Was the disinflation of the early 1980s anticipated?
Dotsey, Michael ; DeVaro, Jed L.
The United States experienced a rise in inflation from 5.5 percent in
the first quarter of 1976 to 9.4 percent in the first quarter of 1980.
This steep increase was followed by the desire to stem inflation and to
reverse its course. Therefore, soon after Paul Volcker was appointed
chairman of the Federal Reserve Board in August 1979, the Federal
Reserve (the Fed) announced new operating procedures and put in place a
disinflationary policy.
During the implementation of that policy, two recessions came in
rapid succession. The first began in January 1980 and lasted through the
middle of that year. Although short in duration, the recession was deep,
with real GDP falling at an annual rate of 10.4 percent in the second
quarter of 1980, the largest postwar decline on record. The second
recession followed almost immediately, beginning in July 1981 and ending
in November 1982. At approximately the same time, the Fed's
aggressive disinflationary policy ended. Some economists have calculated
the cost in terms of cumulative output lost to be roughly 24 percent of
total output over the period 1980:1 to 1983:4.(1) But during that
period, inflation was brought down from 10.1 percent in 1980 to 4.4
percent in 1982.
This episode was dramatic because of both the significant loss of
output and the equally significant decline in inflation. Also, the
policy of disinflation was announced and was carried out over a period
of three years. Thus, the episode has the potential to shed light on a
number of competing macroeconomic theories that attempt to explain the
linkage between real economic activity and nominal disturbances. The
usefulness of the 1980's experience in this purpose depends
critically on whether the decline in inflation was anticipated. If the
disinflation was largely unexpected, even after the policy had been in
place for some time, then it will be difficult to discriminate between
the theories.
The first set of theories can broadly be classified as Keynesian and
are characterized by elements of nominal rigidities in prices and wages.
Specifically, we have in mind models like those of Fischer (1977),
Taylor (1980), or Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1988). In these models,
staggered price setting slows the adjustment of the price level to
changes in the money stock. Thus, inflation has inertia, and anticipated
monetary contractions can precipitate a recession by causing aggregate
demand to fall. The fall in aggregate demand will of course be greater
if the disinflationary policy is unanticipated, since even those firms
in the process of resetting their prices will make mistakes.
Other models in which unanticipated changes in monetary policy have
an effect on real economic activity are the neoclassical monetary
business-cycle models of Lucas (1973), McCallum (1980), and Sargent and
Wallace (1975). In these models, agents partially infer nominally
induced movements in prices as being driven by real disturbances. Thus,
an unanticipated fall in money causes prices to be lower than expected,
resulting in a decline in the supply of output. If policy is
anticipated, however, and there is no confusion about the impulses
driving prices, agents are not induced to supply less output. The entire
effect of policy is nominal.
Economists have varying opinions concerning the extent to which
disinflation was anticipated during the 1980-83 period, and these views
partially determine their preferred theory. For example, in discussing a
number of policy changes, including the one in which we are interested,
Akerlof, Rose, and Yellen (1988) argue that
Mr. Volcker's similar policy produced changes in equilibrium
output long after the policies were announced (and seem to be credible).
The changes persisted sufficiently long after their announcement that it
is extraordinarily difficult to believe that the changes in employment
and output they caused were due to the slow propagation of unanticipated
shocks. (P. 68)
Their view is that the Fed possessed sufficient credibility, implying
that the policy change was believed either immediately or soon
thereafter and hence that the disinflation was largely anticipated. If
that was indeed the case, then their conclusion that the episode was
more in line with Keynesian-style theories than neoclassical ones is
well taken.
The degree of Fed credibility, and hence the extent to which the
disinflation was anticipated, is open to question. Goodfriend (1992), in
his description of the Fed's fight against inflation, divides the
period into three distinct parts: the aborted fight against inflation
from October 1979 to April 1980, when short-term interest rates rose by
over 600 basis points; an easing of policy during the first recession,
when rates fell by 800 basis points; and a second aggressive
disinflationary policy from August 1980 to October 1982, when rates were
eventually pushed up by 1000 basis points over their July 1980 levels.
