The rational expectations hypothesis of the term structure, monetary policy, and time-varying term premia.
Dotsey, Michael ; Otrok, Christopher
Most empirical studies of the rational expectations hypothesis of the
term structure (REHTS) generally find that the data offer little support
for the theory.(1) In many cases this large body of empirical work
indicates that the theory does not even provide a close approximation of
market behavior. This feature has led some investigators to search for
alternative "irrational" theories of behavior in order to
explain the data. We, on the other hand, believe that the rejections are
so striking that the large amount of irrationality implied by the data
is too implausible for this avenue to be treated seriously. Since the
rejection of rational expectations in these studies generally involves
the rejection of more complicated joint hypotheses, we choose to focus
our energies on exploring a broader class of models that are consistent
with REHTS.
In particular, we examine a model that incorporates Federal Reserve
behavior along with a reasonable parameterization of term premia to
revise the theory. The consideration of Fed behavior was first suggested
by Mankiw and Miron (1986), who found that REHTS was more consistent
with the data prior to the founding of the Fed. Even stronger evidence
is presented in Choi and Wohar (1991), who cannot reject REHTS over the
sample period of 1910-14. Cook and Hahn (1990) and Goodfriend (1991)
argue persuasively that the Federal Reserve's use of a funds rate
instrument, and, in particular, the way in which that instrument is
employed, is partly responsible for the apparent failure of REHTS.
Recently Rudebusch (1994), in a study very much in the spirit of
ours, provides some empirical support for the Cook and Hahn (1990) and
Goodfriend (1991) hypothesis. Further, McCallum (1994) shows the
theoretical linkage between the Fed's policy role and the
regression estimates in various tests of REHTS when the Fed responds to
the behavior of longer-term interest rates.
While Fed behavior represents a potentially important component for
explaining the empirical results of tests of REHTS, any explanation of
these results that also maintains rational expectations must include
time-varying term premia. Without time-varying term premia, tests of
REHTS will not be rejected. This fact is pointed out in Mankiw and Miron
(1986) and Campbell and Shiller (1991). Further, Campbell and Shiller
indicate that white-noise term premia are insufficient to reconcile
theory with data. We find this to be the case as well. Thus, we examine
a more elaborate model of term premia coupled with Fed behavior in an
attempt to explain some of the empirical results on REHTS.
Before developing a theory of Fed behavior and linking it to
empirical work on REHTS, we present, in Section 1, a brief overview of
the rational expectations hypothesis of the term structure. Then, in
Section 2, we construct a model of Fed behavior that emodies the key
elements described in Goodfriend (1991). We use the resulting model
along with REHTS to generate returns on bonds of maturities ranging from
one to six months. In Section 3 we focus, in essence, on the empirical
regularities documented by Roberds, Runkle, and Whiteman (1993). We show
that Fed behavior is not enough to reproduce their findings. Then, in
Section 4, we turn our attention to incorporating a more realistic
behavior of term premia. Combining these term premia with rational
investor and Fed behavior generates data that is roughly consistent with
the Roberds, Runkle, and Whiteman results. Section 5 concludes.
1. THE RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS THEORY OF THE TERM STRUCTURE
Tests and descriptions of the rational expectations theory of the
term structure constitute a voluminous literature. An excellent survey
can be found in Cook and Hahn (1990), and an exhaustive treatment is
contained in Campbell and Shiller (1991). The basic idea is that with
the exception of a term premium, there should be no expected difference
in the returns from holding a long-term bond or rolling over a sequence
of short-term bonds. As a result, the long-term interest rate should be
an average of future expected short-term interest rates plus a term
premium. Specifically, the interest rate on a long-term bond of maturity
n, [r.sub.t](n), will obey
[r.sub.t](n) = 1/k [summation of][E.sub.t][r.sub.t+mi](m) where i = 0
to k - 1 + [[Phi].sub.t](n, m), (1)
where [r.sub.t+mi](m) is the m period bond rate at date t + mi,
[E.sub.t] is the conditional expectations operator over time t
information, and [[Phi].sub.t](n, m) is the term premia between the n
and rn period bonds.(2) In equation (1), k = n/m and is restricted to be
an integer.
