Some not-so-unpleasant monetarist arithmetic.
Dotsey, Michael
The motivation for this article is the well-known and controversial
work of Sargent and Wallace (1981), who show the potential importance of
the government's budget constraint for the behavior of nominal
variables. The government's lifetime budget constraint can place
restrictions on the behavior of future money growth and thus influence
current economic magnitudes through expectational channels. Some of
Sargent and Wallace's results are indeed striking, and indicate
that tight monetary policy can lead to the unpleasant outcome of both
higher expected inflation and a higher price level. Theoretically, they
highlight important intertemporal considerations, but one wonders if
these considerations are quantitatively meaningful in reality.
In order to investigate the quantitative significance of monetarist arithmetic, I develop a dynamic stochastic model in which the
government's budget constraint has nontrivial implications. In
particular, I use the methodology of Dotsey (1994) and Dotsey and Mao
(1996). Here both money growth and taxes are stochastic, but one or both
must endogenously respond to government debt if the government is to
maintain budget balance. When the monetary authority does not respond to
debt, I term its policy independent monetary policy, and when it does
respond to debt, I call it dependent monetary policy. The primary focus
of the article is on the behavior of nominal variables and involves a
comparison of their behavior when the monetary authority is and is not
independent. The main result is that, for reasonable parameterizations,
and when the tax authority responds to the level of debt, the underlying
nominal behavior of the economy does not significantly depend upon
whether the monetary authority reacts to government financing
considerations. In this sense the monetarist arithmetic is not so
unpleasant.
The considerations addressed in this article are also similar to
those discussed in Aiyagari and Gertler (1985), Leeper (1991), and
Woodford (1995). These authors are all concerned with the relationship
between the behavior of money and nominal variables in models that
emphasize the importance of the government's budget constraint. The
article proceeds as follows. Section 1 reviews the key elements of the
above-cited papers that are most relevant to the experiments carried out
in this article. Section 2 describes the behavior of taxes and money
growth as well as the underlying economic model. Section 3 investigates
parameterizations that produce the spectacular example presented in
Sargent and Wallace, in which current inflation increases under
contractionary monetary policy. These parameterizations do not
accurately characterize the U.S. economy and the spectacular example
does not occur under realistic behavioral assumptions. Section 4
analyzes a model economy that is more consistent with that of the United
States. For this case, data are generated under both independent and
dependent monetary policy rules. Only minor differences are found in the
behavior of nominal variables. Section 5 concludes.
1. LITERATURE SURVEY
Sargent and Wallace (1981) present a model economy that satisfies the
monetarist assumptions that the monetary base is closely connected to
the price level and that the monetary authority can raise seignorage
through money creation. They show that under certain conditions the
monetary authority's ability to control inflation is limited. The
major condition responsible for this result is the exogeneity of the
process for the government's deficit. Given this exogeneity, tight
money today leads to higher inflation in the future and may even lead to
higher inflation today.
Leeper (1991) extends the Sargent and Wallace analysis to a
stochastic environment. Leeper's model is, however, somewhat
different in that the monetary authority uses an interest rate
instrument and reacts, in some cases, to the rate of inflation. The
monetary authority does not react specifically to debt as it does in the
model presented below. Also, another distinction between Leeper's
model and my model is that I use money as the policy instrument.(1) This
modeling is more directly related to Sargent and Wallace.
Like Leeper, I find that when monetary policy is independent, fiscal
disturbances in the form of lump sum taxes have no influence on either
nominal or real variables. Also, as in Leeper, when the monetary
authority responds to debt, fiscal disturbances do affect the economy.
Both the price level and the nominal interest rate are positively
related to debt. Contrary to his analysis, however, I find that a
monetary contraction does not generally cause the nominal interest rate
to rise. This difference is a result of the more general stochastic
process that governs monetary policy, a process that allows for varying
degrees of persistence in policy. A current decline in money growth need
not be offset by an immediate increase in next period's money
growth as occurs in one of the examples emphasized in his paper.
The analysis here is also related to the work of Aiyagari and Gertler
(1985) and Woodford (1995). These authors indicate that when monetary
policy is influenced by the government's intertemporal budget
constraint, nominal variables are sensitive to debt. In contrast to the
results in Aiyagari and Gertler, the model considered here indicates
that the nominal interest rate and inflation are not necessarily higher
when monetary policy depends on the level of government debt. The
difference in results occurs because the stochastic process for money
growth implies that low money growth rates are more likely when the debt
is low. Thus, the possible values of the nominal interest under a
dependent monetary policy span the values that occur when monetary
policy is independent.
