Stored value cards: costly private substitutes for government currency.
Lacker, Jeffrey M.
Stored value cards look like credit cards but are capable of storing
monetary value. There are a number of stored value card systems being
developed in the United States, and some have already been implemented
in Europe and elsewhere. Stored value cards are particularly well-suited
for transactions that would otherwise be carried out with currency and
thus are a private substitute for government fiat money, like private
bank notes. Unlike bank notes, however, stored value cards employ new
technologies that are quite different from, and potentially more costly
than, the coins and paper currency they are aimed at replacing. This
article explores the basic welfare economics of costly private
substitutes for government currency, an important class of payments
system innovations.(1)
Consumers and merchants are likely to benefit from the introduction
of stored value cards. Many might prefer to avoid the inconvenience and
cost of handling paper currency. The usual presumption, in the absence
of market imperfection, is that a successful new product must provide
social benefits in excess of social costs. Issuers will attempt to cover
their costs and earn a competitive return while providing consumers and
merchants with a means of payment they prefer. They can do so if
consumers and merchants are collectively willing to pay enough, either
directly or indirectly, to remunerate issuers for the opportunity cost
of the inputs devoted to the alternative means of payment. If stored
value thrives, standard reasoning suggests that it must be because the
value to consumers and merchants exceeds the cost of provision.
The fact that stored value is a monetary asset provides further
reason to believe that it will be beneficial. Currency is subject to an
implicit tax due to inflation, which reduces its rate of return relative
to other risk-free nominal assets. Like any other (non-lump-sum) tax,
the inflation tax distorts economic decisions, giving rise to deadweight
costs as people try to economize on the use of currency. Private
substitutes for currency provide a means of avoiding the seigniorage tax, alleviating the deadweight loss associated with any given inflation
rate. Stored value cards can increase economic welfare by easing the
burden of inflation.
Stored value cards could be socially wasteful, however. Stored value
liabilities compete with an asset, currency, that pays no interest,
while issuers are free to invest in interest-earning assets. Thus one
portion of the return to stored value issuers is the spread between
market interest rates and the rate of return on currency. This return
far exceeds the government's cost of producing and maintaining the
supply of currency - less than two-tenths of a cent per year per dollar
of currency outstanding.(2) At current interest rates the private
incentive to provide stored value exceeds the social cost of the
currency replaced by as much as 4 or 5 cents per dollar. Thus stored
value cards, if successful, will replace virtually costless government
currency with a substitute that could cost substantially more.
This article presents a model in which both currency and stored value
are used to make payments. Stored value cards are provided by a
competitive intermediary sector and are used in transactions for which
the cost of stored value is less than the float cost associated with
using currency. Conditions are identified under which the equilibrium
allocation of the economy with stored value cards does or does not
Pareto-dominate that of an otherwise identical economy without stored
value cards. The critical condition is a boundary on the average cost of
stored value: stored value is beneficial or harmful depending upon
whether, other things equal, average cost is below or above a certain
cutoff. If average cost is low, the reduction in the deadweight loss due
to inflation will be large and the resource cost will be low. If average
cost is high, the resource diversion will be large and there will be
little effect on the burden of inflation.
The fact that costly private substitutes for government fiat money
can reduce welfare was demonstrated by Schreft (1992a), and the model
presented below is an extension of hers. This fact should not be
surprising - as I argue below, we should expect the same result in any
model with multiple means of payments.(3) The interest foregone by
holding currency is an opportunity cost to private agents, and they are
willing to incur real resource costs to avoid it. The resource cost of a
money substitute is a social cost, while the interest cost associated
with currency is not. Thus the private incentive to provide a substitute
for government currency is greater than the social benefit, a point
stressed by Wallace (1986). He has argued that a positive nominal
interest rate provides a similar incentive to issue private banknotes
(Wallace 1983). While banknotes employ virtually the same technology as
government currency, stored value employs a very different technology
but serves the same role - both are private substitutes for government
currency.
The best policy in the model is one in which the nominal interest
rate is zero - the Friedman rule for the optimum quantity of money
(Friedman 1969). For a given positive nominal interest rate, however,
Schreft (1992a) has shown that quantitative restrictions on the use of
credit as a means of payment can improve welfare. The same is true for
stored value as well, since stored value is just another form of credit
as a means of payment; if nominal interest rates are positive, then the
right kind of quantitative constraints on stored value cards, if
practical, can improve welfare by preventing the most wasteful uses. A
non-interest-earning reserve requirement on stored value liabilities is
inferior to quantitative constraints because it imposes an inframarginal
tax on users of stored value.
No attention is paid here to consumer protection or to the safety and
soundness of bank stored value activities (see Blinder [1995] and Laster
and Wenninger [1995]). The analysis presumes that stored value systems
provide relatively fraud- and counterfeit-proof instruments. Historical
instances of private issue of small-denomination bearer liabilities,
such as the early nineteenth century U.S. "free banking" era,
have raised concerns about fraudulent note issue (see Friedman [1960]).
Williamson (1992) shows that a government monopoly in issuing
circulating media of exchange may be preferable to laissez-faire private
note issue due to asymmetric information about bank portfolios. Others
argue that a system of private banknote issue can function rather well:
see Rolnick and Weber (1983, 1984). In any case, current communications
technologies and regulatory and legal restraints are quite different
from those of the early nineteenth century. Whether the concerns of
Friedman and Williamson are relevant to stored value cards is beyond the
scope of this article; the focus here is the implication of the
seigniorage tax for the private incentives to provide currency
substitutes.
1. STORED VALUE CARDS
Stored value cards - sometimes called "smart cards" -
contain an embedded microprocessor and function much like currency for a
consumer. Value is loaded onto a card at a bank branch, an automated
teller machine (ATM), or at home through a telephone or computer hookup with a bank. Customers pay for the value loaded onto the card either by
withdrawing funds from a deposit account or by inserting currency into a
machine. Customers spend value by sliding it through a merchant's
card reader, which reduces the card's balance by the amount of the
purchase and adds it to the balance on the merchant's machine.
Merchants redeem value at the end of the day through a clearing
arrangement similar to those used for "off-line" credit card
or ATM transactions. The merchant dials up the network and sends in the
stored value, which is then credited to the merchant's bank
account. More elaborate systems allow consumers to transfer value from
card to card.
The value on a stored value card is a privately issued bearer
liability. It is different from a check because the merchant does not
bear the risk of insufficient funds in the buyer's account. It is
different from a debit card in that the consumer hands over funds upon
obtaining the stored value, while a debit card leaves the funds in the
consumer's account until the transaction is cleared. Thus a debit
card is a device for authorizing deposit account transfers, while a
stored value card records past transfers.
For consumers, stored value cards can be more convenient than
currency in many settings; some consumers are likely to find cards
physically easier to handle than coins and paper notes. The technology
could conceivably allow consumers to load value onto their cards using a
device attached to their home computer, saving the classic "shoe
leather" cost of bank transactions. For merchants, stored value
cards offer many of the advantages of credit card sales. The merchant
saves the trouble of handling coins and notes (banks often charge fees
for merchant withdrawals and deposits of currency) and avoids the risk
of employee theft. Stored value improves on the mechanisms used for
credit and debit cards, however, because the merchant's device
verifies the validity of the card, without costly and time-consuming
on-line authorization. Thus stored value cards extend the electronic
payments technology of credit card transactions to more time-sensitive
settings where on-line authorization is prohibitive.