The rational expectations hypothesis implies that [r.sub.t+mi](m) =
[E.sub.t][r.sub.t+mi](m) + [e.sub.t+mi](m), where [e.sub.t+mi](m) has
mean zero and is uncorrelated with time t information. Using this
implication, one can rearrange equation (1) to yield the following
relationship:
1/k[summation of][[r.sub.t+mi](m) - [r.sub.t](m)] where i = 1 to k -
1 = [Alpha] + [r.sub.t](n) - [r.sub.t](m) + [v.sub.t](n, m), (2)
where [v.sub.t](n, m) = 1/k[summation of][e.sub.t+mi](m) where i = 1
to k - 1 - [[[Phi].sub.t](n, m) - [Alpha]] and [Alpha] is the
non-time-varying
part of the term premium. Thus, future interest rate differentials on
the shorter-term bond are related to the current interest rate spread
between the long- and short-term bond.
Equation (2) forms the basis of the tests of the term structure that
we focus on in this article. This involves running the regression
1/k[summation of][[r.sub.t+mi](m) - [r.sub.t](m)] = where i = 1 to k
- 1 [Alpha] + [Beta][[r.sub.t](n) - [r.sub.t](m)] + [v.sub.t](n, m) (3)
and testing if [Beta] = 1. We shall focus our attention on n = 2, 3,
4, 5, and 6 months and m = 1 and 3 months. For m = 3 and n = 6 (implying
k = 2), the appropriate regression would be
1/2 [[r.sub.t+3](3) - [r.sub.t](3)] = [Alpha] + [Beta][[r.sub.t](6) -
[r.sub.t](3)] + [v.sub.t](6, 3). (3[prime])
That is, the change in the three-month interest rate three months
from now should be reflected in the difference between the current
six-month and three-month rates because the pricing of the six-month
bill should reflect any expected future changes in the rate paid on the
three-month bill.
In the absence of time-varying term premia, the coefficient [Beta]
should equal one. In practice, however, that has not been the case. For
example, Table 1 reports some estimates obtained by Roberds, Runkle, and
Whiteman (1993) and Campbell and Shiller (1991). Not only is [Beta]
[less than] 1, but the degree to which [Beta] deviates from one
increases as k increases. Also, the coefficient in the regression when n
= 6 and m = 3 is of the wrong sign and insignificantly different from
zero.
This latter result is in stark contrast to estimates obtained by
Mankiw and Miron (1986) and Choi and Wohar (1991), who find that prior
to the advent of the Fed, the theory fared much better. These two sets
of results, which primarily involve r(6) - r(3), imply a number of
possibilities among which are the following: (1) REHTS once held but no
longer does (perhaps because investors have become irrational), (2) the
nature of term premia has changed, or (3) Federal Reserve policy has in
some way affected the nature of the empirical tests.
In analyzing these possibilities, we first note that the term premia
must be time-varying for plim [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (i.e.,
the predicted value of [Beta] to be something other than one). To show
this, we report the probability limit of [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] in (3[prime]), which is adopted from the derivation in Mankiw
and Miron (1986):
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1](3)] is the variance
of the expected change in the three-month interest rate, [Rho] is the
correlation between [E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1](3) and
[[Phi].sub.t](6,3), and [[Sigma].sup.2][[[Phi].sub.t](6, 3)] is the
variance of the term premium.(3)
Expression (4) is informative for our purposes. Notice that for
nonstochastic term premia, plim [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Hence
stochastic term premia are required for [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]. Also observe that as [[Sigma].sup.2][[[Phi].sub.t](6, 3)]
increases, plim [Mathematical Expression Omitted] decreases. Further,
note that plim [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is a complicated
function of [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1](3)], but as this
term gets fairy large, plim [Mathematical Expression Omitted] goes to
one. More generally, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] deviation from a
value of one will depend on the ratio of the variance of the term
premium to the variance of the expected change in interest rates.
It is this latter variance that Fed behavior may influence. In this
regard, Mankiw and Miron (1986) document the variation over time in this
variable and show that [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1](3)]
was much larger prior to the creation of the Federal Reserve System.
Mankiw and Miron attribute this finding to the Fed's concern for
interest rate smoothing.
