Reflections on monetary policy.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr.
It is a pleasure and indeed an honor to be with you this evening. I
must confess that when I recall the long line of distinguished
economists who have delivered the Sandridge lecture, I wonder whether I
am really worthy of this opportunity. But in any case I am grateful for
it and will strive to make the most of it.
I have worked at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond for just about
a quarter of a century, and for virtually all of that time I have been
involved in one way or another in the formation of monetary policy. For
most of that period I was an advisor to the president of the Richmond
Fed, and for the last two years I have served as president myself. Given
this background, I believe the most useful thing I can probably do this
evening is to make a few remarks about monetary policy and some of the
major issues the Fed is facing in conducting policy currently, in the
context of my experience with the policymaking process over the years.
The last 25 years have been extraordinarily eventful ones for
monetary policy in many ways. In this period there were fundamental
changes in attitudes among policymakers, financial market participants,
and the public regarding the appropriate role of monetary policy and
also about some of the procedures used by the Fed in implementing policy
decisions. The major factor triggering this reevaluation without any
doubt was the inflation that began at the end of the 1960s and peaked at
about 13 percent at the beginning of the 1980s. This rise in inflation
was unprecedented in recent peacetime American history; it was largely
unexpected by the public and the Fed; and it severely challenged widely
held assumptions about the economy and inflation prevailing at the time.
The inflation in the 1970s was followed by a severe recession in the
early 1980s and, subsequently, a sharp deceleration in the rate of
inflation to approximately 4 to 5 percent. Most recently, as you know,
inflation has been running at about a 3 percent rate, which is the
lowest rate since I began my career at the Fed. If the 1970s taught us
the necessity of containing inflation, I would say that the major lesson
of the 1980s was the importance of (1) having a long-run strategy to
achieve that goal and (2) maintaining the public's confidence in
that strategy or, to use the currently popular jargon, maintaining the
credibility of the strategy.
Tonight I want to look back over my years at the Fed, explain to you
how developments over this period have influenced thinking about
monetary policy and how it should be conducted, and share some of my own
views with you. My purpose is not so much to convince you of the wisdom
of my views, although I certainly hope you find at least some of them
persuasive, but to give you perhaps a fuller appreciation of the
fundamental issues facing monetary policy today.
1. THE ORIGIN OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND ITS MANDATE
Let me begin with just a few introductory comments about the Fed.
Most if not all of you are probably familiar with the Fed; nonetheless,
a brief review may increase your appreciation of some of the points I
will be making.
The Federal Reserve was established by Congress in 1914. Initially,
the Fed's main purpose or "mandate" was to cushion
short-term interest rates from liquidity disturbances arising from
banking panics or from seasonal changes in the demand for credit. In
later years, however, the Fed's mandate was broadened to include a
wide range of macroeconomic goals. Currently, Section 2A of the Federal
Reserve Act instructs the Fed to "maintain long-run growth of the
monetary aggregates commensurate with the economy's long-run
potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals
of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest
rates." Moreover, in carrying out monetary policy, the Fed is to
"[take] account of past and prospective developments in employment,
unemployment, production, investment, real income, productivity,
international trade and payments, and prices."
The Fed has a measure of independence within the government in that
it makes its month-to-month policy decisions without the direct
involvement of Congress, but it is fully accountable to Congress.
Accordingly, the Fed reports formally to Congress on monetary policy
every six months, and the chairman of the Fed's Board of Governors
and other System officials testify before congressional committees on
monetary policy issues as well as other matters throughout the year. The
body within the Fed that actually formulates and carries out monetary
policy is called the Federal Open Market Committee. It is made up of the
seven members of the Board of Governors located in Washington and, at
any particular time, five of the twelve regional Federal Reserve Bank
presidents. I am a voting member of this committee every third year. I
voted last year and will vote again in 1997.
A final point I would make is that the Fed's policy instrument -
the particular variable it controls on a week-to-week basis to achieve
its ultimate policy objectives - is the interest rate on reserves that
private banks lend to one another, generally referred to in financial
markets as the "federal funds rate." Changes in this rate
trigger adjustments in other interest rates, in money and credit flows,
and ultimately in broad macroeconomic variables - particularly the
aggregate level of prices in the economy.
So the key points about the Fed are (1) that it is a creature of
Congress, which has ultimate authority over it; (2) that, as such, it
receives its "mandate" from Congress, regarding what it should
try to achieve with monetary policy; (3) that the policymaking Federal
Open Market Committee has some degree of independence in making its
short-ran policy decisions, although over time these decisions are
subject to congressional review; and (4) that the Fed's policy
instrument is the federal funds rate.
