many states of the economy at time t. [s.sup.t] represents a particular
history of realizations up to time t. That is, [s.sup.t] = ([s.sub.0],
[s.sub.1], ... [s.sub.t]) is a particular history of events up to time
t. The set St represents all the possible histories that can occur. Each
event occurs with probability [Pi]([s.sup.t]) and each history occurs
with probability [Pi]([s.sup.t]). Each agent rents out labor and capital
to firms in competitive rental markets and earns the appropriate
marginal product of each factor.
The first-order conditions for optimal bond and capital
accumulation are
(1a) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
(1b)[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
These conditions imply that agents accumulate assets so that they are
just indifferent between consuming an extra unit of consumption in any
particular state [s.sub.t] or investing in either another bond or an
extra unit of capital and consuming the proceeds of that investment next
period. Also, since a government bond returns the same amount in each
state at t + 1, it is less risky than holding capital whose return is
uncertain. The interest on a government bond will, therefore, generally
be less than the expected return on capital. That is, capital will on
average earn a premium over bonds with the amount of the premium
depending on the agent's aversion to risk and the underlying
riskiness of the return on capital. It is this feature of bonds and
capital that initially seems to suggest that the government, by issuing
bonds and owning some more capital, can reduce the tax burden associated
with any stream of transfer payments. However, as the first-order
conditions make clear, both of these choices have the same value when
adjusted for risk, namely the current marginal utility of consumption.
Thus, there is no free lunch.
The Government
Each period the government makes some transfers, collects some taxes,
and adjusts its portfolio by either issuing or repurchasing some
government bonds or buying or selling some capital, x (or claims to the
capital, which amount to the same thing). In each state, the
government's net holding of assets obeys
(2) [b.sup.s]([s.sup.t]) - x([s.sup.t])= b([s.sup.t-1])[1 +
r([s.sup.t-1])] + Tr([s.sup.t]) - T([s.sup.t]) - [Rho]([s.sup.t]) x
([s.sup.t-1]).
It is clear from this expression that, all other things equal, an
increase in the capital stock held by the government at time t- 1
reduces the taxes that are necessary to maintain the same net asset
position. The experiment we are interested in, however, is not what
happens if someone donates an extra unit of capital to the government
but what happens when the government increases its holdings of capital
by issuing additional debt.
Market Clearing
For any allocation of consumption, bonds, and capital to be an
equilibrium, it must be consistent with the resource constraints of the
economy and with supply equaling demand. In particular, for each state
the following equations hold:
(3) c([s.sup.t]) + k([s.sup.t]) + x([s.sup.t]) =
A([s.sub.t])[[k([s.sup.t-1]) + x([s.sup.t-1]).sup.[Alpha]]
[n.sup.1-[Alpha]]
and
(4) [b.sup.s] ([s.sup.t]) = [b.sup.d] ([s.sup.t]).
Equation (3) indicates that the amount consumed and invested must
equal the output produced in the current period, and equation (4)
requires that the supply of bonds issued by the government must be equal
to the demand for these bonds by the public.
Solution
The consumption decision of agents will now be shown to be
independent of portfolio decisions of the government. Alternatively,
agents do not care who owns the capital stock since they are indifferent
between holding an extra unit of government debt or an extra unit of
capital. In particular, consumption in any state is given by
(5) c([s.sup.t]) = (1 - [Beta])A([s.sub.t]) K)[s.sup.t-1],
where K is the aggregate capital stock equal to k + x. The
accumulation of private capital is then expressed as
(6) k([s.sup.t]) = [Beta]A([s.sub.t])K([s.sup.t-1]) -
x([s.sup.t-1]).
As long as government capital does not exceed
[Beta]A([s.sub.t])K([s.sup.t-1]), the above solutions satisfy the
first-order conditions of agents and do not violate the economy's
overall resource constraint. Thus, for any supportable path of taxes and
transfer payments, individuals are indifferent as to who owns the
capital stock.
The Model with Distortionary Taxes
Next consider the case where the government raises revenue through
distortionary taxation. In this setting it is not so easy to represent
analytically the solution to the decision problem of agents. However, by
looking at the individual's first-order conditions and budget
constraints along with the budget constraint and transversality condition of the government, one sees that the proportion of the capital
stock owned by the government is irrelevant.