As Cook and Hahn (1990) point out, however, rate smoothing cannot be
the total story since the regression coefficient on [[r.sub.t](2) -
[r.sub.t](1)] is highly significant and close to one; moreover, for
longer-term bonds the term structure does help predict future changes in
interest rates. Regarding the short end of the yield curve, Cook and
Hahn postulate that one must consider the discontinuous [TABULAR DATA
FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] and infrequent changes in policy. Therefore,
economic information that will affect future policy is often known prior
to actual policy reactions. This factor implies that movements in the
short end of the term structure will anticipate policy and hence have
predictive content. In terms of equation (4), the variance of
[Delta][E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1](1) is likely to be greater than the variance
of [Delta][E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1](3).
Additional arguments supporting the relevance of monetary policy for
tests of REHTS can be found in Goodfriend (1991) and McCallum (1994).
McCallum shows that if the Fed reacts to movements in the term
structure, then the strength of that reaction will influence estimates
of [Beta] in tests of REHTS.
Taken together, these papers indicate that capturing Fed behavior is
potentially important for understanding the term structure. We now
attempt such an exercise.
2. A MODEL OF FED BEHAVIOR
Our model of Fed behavior is designed to capture the basic
characteristics described by Goodfriend's (1991) analysis of
Federal Reserve policy. In particular, we model the Federal
Reserve's adjustment of its funds rate target as occurring at
intervals and only in relatively small steps. Also, funds rate changes
are often followed by changes in the same direction so that the Fed does
not "whipsaw" financial markets. While the Fed is generally
viewed as adjusting the funds rate to achieve various economic goals,
for our purposes it is sufficient to let the Fed's best guess of an
unconstrained optimal interest rate target follow an exogenous process.
For simplicity, let
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the unconstrained optimal
interest rate. That is, it is the interest rate the Fed would choose
before the arrival of new information if it were not constrained to move
the funds rate discretely. One could think of [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] as arising from a reaction function, but equation (5), along
with additional behavioral constraints, is sufficient for the purpose of
our investigation. To capture Fed behavior, we model changes in the
funds rate according to the following criteria:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The behavior described by equation (6) implies that at each decision
point Fed is guided by its overall macroeconomic goals as depicted by
the behavior of [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. It adjusts its
instrument [Mathematical Expression Omitted] incrementally and
discretely. Thus, for a big positive shock to [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], the Fed would be expected to raise the funds rate at a number
of decision points until [Mathematical Expression Omitted] approximated
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. There would also be only a small
probability that the Fed would ever reverse itself (i.e., raise the
funds rate one period and lower it the next).
We parameterize the variance of [u.sub.t] and the parameter [Rho] so
that the behavior of the funds rate target, [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], is consistent with actual behavior over the period 1985:1 to
1993:12. The parameter [Rho] is set at 0.15, and [u.sub.t] has a
variance of 0.09. In particular, [u.sub.t] is distributed uniformly on
the interval [-0.525, 0.525]. A uniform distribution is used to
facilitate the pricing of multiperiod bonds in the next section.
The behavior generated by a typical draw from our stochastic process and by the actual funds rate target are reasonably similar. These are
depicted in Figures 1 and 2. Table 2 provides some additional methods of
comparison. The low p-values of Fisher's exact test indicate that
both actual and model data are consistent with targeted interest rate
changes not being independent of the sign of previous changes.(4)
However, a somewhat smaller percentage of interest rate changes are of
the same sign in the model. The Fed, as modeled here, is more likely to
reverse itself than the Fed actually did over this period. Also, the Fed
of our model is more likely to leave the funds rate unchanged. Finally,
the correlation coefficient between funds rate changes in the model is
not significantly different from the actual correlation coefficient
displayed by the data.
We thus feel that equations (5) and (6) jointly represent a
reasonable and tractable model of Federal Reserve behavior, especially
if [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is thought of as depending upon
underlying economic behavior.
3. MONETARY POLICY AND THE TERM STRUCTURE
As described by equations (5) and (6), the Federal Reserve determines
the behavior of the one-period nominal interest rate. The FOMC meets
formally eight times per year and informally via conference calls. Also,
the chairman may act between FOMC meetings so that in actuality the term
of the one-period rate is less than one month. Further, the timing
between decision periods is stochastic and can be as little as one week
or as long as an intermeeting period.(5) For simplicity, we model the
decision period as monthly. Thus, the pricing of a two-month bond or,
more accurately, a two-month federal funds contract will obey
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Table 2 Actual and Model Data Comparison
Actual Model
Percent of Changes of Same Sign 0.833 0.648
Fisher's Exact Text 2.6E-06 0.003600
p-value (standard error) (0.011)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] 0.2661 0.3242
(standard error) 0.04948
Std([E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1] - [r.sub.t]) 0.2409 0.1234
(standard error) (0.0034)
Std[[E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1](2) - [r.sub.t]] 0.2562 0.1457
(standard error) (0.0039)
Std[[E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1](3) - [r.sub.t]] 0.2687 0.1565
(standard error) (0.0040)
Std[[E.sub.t][r.sub.t+3](3) - [r.sub.t](3)](*) 0.1858 0.1306
(0.0052)
* Goldsmith-Nagan yields 0.2011.