2. PREVAILING VIEWS REGARDING MONETARY POLICY IN THE 1960s
With these points about the Fed in mind, let me review policy over
the last 25 years, obviously in a very summary fashion. When I began my
career at the Fed in 1970, there were three widely held views about the
economy that strongly influenced monetary policy and the procedures used
to implement it. First, most economists believed that there was a
Phillips Curve trade-off between unemployment and inflation in the long
run as well as the short run. As you all know, this famous curve
summarizes the inverse empirical correlation between unemployment and
inflation especially evident in the 1950s and 1960s. The implication for
monetary policy, in the eyes of many, was that the Fed could exploit the
trade-off the curve seemed to indicate: that is, it could seek a lower
level of inflation at the cost of higher unemployment; conversely - and
perhaps more to the point - it could seek lower unemployment at the cost
of higher inflation.
The second widely held assumption was that economists knew enough
about the structure of the economy and the way businesses and consumers
behave to permit the Fed to make policy decisions that would eliminate,
or at least greatly diminish, the amplitudes of business cycles. This
confidence had been fostered by the relatively steady economic growth
that had characterized the 1960s and by the neo-Keynesian macroeconomic
theories dominant at the time.
The third important idea commonly held in the 1960s was that the
welfare costs of inflation were small and that, in any case, they were
pretty much limited to the "shoe-leather costs" associated
with economizing on money balances in moderately inflationary periods.
Of course, there had not been much inflation since the Korean War in the
early 1950s, so this belief that inflation was a relatively benign
phenomenon probably reflected the absence of any significant recent
experience with inflation.
3. INFLATION IN THE 1970s AND ITS EFFECTS
Each of these three views fell victim - largely, if not completely -
to developments in the 1970s. During this period there were three major
cycles of rising inflation, each more severe than the one before. Each
of these accelerations of inflation, in turn, was followed by a sharp
tightening in monetary policy and a recession. The most memorable
episode occurred in 1979 and 1980, when the Consumer Price Index rose at
an annual rate exceeding 12 percent. Confronted with this situation, the
Fed took actions that raised short-term interest rates to unprecedented
levels, and the worst recession in the postwar period followed, lasting
fully six quarters between mid-1981 and the end of 1982.
Sharp increases in oil prices in the mid- and late 1970s no doubt
contributed to inflation, but in the long run we know that monetary
policy determines the rate of inflation; consequently, inflation could
not have risen so sharply over this period without the Fed's
acquiescence. There are a number of explanations for the Fed's loss
of control over inflation in this period, but in retrospect the
breakdown is not terribly surprising. If one combines the notions (1)
that the Fed can trade off higher inflation for lower unemployment, (2)
that the costs of inflation are small and, moreover, (3) that the Fed
has sufficient knowledge about the economy's structure to fine-tune
economic activity, it is not difficult to see how the Fed could be led
to make monetary policy decisions that had an inflationary bias.
In any case, our experience in the 1970s had a profound impact on
conventional thinking about inflation and monetary policy. Most
obviously it provided much new data that was, to put it mildly,
inconsistent with the Phillips Curve relationship observed in the 1960s.
It was in the 1970s, of course, that the term "stagflation"
arose to describe a combination of high inflation and low growth. In
recent years substantial research has been done on the long-run
relationship between growth and inflation - much of it based on
cross-country data - and I think it is fair to say that on balance there
is no compelling evidence that higher inflation is associated with
higher growth. Indeed, the research suggests that the relationship may
be inverse. The implication, of course, is that inflationary monetary
policy is not conducive to economic growth; indeed, the opposite may be
true.
The 1970s inflation also made people realize that the costs of
inflation are much greater and more varied than had been thought
earlier. We now understand much better than we did before that inflation
creates arbitrary and unfair redistributions of income and wealth that
cause social tensions and weaken the fabric of society. Inflation also
distorts the signals that prices send in our market economy, which
produces serious inefficiencies in the allocation of resources and
reduces economic growth. Further, inflation needlessly causes people to
spend additional time and energy managing their personal finances.
Finally, the 1970s experience illustrated all too well that the public
distress caused by rising inflation is inevitably followed by corrective
monetary policy actions that depress economic activity, often - as in
the early 1980s - severely.
The third consequence of our experience with inflation in the 1970s
was a healthy diminution in our confidence that we knew enough about the
structure of the economy and the way it functions to fine-tune economic
activity and eliminate recessions. As you know, this diminished
confidence in our ability to guide economic activity has been mirrored
by important developments in monetary theory over the last two decades.