2. A MODEL OF CURRENCY AND STORED VALUE
This section describes a model in which stored value and currency
both circulate in equilibrium. Monetary assets are useful in this model
because agents are spatially separated and communication is costly. In
the absence of stored value, agents use currency whenever shopping away
from home, and the structure of the model is reduced to a simple
cash-in-advance framework. Stored value is a costly private substitute
for currency, similar to costly trade credit in Schreft's (1992a,
1992b) models.
The model is a deterministic, discrete-time, infinite-horizon
environment with a large number of locations and goods but no capital.
At each location there are a large number of identical households
endowed with time and a technology for producing a location-specific
good. Each period has two stages. The first takes place before
production and, in principle, allows any agent to trade any contingent
claim with any other agent. During the second stage, production and
exchange take place. One member of the household - the
"shopper" - travels to other locations to acquire consumption
goods. Simultaneously, the other member of the household - the
"merchant" - produces location-specific goods and sells them
to shoppers from other locations. Shoppers are unable to bring with them
goods produced in their own location, so direct barter is infeasible.
The fundamental friction in this environment is that it is
prohibitively costly for agents from two different locations to verify
each other's identities. As a result, intertemporal exchange
between agents from different locations is impossible', or, more
precisely, not incentive compatible. Meetings between shoppers and
merchants away from home thus effectively resemble the anonymous
meetings of the Kiyotaki-Wright (1989) model. This provides a role for
valued fiat currency. Because agents from the same location are known to
each other, households can exchange arbitrary contingent claims with
other households at the same location during the "securities
market" in the first stage of each period. Households could travel
to other locations during the securities market, but anonymity prevents
meaningful exchange of intertemporal claims.
The stored value technology is a costly way of overcoming this
friction. There are a large number of agents that are verifiably known
to all - all them "issuers." They are price-takers and thus
earn a competitive rate of return. Like all other agents they can travel
to any other location during the securities market, but since their
identities are known, they are able to issue enforceable claims. The
claim people want to buy is one they can use in exchange in the goods
market. The difficulty facing such an arrangement, however, is
authenticating the claim to the merchant - in other words, the
difficulty of providing the shopper with a means of communicating the
earlier surrender of value. Issuers possess the technology for creating
message-storage devices - "stored value cards" - that shoppers
can carry and machines that can read and write messages on these
devices. Issuers offer to install machines with merchants. These
machines can read, verify, and write messages on shoppers' cards
and can record and store messages.
In principle the stored value technology described here could be
configured to communicate any arbitrary messages. In this setting,
however, a very simple message space will suffice. The shopper's
device carries a measure of monetary value, and the merchant's
device deducts the purchase price from the number on the shopper's
card and adds it to the measure of value stored on the merchant's
device. During the next day's securities market, the issuer visits
the merchant and verifies the amount stored on the reader. The issuer
sells stored value to households in securities markets and then redeems
stored value from merchants during the next day's securities
markets. Messages in this case function much like the tokens in
Townsend's (1986, 1987, 1989) models of limited communication. From
this perspective, currency and stored value can be seen as alternative
communications mechanisms.
I will adopt a very simple assumption concerning the cost of the
stored value technology. I will assume that the card-reader devices that
merchants use are costless to produce but require maintenance each
period and that only issuers have the expertise to perform this
maintenance. The amount of maintenance required depends on the location
in which the device is installed and is proportional to the real value
of the transactions that were recorded on the device. Some locations are
more suited to stored value systems than others. This assumption will
allow stored value and currency to coexist in equilibrium, with currency
used at the locations that are less well-suited for stored value. The
proportionality of costs to value processed might reflect security
measures or losses due to fraud that rise in proportion to the value of
transactions. I make no effort to model such phenomena explicitly but
merely take the posited cost function as given. There are no other
direct resource costs. In particular, stored value cards themselves are
costless.(4)
The stored value cost function here is quite simple and in many
respects somewhat unrealistic. Merchants' devices and the
communications networks used to "clear" stored value are,
arguably, capital goods and should be represented as investment
expenditures rather than input costs. I am abstracting from capital
inputs here, but this seems appropriate in a model with no capital goods
to begin with.(5) Another feature of my cost function is that cost is
proportional to the value of the transaction. In practice, the resource
cost of electronic storage and transmission might not vary much with the
numerical value of the message: transmitting "ten" should not
be much cheaper than transmitting "ten thousand." Thus it
seems plausible that a communications system, once built, would be
equally capable of carrying large and small value messages.(6) The cost
function I adopt is the simplest one that is sufficient to demonstrate
the claim that the introduction of stored value cards can reduce
economic welfare. One critical feature is that the relative opportunity
costs of stored value and currency vary across transactions so that both
potentially circulate in equilibrium. A second critical feature is that
there are constant returns to scale in providing stored value at any
given location so that competition among providers is feasible. It
should become clear as I proceed that the results are likely to carry
over to settings with more elaborate cost functions.
The assumed technology also implies that the choice between currency
and stored value takes a particularly simple form. The cost of using
currency is the interest foregone while it is in use. The cost of stored
value is simply the resource cost described above. By assuming that
government currency is costless, I am abstracting from many of the
factors mentioned in the previous section such as physical convenience,
currency handling costs, and employee theft. Costless currency
simplifies the presentation without loss of generality. In the appendix
I describe a model in which there are private costs of handling currency
and show that Proposition 1 below still holds. One could also modify the
model to include government currency costs, as in Lacker (1993). The
appendix also contains a model in which stored value substitutes for
other more costly means of payment such as checks or credit cards;
Proposition 1 holds in that model as well.
I can now begin describing the model more formally.(7)
Households
Time is indexed by t [greater than or equal to] 0, and locations are
indexed by z and h, where z, h [element of] [0, 1). For a typical
household at location h [element of] [0, 1), consumption of good z at
time t is given by [c.sub.t](h,z), and labor effort is given by
[n.sub.t](h). Households are endowed with one unit of time that can be
devoted to labor or leisure. The production technology requires one unit
of labor to produce one unit of consumption good. Household preferences
are
[summation of] [[Beta].sup.t]u([c.sub.t](h), 1 - [n.sub.t](h)) where
t=0 to [infinity], [c.sub.t](h) = [inf.sub.z][c.sub.t](h, z), (1)
where u is strictly concave and twice differentiable. Household
preferences are thus Leontieff across goods. This assumption implies
that the composition of consumption is unaffected by the relative
transaction costs at different locations, which considerably simplifies
matters. In addition, it implies that transaction costs at a given
location are passed on entirely to shoppers, since demand at a given
location is inelastic.(8) Since all goods will bear a positive price in
equilibrium, we can assume without loss of generality that [c.sub.t](h,
z) = [c.sub.t](h) for all z.