This last sustained tightening broke the inflationary environment. Thus
Federal Reserve policy was far from uniform and this lack of uniformity
may have impaired the Fed's credibility, implying that the
disinflation could very well have been unanticipated. Thus, how well the
public anticipated the disinflation can help measure the Federal
Reserve's credibility during that period.
1. DESCRIPTION OF THE 1976-1983 PERIOD
We begin with a brief overview of the period in question, confining ourselves to a description of the behavior of inflation, real GDP
growth, M1 growth, and the federal funds rate [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE
1A TO 1C OMITTED]. Inflation is measured by quarterly changes in the GDP
deflator and all quarterly growth rates are annualized.
As Figure 1a illustrates, the period was characterized by a run-up in
inflation from 5.5 percent in 1976:1 to 11.1 percent in 1981:1 and then
by a rapid decline to 4.09 percent in 1983:4. Associated with this rapid
disinflation were two recessions [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 1B OMITTED].
The first one began in January 1980 and was accompanied by a 10.4
percent annualized decline in real GDP during the second quarter of that
year, and the second one began in July 1981.
In response to the increase in inflation, the Federal Reserve
announced a change in operating procedures in October 1979 and raised
the funds rate from 11.4 percent in September to 17.6 percent in April
1980 [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 1C OMITTED]. The steep decline in economic
activity caused the Fed to temporarily back off from its disinflationary
policy, and the funds rate fell to 9.03 percent in July 1980. As a
result, not much headway was made in curbing inflation.
As the economy recovered in the fourth quarter of 1980, the Fed
resumed its policy of disinflation. The funds rate was raised from 10.8
percent in September 1980 to as high as 19.10 percent in June 1981. This
second attempt at reversing the inflationary trend in the economy was
successful. The economy experienced its second recession, but inflation
also fell from 11.1 percent in 1981:1 to 4.4 percent in 1982:1.(2)
The go-stop-go nature of the Fed's fight against inflation is
also depicted in the growth of effective M1 against its targets. When
gauging the tightness of monetary policy by the discrepancy between
money growth and monetary targets, effective M1 is the appropriate
aggregate to look at. Effective M1 is a measure of actual M1 adjusted
for the effects of deregulation and was the monetary variable of primary
concern to the Fed over this period.(3) In 1980, when the Fed relaxed
its disinflationary policy, effective M1 grew at a rate of 6.9 percent,
which exceeded the top of the target range by 0.4 percent. Also, much of
this growth took place in the second half of the year after policy had
eased. In 1981, however, effective M1 grew by only 2.4 percent, a full
1.1 percent below the bottom of the target range. This decline in M1
growth was a reflection of the reinstitution of tight monetary policy
and served to further signal the Fed's renewed anti-inflationary
stance.
Thus, an examination of the two most relevant economic series for
depicting monetary policy during the early 1980s - the funds rate and
effective M1 - indicates that the fight against inflation was somewhat
discontinuous. It is, therefore, highly possible that the credibility of
the Fed's policy was achieved only gradually.
The discontinuous nature of policy led to renewed inflation in 1980
as well as to a sharp increase in long-term bond rates relative to the
funds rate - what Goodfriend calls an "inflation scare" -
earlier in the year. From Goodfriend's account, one may conclude
that the Fed did not achieve credibility until the summer of 1982. It is
thus entirely possible that although the Fed announced its resolve to
fight inflation as early as October 1979, the policy was not fully
credible until mid-1982. Thus, it may be that much of the disinflation
was unexpected and that the 1980-83 period is perfectly consistent with
the neoclassical model.
To shed further light on the degree to which the disinflation was
anticipated, we adopt the innovative empirical methodology of Hamilton
(1992). By combining information in commodity futures markets with the
macroeconomic information readily available at the time, we decompose actual inflation into its anticipated and unanticipated components. Our
results imply that a substantial portion of the disinflation was
unanticipated and that the Fed suffered from a credibility problem.