Much of the work in this area adopts the confusing terminology of
Ricardian and non-Ricardian monetary policy. I choose not to use this
terminology and instead use the terms independent and dependent monetary
policy. As Aiyagari and Gertler point out, Ricardian monetary policies
do not necessarily imply that the Ricardian equivalence theorem holds.
Also, different authors appear to have somewhat different
interpretations of what constitutes a Ricardian monetary regime.
Aiyagari and Gertler adopt Sargent's (1982) definition, which
refers to whether or not government bonds are fully backed by taxes.
That is, the fiscal authority commits to a tax process with a present
discounted value equal to the present discounted value of government
spending and the current value of outstanding government debt.
Woodford's definition is somewhat different. It refers to the
transversality condition on debt and whether that condition holds
independently. Thus, in Woodford's terminology, a model can be
Ricardian even though seignorage revenues respond to changes in
government debt. His definition, therefore, allows money to respond to
debt in a Ricardian world. In all the models considered below, the real
value of the debt is bounded, and hence its present discounted value
approaches zero. Yet debt does have real and nominal effects in some of
the models. Therefore, I prefer to use the terminology of independent
and dependent monetary policy.
2. THE MODEL
In this section I depict the fiscal and monetary policy process as
well as the technology and behavioral assumptions that characterize the
economic environment relevant to this study.
Fiscal and Monetary Policy Processes
The monetary and fiscal policy processes analyzed here are stochastic
and satisfy the government's budget constraint. Monetary policy is
defined over changes in base growth rather than in terms of setting the
nominal interest rates. This depiction of policy is consistent with
previous literature relating deficit finance and inflation.(2) This
modeling of monetary policy also allows one to investigate the
consequences of money growth's dependence on debt while
incorporating the empirically relevant behavior of taxes responding to
debt (see Bohn [1991]). Interest rate smoothing could easily be
incorporated by allowing the monetary authority to respond to unexpected
movements in the nominal interest rate without affecting the existence
or uniqueness of the solutions (see Boyd and Dotsey [1996]).
Money, [M.sub.t], is introduced through open market operations and
behaves according to
[M.sub.t] = [M.sub.t-1](1 + [[Eta].sub.t]), (1)
where [[Eta].sub.t] is the stochastic rate of money growth.
Taxes are proportional to output. Thus, tax revenues, [T.sub.t], are
given by
[T.sub.t] = [[Tau].sub.t][Y.sub.t], (2)
where [Y.sub.t] is current nominal output and [[Tau].sub.t] is the
current tax rate. The government's nominal debt, [B.sub.t+1],
therefore, follows
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (3)
where G represents fixed transfer payments, and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] is the price of a bond at date t that pays one
dollar at date t + 1. The real value of debt relative to ouput,
[B.sub.t+1]/[Y.sub.t+1] = [b.sub.t+1], can be written as
[b.sub.t+1] = [R.sub.t][g + [b.sub.t] - [[Tau].sub.t] -
([[Eta].sub.t]/(1 + [[Eta].sub.t]))([M.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t])]([Y.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t+1]), (4)
where [R.sub.t] is the gross one period nominal interest rate.
A sufficient condition for the government to obey its lifetime budget
constraint is for the tax and money growth processes to behave so that
the debt-to-GNP ratio is bounded. For that to happen, either one or both
processes must depend on government debt. When money and tax rates
respond to debt they are modeled as two-state Markov processes with
endogenous transition probabilities. Thus the processes are time
varying. In particular, let the transition probabilities for taxes be
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (5)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and those for money growth be
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (6)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where the subscripts l and h refer to low and high, respectively.
As long as the debt-to-GNP ratio rises when both taxes and money
growth rates are low and falls when tax rates and money growth rates are
high, the debt-to-GNP ratio is bounded and will only rarely lie outside
the interval [0,1/[Phi]]. As [b.sub.t] approaches 1/[Phi], both taxes
and money growth will be high with probability one. Similarly, as
[b.sub.t] approaches 0, both taxes and money growth will be low. The
parameters [Nu] and [Psi] control the persistence of the two processes.