I cannot review these developments here in any detail, but most monetary
economists now believe that the economy will inevitably be buffeted by
various unexpected "shocks" from a variety of directions -
such as the energy sector or the stock market - and that it simply is
not feasible, and probably not desirable, for the Fed to try
systematically to offset the effects of these shocks on the economy.
Indeed, we have to be very careful that our efforts to cushion the
effects of such shocks do not create rising inflation and thereby
exacerbate the economy's problems. As in the practice of medicine,
our first responsibility is to do no harm.
I hasten to add that this recognition of the limitations of monetary
policy does not relieve the Fed from making short-run policy decisions.
And inevitably these decisions will be affected by current developments
in the economy. My main point here is that we now realize that these
short-run decisions must be consistent with a feasible and credible
longer-term policy strategy and that we should not compromise this
strategy in a futile attempt to fine-tune the economy.
4. THE IMPACT OF THE 1970s EXPERIENCE ON POLICY PROCEDURES
The 1970s inflation pointed to two fundamental weaknesses in the
Fed's overall conduct of monetary policy - weaknesses that to some
extent are still present today. First, the System did not have a clear
and unambiguous longer-run objective. As inflation accelerated in the
mid- and late 1970s, it became apparent that to contain inflation the
Fed needed to set targets for some nominal variable that it could
control over time and that was clearly linked to inflation over time.
It was in this period that the Federal Open Market Committee first
began to set numerical targets for growth rates of the money supply.
Initially, the committee set short-run targets for internal use only.
Subsequently, in response to a congressional resolution in 1975, the
committee began voluntarily to announce quarterly targets for the growth
rates of several definitions of the money supply. Finally, the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978 required the Fed to set money-growth
targets on a fourth-quarter-to-fourth-quarter basis and to present them
formally to Congress. Unfortunately, there was a major flaw in the
targeting procedure - commonly referred to as "base drift" -
which in fact remains to this day. Base drift occurs because the base
level of the money supply used in calculating each new annual target is
not the target level set for the fourth quarter of the preceding year,
but the actual level achieved in that period. Therefore, target misses
are forgiven when new targets are set, which allows the base level to
drift, either upward or downward. In the late 1970s persistent upward
base drift led to a prolonged period of unacceptably rapid growth in the
monetary aggregates, which in my judgment was a major factor
contributing to the subsequent double-digit inflation.
The second weakness in the conduct of policy highlighted by the
inflation of the 1970s was the tenuous link between the Fed's
month-to-month policy decisions and the emerging longer-run money supply
objectives. Under the procedure in place through much of the decade, the
Fed was supposed to tighten policy if money growth exceeded the annual
target ranges, but the response in any instance was entirely at the Open
Market Committee's discretion and, in practice, responses were
uncertain and unpredictable. Many economists would agree that the Fed
did not react aggressively enough to the persistent above-target growth
registered in the latter years of the decade. To deal with this problem,
in October 1979 the Fed instituted a new, so-called nonborrowed reserve
operating procedure. This procedure was quite complicated in its actual
implementation, and I will not try to explain it in any detail tonight.
Suffice it to say that the innovation was a monetary policy milestone
because for the first time in the Fed's history, its operating
procedure caused short-term interest rates to rise automatically in
response to excessive money growth.
The nonborrowed reserve procedure was abandoned in October 1982,
mainly because of increasingly significant practical problems in
defining the money supply accurately in a period of rapid technological
and institutional change and financial innovation - a problem that has
continued to this day. Since then, month-to-month operating decisions
have become once again entirely discretionary. I am uncomfortable with
this procedure, needless to say, and I will return to this point in a
few minutes.
5. DISINFLATION IN THE 1980S: THE IMPORTANCE OF CREDIBILITY
The prolonged recession in the early 1980s was followed by a
pronounced disinflation, and by the end of 1983 the inflation rate had
fallen to approximately 4 percent, where it remained for the next ten
years. In recent years the rate has fallen further to approximately 3
percent. Against the background of these developments, one can say that
the decade of the 1980s was a relatively tranquil period for monetary
policy - certainly by comparison to the preceding decade. But the more
recent period was not without its own lessons for policy. If the 1970s
taught the Fed that the costs of inflation are significant and that it
must commit itself clearly and fully to a low-inflation policy, the
years since have underlined the necessity of maintaining the credibility
of this policy - by which I mean maintaining the public's
confidence that controlling inflation is not a sometime thing but a
permanent feature of the Fed's overall longer-term monetary
strategy.