2. METHODOLOGY(4)
To analyze the degree to which the disinflation of the early 1980s
was anticipated, we must construct a series depicting the public's
expectations of inflation. The methodology we use for constructing such
a series is that of Hamilton (1992). His procedure incorporates publicly
available aggregate data and financial market data on commodity futures
contracts to estimate price-level expectations. The data on futures
contracts are optimally weighted in an effort to uncover information
possessed by the public but not by the econometrician. The use of future
changes in commodity prices from their expected values represents a
novel way to uncover what agents believed at any given moment. Because
the change in policy was a major one, these data are potentially useful
for uncovering beliefs about inflation since financial markets often
react aggressively to changing inflationary expectations.(5)
Specifically, suppose that the public's expectation of next
period's price level, [p.sub.t+1], is given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where the superscript e denotes an expectation, [x.sub.t] is a vector
of all relevant aggregate information, and [[Alpha].sub.t] represents
information that agents find valuable in forecasting prices but that is
unavailable to the econometrician. For example, [x.sub.t] could include
economic time series published by the Commerce Department or the Federal
Reserve, while [[Alpha].sub.t] could involve disaggregated information
that individuals observe but that is unpublished.
Let the public's true expectational error be defined by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Note that under rational expectations
[a.sub.t+1] is white noise and uncorrelated with time t information.
Next, consider the forecasting error, [u.sub.t+1], that occurs from the
prediction of [p.sub.t+1] using only the information in [x.sub.t].
Specifically, [u.sub.t+1] is the error term in
[p.sub.t+1] = [x[prime].sub.t][Delta] + [u.sub.t+1], (2)
which is a typical forecasting equation. From equation (1) and the
definition of [a.sub.t+1], [u.sub.t+1] is equal to [[Alpha].sub.t] +
[a.sub.t+1]. By including enough own lags of [p.sub.t] in [x.sub.t],
[u.sub.t+1] can be made white noise. A simple and consistent assumption
is to treat [[Alpha].sub.t] as white noise as well.
Because the variance of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is equal to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], we observe that if the econometrician
uses only the information in [x.sub.t] to forecast [p.sub.t+1], the
variance of the forecast errors will exceed that of the true forecast
errors. Improving upon these forecasts requires inferences of
[[Alpha].sub.t]. The better the inference of [[Alpha].sub.t] the closer
the econometrician's forecast will coincide with the public's.
Hamilton proposes that data from commodities markets be used to help
form an optimal prediction of [[Alpha].sub.t].
For ease of exposition, we will analyze the case in which there is
one commodity. Using data on the log of the commodity's forward
price at date t, [f.sub.t], and the log of its expected future spot
price next period, [E.sub.t][s.sub.t+1], a simple efficient markets
model implies that
[f.sub.t] = [E.sub.t][s.sub.t+1] - k, (3)
where k incorporates the variance of [s.sub.t] and a constant risk
premium. Equation (3) implies that the forecast error of the spot price
is observable and given by
[s.sub.t+1] - [f.sub.t] = k + [v.sub.t+1], (4)
where [v.sub.t+1] is the forecast error. Under rational expectations,
[v.sub.t+1] is uncorrelated with time t information. In particular, it
is uncorrelated with the elements of [x.sub.t] and [[Alpha].sub.t]. It
is reasonable, however, to believe that the forecast error for a given
commodity and the aggregate price level are correlated. For example, any
demand shock (such as a monetary policy shock) could influence all
prices, including commodity prices, in a similar way. This relationship
is given by
[v.sub.t+1] = [q.sup.a][a.sub.t+1] + [e.sub.t+1]. (5)
Hence, observation of [v.sub.t+1] implies some knowledge of
[a.sub.t+1].
Next, consider a regression of the forward price on information
available to the econometrician,
[f.sub.t] = [x[prime].sub.t][Beta] + [[Omega].sub.t]. (6)
In this regression, [[Omega].sub.t] represents information that
agents find relevant for pricing a commodity and that is unavailable to
the econometrician, because [f.sub.t] is observed at time t, and if the
econometrician had all the relevant information then [[Omega].sub.t]
would be zero. Thus, [[Omega].sub.t] has an interpretation similar to
[[Alpha].sub.t], and the two should be related. Let this relationship be
described by the linear projection
[[Omega].sub.t] = [q.sup.[Alpha]][[Alpha].sub.t] + [[Epsilon].sub.t],
(7)
where [[Epsilon].sub.t] denotes information that agents have about
future commodity price movements that is uncorrelated with aggregate
price movements.