For any given debt-to-GNP ratio, as [Nu] and [Psi] increase, the
probability of remaining in the current state increases. The above
specifications of policy imply that current realizations of taxes and
money growth have implications for the entire future path of policy
through their effect on debt.
It is important to note that both the unconditional mean and the
persistence of money growth do not depend on the debt-to-GNP ratio. If
instead the monetary authority had no control over the mean and over
persistence of money growth rates, it would be trivial to show that the
nominal behavior of the economy depended on fiscal policy. Instead I
explore the more difficult question of whether conditional dependence of
monetary policy on debt affects nominal magnitudes.
Alternatively, cases in which one of the processes is invariant to
debt can be analyzed. I allow for the invariance of tax rates when
investigating parameterizations that yield the spectacular case of
Sargent and Wallace. I also compare the nominal behavior of an economy
when the money growth process does and does not depend on debt.
Technology and Preferences
Since I am primarily concerned with the nominal behavior of the
economy, I treat real output as fixed at a constant level, y. Agents
derive utility from consumption, c, and real balances, m. Specifically,
they maximize
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
subject to the per-period budget constraint
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where p is the price level and E is the expectations operator
conditional on time 0 information. This specification of preferences
allows one to look at a range of interest elasticities of money demand
and to freely parameterize the ratio m/c.
The first-order conditions determining the demand for money and the
optimal consumption-saving decision by individuals are given by
([m.sub.t] / [c.sub.t]) = [([Theta](1 + [r.sub.t]) /
[r.sub.t]).sup.1/(1+[Rho])] (7)
and
(1 / 1 + [r.sub.t]) [[1 +
[Theta][([c.sub.t]/[m.sub.t]).sup.[Rho]]].sup.-(1/[Rho])-1] =
[Beta][E.sub.t]{[[1 + [Theta]
[([c.sub.t+1]/[m.sub.t+1]).sup.[Rho]]].sup.-(1/[Rho])-1]
([p.sub.t]/[p.sub.t+1])}, (8)
where [r.sub.t] is the net nominal interest rate and [E.sub.t] is the
expectations operator conditional on time t information. Agents are
assumed to know all contemporaneously dated variables as well as the
nominal value of end-of-period government debt. Equation (7) implies
that money demand is unit elastic with respect to the scale variable
consumption and has an interest elasticity of -(1/(1 + [Rho]))(1/(1 +
r)). Also, for a given steady-state interest elasticity the parameter
[Theta] determines the velocity of money. For example, as [Rho] goes to
infinity m = c and the model approaches a cash-in-advance specification,
while as p goes to zero money demand becomes unit elastic. Equation (8)
governs the optimal consumption-saving decision. Note that real money
balances influence intertemporal consumption choices through their
effect on the marginal utility of consumption. Higher current real money
balances increase the marginal utility of consumption and, holding
expected future consumption and money balances constant, imply a higher
real interest rate.
Equilibrium
The equilibrium conditions for this economy are
[c.sub.t] = y, (9)
[M.sub.t]/[p.sub.t] = [m.sub.t], (10)
and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (11)
along with the first-order conditions (7) and (8), the agent's
budget constraint, and the government's budget constraint (3). The
three equations (9)-(11) merely state that demand equals supply in the
goods, money, and bond markets, respectively. Substituting (7) into (8)
and using (9) and (10), these four equations can be used to derive a
functional equation for the nominal interest rate. Combined with the law
of motion for real government debt (equation [4]) and the stochastic
processes for taxes and money growth, the equilibrium functions for the
nominal interest rate r(b, [Tau], [Eta]) and next period's real
debt b[prime](b, [Tau], [Eta], [Tau][prime], [Eta][prime]) can be solved
(where the symbol "[prime]"refers to next period value of a
variable). Using the solution for r, one can readily derive the
solutions for real balances, prices, and expected inflation. Thus,
equilibrium is a set of functions for r, b[prime], p, c, and m that
satisfy equations (4), and (7)-(11). Because there is no closed form
solution, I obtain the solution numerically by solving for the relevant
functions along a grid of real debt levels and at the values of taxes
and money growth.