Notes: Model data are from 250 draws of a series with 300
observations. The null of Fisher's exact test is that the sign of
the change in the funds rate is independent of the sign of the
previous change.
In calculating the expectation of interest rates further than one
period ahead, say, for example, two periods ahead, one needs to form
time t expectations of terms such as [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Assuming that [u.sub.t] is uniformly distributed, the expressions we
obtain for the various probabilities are linear in [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Thus, one can
pass the expectations operator through the respective cumulative
distribution functions.
For pricing three-, four-, five-, and six-month term federal funds,
we use expressions analogous to equation (7). In order to examine the
effect that our model of monetary policy has on tests of the rational
expectations hypothesis of the term structure, we generate 250
simulations, each containing 300 values of each rate. The results are
presented in Table 3, where standard errors have been corrected using
the Newey-West (1987) procedure. We report results when [TABULAR DATA
FOR TABLE 3 OMITTED] there is no term premium (row 1) and when there is
a white-noise term premium with standard deviation 0.10 (row 2).
The results indicate that in the absence of time-varying term premia,
there is no departure of estimates of [Beta] from one. This essentially
serves as a check on our calculations, since all interest rates are
calculated using REHTS. With a time-varying term premia, REHTS is
rejected. However, the rejection of the model's data is not in
keeping with the result on actual data. The estimates of [Beta] are
increasing in k = n/m rather than decreasing. Also, the results for k =
2 and m = one month, two months, and three months, respectively, are
almost identical for the model, while they are strikingly different for
the data. Looking at Table 2 and equation (4) shows why. Table 2
indicates that [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1](m)] is
approximately the same for m = 1 and m = 3. (When m = 2, its value is
0.151.) With [[Sigma].sup.2][[Phi](n, m)] equivalent by construction,
the estimate of [Beta] will not vary much across experiments. For a
model with white-noise term premia to replicate actual empirical
results, it must generate [[Sigma].sup.2]([E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+1])
[greater than] [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+2](2)] [greater
than] [[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][Delta][r.sub.t+3](3)], which does not
happen in our particular model.
Interestingly enough, as shown in Table 2, the required behavior of
[[Sigma].sup.2][[E.sub.t][r.sub.t+1](m) - [r.sub.T](1)] does not occur
in the data either. We are therefore forced to conclude that our
description of monetary policy, along with white-noise term premia, is
insufficient to explain the empirical results in Roberds, Runkle, and
Whiteman (1993) as well as in Campbell and Shiller (1991). Our failure
could be due primarily to an insufficient model of policy or to an
inadequate model of term premia. In the next section we modify our model
of term premia and reexamine REHTS on data generated by our modified
model.
4. A DESCRIPTION OF TERM PREMIA
To generate term premia that potentially resemble the stochastic
processes of actual term premia, we need some way of estimating term
premia. For this we turn to the multivariate ARCH-M methodology
described in Bollerslev (1990). We use a multivariate model since the
term premia generated from a univariate model are highly correlated. In
essence, we estimate a multivariate ARCH-M model of excess holding
period yields then use the estimated process to simulate time-varying
term premia. The simulated processes, along with the model in Section 2,
are used to generate data on interest rates. This simulated data is then
used to estimate regressions like (3[prime]).
In estimating term premia (for the case in which k = 2), first define
the excess holding period yield, [y.sub.t](n, m), as
2[r.sub.t](n) - [r.sub.t+m](m) - [r.sub.t](m).
From equation (1) we see that this is merely [E.sub.t][r.sub.t+m](m)
- [r.sub.t+m](m) + 2[[Phi].sub.t](n, m), which is the sum of an
expectational error and twice the actual term premium as defined in (1).