Individual Decisions
With distortionary taxes on both labor and interest income, the
representative agent maximizes lifetime utility subject to the following
per-period budget constraint,
(7)[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Unlike the previous budget constraint, the government now taxes wages
and the return on capital and bonds at the rate r. The first-order
necessary conditions for optimal bond holdings and investment are
(8a)[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
(8b) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The consumer's accumulation of assets must also satisfy the
transversality condition,
(9) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the
price of a contingent claim. In the above expression [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] indicates a particular history of
states from t to t + j and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] is the set of all possible histories.
Government
The government's budget constraint is given by
(10) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and indicates that the government's net liability position
depends on its debt, the net interest paid on that debt, its revenues
from taxing income earned from capital and labor, as well as the revenue
it earns on its own capital stock.(4) The budget constraint implies that
in states where capital has a relatively high rate of return, some debt
is retired, while in states where capital's return is low, debt is
issued. The government's net asset position must also satisfy the
transversality condition
(11) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Equilibrium
Formally, the definition of an equilibrium is given by Equilibrium:
Given the initial conditions b([s.sub.t-1]), x([s.sub.t-1]), and
k([s.sub.t-1]), an equilibrium is a sequence of quantities and prices
{b(s), k(s),x(s), K(s), c(s), w(s), r(s), [Rho](s), [Tau](s), Tr(s)} for
all histories [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
satisfying the individual's first-order conditions (8a) and (8b),
the individual's budget constraint (7), the government's
budget constraint (10), the economy's resource constraint (3), and
the transversality conditions of both the individual and the government
(9) and (11).
Irrelevance Proposition:(5) Suppose that {b(s), k(s),x(s), K(s),
c(s), w(s), r(s), [Rho](s), [Tau](s), Tr(s)} is an equilibrium, then any
{[bar]b(s), [bar]k(s), [bar]x(s), K(s), c(s), w(s), r(s), [Rho](s),
[Tau](s), Tr(s)} is an equilibrium if [bar]b(s), [bar]k(s), [bar]x(s)
satisfy (a) k(s), [bar]x(s) [is greater than or equal to] 0 and k(s) +
[bar]x(s) = [bar]k(s), and (b) b(s) is defined recursively by (10).
Proof: The individual's first-order conditions and the
economy's resource constraint are satisfied because the real
allocations are identical in the two equilibriums. The individual's
transversality condition is, therefore, also satisfied. Equilibrium in
the goods market and condition (b) imply that the household's
budget constraint is also satisfied. Examining the lifetime budget
constraint of the government from date t onward, one derives that
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Because the first two terms are the same for both equilibriums, the
last term must be the same for both equilibriums. Therefore, the
transversality condition must hold for the second equilibrium. Hence,
different distributions of the capital stock do not affect the aggregate
capital stock, consumption, rates of return, tax rates, wages, or
transfer payments.
As demonstrated in these models, the ownership of the capital
stock has no effect on economic outcomes and is not an avenue that can
be used to rescue the Social Security System in an economy where agents
are altruistically linked to future generations and, hence, behave as if
they were infinitely lived.
4. A MODEL WITH FINITE LIVED AGENTS
The previous two cases demonstrate that a premium in the return to
capital relative to bonds is not sufficient for government portfolio
decisions to have any real effect on consumer decisions. Changes in
portfolio allocations do not affect the lifetime opportunities of the
average individual, so they do not have any real consequence. In a model
with finite lived agents, however, portfolio decisions generally will
affect the economic behavior of consumers--not because capital earns a
higher return than bonds but because a change in the portfolio of old
agents must affect their consumption decisions. In the last period of
life it is the only decision they have left to make. Thus, the
government ownership of capital means that the current old agents hold
more bonds. This consideration implies that their consumption stream has
different risk characteristics than if the government owned no capital.
Because the government's ownership of capital can transfer risk
between current and future generations, it can change behavior.(6) In
the setting of infinitely lived agents, there is no one to whom they can
transfer risk. But because we are now considering different generations,
there is the potential for risk transfer. How big an effect policies
involving portfolio composition may have is an open question. In this
section, some rough estimates are formed in a simple two-period
overlapping generations model. The results suggest that government
ownership of capital may not be the boon that its proponents suggest.
The Individual
In the first period of life, a young individual works a fixed number
of hours, n. With his earnings, he pays taxes, saves to finance
consumption when old, and purchases goods for current consumption.