3. THE SPECTACULAR CASE
In their spectacular example, Sargent and Wallace showed that it is
possible for lower current money growth to cause both higher expected
inflation and a higher price level. The higher expected inflation occurs
because lower money growth increases the government's indebtedness,
implying that money growth must be, on average, higher in the future.
The higher expected future money growth leads to higher expected
inflation. Also, the higher expected inflation reduces the current
demand for real balances. If the reduction in demand is large enough,
the price level must rise to clear the money market. As Drazen (1985)
points out, this latter result requires an interest elasticity of at
least one in absolute value. Using the model of the previous section, we
are able to produce a spectacular example. To do so requires some
additional assumptions that are extreme when compared to actual economic
behavior in the United States. Besides the unusual responsiveness of
money demand to nominal interest rates, the ratio m/c must be higher
than one observes in the data, and rates of money growth in the high
money growth state must be somewhat higher than commonly observed in the
post-war United States. Both of these counterfactual parameterizations
must be made in order to bound the debt-to-GNP ratio. That is, both the
tax base and the tax rate on money balances in the high money growth
state must be sufficiently high to pay off the increased debt burden
that accrues in the low money growth state.
The policy functions for the spectacular example are depicted in
Figure 1. To produce this example, the interest elasticity of money
demand was set at -1, the steady-state ratio m/c was set at 0.25, and
the low and high money growth rates were selected to be -1.25 percent
and 13.5 percent, respectively. Also, money growth is quite persistent
with [Psi] = 5. This parameterization corresponds to an autocorrelation of roughly 0.65. The model is calibrated at an annual frequency and
[Beta] = 0.98. With these parameter values, the debt to GNP ratio lies
between -0.46 and 0.58. As shown in the top panel of Figure 1, the
nominal interest rate is higher when money growth is low, even though
the money growth process is characterized by substantial persistence.(3)
This persistence is depicted in the middle panel of Figure 1, which
shows that agents expect substantially higher future money growth when
money growth is currently high. One also observes, in the bottom panel,
that the price level is higher when money growth is low.
To highlight the necessity of the high interest elasticity, I also
examine the case in which the interest elasticity is -0.20. This value
is representative of money demand in the United States (see Dotsey
[1988]). As shown in Figure 2, both the nominal interest rate and the
price level are higher when current money growth is high. Thus, the
spectacular case is reversed. Additional insight into the important role
that the interest elasticity plays in producing the spectacular result
can be found in Table 1. This table shows the interest rates that would
occur under the high and low money growth rates for various elasticities
of money demand. These interest rates are obtained from the following
thought experiment. Suppose that the transition probability for money
growth is 0.8 and independent of the debt. Also suppose that the tax
authority adjusts taxes to bound the level of debt. Then high current
money growth always implies higher future money growth. The interest
rates that solve equation (8) can be calculated for various values of
the interest elasticity and a value of m/c = 0.25. As depicted in the
table, the difference between the nominal interest rate when money
growth is high as opposed to when it is low narrows substantially as the
interest elasticity increases in absolute value.
The narrowing of the spread between interest rates under high and low
money growth along with the implication that current low money growth
leads to higher average future money growth produce the spectacular
example. Furthermore, the high interest elasticity implies that money
demand falls by more than one-for-one with the money supply and the
price level must rise to equilibrate the money market.
Table 1 Interest Elasticity Effects on Interest Rates
Interest Elasticity of
Money Demand [R.sub.t] [R.sub.h]
-0.10 0.051 0.119
-0.25 0.063 0.100
-0.50 0.068 0.092
-0.75 0.071 0.088
-1.00 0.072 0.086
Note: In this example money growth takes on the values -0.0055 and
0.142, and the transition probability of remaining in the same
state is 0.8.
4. MONETARIST ARITHMETIC IN A CALIBRATED MODEL
To explore the empirical significance of monetarist arithmetic, I
calibrate two related models and compare the behavior of nominal
variables and expected lifetime utility. In both models, endowment is
fixed at one unit and government transfers are equal to 0.189. The
models are calibrated to produce a steady-state interest elasticity of
money demand of -0.20 and a ratio of money to consumption of 0.10. At an
annual frequency, both of these values are consistent with U.S. data.