In the securities market households acquire both currency and stored
value. Since the units in which value is stored are arbitrary, there is
no loss in generality in assuming that stored value is measured in units
of currency. Thus one dollar buys one unit of stored value. Let
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
denote the consumption of good z at time t purchased with currency and
stored value, respectively. Let [m.sub.t](h) and [s.sub.t](h) be the
amount of currency and stored value acquired in the securities market at
time t. Then the trading friction implies that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and (2)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (3)
where Pt is the price of goods for currency and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] is the price of goods for stored value at location
z.(9)
Household h sells [Mathematical Expression Omitted] units of output
for currency and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] units of output for
stored value. In addition, they sell [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
units of output to issuers. Since issuers are well known, merchants are
willing to sell to them on credit and accept payment in next
period's securities market. Feasibility requires
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (4)
At the end of the period, the household has [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] units of stored value on their card reader to be redeemed at t
+ 1. Issuers pay interest at the nominal rate [i.sub.t], the market rate
on one-period bonds, but deduct a proportional charge at rate
[r.sub.t](h) from the proceeds to cover their costs. Thus the household
receives [Mathematical Expression Omitted] units of currency at t + 1
for the stored value they have accepted.(10)
Households bring the following to the securities market: currency
from the previous period's sales, stored value to be redeemed,
maturing bonds, and any currency that might be left over from shopping
in the previous period. Letting [b.sub.t] be bond purchases at t, and
[[Tau].sub.t] be lump-sum taxes at t, households face the following
budget constraint at time t + 1:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (5)
Households maximize (1) subject to (2) through (5) and the relevant
nonnegativity constraints, taking prices and interest rates as given.
Issuers
There are a large number of issuers at location zero, distinct from
the households described above. Their preferences depend on their
consumption [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and leisure [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] according to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (6)
Issuers sell [s.sub.t](z) units of stored value per capita in
securities market z at time t in exchange for [s.sub.t](z) units of
currency and redeem [s[prime].sub.t](z) units of stored value per capita
from merchants at market z at time t + 1 in exchange for [1 -
[r.sub.t](z)](1 + [i.sub.t])[s[prime].sub.t](z) units of currency. All
of the stored value they issue will be spent by households and then
redeemed from card readers in equilibrium, so issuers face the
constraint
[integral of] [s.sub.t](z)dz between limits 1 and 0 = [integral of]
[s[prime].sub.t](z)dz between limits 1 and 0. (7)
Maintenance of the devices on which the stored value at location z is
redeemed requires [Mathematical Expression Omitted] units of labor
effort, where [Gamma](z) is a continuous, strictly increasing function with [Gamma](0) = 0. Total maintenance effort is therefore
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (8)
The alternative for issuers who are not active is to consume nothing
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], which can be interpreted as the
proceeds of some alternative autarchic activity.
The family of an issuer consists of a worker and a shopper. The
worker manages the stored value business, while the shopper travels
around during the goods market period purchasing consumption. Since
issuers are known to all, the shopper can buy on credit, paying
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] in the location-z securities market at
t + 1 for goods purchased there at t. Excess funds are invested in bond
holdings [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. An issuer's securities
market budget constraint is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (9)
Active issuers maximize (6), subject to (7) through (9) and the
relevant non-negativity constraints, by choosing consumption, bonds,
labor effort, and the amount of stored value to issue and redeem at each
location. Because there are a large number of issuers, competition
between them will drive the utility of active issuers down to the
reservation utility associated with inactivity. Issuers initially have
no assets.
Government
The government issues fiat money [M.sub.t] and one-period bonds
[B.sub.t], collects lump-sum taxes [T.sub.t], and satisfies
[M.sub.t+1] + [B.sub.t+1] = [M.sub.t] + (1 + [i.sub.t])[B.sub.t] -
[T.sub.t+1] (10)
for all t. The government sets a constant money growth rate [Pi] =
[M.sub.t+1]/[M.sub.t] - 1, where [Pi] [greater than or equal to] [Beta]
- 1.
Equilibrium
A symmetric monetary equilibrium consists of sequences of prices,
quantities and initial conditions [M.sub.-1] and (1 +
[i.sub.-1])[B.sub.-1], such that households and issuers optimize, the
lifetime utility of active issuers is equal to the lifetime utility of
inactive issuers starting at any date, the government budget constraint
(10) holds, and market clearing conditions hold for
[M.sub.t],[B.sub.t],[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] for all t and
z. I restrict attention to stationary equilibria, in which real
magnitudes are constant over time. Where possible, time subscripts will
be dropped from variables that are constant over time; variables refer
to date t quantities unless otherwise noted.
The first-order necessary conditions for the issuer's
maximization problem imply
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (11)
The left side of (11) is the nominal net return from issuing one
dollar's worth of stored value at t to be redeemed at location z at
t + 1, with the proceeds invested in a bond maturing at t + 1. Interest
on the bond is paid over to the merchant, with a portion r(z) of the
payment deducted as a fee. The right side of (11) is the nominal cost of
enough consumption goods to compensate the issuer for the disutility of
maintaining the stored value device at location z. Thus condition (11)
states that for stored value issuers marginal net revenue equals
marginal cost at each location.
Merchants consider whether to sell output for currency or for stored
value. The first-order necessary conditions for the household's
maximization problem imply that if merchants are indifferent between
accepting currency and stored value, then
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (12)
As a result, the last two terms in the household's budget
constraint (5) simplify to [p.sub.t]n(h). Households at all locations
face identical terms of trade between consumption and leisure despite
the difference in transaction costs across locations. Consumption and
labor supply are therefore identical across locations and the notation for h can be suppressed.
When shoppers consider whether to use currency or stored value to
purchase consumption at location z, they compare the unit cost of the
former, [p.sub.t], to the unit cost of the latter, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]. Using (11) and (12), shoppers use stored value if
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (13)
Thus stored value is used where [Gamma](z) [less than] i. Because
[Gamma] is strictly increasing, the boundary between the stored value
and the currency locations can be written as a function [Zeta](i)
[equivalent to] [[Gamma].sup.-1](i). Stored value will coexist with
currency as long as i is less than [Gamma](1), the cost of stored value
at the highest cost location. If i [greater than or equal to]
[Gamma](1), then stored value drives out currency; in this case
[Zeta](i) is one.
The total resource cost of stored value for a given nominal rate is
[integral of] [Gamma](z)dz [equivalent to] [Gamma](i) between limits
[Zeta](i) and 0. (14)
Steady-state equilibrium values of c and n can be found as the
solutions to the first-order condition
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n)/[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) = 1 + [1 - [Zeta](i)]i +
[Gamma](i), (15)
along with the feasibility condition
n = c[1 +[Gamma](i)]. (16)
For a given nonnegative nominal interest rate, consumption and
employment are determined by (15) and (16).(11) Assuming that neither
leisure nor consumption are inferior goods, then v(c, 1 - n) [equivalent
to] [u.sub.1](c, 1 - n)/[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) is decreasing in c and
increasing in 1 - n. If in addition we assume that v(c, 1 - n) goes to
infinity as c goes to zero and zero as 1 - n goes to zero, then we are
guaranteed an interior solution; the proof appears in the appendix. The
real interest rate is [[Beta].sup.-1] - 1 in all equilibria, and the
inflation rate is [Beta](1 + i) - 1.
Without stored value cards the economy has the same basic structure
as a standard cash-in-advance model (Lucas and Stokey 1983) and can be
obtained as a special case in which [Zeta](i) (and thus [Gamma](i))
equals zero.