Saving takes the form of ownership of the capital stock and government
bonds. When the individual reaches old age, he receives transfers from
the government, rental on the capital stock that then fully depreciates,
and after-tax interest plus principal on his government bonds. With this
income he purchases consumption goods. In this model economy production
is stochastic and transfer payments are fixed. Formally, the
individual's problem is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
subject to the budget constraints
(13a) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
(13b) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where the last constraint must hold for each possible state
[s.sub.t+1] drawn from the set [S.sub.t+1]. The superscripts y and o
refer to young and old, respectively.
Here, as in the previous examples, s indexes the various possible
states that can occur. The above specification assumes that agents know
what state they are currently in but are unsure about next period's
state. All they know is the probability, [Pi], of any particular state
occurring. Specifically, at time t, agents know how productive the
economy is, the transfers that are given to both the current old and
current young, the current tax rates on labor income, [Tau], and
interest income, [[Tau].sup.k], the current wage rates, and the promised
rate of interest on government bonds. They do not, however, know what
these variables will be in the future. Thus, they attempt to maximize
not only the utility from current consumption but expected utility from
future consumption.
The first-order conditions for the problem are
(14a) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(14b) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(14c) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and
(14d) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where a prime indicates the first derivative and
[[Lambda].sub.y]([s.sup.t]) and [[Lambda].sup.0]([s.sup.t+1] are the
multipliers associated with the constraints (13a)and (13b). The last two
constraints give the efficient consumption-saving decisions of the
current young. These conditions state that at an optimum the marginal
utility of forgoing one unit of consumption today must be equal to
expected marginal utility of additional consumption tomorrow earned from
the proceeds of investing in another unit of either capital or bonds.
Notice that the last two equations also imply that the certain yield on
a bond and the expected after-tax yield on capital must be such that the
agent is indifferent between holding a bond or capital. As before,
because the return on capital is uncertain, the premium that capital
earns over bonds depends on the agent's degree of risk aversion.
Firms
Firms produce output by employing the labor of the young and renting
capital from the old and from the government. The production function is
constant returns to scale and is given by
(15) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where Y is aggregate per capita output, and K is the aggregate per
capita capital stock. The maximization of profits implies that each
factor receives its marginal product, which will depend on the
productivity shock A([s.sub.t]).
Government
The government issues bonds and purchases capital. It also supplies
transfers to the young, [T.sup.y], and the old, [T.sup.0]. These latter
transfers may be thought of as Social Security although in reality the
old receive more than just OASI payments alone. The government also
raises revenue by taxing wage and capital income as well as the interest
earned on bonds. Specifically, the government's budget constraint
is
(16) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where B(s) is the per capita aggregate supply of government bonds and
x(s) is the per capita capital stock owned by the government. The
government's net indebtedness B - x is positively influenced by its
repayment of existing debt, the interest on that debt, and transfer
payments. The government's earnings on its capital stock, as well
as the revenue from the taxation of labor, bonds, and the private
sector's return on capital, all reduce the government's
indebtedness.
Equilibrium
Equilibrium in this model is defined as a sequence of quantities
(consumption, capital, and bond allocations), factor prices (wages,
interest rates, and rental rates), and taxes and transfers that are
consistent with each agent's maximization of expected utility, and
the firms' maximization of profits. Equilibrium satisfies the
individual's budget constraints (13a) and (13b), the
government's budget constraint (16), and the government's
transversality condition and results in the clearing of both the bond
and goods markets. In particular for each possible history,
(17a) Y([s.supt]) = [c.sup.o]([.sup.t]) + [c.sup.y]([s.sup.t]) +
K([s.sup.t])
and
(17b) B([s.sup.t]) = b([s.sup.t]).
Also, the per capita capital stock must equal its individual
components, i.e., K(s) = k(s) + x(s).
Unlike the case where agents are in effect infinitely lived, a
similar irrelevance proposition does not apply. In the overlapping
generations model, two separate budget constraints, one for the current
old, (13b), and one for the current young, (13a), must hold
simultaneously. Notice that the sum of these two budget constraints is
the same as the budget constraint for the infinitely lived agent. Thus
any allocation that satisfies the economy's resource constraints
and the government's budget constraint will satisfy the sum of the
two agents' budget constraints; hence, total consumption will be
unchanged. However, this allocation will not generally satisfy each
budget constraint separately, and individual consumption will vary with
changes in the distribution of capital. The variation in individual
consumption implies that rates of return will have to change as well and
that the same sequence of tax rates cannot support an identical path of
transfer payments.