The multivariate ARCH-M specification that we estimate over the
sample period 1983:1-1993:12 is given by
[y.sub.t] = [Beta] + [Delta] log [h.sub.t] + [[Epsilon].sub.t], (8)
where [[Epsilon].sub.t] conditioned on past information is a normal
random vector with variance-covariance matrix [H.sub.t]. The elements of
[H.sub.t] are given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[h.sub.ij,t] = [[Rho].sub.ij][h.sub.ii,t][h.sub.jj,t], (9)
where [y.sub.t] is a 3 by 1 vector of the ex-post excess holding
period yields on Treasury bills that includes the two-month versus
one-month bill, the three-month versus one-month bill, and the six-month
versus three-month bill.(6) The [w.sub.i] are fixed weights given by (13
- i)/78. In this specification of the model, the covariances [h.sub.ij]
are allowed to vary but the correlation coefficients, [[Rho].sub.ij],
between the errors are constant. The coefficient estimates are reported
in Table 4. Almost all the coefficients are highly significant.
The term premia derived from this model are depicted in Figure 3 and
are labeled T2, T3, and T6. Recall that T2 and T6 are twice [Phi](2, 1)
and [Phi](6, 3), respectively, while T3 is three times [Phi](3, 1). One
notices the term premia spike upward in 1984, in late 1987, and in early
1991. The term premium on two-month bonds also spikes in late 1988 and
early 1989. The 1987 episode is associated with the October stock market
crash. Interestingly, the 1984 and 1988-89 episodes correspond to the
inflation-scare episodes documented in Goodfriend (1993). The last spike in the term premia occurs around the time of the Gulf War and a
recession.
Table 4 Coefficient Estimates for ARCH-M Model Log likelihood =
149.72
Coefficient Estimate Standard Error Significance Level
[[Beta].sub.2] .98 .13 .0000
[[Delta].sub.2] .46 .13 .0005
[[Gamma].sub.2] .058 .018 .0009
[[Alpha].sub.2] .92 .20 .0000
[[Beta].sub.3] 1.46 .13 .0000
[[Delta].sub.3] 1.25 .47 .0076
[[Gamma].sub.3] .52 .089 .0000
[[Alpha].sub.3] .44 .13 .0010
[[Beta].sub.6] .94 .45 .0389
[[Delta].sub.6] .79 .82 .331
[[Gamma].sub.6] .25 .08 .0011
[[Alpha].sub.6] .23 .17 .0601
[[Rho].sub.23] .92 .016 .0000
[[Rho].sub.26] .48 .082 .0000
[[Rho].sub.36] .67 .060 .0000
Statistical data for the in-sample residuals, the estimated term
premia, and the ex-post holding period yields are depicted in Table 5.
In attempting to ascertain the joint importance of Fed behavior and
time-varying term premia in explaining the regression results of
Campbell and Shiller (1991) as well as Roberds, Runkle, and Whiteman
(1993), we perform three experiments. First we generate a funds rate
that is stationary and thus does not display the interest rate smoothing
or discrete interest rate changes that are embodied in our model of Fed
behavior. Longer-term interest rates are then derived using equation (1)
and the rational expectations hypothesis. We do this to see if our model
of term premia by itself can account for the actual regression results.
Next we examine an interest rate process that includes a greater degree
of smoothing but does not require discrete changes in the funds rate.
Finally, we combine our model of term premia with our depiction of Fed
behavior and investigate whether this model of interest rate
determination can explain the regression results obtained using actual
data. The results we analyze involve the cases in which n = 2, m = 1,
and n = 6, m = 3 (i.e., the term spread between the two-month and
one-month bills and the six-month and three-month bills).
To begin, we model the one-period interest rate as [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]. As in our actual model of Fed behavior, [u.sub.t]
is distributed uniformly on the interval [-0.525, 0.525]. Combining this
behavior with term premia generated from our estimated ARCH-M model, we
generate data on longer-term interest rates using equation (1). The
regression results based on 500 simulations of 125 observations are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where standard errors are in parentheses. REHTS is not rejected by
the second regression, and the results of this regression are consistent
with those documented in Mankiw and Miron (1986) and Choi and Wohar
(1991) for the period prior to the rounding of the Fed. One must
therefore conclude that our model of term premia is not sufficient for
generating data that are capable of replicating regression results using
actual post-Fed data.