3. THE WELFARE ECONOMICS OF STORED VALUE
An optimal steady-state allocation is defined by the property that no
other feasible steady-state allocation makes at least one type of
household better off without making some other type of household worse
off. Two features of the model make optimality relatively easy to
assess. Even though at some locations goods are sold for currency and at
other locations goods are sold for stored value, households at all
locations face identical terms of trade between consumption and leisure.
As a result, all households at all locations will have the same lifetime
utility in any given equilibrium. We can therefore focus our attention
on the well-being of a representative household at a representative
location. Second, because the lifetime utility of any given issuer is
zero in all equilibria, we can effectively ignore the welfare of issuers
when comparing equilibrium allocations. This just reflects the fact that
issuers receive a competitive rate of return and are indifferent as to
how they obtain it; constant returns to scale in providing stored value
at any location implies that issuers earn no rents. Given these two
features, we can compare alternative allocations by considering their
effect on the lifetime utility of a representative household.
For the version of this economy without stored value, the welfare
economics are well known. Households equate the marginal rate of
substitution between consumption and leisure to 1 + i rather than 1, the
marginal rate of transformation, because consumption is provided for out
of currency accumulated by working in the previous period, and currency
holdings are implicitly taxed at rate i. Optimality requires that the
marginal rate of substitution equal the marginal rate of transformation,
which only holds if the nominal interest rate is zero. A positive
nominal interest rate distorts household decisions, inducing
substitution away from monetary activity (consumption) toward
nonmonetary activity (leisure). The resulting welfare reduction is the
deadweight loss from inflation in this model. Intuitively, inflation
reduces the rate of return on currency, which causes consumers to
economize on the use of currency. In a cash-in-advance economy they can
do this only by consuming less of the goods whose purchase requires
currency. The optimal monetary policy is to deflate at the rate of time
preference, [Pi] = [Beta] - 1, so that the nominal interest rate is zero
and the distortion in (15) is completely eliminated (Friedman 1969.).
Note that in the absence of stored value, inflation has no effect on the
feasibility frontier (16).
I will compare two steady-state equilibria with identical inflation
rates, one with and one without stored value. Since the real rate is the
same in all equilibria, the nominal rate is constant across equilibria
as well. Stored value has two effects on a typical household's
utility. The first is to alter the marginal rate of substitution between
monetary and nonmonetary activities. The transaction cost associated
with purchases using stored value at a given location z [less than]
[Zeta](i) is [Gamma](z), which is less than i, the private opportunity
cost associated with using currency: see Figure 1. Thus stored value
reduces the average transaction cost associated with consumption goods.
This can be seen from (15), noting that the average cost of stored
value, [Gamma](i)/[Zeta](i), is less than i. Stored value reduces the
right side of (15) by the amount [Zeta](i)i - [Gamma](i), shown as the
region A in Figure 1. Therefore, stored value cards reduce the
distortion caused by inflation. By itself, this increases welfare. Note
that the lower the total cost of stored value [Gamma](i), holding
constant i and [Zeta](i), the larger the welfare gain from stored value.
The second effect is through the feasibility constraint. Stored value
cards involve real resource costs. Maintenance of the technology
requires issuers' labor time, and consumption at every location
must be diverted to compensate issuers for their effort. Currency
requires no direct resource costs in this model.(12) The introduction of
stored value shifts the consumption-leisure feasibility frontier (16)
inward, since resources must be diverted to cover the real costs of
stored value. The area under [Gamma](z) from zero to [Zeta](i) in Figure
1 is equal to [Gamma](i), the real resource costs devoted to stored
value activities. In contrast, the opportunity cost associated with
currency (the area under i) is merely a transfer payment. By itself, the
resource cost of stored value reduces welfare; a virtually costless
government money is replaced by a costly private money. Note that the
larger the total cost of stored value (holding constant i and
[Zeta](i)), the larger the reduction in welfare.
The net effect of stored value cards on economic welfare is
indeterminate and depends on the structure of stored value costs across
locations. Since we are comparing two equilibria with the same nominal
interest rate, we know that the marginal location has a cost of i. But
conditions (15) and (16) tell us that the effect depends on the shape of
the cost function. The benefit of stored value in (15) varies positively
with the area A in Figure 1. The detrimental effect of stored value in
(16) varies positively with [Gamma](i). Both effects depend solely on
[Gamma](i) for any given i and [Zeta](i). If costs are low across most
locations but then rise sharply - for example, if [Gamma] is quite
convex - then [Gamma](i) will be relatively small. In this case the
negative effect through the feasibility condition will be small, and the
positive effect through the marginal rate of substitution. [Zeta](i)i -
[Gamma](i), will be large. If instead costs are large at most locations
- for example, if [Gamma] is quite concave - then [Gamma](i) is close to
[Zeta](i)i, the resource costs will be large, and the gain from reducing
the marginal rate of substitution will be small. Thus the greater the
convexity of costs across locations, the more likely it is that stored
value cards improve economic welfare. This intuition is formalized in
the following proposition. (The proof appears in the appendix.)
Proposition 1: Fix i. Compare an economy with no stored value to an
arbitrary stored value economy with a given ratio of stored value to
currency, [Zeta](i)/[1 - [Zeta](i)]. There is a cutoff [[Gamma].sup.*]
[which depends on i and [Zeta](i)] such that if [Gamma](i) [greater
than] [[Gamma].sup.*], then welfare is lower in the stored value
economy, and if [Gamma](i) [less than] [[Gamma].sup.*], then welfare is
higher in the stored value economy.
The principle described in Proposition 1 appears to be quite general.
In any model in which there is a deadweight loss due to the inflation
tax, a private substitute for currency will reduce the base on which the
tax is levied. The cost of the substitute must be less than the tax it
evades - otherwise it would not be introduced. With the tax rate (the
nominal interest rate) held constant, the incidence of the tax is lower
and so the deadweight loss associated with that distortion will fall.
Thus in any model we should expect that private substitutes for fiat
money help reduce the burden of a given inflation rate.
The negative welfare effect of stored value cards would seem to
generalize as well. Absent market imperfection, participants will adopt
stored value if their collective private benefits exceed their
collective private costs. But their net benefits differ from social net
benefits in two ways; the capture of seigniorage is not a social
benefit, and they do not bear the governmental cost of currency
provision. The gap between the nominal interest rate and the
government's per-dollar cost of providing currency thus represents
the excess incentive to implement currency substitutes.
More realistic or elaborate models would also display the principle
described in Proposition 1. For example, if stored value costs do not
depend directly on the value of messages, then the fee an issuer
collects from a merchant would be independent of the merchant's
sales.(13) The relevant cost comparison is then between the seigniorage
tax, which is proportional to production, and the fixed fee, which is
not. In this case the set of locations using stored value would vary
with equilibrium consumption, instead of being independent of
consumption as in the model above. Nevertheless, stored value would
reduce transaction costs where it is used, and the benefit of a reduced
inflation tax burden would have to be weighed against the added resource
costs.