The statistical problem is to form an optimal forecast of
[[Alpha].sub.t] given knowledge of [u.sub.t+1], [v.sub.t+1], and
[[Omega].sub.t], because it is these three observed disturbances that
contain information about [[Alpha].sub.t]. This optimal forecast allows
us to form the expectation of the aggregate price level that best
represents the one formed by the public. Using data on aggregate prices,
commodity spot and forward prices, and [x.sub.t], construct the error
terms [u.sub.t+1], [v.sub.t+1], and [[Omega].sub.t] according to equations (2), (4), and (6). The optimal predictor of [[Alpha].sub.t]
can then be formulated as
[E.sub.t+1][[Alpha].sub.t] = [A.sub.1][u.sub.t+1] +
[A.sub.2][[Omega].sub.t] + [A.sub.3][v.sub.t+1], (8)
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The coefficients in equation (8) are population regression
coefficients. The matrix in (9) is the variance-covariance matrix of the
disturbances [u.sub.t+1] = [a.sub.t+1] + [[Alpha].sub.t]. In deriving
this matrix, various orthogonality conditions implied by rational
expectations were used. The vector [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is
the covariance between [[Alpha].sub.t] and the three observed
disturbance terms.
The optimal forecast of next period's price level is then
depicted by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
In calculating the public's expectations of next period's
price level, the econometrician uses time t + 1 information from
commodity spot markets. This information is needed to extract the
optimal forecast of [[Alpha].sub.t], which contains relevant information
available to the public but not to the econometrician.
Unfortunately, there is one technical difficulty. To estimate the
coefficients [A.sub.1], [A.sub.2], and [A.sub.3], we must have estimates
of [q.sup.a], [q.sup.[Alpha]], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The variance-covariance matrix in
(9), however, has only five independent pieces of information, which
means that the system is not identified. An additional restriction is
needed, and we follow Hamilton by imposing [q.sup.a] =
[q.sup.[Alpha]].(6)
This restriction has some intuitive appeal. Suppose, for example,
that the relevant aggregate information that agents possess is a demand
shock that affects commodity prices and the aggregate price level in
similar ways. That is, anticipated and unanticipated movements affect
[s.sub.t+1] and [p.sub.t+1] proportionately, although the absolute
effects of an anticipated movement need not be the same as those of an
unanticipated movement. Then [q.sup.a] and [q.sup.[Alpha]] should be
equal. Under the restriction [q.sup.a] = [q.sup.[Alpha]], the ratio of
the covariance of [u.sub.t+1] and [v.sub.t+1] to the covariance of
[u.sub.t+1] and [[Omega].sub.t] is equal to [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], which reflects the extent that agents are actually surprised
by movements in the aggregate price level.
However, this restriction may not be valid. If, for example, the
unanticipated disturbances that affect commodity prices are largely
idiosyncratic, while the information that agents actually possess
affects both markets similarly, then [q.sup.a] would not equal
[q.sup.[Alpha]]. In any event, the restriction can be tested. And with
multiple commodities, the restriction need only be placed on one
commodity to achieve identification.
3. ESTIMATION
Before estimating the analogous multivariate system given by (1),
(4), (6), and the variance-covariance matrix in (9), we describe our
commodity price data and perform some necessary diagnostic tests. We
used data on wheat, corn, oats, and soybean futures, since these were
the only commodity data available for our sample period. In what
follows, we use the price of a futures contract that is about to expire
as the measure of the spot price. Because the futures contracts are four
months in duration, the data set is three times per year (such intervals
are denoted by roman numerals).