We now understand more clearly than before the vital role credibility
plays in minimizing the cost of reducing inflation and eventually
stabilizing the price level. In practical terms, maintaining credibility
means the Fed must react promptly to rising inflation expectations. If
the Fed's policy actions suggest an indifference to higher expected
inflation, the public will lose confidence in its strategy, and workers
and firms will demand higher wages and charge higher prices in a
perfectly natural effort to protect wages and profits from inflationary
erosion. The longer the Fed waits to respond to deteriorating inflation
expectations, the more likely it will need eventually to raise real
short-term interest rates sharply with potentially depressing effects on
business activity. In a nutshell, low credibility makes it more costly
from an economic perspective to pursue an anti-inflation strategy.
A few years ago one of my colleagues at the Richmond Fed, Marvin
Goodfriend, wrote a widely read article(1) in which he referred to
episodes of sharply rising inflation expectations as "inflation
scares," and use of that term has now become rather general.
Inflation scares can be captured by a variety of financial market
indicators, but in my view the most reliable is the long-term bond rate,
and this is the indicator I watch most closely to gauge the credibility
of our anti-inflation strategy. A sharp rise in long-term rates - as
occurred, for example, in the first half of 1994 - is a strong signal
that inflation expectations have risen and the credibility of our policy
has declined, and it is a sign that demands a response from the Fed. The
Fed has, in fact, reacted to inflation scares more promptly in recent
years than earlier, and I believe that this has been one of the
hallmarks of recent monetary policy.
6. PRINCIPLES FOR MONETARY POLICY
This completes my review of monetary policy over the last quarter
century. I hope it has helped you appreciate why I believe so strongly
that the Fed can make its maximum contribution to the economy's
growth and productivity by providing a stable price environment in which
private individuals, households, and business rinns can thrive. For me,
the broadest lesson of our experience in the seventies and the eighties
is that the overriding goal of monetary policy should be the elimination
of inflation, and by that I mean achieving a condition where changes in
the general price level are no longer a significant factor in the
economic decisions of individuals and businesses.
In this regard, it seems clear that we should not be satisfied with
the current 3 to 4 percent inflation rate. One frequently hears the
argument that the benefits of achieving price-level stability do not
justify the costs. I disagree strongly with this assertion, because I do
not believe that a 3 to 4 percent inflation rate could ever be a
credible monetary policy objective in the way that price-level stability
could. A Fed commitment to aim for 3 or 4 percent inflation - despite
its relatively moderate level by recent historical standards - would
lack credibility because financial markets and the public quite
understandably would fear that eventually the Fed would tolerate higher
inflation to achieve some short-term objective. In technical terms, the
"time inconsistency" problem in conducting monetary policy,
which is one of the most important elements in the recent professional
literature on policy, would be much more compelling in a policy regime
with a 3 to 4 percent inflation objective than in a regime firmly
committed to price stability. This suspicion, in turn, would create
uncertainty regarding future inflation, and the attendant increase in
risk obviously could harm the economy in a variety of ways.
So my first core belief about monetary policy is that the Fed should
remain committed to a policy of eventually achieving true price-level
stability and strengthen that commitment in any way it can. My second
core belief is that the System needs to maintain the credibility of this
policy, which implies - among other things - that its policy procedures
and short-ran policy actions must be consistent, to the greatest extent
possible, with its long-term price stability objective. (I will make
some specific points in this regard in a minute.) As I have already
noted, by maintaining credibility the Fed can make its anti-inflationary
strategy less costly in the transition to price stability and therefore
more likely to be successful.
If I have been persuasive this evening, you may think that the two
monetary policy principles I have put forward - a policy of price
stability and maintenance of the credibility of that policy - are
obvious and that there is little left to say. Unfortunately, we still
have a substantial distance to go in putting these principles fully into
practice. To see that our price stability objective lacks full
credibility, one has only to open the newspaper and look at the current
level of the long-term U.S. Treasury bond rate, which is still well over
7 percent. Since it is doubtful that real long-term bond rates ever rise
above 4 percent, this means that market participants, on average,
currently expect a long-run inflation rate of at least 3 percent.
What are the reasons for this lack of credibility? I think there are
a number, and I would like to close my remarks tonight by identifying
sortie of them and sharing some ideas about what might be done to deal
with them.
As I have indicated before, I believe the most pressing problem the
Fed faces in conducting monetary policy currently is the lack of a clear
policy mandate from Congress. As I explained earlier, the current
mandate contained in the 1978 Humphrey-Hawkins law makes the Fed
responsible for a laundry list of economic outcomes having to do with
employment, productivity, international trade, and so forth, in addition
to the price level. A revised mandate instructing the Fed to focus
squarely on achieving price stability almost certainly would enhance the
contribution of monetary policy to the nation's long-run economic
growth and productivity - indeed, because it would do so, it would
increase, not reduce, the likelihood that the laudable objectives of the
Humphrey-Hawkins law will be achieved.