In the absence of stored value, inflation is costly in the model
because it distorts the choice between monetary and nonmonetary
activities. Some economists have suggested that an important cost of
inflation is that it encourages costly private credit arrangements as
substitutes for government money (see Ireland [1994], Dotsey and Ireland
[1995], Lacker and Schreft [1996], and Aiyagari, Braun, and Eckstein
[1995]). Stored value could reduce this cost of inflation by displacing
even more costly means of payment such as checks or credit cards. The
social benefit of stored value would then also include the reduction in
payments cost for some transactions. This benefit would be larger, the
smaller the cost of stored value. But again, the benefit of stored value
would have to be weighed against the resource cost of substituting
stored value for virtually costless currency. As long as stored value in
part substitutes for currency, Proposition 1 again emerges; the lower
the average cost of stored value cards, the greater the gain from
displacing more costly means of payments, and the smaller the resources
diverted to stored value systems. (A straightforward extension of the
model demonstrating this result is described in the appendix.)
As I mentioned earlier, stored value seems likely to offer consumers
and merchants greater physical convenience or some other advantages over
currency that are not captured in the model presented above. Such
advantages would not alter the basic feature of Proposition 1, however.
If merchants find stored value less costly to handle than currency,
their savings will presumably be reflected in their willingness to pay stored value issuers; the social benefit of stored value to merchants
will be reflected in issuers' revenues. Similarly, if consumers
find stored value more convenient than currency, they should be willing
to pay, either directly or indirectly, and the benefit of stored value
to consumers will be reflected in issuers' revenues. The greater
convenience of stored value cards will provide issuers with added
incentive to provide stored value, but the nominal interest rate (minus
the government currency cost) would still constitute a source of private
return to issuing stored value that is not matched by any social benefit
of replacing currency. To demonstrate this point, the appendix describes
a simple extension of the model in which there are private costs to
handling currency and shows that Proposition 1 again holds true.
What if consumers earn interest on their stored value cards, a
possibility that appears to be technologically feasible? Could this
upset the conclusions of Proposition 1? In the model, merchants earn
interest on stored value balances, although they pay some of this
interest back to issuers in the form of redemption fees. Stored value
yields no explicit interest for shoppers. An equivalent scheme would be
for shoppers to earn interest on stored value but face higher prices at
locations that accept stored value. The interest earnings would more
than compensate shoppers for the higher price at those locations. Stored
value would again be used at locations at which the resource cost does
not exceed the opportunity cost of using currency.
What if stored value completely displaces currency? In this case the
meaning of the nominal interest rate in the model becomes somewhat
ambiguous; because currency does not circulate, it might not serve as
the unit of account. Nonetheless, the difference between the real return
on bonds and the real return on stored value liabilities will not exceed
the marginal cost of providing stored value.(14) Unless this difference
is less than the government's cost of providing currency, the
principle underlying Proposition 1 still applies.
Bryant and Wallace (1984) have argued that different rates of return
on different government liabilities can be justified as an optimal tax.
If all sources of government revenue require distortionary taxation,
then it may be beneficial to raise some revenues from the taxation of
currency holders. This consideration is not captured in the model
described above. The seigniorage tax merely finances interest payments
on government bonds. The reduction in seigniorage revenues was offset by
a reduction in outstanding government debt or an increase in lump-sum
taxes, keeping the nominal rate constant. If instead the loss of
seigniorage had to be recovered by raising other distortionary taxes, it
would strengthen the case against stored value. The additional
deadweight burden of the compensating tax increases would have to be
added to the resource cost of stored value. Similarly, nonzero government expenditures financed in part through seigniorage would not
change the basic features of Proposition 1.
4. POLICY
In the presence of one distortionary tax a second distortion can
sometimes improve economic welfare. A positive nominal interest rate is
a distortionary tax on holders of government currency. In the
laissez-faire regime with stored value, welfare can be lower because of
the costs of stored value, which suggests that constraints on the issue
of stored value cards might be welfare-enhancing. This turns out to be
true. Restrictions on the issue of stored value can improve welfare, in
this second-best situation, by reducing the costly displacement of
government currency.(15)
Consider first a simple quantitative restriction on the use of stored
value. Imagine a legal restriction that limits the quantity of stored
value used by households, or, equivalently, that limits the locations at
which stored value is accepted. Households can only make a fraction
[Eta] of their purchases using stored value, where the government sets
[Eta] between 0 and [Zeta](i). Households will continue to use stored
value where it is most advantageous to do so - at locations 0 through
[Eta]. At locations [Eta] through 1, households use currency.
Equilibrium is still characterized as the solution to (15) and (16),
except that [Zeta](i) is replaced by [Eta]. For a given nominal interest
rate, consumption and employment are determined as the solutions to
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n)/[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) = 1 + (1 - [Eta])i +
[integral of] [Gamma](z)dz between limits [Eta] and 0 and (17)
n = c[1 + [integral of] [Gamma](z)dz between limits [Eta] and 0].
(18)
Define c([Eta]) and n([Eta]) as the solutions to (17) and (18) for
[Eta] [element of] [0, [Zeta](i)], and v([Eta]) [equivalent to]
u(c([Eta]), 1 - n([Eta])). The function v([Eta]) is the equilibrium
utility of a representative household under the constraint that no more
than a fraction [Eta] of purchases can be made using stored value.
Proposition 2: v[prime][[Zeta](i)] [less than] 0; therefore there is
a binding restriction [Eta] [less than] [Zeta](i) on stored value under
which steady-state utility is higher than under the laissez-faire
regime.
Reducing [Eta] marginally below [Zeta](i) has two effects. The direct
effect via the resource constraint (18) is to eliminate the most costly
uses of stored value, allowing greater consumption at each level of
employment. The increase in utility at [Eta] = [Zeta](i) is proportional
to [Gamma](i). The second effect via the marginal rate of substitution
is to substitute currency (transaction cost i) for stored value
(transaction cost [Gamma]([Eta])). The fall in utility is proportional
to i - [Gamma]([Eta]), which vanishes at [Eta] = [Zeta](i) =
[[Gamma].sup.-1](i), since at the margin stored value and currency bear
the same transaction cost. The first-order resource savings dominates
the negligible increase in the burden of inflation. The net effect of
decreasing [Eta] is positive. Therefore there must be a value [Eta]
[less than] [Zeta](i) that results in higher steady-state utility than
the laissez-faire regime. Note that Proposition 2 holds whether or not
the stored value equilibrium is worse than the no-stored-value
equilibrium; even if stored value is welfare-enhancing, quantitative
constraints would still be worthwhile.(16)
An alternative method of restraining stored value is to impose a
reserve requirement. Issuers are required to hold currency equal to a
fraction [Delta] of their outstanding stored value liabilities. Issuers
earn (1 - [Delta])i rather than i on their assets, and the cost of
foregone earnings, [Delta]i, is passed on to merchants and ultimately to
consumers. Stored value is used at fewer locations for any given
interest rate - only where [Gamma](i) [less than] (1 -[Delta])i. Raising
the reserve requirement from zero reduces the amount of resources
diverted to stored value. By itself this increases utility by easing the
feasibility frontier in (18). The first-order condition (15) becomes
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n)/[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) = 1 + [1 - [Zeta](i,
[Delta])]i + [integral of] [(1 - [Delta]).sup.-1][Gamma](z)dz between
limits [Zeta](i,[Delta]) and 0,
where [Zeta](i, [Delta]) [equivalent to] [[Gamma].sup.-1] [(1 -
[Delta])i]. Increasing the reserve requirement now has two effects on
the marginal rate of substitution. First, raising [Delta] expands the
set of locations at which currency is used instead of lower-cost stored
value. This effect operates through [Zeta](i, [Delta]) in (19). Second,
raising [Delta] increases the transaction cost at all locations at which
stored value is used. This effect increases the integrand in the last
term in (19) and does not vanish at [Delta] = 0. The first effect is
identical to the effect of decreasing the quantitative constraint [Eta]
in (17). The quantitative constraint does not involve the second effect
in (19), since it leaves inframarginal stored value users unaffected. In
contrast, the reserve requirement imposes a tax on all stored value
users. Therefore, a quantitative constraint is superior to a reserve
requirement in this environment. A reserve requirement improves welfare
only if the second effect in (19) does not dominate.(17)
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
When the nominal interest rate is positive, there is an incentive to
develop substitutes for government currency. This incentive is likely to
exceed the social benefit of such substitutes because the private
opportunity cost of holding currency is larger than the social cost of
providing currency. Although stored value can lower the opportunity cost
of payments media for inframarginal consumers, the real resources
diverted to stored value are wasteful from society's point of view.