Commodity Price Behavior
Expected and actual inflation rates for the four commodities are
given in Table 1. Actual inflation in a commodity market is calculated
as the change in the log of the spot price during the period in
question, while expected inflation is represented by three times the
average log difference between the four-month futures price and the spot
price at each four-month interval. From the table it is evident that
expected commodity price increases greatly exceeded actual increases
during the 1981-83 period. Further, graphs of expected commodity price
inflation versus actual commodity price inflation [ILLUSTRATION FOR
FIGURES 2A TO 2D OMITTED] show that, with the exception of oats,
expected inflation was generally higher than actual inflation. These
results foreshadow the main results of the statistical model: the
overestimate of commodity price inflation will be mirrored in an
overprediction of the aggregate inflation rate.
Commodity Market Efficiency
One of the maintained hypotheses of the model discussed in Section 2
is that the commodity market is efficient. This was depicted by equation
(4) in which the expectational error, [v.sub.t+1], is normally
distributed white noise. We therefore test to determine whether
[v.sub.t+1] is indeed normal and whether it is correlated with time t
information. P-values for the skewness and kurtosis tests indicated that
in the cases of wheat and soybeans, we can reject normality.
Furthermore, the error terms were correlated with a menu of available
time t information. We thus cannot proceed under the assumption that
equation (4) provides an adequate description of commodity market
behavior. Instead we allow for time varying risk premiums and replace
equation (4) with
[s.sub.t+1] - [f.sub.t] = [x[prime].sub.t][Kappa] + [v.sub.t+1]
(4[prime])
for each commodity. Upon doing so, we cannot reject the normality of
[v.sub.t+1] and we also find that [v.sub.t+1] is uncorrelated with
interest rates, forward commodity prices, and its own lagged values.
Table 1 Expected and Actual Inflation Rates for Four Commodities
1978 to 1980
Commodity Expected Actual
Wheat 4.01 10.16
Corn 14.82 17.24
Oats 31.11 13.79
Soybeans 9.93 6.44
1981 to 1983
Commodity Expected Actual
Wheat 19.78 -0.39
Corn 11.08 6.05
Oats 3.34 -5.48
Soybeans 10.80 9.01
Sources: Commodity prices were obtained from the Chicago Board of
Trade Statistical Annual. Actual inflation figures represent the
change in the log of the spot price between September 1978 and
September 1980 (upper panel) and September 1981 and September 1983
(lower panel) divided by three, while the expected inflation figures
represent three times the average log difference between the
four-month future price at time t and the spot price at time t,
where t is indexed three times per year from September 1978 to May
1980 (upper panel) and from September 1981 to May 1983
(lower panel).
Estimating and Testing the Model
Before formally estimating the model, we performed augmented
Dickey-Fuller tests on aggregate prices, spot prices, and forward
commodity prices over the period 1970:II to 1986:III. We could not
reject nonstationarity of the price level, but we were able to reject
nonstationarity of commodity prices. Also, for [u.sub.t+1] to be white
noise required the inclusion of two lags of the inflation rate. The
system that we estimate is depicted by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where f and s are 4 by 1 vectors, [Delta] is a 9 by 1 coefficient
vector, [Beta] and [Kappa] are 9 by 4 matrices of coefficients, and u,
[Omega], and v are the disturbance terms. The vector of explanatory
variables [x.sub.t] includes a constant term, two seasonal dummies (d1
and d2), two lags of the inflation rate, and the four commodity spot
prices.(7)
The variance-covariance matrix in (9) is now 9 by 9 and is given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where [Sigma] = E[[[Epsilon].sub.t][[Epsilon][prime].sub.t]] and S =
E[[e.sub.t][e[prime].sub.t]]. We estimate equations (11) and (12) by
full-information maximum-likelihood and jointly test the orthogonality
conditions assumed under rational expectations and the identifying
restriction [q.sup.[Alpha]] = [q.sup.a]. We use the Sims (1980) adjusted
likelihood-ratio test, which is distributed [[Chi].sup.2](19).(8) The
p-value for the test statistic was 0.45, implying that we cannot jointly
reject the restrictions at standard confidence levels. However, for the
system using all four commodities, there is not significant covariation between [[Omega].sub.t] and [u.sub.t+1], and [[Omega].sub.t] and
[v.sub.t+1]. As a result, we cannot reject the hypothesis that [q.sup.a]
= [q.sup.[Alpha]] = 0.