Analyzing the Effects of Government Ownership of Capital
To analyze the effects of government ownership of capital, I analyze
the effect on average tax rates of changes in the proportion of the
capital stock owned by the government. In doing so, the pattern of
transfer payments and the government's net asset position, B - x,
are fixed. As a result the experiment does not create any additional
government indebtedness and maintains the level of benefits received by
the elderly. The results of this experiment are suggestive but not
definitive. The model I use is admittedly stylized. Moreover, I do not
investigate plausible alternative fiscal policies, including those
fixing the net present discounted value of government liabilities rather
than fixing them in each and every period. The latter policy would
produce a smoother stream of taxes than the one analyzed here but would
be computationally much harder to implement. Also, because of the
assumption that people live for two periods only, the benefits of
risk-sharing are likely to be overemphasized in this framework. Old
agents are required to hold all of the capital stock; thus any ownership
of capital by the government reduces their exposure to rate-of-return
risk. If the model included more periods, old agents could shift some of
this burden to agents in their middle ages and thus reduce the
risk-sharing benefits that ensue from the government's ownership of
capital. The model also excludes other forms of risk-sharing
arrangements, such as capital-gains loss-offsets and progressive
taxation. Adding these features to the model would further reduce the
gains to intergenerational risk-sharing.(7)
The equations used to solve the model include one that specifies
the policy of fixing the government's net indebtedness and an
equation that specifies the taxation of labor income relative to
interest income. Equations 13(a,b), 14(c,d), 15, 16, and the two
first-order conditions that determine the marginal product of capital and labor are also employed. Together with a behavioral relationship
that specifies the government's purchase of capital, the solution
to the model involves solving 11 independent equations in 11 unknowns.
The variables solved for are the privately held capital stock, the
publicly held capital stock, government bond issue, consumption by the
young, consumption by the old, output, the interest rate paid on bonds,
the rental rate on capital, wages, and the tax rates on labor and
interest income, respectively. This system can be reduced to three
equations that determine the interest rate, the aggregate capital stock,
and the tax rate. In deriving these equations, I assume that the
government maintains ownership of a fixed percentage of the capital
stock, tr. It is also assumed that utility displays constant relative
risk aversion and takes the form u(c) = [c.sup.1-[Sigma]]-1 / 1-[Sigma].
Thus, the solution to this three-equation system yields the policy
function for K([s.sup.t]) = [h.sub.k][K([s.sup.t-1]),A([s.sub.t]),
A([s.sub.t]), A([s.sub.t-1])], the functions [Tau]([s.sup.t]) =
[h.sub.[Tau]] [K([s.sup.t-1]), A([s.sub.t]), A([s.sub.t-1])], and
r([s.sup.t]): [h.sub.r][K([s.sup.t-1]), A([s.sup.t]), A([s.sub.t-1])].
To analyze the effects of government investment in capital, two
slightly different models are simulated, one in which only labor is
taxed, [[Tau].sup.k] = 0, and one in which all income is taxed at the
same rate, [Tau] = [[Tau].sup.k]. For given values of transfers and net
government indebtedness, I then compare tax rates and the aggregate
capital stock in model economies in which the government owns 0, 2.5, 5,
and 10 percent of the capital stock. The proposal of investing up to 40
percent of the Social Security Trust Fund in equities would result in a
much smaller proportion of government ownership of the capital stock
than any of the percentages considered. In 1995 the value of the Social
Security Trust Fund was approximately $458 billion, while the value of
traded equity was greater than $7.7 trillion. Thus, the experiments
will, on this dimension, overstate the effects of the current proposal.
In essence, I am comparing the equilibrium outcomes of four different
economies. Transitional questions are, therefore, not addressed by this
experiment.
Calibration
In calibrating the model, I envision a period as corresponding to 25
years. [Beta] is set at 0.5, which corresponds to an annual discount
factor of roughly 0.973. Labor's share of output, [Alpha], is 2/3,
and the coefficient of relative risk aversion, (7, is set at 10,
implying an average equity premium between 5.7 percent and 7.1 percent.