For a given nominal interest rate, stored value cards are good or bad
for welfare depending upon whether the average cost of stored value is
below or above a certain cutoff. Quantitative restrictions on stored
value can be socially beneficial, in this second-best situation, because
they reduce the amount of resources absorbed by the most costly stored
value applications. I do not claim to show that such restrictions can be
easily implemented - only that if such restrictions were practical, they
would enhance welfare.
Wallace (1983) pointed out that the U.S. government has effectively
prohibited the private issue of paper small-denomination bearer notes
such as bank notes. In the absence of such a ban, he argued, private
intermediaries could issue perfect substitutes for government currency
backed by default-free securities such as U.S. Treasury bills. In this
case one of two things could occur. Either the nominal rate of return
would not exceed the marginal cost of such intermediation, which he
reckoned at close to zero, or government currency would cease to
circulate. Stored value cards are just another way of issuing
small-denomination bearer liabilities. As a corollary to Wallace's
thesis, then, we should expect one of two things to happen. Either the
nominal interest rate will not exceed the marginal cost of an additional
dollar's worth of stored value, or government currency will cease
to circulate. All I have added to Wallace's argument is the
observation that since stored value employs a technology that is
different from, and potentially far more costly than, the government
currency it would replace, it is possible that either outcome could
reduce economic welfare.
The restrictions that have prevented private paper substitutes for
currency were in place since at least the end of the Civil War. As
Wallace (1986) notes, "(i)f there is a rationale for that policy .
. . then it would seem that it would apply to other payments instruments
that potentially substitute for the monetary base." These
longstanding restrictions on paper note issue evidently have been
repealed.(18) Current policy thus avoids the inconsistency of allowing
electronic substitutes for government currency while preventing paper
substitutes.
APPENDIX
Government Currency Costs
The Annual Report of the Director of the Mint reports the coinage
cost per $1,000 face value for every denomination of coin, along with
the number manufactured. For 1993 (the latest year available) this
yields a coin manufacturing cost of $166.2 million (31.3 percent of face
value). For coin operating cost the 1994 PACS Expense Report lists total
cost of coin service of $14.7 million (Board of Governors 1994b). Total
government cost of coin is the sum of manufacturing and operating costs,
or $180.9 million. U.S. Treasury Department Bulletin reports coin in
circulation on December 31, 1993, as $20.804 billion. For coin,
therefore, the cost per dollar outstanding is $0.008695.
For currency, governmental cost for 1993 is the sum of Federal
Reserve Bank operating expenses of $123.7 million (Board of Governors
1994b), and the Reserve Bank assessment for U.S. Treasury currency
expenses of $355.9 million (Board of Governors 1994a). Total cost for
currency is thus $479.6 million, or $0.001394 per dollar outstanding,
based on $343.925 billion in currency outstanding at the end of 1993
(Board of Governors 1994a).(19)
Combining currency and coin costs yields a total of $660.5 million
for 1993. The total value of currency and coin in circulation was
$36.729 billion. The total government cost of coin and currency per
dollar outstanding is therefore $0.001798.
Proofs
Existence: Define c(y) and n(y) as the joint solutions to
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n) = q[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) and qc + (1 - n) = y. Here q
is the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure,
the right-hand side of (15). The assumptions on preferences imply that
c(y) and 1 - n(y) are unique, strictly positive for y [greater than] 0,
continuous, and monotone increasing. Assume r [greater than] 0, where r
is the marginal rate of transformation between consumption and leisure,
the bracketed term in (16). Then rc(y) + [1 - n(y)] is strictly
increasing in y, there exists a unique y such that rc(y) + [1 - n(y)] =
1, and thus n(y) = rc(y).
Proposition 1: Define c(q, r) and n(q, r) as the unique solutions to
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n) = q[u.sub.2](c, 1 - n)
n = rc,
where attention is restricted to r [greater than or equal to] 1 and q
[greater than or equal to] r. Define V(q, r) = u(c(q, r), 1 n(q, r)). It
is easy to show that since neither leisure nor consumption is an
inferior good, V is strictly decreasing in q and r.
The first-best allocation has a nominal interest rate of zero, so q =
r = 1. Economies with positive nominal rates but no stored value have q
= 1 + i [greater than] 1 and r = 1. For given i and [Zeta](i), q and r
vary positively with the aggregate [Gamma](i). This amounts to varying
average cost holding marginal cost constant at location z = [Zeta](i).
Note that [Gamma](i) can lie anywhere in the interval (0, [Zeta](i)i).
Define w([Gamma]) = V(1 +(1 - [Zeta](i))i + [Gamma], 1 + [Gamma]). Then
w(0) = V(1 + (1 - [Zeta])i, 1) [greater than] V(1 + i, 1), and
w([Zeta](i)i) = V(1 + i, 1 + [Zeta](i)i) [less than] V(1 + i, 1). Since
w([Gamma]) is continuous and strictly decreasing in [Gamma], it follows
immediately that there exists a unique [[Gamma].sup.*] for which
w([[Gamma].sup.*]) = V(1 + i, 1).
Proposition 2: Define q([Eta]) as the right side of (17), and
r([Eta]) as the bracketed term in (18). With v([Eta]) [equivalent to]
V(q([Eta]), r([Eta])), we have [Mathematical Expression Omitted], since
[Gamma]([Zeta](i)) = i and [V.sub.r] [less than] 0.
A Model in Which Stored Value Substitutes for Other Means of Payment
In this section I describe a simple extension of the model in which
there are three means of payment: government currency, stored value, and
another costly private means of payment. The latter can be thought of as
checks or credit cards and is supplied by an industry with the same
general properties as the stored value sector. Locations will now be
indexed by [z.sub.1] and [z.sub.2]. Stored value costs depend only on
[z.sub.1] according to [Gamma]([z.sub.1]). The cost of checks depends
only on [z.sub.2] according to a continuous and monotone increasing
function [Chi]([z.sub.2]). To simplify the exposition, I will abstract
from the effect of inflation on labor supply and assume that labor is
supplied inelastically: n [equivalent to] 1 and u(c, 1 - n) [equivalent
to] u(c).