This lack of rejection is due largely to the inclusion of wheat.
Figure 2a shows that actual wheat inflation is volatile, especially
early in the sample period. For a system containing only corn, oats, and
soybeans, the covariation between the relevant error terms is more
significant, and the hypothesis that [q.sup.a] = [q.sup.[Alpha]] = 0 can
be rejected at the 9 percent significance level. Furthermore, the joint
hypothesis involving [q.sup.a] = [q.sup.[Alpha]] and the rational
expectations orthogonality conditions has a p-value of 0.66.
The estimation results for the model are displayed in Table 2. The
variance of the inflation forecast [u.sub.t+1], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], is 0.538, most of which is due to [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]. This result implies that most of the residual, [u.sub.t+1],
took people by surprise.
4. PREDICTION
The predictions of inflation over the period 1971:I to 1986:III are
calculated using
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The last term in (13) is derived from the optimal prediction formula
given in (10). Thus,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where the subscripts c, o, and s refer to corn, oats, and soybeans.
Using (14) we can decompose the forecasts of inflation into simple
forecasts, [x[prime].sub.t][Delta], and the individual contributions
from the price term ([p.sub.t+1] - [x[prime].sub.t][Delta]), the three
futures terms ([f.sub.t] - [x[prime].sub.t][Beta]), and the three
commodity market surprise terms ([s.sub.t+1] - [f.sub.t] -
[x[prime].sub.t][Kappa]). These decompositions are given in Table 3.
Examining the entire sample period, the contributions of the price term
and the futures term can at times be meaningful, affecting the forecasts
by an annual rate as high as 87 and 51 basis points, respectively. The
commodity market surprise term, however, rarely has much effect on the
forecasts, which is attributable to the small covariance between
[u.sub.t+1] and [v.sub.t+1]. Expectations of inflation are displayed in
Table 4. The first two columns give the four-month actual and expected
inflation rates at annualized rates, the third and fourth columns give
eight-month actual and expected inflation at annualized rates, and the
fifth and sixth columns give the annual actual and expected inflation
rates. The first expectation reported in each instance is the one that
is conditional on 1979:III information, since this is the period in
which the Fed announced its disinflationary objectives. For example,
13.78, the first number in column 6, is the inflation rate expected for
1980 given 1979:III information.
The eight-month-ahead and the one-year-ahead forecast errors strongly
imply that a significant part of the disinflation in the early 1980s was
unanticipated. Expected inflation exceeds actual inflation in all but
three periods in the eight-month forecasts and in every period in the
one-year forecast. On average, agents expected 1.03 percent and 2.23
percent more inflation than actually occurred over the eight-month and
one-year forecast horizons, respectively. The one-period-ahead forecast
errors do not, however, give as clear a signal. Expected inflation
exceeds actual inflation by only 27 basis points on average for the
entire period. The combination of these two results implies that the
four-month forecasts of inflation four months out and eight months out
are drastically overpredicting inflation.(9) That is, even though
inflation is declining, agents do not seem to believe that the
disinflationary path will continue. Essentially, longer-run expectations
appear to be much too static over the period. In this sense, the
econometric model indicates that much of the disinflationary path was
unanticipated.