The discount factor is set at 0.98, implying a steady-state real
interest rate of two percent. The money growth rates are 0.049 and
0.086, while the tax rates are 0.17 and 0.229. The debt-to-GNP ratio
lies within the interval [-0.12, 0.62]. The two models are similar in
that the tax authority responds to the debt-to-GNP ratio as described in
equation (5). The persistence parameter, v, is set at 3.5. The first
model considered depicts a dependent monetary policy as described by
equation (6) with a persistence parameter, [Psi], equal to 5.0. The
second model allows monetary policy to be independent and the transition
probability of remaining in the same state of money growth is 0.85.
These parameterizations of tax rates and money growth produce
realizations that are consistent with U.S. experience over the period
1961 to 1995.
Policy Functions
The policy functions for the case in which monetary policy responds
to debt are depicted in Figure 3. One sees that expected money growth is
positively related to government debt. As government debt approaches one
half of GNP, the probability of both taxes and money growth being high
approaches one. Similarly, as debt approaches zero, the probability of
both taxes and money growth being low approaches one. Thus, the policy
functions for the different states converge as debt approaches its upper
and lower bounds. The positive relationship between money growth and
debt leads to a positive relationship between debt and both the nominal
interest rate and the price level. The persistence of the money growth
process also implies that higher rates of money growth lead to higher
nominal interest rates and a higher price level. Also, for any given
rate of money growth, higher taxes imply lower nominal interest rates
and lower prices. This result occurs because higher taxes reduce the
debt and, therefore, imply a lower average rate of future money growth.
Consequently, like Leeper (1991) and Aiyagari and Gertler (1985), the
model implies that fiscal policy affects nominal variables through its
influence on the path of future money growth.
The real interest rate in this model is also related to the level of
debt, monetary policy, and fiscal policy. Higher rates of money growth
are associated with lower real balances and with a lower marginal
utility of consumption. In the case where money growth is high, the
expected value of next period's money growth will be less than its
current rate. Hence, next period's real balances are expected to be
higher and next period's expected marginal utility will be greater
than current marginal utility. This relationship between current and
expected future marginal utility implies that the real interest rate
will be lower when money growth is currently high. Also, for any given
rate of money growth, higher taxes imply lower expected money growth in
the future. This lower expected future money growth is associated with
higher expected future real balances and a higher expected future
marginal utility of consumption. Thus, the real interest rate is lower
when taxes are high. Similarly, because lower debt implies lower future
money growth, the real interest rate is low when debt is low.
When monetary policy is independent, the policy functions look very
different. As shown in Figure 4, debt and fiscal policy no longer have
any effects on economic variables. This invariance occurs because taxes
and debt do not influence the path of money growth. The policy
functions, therefore, take on only two values, one is associated with
low money growth, and the other with high money growth. As in the
previous case, high money growth results in higher interest rates and a
higher price level. Comparison of Figures 3 and 4 reveals that the
interest rate and the price level are not necessarily always lower under
independent monetary policy. This latter result contrasts with the
findings of Aiyagari and Gertler (1985) and occurs because conditional
on the debt being low, money growth is much more likely to be low with a
dependent monetary policy. Their results, therefore, are sensitive to
the actual stochastic specification of policy.
Further Comparison of the Two Policies
To further contrast economic consequences of independent and
dependent monetary policies, I examine time series from model
simulations. Each simulation is 100 periods long and the results are
averaged over 500 simulations. With respect to dependent monetary
policy, the simulated tax process has a mean of 0.187 and a standard
deviation of 0.027. These values compare with an actual mean of average
tax revenues over the period 1961 to 1995 of 0.189 and standard
deviation of 0.0074. The simulated tax process is somewhat more variable
than the historical series on average tax rates but shows about the same
degree of variability as the average marginal tax rate series computed
using the methodology of Barro and Sahasakul (1986).(4) The mean of
money growth is 0.06 and its standard deviation is 0.017. These values
are similar to the actual values for the growth rate of the monetary
base, which had a mean of 0.067 and a standard deviation of 0.020.
A further comparison between the generated processes for taxes and
money growth and their empirical counterparts can be obtained by
examining the following linear regressions. For generated data under a
dependent monetary policy, the regressions are given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (12)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (13)
while for an independent monetary policy the corresponding
regressions are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (14)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (15)
where standard errors are in parentheses. From these regressions
alone, it would be difficult to distinguish between the two regimes. All
the comparable coefficients differ insignificantly from each other and
in neither regime does monetary policy appear to depend on debt. The
reason for the insignificant coefficient on debt in the money growth
regression (13) is that taxes are doing the bulk of the work in
controlling debt. The money growth process is highly persistent
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 5 OMITTED], even at the bounds of the debt
space, and taxes are more likely to change states in order to reduce the
debt when it is high or increase the debt when it is low. Thus, a simple
econometric exercise to test whether seignorage is influenced by debt
would fail to uncover this feature in the dependent monetary regime.