Inflation is inefficient in this version of the model solely because
it diverts resources to the production of money substitutes. Consumption
equals output (which is fixed and equal to 1) minus the resource costs
of checks and stored value. In the absence of stored value, shoppers use
currency at locations where [Chi]([z.sub.2]) [greater than] i, and use
checks where [Chi]([z.sub.2]) [less than] i. Without stored value, then,
the cost of inflation is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Shoppers will use stored value at locations where [Gamma]([z.sub.1])
[less than] min[[Chi]([z.sub.2]), i]. With stored value, the consumption
diverted to alternative monies is
[integral of] [Gamma]([z.sub.1])d[z.sub.2]d[z.sub.1] with limit S(i)
+ [integral of] [Chi]([z.sub.2])d[z.sub.2]d[z.sub.1] with limit C(i),
where S(i) [equivalent to] {([z.sub.1], [z.sub.2]) s.t.
[Gamma]([z.sub.1]) [less than] MIN[i, [Chi]([z.sub.2])]}
and C(i) [equivalent to] {([z.sub.1], [z.sub.2]) s.t.
[Chi]([z.sub.2]) [less than] MIN[i, [Gamma]([z.sub.1])]}.
As in the model in the text, stored value wastes resources: at
locations described by [z.sub.1] [less than] [[Gamma].sup.-1] (i) and
[z.sub.2] [greater than] [[Chi].sup.-1](i), stored value costs are
incurred where formerly (costless) currency was in use. At these
locations, the greater the average cost of stored value the greater the
resource diversion. However, at locations described by [z.sub.2] [less
than] [[Chi].sup.-1](i) and [Gamma]([z.sub.1]) [less than]
[Chi]([z.sub.2]), stored value substitutes for more costly check use. In
this region the resource savings is larger, the smaller the average cost
of stored value. Whether the resource savings from displacing checks
outweighs the resource cost of displacing currency depends on the stored
value cost function. It is straightforward to show that there is once
again a cutoff value; if average stored value costs are below the
cutoff, stored value is welfare-enhancing, while if average cost is
greater than the cutoff, stored value reduces welfare.
A Model with Costs of Handling Currency
This section describes an extension of the model in which handling
currency is costly to merchants and shows that Proposition 1 also holds
in this extended economy. (The same is true of an extended model in
which handling currency is costly to shoppers, but that model is omitted
here.) Suppose then that accepting currency as payment requires
time-consuming effort on the part of merchants. For convenience, I will
assume that the time requirement is proportional to the real value of
currency handled and is equal to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where the parameter [Alpha] [greater than] 0. The feasibility
condition (4) now becomes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (4[prime])
One unit of labor devoted to goods sold for currency now yields
[p.sub.t]/(1 + [Alpha]) units of currency at the beginning of period t +
1. One unit of labor devoted to goods sold to an issuer must provide the
same yield, so in (5) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is replaced with
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. In the issuer's budget
constraint, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is replaced by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The first-order condition from the
issuer's problem becomes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (11[prime])
One unit of labor devoted to cash sales yields [p.sub.t]/(1 +
[Alpha]) units of currency at t + 1. Therefore (12) becomes
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (12[prime])
The last two terms in the household's budget constraint (5) now
simplify to [p.sub.t][n.sub.t](h)/(1 + [Alpha]).
Shoppers now use stored value if and only if (1 + [Alpha])(1 + i)
[greater than] [1 + [Gamma](z)]. Define [Zeta](i) by (1 + [Alpha])(1 +
i) = (1 + [Gamma]([Zeta](i))). At this point I make a minor modification
to the model. The preferences of issuers are altered so that goods from
different locations are perfect substitutes:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
With this modification, the feasibility condition for this model
simplifies to
n = c{(1 + [Alpha])[1 - [Zeta](i)] + [Gamma](i)}, (16[prime])
reflecting the fact that both currency handling costs and stored
value costs affect the aggregate resource constraint. The first-order
condition for this model is
[u.sub.1](c, 1 - n) / [u.sub.2](c, 1 - n) = (1 + [Alpha]){1 + [1 -
[Zeta](i)]i + [Gamma](i)} [equivalent to] q. (15[prime])
Once again the optimal monetary policy is the Friedman rule, but now
stored value circulates even when the nominal interest rate is zero,
since in some applications stored value is less costly than currency
[[Gamma](z) [less than] [Alpha]]. It is easy to demonstrate that
Proposition 1 holds in this economy as well: for any fixed positive
nominal interest rate there exists a cutoff [[Gamma].sup.*] such that
the stored value economy Pareto-dominates the economy without stored
value if and only if [Gamma](i) [less than] [[Gamma].sup.*].
The author would like to thank Michelle Kezar and Helen Upton for
research assistance, reviewers Mike Dotsey, Tom Humphrey, Ned Prescott,
and John Weinberg for extensive comments, James McAfee for useful
references, Urs Birchler, Scott Freeman, Marvin Good-friend, Don Hester,
Dave Humphrey, Peter Ireland, Bob King, Bennett McCallum, Geoffrey
Miller, Kevin Reffett, Will Roberds, Stacey Schreft, and Bruce Summers
for helpful comments and conversations, and an anonymous reviewer for
helpful comments. The author is solely responsible for the contents of
this article. The views expressed do not necessarily reflect those of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
1 I will use the term "currency" rather than "currency
and coin" to refer to government-supplied notes and coinage; the
analysis applies equally to government-minted coin.
2 See appendix for documentation.
3 For models of multiple means of payment see Prescott (1987),
Schreft (1992a, 1992b), Marquis and Reffett (1992, 1994), Ireland
(1994), Dorsey and Ireland (1995), English (1996), and Lacker and
Schreft (1996).
4 Indirect evidence suggests that the resource costs of stored value
systems could be substantial. A variety of sources indicate that bank
operating expenses associated with credit cards amount to around 3 or 4
percent of the value of credit card charge volume. This does not include
the direct expenses of merchants such as the costs of card readers.
Stored value systems may avoid some expenses such as the costs
associated with credit card billing and the cost of on-line
communications. On the other hand, the cost of stored value cards
themselves are greater than the cost of traditional "magnetic
strip" cards.
5 See Ireland (1994), Marquis and Reffett (1992, 1994), and English
(1996) for models with private payment technologies requiring capital
goods.
6 Ireland (1994) studies a similar model in which cost is independent
of the value of the transaction. Also see Prescott (1987) and English
(1996). For a partial equilibrium model see Whitesell (1992).
7 The model is most closely patterned after the environment in
Schreft (1992a) and Lacker and Schreft (1996). The main difference is
that here the alternative payments medium is used at a subset of
locations by all shoppers visiting that location, rather than at all
locations but by only a subset of shoppers visiting that location. Also,
I allow a general cost function while Schreft's cost function is,
for convenience, linear in distance.
8 Allowing substitution between goods would imply that the
composition of consumption varies with changes in relative transaction
costs. Relative prices net of transaction costs would then vary across
locations, destroying the symmetry in households' consumption and
leisure choices. See Ireland (1994) and Dotsey and Ireland (1995) for
models which relax the Leontieff assumption.