Table 3 Decomposition of Expectation of Inflation
Period Simple Price Futures Surprise
Ending Actual Forecast(1) Term(2) Term(3) Term(4)
1970:III 1.77 1.43 0.049 0.0005 0.008
1971:I 1.00 1.38 -0.055 -0.028 0.015
1971:II 1.23 1.56 -0.047 -0.072 0.017
1971:III 0.98 1.54 -0.081 0.046 0.002
1972:I 0.97 1.25 -0.040 0.033 0.013
1972:II 1.19 1.58 -0.055 -0.11 -0.006
1972:III 1.42 1.35 0.010 0.002 -0.011
1973:I 2.77 1.44 0.19 0.17 -0.006
1973:II 2.92 3.28 -0.052 -0.009 -0.023
1973:III 3.48 3.29 0.027 -0.041 0.010
1974:I 3.77 7.84 0.13 0.046 0.004
1974:II 4.03 3.27 0.11 0.065 -0.026
1974:III 3.30 3.53 -0.033 -0.012 0.007
1975:I 1.52 3.15 -0.23 0.021 0.013
1975:II 2.79 2.04 0.11 0.071 -0.011
1975:III 2.17 1.70 0.068 -0.048 0.008
1976:I 1.07 1.80 -0.10 -0.060 -0.012
1976:II 2.11 1.27 0.12 -0.041 -0.014
1976:III 1.89 1.58 0.04 0.023 0.006
1977:I 2.52 2.11 0.060 0.049 -0.010
1977:II 1.81 2.92 -0.16 -0.014 0.032
1977:III 2.26 2.37 -0.016 -0.055 -0.002
1978:I 2.83 2.16 0.10 0.075 -0.008
1978:II 3.05 2.87 0.025 0.049 0.015
1978:III 2.96 3.16 -0.028 -0.007 0.012
1979:I 4.15 3.21 0.14 -0.047 -0.000
1979:II 4.12 3.57 0.078 -0.066 0.003
1979:III 4.73 3.91 0.12 0.072 0.004
1980:I 4.63 3.94 0.10 -0.026 0.001
1980:II 2.66 4.08 -0.20 -0.074 -0.021
1980:III 3.86 3.36 0.072 0.009 0.002
1981:I 2.83 2.73 0.013 0.005 -0.003
1981:II 3.72 2.97 0.118 -0.067 0.011
1981:III 1.39 2.64 -0.18 0.025 0.009
1982:I 1.58 2.18 -0.086 -0.039 -0.011
1982:II 1.86 1.27 0.084 -0.013 0.014
1982:III 0.20 1.57 -0.20 0.080 0.004
1983:I 1.32 1.11 0.030 -0.11 -0.010
1983:II 1.20 0.89 0.044 -0.05 0.021
1983:III 1.68 1.68 -0.001 -0.13 -0.001
1984:I 1.36 1.55 -0.027 0.003 -0.007
1984:II 1.15 1.74 -0.085 0.059 -0.005
1984:III 0.95 1.10 -0.021 0.069 0.001
1985:I 1.41 0.83 0.083 -0.066 -0.006
1985:II .084 1.13 -0.042 0.099 0.019
1985:III 1.65 1.34 0.045 0.036 -0.007
1986:I -0.82 1.22 -0.29 -0.031 0.016
1986:II 0.91 1.13 -0.031 0.11 0.015
1986:III 1.35 0.49 0.12 -0.071 -0.019
1 The simple forecast is equal to [x[prime].sub.t][Delta].
2 The price term is given by [A.sub.1]([p.sub.t+1] -
[x[prime].sub.t][Delta]) in equation (10).
3 The futures term is given by [A.sub.2]([f.sub.t] -
[x[prime].sub.t][Beta]) in equation (10).
4 The surprise term is given by [A.sub.3]([s.sub.t+1] - [f.sub.t] -
[x[prime].sub.t][Kappa]).
Table 4 Actual and Expected Inflation: 1980 to 1983
One period ahead Two periods ahead One year ahead
Period
Ending Actual Expected Actual Expected Actual Expected
1980:I 14.19 11.88
1980:II 13.89 11.88 14.04 12.87
1980:III 7.98 12.66 10.94 12.80 12.02 13.78
1981:I 11.58 10.17 9.78 13.10 11.15 13.31
1981:II 8.49 8.19 10.02 10.17 9.34 13.91
1981:III 11.16 9.18 9.83 8.88 10.40 10.67
1982:I 4.17 7.83 7.67 8.81 7.93 8.90
1982:II 4.74 6.51 4.44 8.84 6.68 9.10
1982:III 5.58 4.47 5.16 6.03 4.82 9.29
1983:I 0.60 4.59 3.09 4.17 3.64 5.93
1983:II 3.96 2.76 2.28 5.03 3.38 4.23
1983:III 3.60 3.06 3.78 2.11 2.73 5.27
Note: Roman numerals denote four-month intervals.