Five years ago Congressman Steve Neal of North Carolina introduced in
Congress an amendment to the Federal Reserve Act proposing just such a
mandate. This resolution would have instructed the Federal Open Market
Committee to pursue a policy strategy that would "reduce inflation
gradually in order to eliminate inflation by not later than 5 years from
the date of enactment of [the] legislation and [to] then adopt and
pursue monetary policies to maintain price stability." We at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond wholeheartedly supported the Neal
amendment, as did many others in the Federal Reserve System, as an
operationally feasible means of increasing the credibility of the
Fed's anti-inflationary strategy. Unfortunately, the amendment did
not pass.
Since Congress has not seen fit to pass the amendment, my personal
view - and I need to emphasize here that I am speaking strictly for
myself - is that the Fed should explicitly and publicly announce that it
is adopting the language of the amendment as its longer-term strategic
policy goal. In my judgment this step would put the Fed's
reputation clearly on the line, which would directly increase the
credibility of our strategy. Moreover, as I have already suggested, such
a step would be fully consistent with the present Humphrey-Hawkins
mandate since price stability would permit the economy to achieve
maximum growth in output and employment over time. In this regard, I
might note that the value of price stability as a primary monetary
policy objective is increasingly recognized around the world. In recent
years the central banks in Canada, New Zealand, and the United Kingdom
have actually specified explicit numerical inflation targets. Since the
Neal amendment does not specify numerical targets, its adoption by the
Fed would be a step short of these actions abroad. Nonetheless, the
amendment's language is sufficiently clear to commit the Fed firmly
to attaining price stability in a specific time frame and hence contains
all the ingredients necessary to enhance the System's credibility.
Moreover - and this is an especially important point - adoption of the
amendment language as its long-term objective would increase the
Fed's flexibility in dealing with short-term economic disturbances
since appropriate short-term actions could be taken without (or with
much less) concern about the potential loss of long-term credibility.
A second area requiring attention is our operating procedures. As I
mentioned in my earlier historical review, only in the three-year period
from October 1979 to October 1982 has the Fed used an operating
procedure that automatically linked movements in our policy instrument -
namely the federal funds rate - to a longer-term policy goal, in this
case growth rates of the monetary aggregates. As I noted earlier, that
procedure was abandoned, largely because of the technical difficulties
that arose in defining an operationally reliable measure of the money
supply in a period of rapid technological and institutional change -
difficulties that unfortunately still confront us. Currently, we still
set annual targets for the money supply, but these targets have little
effect on our month-to-month policy decisions, which are made pretty
much in the same discretionary fashion that characterized the pre-1979
period. This is another important reason why, in my judgment, our
credibility is not as full as it could be and should be.
What the Fed needs, in my view, is an operating procedure that
clearly links our short-run policy actions directly to our longer-run
inflation goals or to some other nominal variable such as nominal gross
domestic product. Regrettably, at this point no such procedure exists
that commands sufficient confidence to be used in practice. Many
economists both inside and outside the Fed are working actively on this
problem, however, and I have confidence that somewhere down the road we
will come up with an acceptable operating procedure that more
systematically and efficiently links our instrument to our goals. In the
meantime, the Fed must retain the independence to take the short-run
policy actions that it believes are most likely to be consistent with
its long-run objectives - recognizing, of course, that it is responsible
for and accountable for the consequences of these decisions.
A final and very important point I would make is that the Fed has a
strong obligation to educate the public about the cost of inflation and
the limitations of activist short-term monetary policies. In my review,
I explained how the inflation of the 1970s led me and many others to
conclude that some of the views regarding inflation and monetary policy
in the 1960s were not valid. Unfortunately, in my opinion, many people
still believe that a long-run as well as a short-run trade-off between
inflation and unemployment exists, that the costs of inflation are
small, and that the Fed can fine-tune economic activity. The persistence
of these views - particularly when they are held by people with
political power - naturally diminishes the credibility of our
anti-inflation strategy, especially given that our mandate is so
imprecise. It would be a tragedy if the lessons of the last 25 years
were forgotten and the nation needlessly experienced another devastating boom-bust cycle like the one in the 1979-82 period. So I think we in the
Fed have an obligation to speak out on these issues. My remarks here
tonight have been an effort in that direction, and I hope that I have
added at least a bit to your appreciation of some of the fundamental
issues facing monetary policymakers today.
1 Marvin Goodfriend, "Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation
Scare Problem: 1979-1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly, vol. 79 (Winter 1993), pp. 1-24.