9 In principle the price of goods for currency could vary across
locations as well, but symmetry will ensure equality across locations.
This is confirmed below: see (12). Note that shoppers do not receive
explicit interest on stored value. Note also that I allow merchants to
charge a different price for different payments instruments.
10 Note that the payment could be thought of as redemption at par
plus a premium [1 - [r.sub.t](h)](1 + [i.sub.t]) - 1. The form of
merchants' payments to issuers depends on issuers' cost
functions. The payment is proportional to the value redeemed because the
issuers' costs are proportional to value redeemed. If costs were
independent of value redeemed, the equilibrium payment would also be
independent of value redeemed.
11 The reduced form structure in (15) and (16) is identical to
Schreft (1992a) and Lacker and Schreft (1996), although the models are
somewhat different. In Schreft's model households use credit when
close to their own home location and currency when farther away; thus at
every location shoppers from nearby use credit and shoppers from a
distance use cash. In contrast, at some locations only stored value is
used and at other locations only currency is used in my model. Also, in
Schreft's model credit costs are linear in distance.
12 See the appendix for a model with positive private costs of using
currency and Lacker (1993) for a similar model with positive government
currency costs.
13 The payments technologies in Ireland (1994) and English (1996)
have this property.
14 This could happen in one of two ways. Currency could remain the
unit of account - a "ghost" money. Issuers would pay interest
to consumers on stored value, and issuers' net interest margin
would not exceed the marginal cost of stored value. Alternatively,
stored value could become the unit of account, in which case the nominal
interest rate would fall to the marginal cost of stored value.
15 This depends, of course, on finding a practical way to restrict
the quantity of stored value issued. I do not address this issue here.
16 Proposition 2 parallels Proposition 2 in Schreft (1992a). In
Schreft's model the government issues no bonds and government
expenditure depends on the seigniorage collected. Lowering the
constraint holding the inflation rate constant increases the demand for
money and thus government expenditures. Schreft's proposition
requires the condition that government expenditures rise by less than
the resource cost of payments services falls when the constraint is
tightened. This condition is unnecessary if government spending is held
constant and instead the bond supply or lump-sum taxes vary across
equilibria. There are no government expenditures in my model. Note that
Proposition 2 depends crucially on the continuity of stored value costs
across locations. If there were a discrete jump in the function [Gamma]
at [Zeta](i), then Proposition 2 might fail to hold.
17 A reserve requirement equal to 1 - [[Gamma].sub.g]/i could be
imposed (where [[Gamma].sub.g] is the government currency cost) as an
experiment to determine whether the resource costs of stored value
exceed the direct benefits, i.e., whether [Gamma](z) [greater than]
[[Gamma].sub.g]. This experiment would not answer the question posed by
Proposition 1, however.
18 Title VI of the Community Development Banking Act, P.L. 103-325
(1994), repealed all restrictions on note issue by national banks except
the 1/2 percent semi-annual tax on outstanding notes. Section 1904(a) of
the Tax Reform Act of 1976 repealed the 10 percent tax on note issue by
corporations other than national banks. De facto restrictions by bank
regulators may still prevent private note issue.
19 For more on the government's cost of currency, see Lacker
(1993).
REFERENCES
Aiyagari, S. Rao, Toni Braun, and Zvi Eckstein. "Transactions
Services, Inflation, and Welfare." Manuscript. 1995.
Blinder, Alan. Statement before the Subcommittee on Domestic and
International Monetary Policy of the Committee on Banking and Financial
Services, U.S. House of Representatives, October 11, 1995.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 80th Annual Report,
1993. Washington: Board of Governors, 1994a.
-----. PACS Expense Report, 1993. Washington: Board of Governors,
1994b.
Bryant, John, and Neil Wallace. "A Price Discrimination Analysis
of Monetary Policy," Review of Economic Studies, vol. 51 (April
1984), pp. 279-88.
Dotsey, Michael, and Peter Ireland. "The Welfare Cost of
Inflation in General Equilibrium." Manuscript. 1995.
English, William B. "Inflation and Financial Sector Size,"
Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series No. 96-16
(April 1996).
Friedman, Milton. "The Optimum Quantity of Money," in The
Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Chicago: Aldine, 1969.
-----. A Program for Monetary Stability. New York: Fordham Univ.
Press, 1960.
Ireland, Peter N. "Money and Growth: An Alternative
Approach," American Economic Review, vol. 84 (March 1994), pp.
47-65.
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and Randall Wright. "On Money as a Medium of
Exchange," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 97 (August 1989), pp.
927-54.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. "Should We Subsidize the Use of
Currency?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
vol. 79 (Winter 1993), pp. 47-73.
-----, and Stacey L. Schreft. "Money and Credit as Means of
Payment," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 38 (August 1996), pp.
3-23.
Laster, David, and John Wenninger. "Policy Issues Raised by
Electronic Money." Paper presented to the Conference on Digital
Cash and Electronic Money, held at the Columbia Business School, April
21, 1995.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Nancy L. Stokey. "Optimal Fiscal and
Monetary Policy in an Economy without Capital," Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 12 (July 1983), pp. 55-93.
Marquis, Milton H., and Kevin L. Reffett. "New Technology
Spillovers into the Payment System," Economic Journal, vol. 104
(September 1994), pp. 1123-38.
-----. "Capital in the Payments System," Economica, vol. 59
(August 1992), pp. 351-64.
Prescott, Edward C. "A Multiple Means of Payment Model," in
William A. Bamett and Kenneth J. Singleton, eds., New Approaches to
Monetary Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 1987.
Rolnick, Arthur J., and Warren E. Weber. "The Causes of Free
Bank Failures: A Detailed Examination," Journal of Monetary
Economics, vol. 14 (November 1984), pp. 267-92.
-----. "New Evidence on the Free Banking Era," American
Economic Review, vol. 73 (December 1983), pp. 1080-91.
Schreft, Stacey L. "Welfare-Improving Credit Controls,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 30 (October 1992a), pp. 57-72.
-----. "Transaction Costs and the Use of Cash and Credit,"
Economic Theory, vol. 2 (1992b), pp. 283-96.
Townsend, Robert M. "Currency and Credit in a Private
Information Economy," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 97
(December 1989), pp. 1323-44.
-----. "Economic Organization with Limited Communication,"
American Economic Review, vol. 77 (December 1987), pp. 954-71.
-----. "Financial Structures as Communications Systems," in
Colin Lawrence and Robert P. Shay, eds., Technological Innovation,
Regulation, and the Monetary Economy. Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1986.
Wallace, Neil. "The Impact of New Payment Technologies: A Macro
View," in Colin Lawrence and Robert P. Shay, eds., Technological
Innovation, Regulation, and the Monetary Economy. Cambridge, Mass.:
Ballinger, 1986.
-----. "A Legal Restrictions Theory of the Demand for
'Money' and the Role of Monetary Policy," Federal Reserve
Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, vol. 7 (Winter 1983), pp. 1-7.
Whitesell, William C. "Deposit Banks and the Market for Payment
Media," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 24 (November
1992), pp. 483-98.
Williamson, Stephen D. "Laissez-Faire Banking and Circulating
Media of Exchange," Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol. 2
(June 1992), pp. 134-67.