Table 5 Statistical Data from ARCH-M Model
Residuals Standard Error Correlation Matrix
[Epsilon]2 .45 1.0
[Epsilon]3 .99 .92 1.0
[Epsilon]6 .64 .50 .70 1.0
Estimated Term Premia Mean Standard Error Correlation Matrix
T2 .60 .15 1.0
T3 1.35 .25 .90 1.0
T6 .53 .13 .77 .85 1.0
Actual Ex-post Yields Mean Standard Error Correlation Matrix
y2 .65 .47 1.0
y3 1.51 1.04 .93 1.0
y6 .62 .68 .55 .74 1.0
Next we model the short-term interest rates as [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], which is consistent with our modeling of
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] in equation (5). Thus, the only
element lacking from our complete model of Fed behavior is the discrete
nature of funds rate behavior given by equation (6). Generating data
using this nonstationary model of [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
along with our model of term premia, we obtain the following regression
results:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Here both coefficients are insignificantly different from zero. Thus,
this experiment does not generate the statistically significant
coefficient commonly found when using actual data on two- and one-month
interest rates.
Finally, we combine the joint modeling of term premia using the
ARCH-M process and Fed behavior given by equations (5) and (6). These
regression results are the following:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Here the joint modeling of term premia and Fed behavior is capable of
explaining a statistically significant coefficient that is less than one
in the shorter-maturity regression, whereas the coefficient in the
regression involving longer maturities is insignificantly different from
zero. An explanation for the increased significance of the coefficient
in the first regression from that estimated in the previous experiment
goes as follows. Due to Fed behavior, the standard deviation of the
expected change in the one-month rate has risen from a value of 0.095 to
0.123, while the standard deviation of the term premia has remained
unchanged. However, there are only 35 episodes in which the coefficient
in the first regression is greater than 0.5 while the coefficient in the
second regression is also less than zero. Thus, the coefficient
estimates that are consistent with the results presented in Roberds,
Runkle, and Whiteman (1993) occur in approximately 7 percent of the
trials.
The results presented above are not entirely satisfactory because the
generated term premia do not exactly match the fitted term premia of the
model (perhaps because the correlation coefficients are constrained to
be time in-variant). The standard deviations of the generated term
premia are somewhat less than those depicted in Table 5, whereas the
correlation coefficients are appreciably less. With generated data,
[[Sigma].sub.T2] = 0.17, [[Sigma].sub.T3] = 0.14, and [[Sigma].sub.T6] =
0.06 while [[Rho].sub.23] = 0.66, [[Rho].sub.26] = 0.20, and
[[Rho].sub.36] = 0.41.
To remedy this situation, we generate data by also allowing the
correlation coefficients, [[Rho].sub.ij], to vary intertemporally. We do
this by allowing them to depend on the [h.sub.jj,t]s in equation (9),
producing standard deviations of [[Sigma].sub.T2] = 0.14,
[[Sigma].sub.T3] = 0.44, and [[Sigma].sub.T6] = 0.12 and correlation
coefficients of [[Rho].sub.23] = 0.88, [[Rho].sub.26] = 0.73, and
[[Rho].sub.36] = 0.83. In a regression using data generated by this
mechanism, the coefficient on the 2,1 term is 0.93(0.16) and on the 6,3
term is 0.79(0.63), where standard errors are in parentheses. Also, in
10 percent of the cases the 6,3 coefficient is less than zero, while the
2,1 coefficient is greater than 0.5. When there is no discretization of
movements in the funds rate, these coefficients are 0.54(0.47) and
0.11(1.95). Both coefficients differ insignificantly from zero.
While the term premia in the last simulation do not come from any
estimated model, the experiment at least shows that regression results
that are in accord with those obtained in practice can be generated by
the combination of (1) Fed behavior that both smooths the movements in
interest rates and only moves interest rates discretely and (2)
time-varying term premia that are calibrated to match data moments.
5. CONCLUSION
This article explores the linkage between Federal Reserve behavior
and time-varying term premia and analyzes what effect these two economic
phenomena have on tests of the rational expectations hypothesis of the
term structure. Adding both these elements to a model of interest rate
formation produces simulated regression results that are reasonably
close to those reported using actual data. We thus feel that a deeper
understanding of interest rate behavior will be produced by jointly
taking into account the behavior of the monetary authority along with a
more detailed understanding of what determines term premia. Reconciling
theory with empirical results probably does not require abandonment of
the rational expectations paradigm.