Based on actual data over the period 1961 to 1995, the corresponding
regressions are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (16)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (17)
With the exception of the insignificance of debt on average tax
rates, the regressions on actual and generated data are quite
similar.(5) The calibrated processes, therefore, seem to be fairly
representative of actual processes.
To compare the influences of monetary policy in the two model
economies, I examine impact effects and correlations. For the chosen
parameterization the steady-state value of the nominal interest rate is
0.0887, the real interest rate is 0.020, and the price level is 10M.
With low taxes, low money growth, and a dependent monetary policy, the
nominal interest rate falls to 0.0807 and the price level declines to
9.810. If taxes were high, then the interest rate would decline to
0.0770 and the price level would fall to 9.719. With an independent
monetary policy, low money growth results in a nominal interest rate of
0.0809 and a price level of 9.814. Here, unlike the finding in Aiyagari
and Gertler (1985), monetary policy in a dependent regime does affect
the price level. Furthermore, although fiscal policy also affects the
price level, the effect is much less than one-for-one. For example,
under low money growth and high taxes, inflation is 4.3 percent as
opposed to 5.0 percent when taxes are low. These contrary results occur
for two reasons. One is the explicit stochastic process for policy and
the other is the lower interest elasticity of money demand. As the
interest elasticity approaches zero, so that m = c, prices must move
one-for-one with money regardless of the regime.
The preceding example shows that the impact effects of monetary
policy differ somewhat across regimes. It remains to ask whether the
correlations between policy and nominal variables are very different
across regimes. The correlations are depicted in Table 2. The top panel
shows the correlation coefficients that occur under a dependent monetary
policy and the bottom panel depicts the same correlations under an
independent monetary policy. With respect to the correlations between
money growth, [Eta], and other nominal variables or between money growth
and real balances, the correlations are somewhat smaller under a
dependent monetary policy, but by-and-large the correlations are quite
similar. The only quantitatively significant differences occur with
respect to correlations involving the real interest rate. However, as
shown by the policy functions, the real interest rate shows very little
variation. Given the presence of measurement error, it would be
difficult in practice to identify the monetary regime through the use of
data on ex ante real interest rates. Thus, the data generated by the two
different models are very much the same.
Table 2 Correlation Coefficients
Dependent Monetary Policy
m r [[Pi].sup.e] [Pi] rr
[Eta] -0.848 0.854 0.862 0.864 -0.900
m -0.998 -0.999 -0.759 0.577
r 1.000 0.765 -0.586
[[Pi].sup.e] 0.770 -0.599
[Pi] -0.742
Independent Monetary Policy
m r [[Pi].sup.e] [Pi] rr
[Eta] -1.00 1.00 1.00 0.88 -1.00
m -1.00 -1.00 -0.88 1.00
r 1.00 0.88 -1.00
[[Pi].sup.e] 0.88 -1.00
[Pi] 0.88
Note: [Eta] is money growth, m is real balances, r is the net
nominal interest rate, [[Pi].sup.e] is expected inflation, [Pi] is
actual inflation, and rr is the ex ante real rate of interest.
5. CONCLUSION
This article analyzes the economic effects of a monetary policy that
responds to debt and compares those effects with ones that arise under
an independent monetary policy. A principal finding is that the nominal
behavior of the two calibrated economies is not very different under the
two types of monetary regimes. Indeed, linear regression analysis is
unable to distinguish between the two economies. It would be even more
difficult to distinguish econometrically between independent and
dependent monetary policy if dependent monetary policy only reacted to
debt at the boundaries of the debt-to-GNP ratio rather than continuously
as it does in the above example. Thus, the monetarist arithmetic is not
overly unpleasant.
My analysis also indicates that in explorations of the
interrelationship between monetary and fiscal policy, the exact form of
the stochastic processes is important. Characteristics of the processes,
such as persistence, are crucial in gauging the economic effects of
policy. Policy, both fiscal and monetary, need not react immediately to
changes in government debt, and the timing of the reaction is important.