Transfers to the old generation are set to equal 4 percent of
steady-state output in the model. When only labor is taxed, such
transfers are equal to the actual percentage of output distributed by
OASI. The government's indebtedness is I percent of output and
transfers to the young are roughly 2.5 percent of output, implying a
steady-state tax rate on labor of 10.67 percent. This tax rate is close
to the current tax rate of 10.52 percent on the OASI portion of the
Social Security tax. Thus, the labor-tax-only model is calibrated to
approximate the tax rate and the transfers that actually occur. Allowing
the government also to tax capital increases the tax base and results in
a lower steady-state tax rate and a somewhat higher level of capital and
more output. The fraction of output transferred to the old is,
therefore, also somewhat lower at 3.65 percent, although the old are
receiving the same transfer in both models.
To analyze the effect on the average tax rate of government
ownership of capital, I simulate both model economies over four
generations or periods 1,000 times and take averages of the tax rates
and capital stock that are produced by the simulations. Each simulation
is started at capital's nonstochastic steady state, which is
invariant to the government's portfolio allocation, and each
succeeding capital stock is solved for based on the preceding realized
value of capital and the past technology shocks. The tax rates and
interest rate that are consistent with this solution are also obtained.
The stochastic process for technology is identically and independently
distributed with mean 1 and standard deviation of 0.08. The standard
deviation was chosen to match the standard deviation of 25-year
cumulative deviations from trend over the post--World War II period.
This figure would represent the standard deviation of any
generation's income from trend income. The standard deviation of
this cumulative deviation from trend output was 0.13. I then used a
standard deviation that was as close to 0.13 as possible and that still
allowed for well-behaved policy functions of the capital stock.(8)
Because of the positive comovement of inputs with the technology shock,
0.13 is an upper bound on the variation in the technology shock. For
example, Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992) obtain estimates of the
relative variability of the technology shock to output anywhere from 48
to 90 percent. Therefore, 0.08 may not be an unreasonable number.
Results
The results of this experiment are reported in Tables 1 and 2. Table
1 includes the results when only labor is taxed, and Table 2 contains
the results when both labor and interest income are taxed. For the case
when only labor is taxed, one sees that average tax rates fall from
0.1059 to 0.1041 as the government increases its ownership of capital
from zero to 10 percent of the aggregate capital stock. At 2.5 percent
ownership, the decline in the average tax rate needed to support the
level of transfer payments is negligible. It follows that ownership of
equities by the Social Security Trust Fund would have little effect on
the viability of the Social Security System. Because the decline in tax
rates is so small, the capital stock is only marginally higher under the
policy of government ownership of capital. In short, this proposed
policy has little economic effect. The case where all income is taxed at
the same rate is qualitatively similar. Basically, each economy's
performance is not influenced by government portfolio decisions.
Table 1 Effects of Government Ownership of Capital (only labor is
taxed)
Fraction of capital owned 0 2.5
Average tax rate 0.1059 0.1054
Standard deviation of tax rate 0.0074 0.0082
Average capital stock 0.1059 0.1061
Standard deviation of capital stock 0.0139 0.0141
Fraction of capital owned 5 10
Average tax rate 0.1049 0.1041
Standard deviation of tax rate 0.0089 0.0105
Average capital stock 0.1063 0.1066
Standard deviation of capital stock 0.0143 0.0147
Table 2 Effects of Government Ownership of Capital (all income is
taxed)
Fraction of capital owned 0 2.5
Average tax rate 0.0610 0.0606
Standard deviation of the tax rate 0.0042 0.0048
Average capital stock 0.1420 0.1421
Standard deviation of the capital stock 0.0163 0.0165
Fraction of capital owned 5 10
Average tax rate 0.0603 0.0596
Standard deviation of the tax rate 0.0053 0.0064
Average capital stock 0.1422 0.1425
Standard deviation of the capital stock 0.0166 0.0169
5. CONCLUSIONS
Current proposals for modifying Social Security have one key feature
in common: namely, investing part of the trust fund in equities.
Advocates believe that such a reallocation of the trust fund's
portfolio will make the system more viable, and maintain the level of
benefits without resorting to large increases in taxes. After analyzing
the effects of such reallocation in some basic economic models, the
results are not encouraging. Even though capital on average earns a
higher rate of return than bonds, the government is not able to take
much advantage of this differential, because only the ability to shift
risk matters. The results in this regard are similar to those found in
Bohn (1997a, b), Mariger (1997), and Smetters (1997). Quantitatively,
this risk shifting from old to young does not significantly affect the
government's budget or the economic behavior of individuals. In
short, under the fiscal policies studied above, there is not much to be
gained by government ownership of the capital stock. Actuarial soundness
of the Social Security System will have to be achieved through other
means.