1 For an extensive set of results, see Campbell and Shiller (1991).
Cook and Hahn (1990) and Rudebusch (1993) also give excellent surveys.
2 Term premia arise naturally in consumption-based asset pricing
models and involve the covariance of terms containing the ratio of
future price-deflated expected marginal utilities of consumption to the
current price-deflated marginal utility of consumption, the price of the
long-term bond, and future prices of the short-term bond. See Labadie
(1994).
3 Rudebusch (1993) derives a similar expression with [Rho] = 0.
4 Model data are from 250 draws of a series with 300 observations.
5 For a more detailed modeling of behavior along these lines, see
Rudebusch (1994).
6 We use T-bills rather than term federal funds because coefficient
estimates using the federal funds rate are insignificant. One possible
explanation for this result is that the excess holding period yield on
federal funds involves both a term premia derived from a
consumption-based asset pricing model as well as default risk that may
be uncorrelated with the term premia. This default risk may add
sufficient noise that it is difficult to estimate the term premia using
ARCH-M type regressions.
REFERENCES
Bollerslev, Tim. "Modelling the Coherence in Short-Run Nominal
Exchange Rates: A Multivariate Generalized ARCH Model," The Review
of Economics and Statistics, vol. 72 (August 1990), pp. 498-505.
Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. "Yield Spreads and
Interest Rate Movements: A Bird's Eye View," Review of
Economic Studies, vol. 58 (May 1991), pp. 495-514.
Choi, Seungmook, and Mark E. Wohar. "New Evidence Concerning the
Expectation Theory for the Short End of the Maturity Spectrum," The
Journal of Financial Research, vol. 14 (Spring 1991), pp. 83-92.
Cook, Timothy, and Thomas Hahn. "Interest Rate Expectations and
the Slope of the Money Market Yield Curve," Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Review, vol. 76 (September/October 1990), pp. 3-26.
Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins.
"Estimating Time Varying Risk Premia in the Term Structure: The
ARCH-M Model," Econometrica, vol. 55 (March 1987), pp. 391-407.
Fama, Eugene F. "The Information in the Term Structure,"
Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 13 (December 1984a), pp. 509-28.
-----. "Term Premiums in Bond Returns," Journal of
Financial Economics, vol. 13 (December 1984b), pp. 529-46.
Goodfriend, Marvin. "Interest Rates and the Conduct of Monetary
Policy," in Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
Vol. 34. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1991, pp. 7-30.
-----. "Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem:
1979-1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
vol. 79 (Winter 1993), pp. 1-24.
Labadie, Pamela. "The Term Structure of Interest Rates over the
Business Cycle," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 18
(May/July 1994), pp. 671-97.
Mankiw, Gregory N., and Jeffrey A. Miron. "The Changing Behavior
of the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Quarterly Journal of
Economics, vol. 101 (May 1986), pp. 211-28.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of
Interest Rates." Manuscript. Carnegie-Mellon University, June 1994.
Mishkin, Frederick S. "The Information in the Term Structure:
Some Further Results," Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol. 3
(October-December 1988), pp. 307-14.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. "A Simple Positive
Semi-Definite Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent
Covariance Matrix," Econometrica, vol. 55 (May 1987), pp. 703-8.
Roberds, William, David Runkle, and Charles H. Whiteman.
"Another Hole in the Ozone Layer: Changes in FOMC Operating
Procedure and the Term Structure," in Marvin Goodfriend and David
H. Small, eds., Operating Procedures and the Conduct of Monetary Policy:
Conference Proceedings. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, 1993.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. "Federal Reserve Interest Rate Targeting and
the Term Structure." Manuscript. Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, May 1994.
-----. "Propagation of Federal Funds Rate Changes to Longer-Term
Rates Under Alternative Policy Regimes," in Marvin Goodfriend and
David H. Small, eds., Operating Procedures and the Conduct of Monetary
Policy: Conference Proceedings. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, 1993.
The authors wish to thank Peter Ireland for many useful and
technically helpful suggestions. The comments of Tim Cook, Douglas
Diamond, Tony Kuprianov, and John Weinberg are also greatly appreciated.
Sam Tutterow provided excellent research assistance. The views expressed
in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve
System.