The empirically based persistence of the process for monetary policy is
one feature of the model that leads to results that differ from those of
other authors.
In addition to demonstrating the importance of the stochastic
processes, the results in this article also indicate that behavioral
parameters play an important role in determining the different effects
that occur under the two types of monetary policy. In particular, the
interest elasticity of money demand is a crucial parameter. The interest
elasticity employed in this article is much lower than that used in the
papers of both Leeper (1991) and Aiyagari and Gertler (1985). The lower
interest elasticity is partly responsible for the influence exerted by
dependent monetary policy on the nominal interest rate in my model,
which is contrary to the results presented in Aiyagari and
Gertler's model. Furthermore, a realistic parameterization of the
interest elasticity implies that the spectacular example of Sargent and
Wallace is implausible. Thus, it appears that although the intertemporal
considerations highlighted by Sargent and Wallace are important
theoretically, they appear to be less so in practice.
I would like to thank Zvi Hercowitz, Robert Hetzel, Tom Humphrey,
Peter Ireland, Alan Stockman, and Alex Wolman for a number of useful
suggestions and Jed DeVaro for research assistance. The views expressed
in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily represent
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.
1 One could always make the money supply rule more realistic by
including elements of interest rate smoothing. For a detailed discussion
on interest rate instruments in a rational expectations model, see Boyd
and Dotsey (1996).
2 For example see Sargent and Wallace (1981), Liviatan (1984),
McCallum (1984), Drazen (1985), Aiyagari and Gertler (1985), and
Woodford (1995).
3 The policy function for expected inflation is qualitatively
identical to that of the nominal interest rate. It is, therefore,
omitted.
4 The Barro and Sahasakul series was taken from DRI, and its standard
deviation is 0.0260.
5 Although taxes do not seem to respond to debt over the short sample
period considered here, fiscal policy does seem to respond to debt over
longer time horizons (see Bohn [1991]) and at lower frequencies (see
Dotsey and Mao [1996]).
REFERENCES
Aiyagari, S. Rao, and Mark Gertler. "The Backing of Government
Bonds and Monetarista," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 16
(July 1985), pp. 19-44.
Barro, Robert J., and Chaipat Sahasakul. "Average Marginal Tax
Rates from Social Security and the Individual Income Tax," Journal
of Business, vol. 59 (October 1986), pp. 555-66.
Bohn, Henning. "Budget Balance through Revenue or Spending
Adjustments? Some Historial Evidence for the United States,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 27 (June 1991), pp. 333-59.
Boyd, John H., III, and Michael Dotsey. "Interest Rate Rules and
Nominal Determinacy," Manuscript. University of Rochester and
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, June 1996.
Dotsey, Michael. "Some Unpleasant Supply Side Arithmetic,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 33 (June 1994), pp. 507-24.
-----. "The Demand for Currency in the United States,"
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 20 (February 1988), pp.
22-40.
-----, and Ching Sheng Mao. "The Effects of Fiscal Policy in a
Neoclassical Growth Model," Working Paper 94-3. Richmond: Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond, February 1996.
Drazen, Allan. "Tight Money and Inflation: Further
Results," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 15 (January 1985),
pp. 113-20.
King, Robert G., and Charles I. Plosser. "Money, Deficits, and
Inflation," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
vol. 22 (Spring 1985), pp. 147-96.
Leeper, Eric M. "Equilibria Under 'Active' and
'Passive' Monetary and Fiscal Policies," Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 27 (February 1991), pp. 129-47.
Liviatan, Nissan. "Tight Money and Inflation," Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 13 (January 1984), pp. 5-15.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Are Bond-financed Deficits Inflationary? A
Ricardian Analysis," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 92
(February 1984), pp. 123-35.
Sargent, Thomas J. "The Ends of Four Big Inflations," in
Robert E. Hall, ed., Inflation: Causes and Effects. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1982.
-----, and Neil Wallace. "Some Unpleasant Monetarist
Arithmetic," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
vol. 5 (Fall 1981), pp. 1-17.
Woodford, Michael. "Price-Level Determinacy without Control of a
Monetary Aggregate," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy, vol. 43 (December 1995), pp. 1-46.