I wish to thank Douglas Diamond, Andreas Homstein, Thomas Humphrey,
Kent Smetters, and Alex Wolman for many useful suggestions and comments.
The views expressed herein are the author's and do not represent
the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
(1) It should be noted that 75-year balance and actuarial soundness
are not the same thing, because the problems of the system tend to
worsen in the future. Thus 75-year soundness today implies 75-year
unsoundness tomorrow.
(2) If the payments promised by Social Security are equivalent to
payments promised on government bonds, then increasing the level of the
measured debt to pay off these claims does not affect the overall
indebtedness of the U.S. government. This action just transfers a
promise into an explicit security. Treating the promised Social Security
benefits in a similar way to any other government IOU implies that the
true level of the government debt is closer to $17 trillion instead of
the $5 trillion currently calculated.
(3) For a detailed analysis of these issues, see Bohn (1997a, b).
(4) Using the above budget constraint and the first-order conditions
of the representative agent, the government's lifetime budget
constraint as of period t can be expressed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Notice that only the sum of private and government-owned capital
stock enters the right-hand side of equation (11). Therefore, for any
sequence of state-contingent prices, only the total capital stock and
not its distribution affects the tax policies that are necessary to
support a given stream of transfer payments.
(5) I would like to thank Andreas Homstein for suggesting and helping
me with this particular form of the argument.
(6) This idea is discussed in Volume II of the Report of the
1994-1996 Advisory Council on Social Security (Department of Health and
Human Services 1997). The effects of government financing decisions on
intergenerational risk-sharing are formally derived in Bohn (1997a, b),
Smetters (1997), and Mariger (1997). Smetters shows that the
risk-sharing engendered by the government's purchase of equities is
equivalent to options contracts between generations.
(7) I wish to thank Douglas Diamond and Kent Smetters for bringing
these points to my attention.
(8) The models investigated above possess two steady states. One
steady state, which is unstable, occurs at relatively low values of the
capital stock. If the technology shock is too large, the capital stock
potentially can enter this unstable region and the policy functions
diverge.
REFERENCES
Barro, Robert J. "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?" Journal
of Political Economy, vol. 82 (November/December 1974), pp. 1095-1117.
Bohn, Henning. "Risk Sharing in a Stochastic Overlapping
Generations Economy." Manuscript. June 1997a.
--. "Social Security Reform and Financial Markets."
Manuscript. June 1997b.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Martin Eichenbaum. "Current
Real-Business-Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor-Market
Fluctuations," American Economic Review, vol. 82 (June 1992), pp.
430-50.
Department of Health and Human Services. Report of the 1994-1996
Advisory Council on Social Security. Washington: Government Printing
Office, January 1997.
Donlan, Thomas G. "Social Investment: Reform of Social Security
Requires Private Investment and More," Barron's Online
(http://www.barrons.com), January 31, 1997.
Greenspan, Alan. Remarks at the Abraham Lincoln Award Ceremony of the
Union League of Philadelphia. December 6, 1996.
Marcks, Ronald H. "Social Security's Most Basic
Infirmity," Wall Street Journal, January 16, 1997.
Mariger, Randall P. "Social Security Privatization: What It Can
and Cannot Accomplish," Finance and Economics Discussion Series,
No. 1997-32. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs,
June 1997.
Miron, Jeffrey A., and David N. Weil. "The Genesis and Evolution
of Social Security," NBER Working Paper 5949. March 1997.
Munnell, Alicia H. The Future of Social Security. Washington:
Brookings Institution, 1977.
Smetters, Kent. "Investing the Social Security Trust Fund into
Equity: An Options Pricing Approach." Washington: Congressional
Budget Office, July 1997.
Stein, Herbert. "Social Security and the Single Investor,"
Wall Street Journal, February 5, 1997.
U.S. General Accounting Office. Report to the U.S. Senate Committee
on Finance and the House of Representatives Committee on Ways and Means,
Social Security Administration: Significant Challenges Await New
Commissioners. Washington: Government Printing Office, February 1997.