5. CONCLUSION
The disinflation that occurred in the early 1980s was a dramatic
event in post-World War II monetary policy. Inflation had reached
unprecedented heights and was brought down fairly rapidly. It is likely
that this disinflation was partially responsible for the two recessions
that occurred in rapid succession. The disinflationary policy was
announced and underscored by a change in Federal Reserve operating
procedures. The policy was carried out over a prolonged period. These
two factors could easily lead to the interpretation that the
disinflation was anticipated and, therefore, that this episode is
consistent with theories emphasizing the impact of anticipated monetary
policy on real economic activity.
Although the policy was announced, evidence documented by Goodfriend
(1992) suggests that it may not have been entirely credible. Hence the
actual disinflation could still have been unanticipated. Determining the
extent to which the disinflation was unanticipated can help ascertain
the degree to which Fed credibility was lacking.
In an attempt to resolve whether the disinflation was anticipated, we
performed a statistical analysis of the public's expectations of
inflation using the methodology developed in Hamilton (1992). Our
conclusion is that much of the disinflation was unanticipated and that
the Fed suffered from a credibility problem. The fact that much of the
disinflation was unanticipated, however, does not allow us to
discriminate among the competing models outlined in the introduction.
Such discrimination would necessarily involve a more subtle hypothesis
test.
We wish to thank Alan Stockman for suggesting this topic. We are also
indebted to James Hamilton for many helpful discussions and for
providing the programs that with slight modifications were used in the
statistical analysis. Mary Finn, Tom Humphrey, Peter Ireland, and Roy
Webb contributed a number of useful suggestions. The views expressed are
those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
1 Using somewhat different procedures, both Fischer (1986) and Ball
(1993) arrive at this conclusion.
2 For a much more detailed description of this period, see Goodfriend
(1992).
3 For more detail on effective M1 behavior and its construction, see
Broaddus and Goodfriend (1984).
4 The description in this section draws heavily on Hamilton (1992),
who provides a more detailed and technically rigorous description.
5 The model does not explicitly incorporate regime changes and to
some extent suffers from the same problems as a standard VAR when
regimes actually do change.
6 The solution is [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted].
7 This is a fairly parsimonious statistical model. In principle,
other variables such as income or money could be included, but doing so
would greatly increase the computational burden. Our representation of
the inflation process follows Hamilton (1992).
8 The test statistic is 2(T - k/T) (likelihood
[unrestricted]-likelihood [restricted]).
9 We checked the unbiasedness of the forecasts by regressing
[Delta][p.sub.t+1] on a constant and [E.sub.t][Delta][p.sub.t+1]. For
the four-month and eight-month regressions, we could not reject a zero
constant and a unitary slope coefficient. However, the hypothesis that
[p.sub.t+1] = [E.sub.t][p.sub.t+1] plus a white noise error was rejected
at the annual frequency. Therefore, we conclude that greater weight
should be placed on the eight-month forecast.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, George A., Andrew Rose, and Janet Yellen. "Comments and
Discussion," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1988, pp.
66-75.
Ball, Lawrence. "What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?"
Working Paper No. 4306. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research,
March 1993.
-----, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer. "The New Keynesian
Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade Off," Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1:1988, pp. 1-65.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, and Marvin Goodfriend. "Base Drift and the
Longer-Run Growth of M1: Experience from a Decade of Monetary
Targeting," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, vol.
70 (November/December 1984), pp. 3-14.
Fischer, Stanley. "Contracts, Credibility, and
Disinflation," in John W. Neville and Victor E. Argy, eds.,
Inflation and Unemployment: Theory, Experience, and Policymaking.
Boston: Allen and Unwin, 1985.
-----. "Wage Indexation and Disinflation," in Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy. Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, vol. 5 (1977), pp. 107-48.
Goodfriend, Marvin. "Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation
Scare Problem: 1979-1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Annual
Report (1992), pp. 7-19.
Hamilton, James D. "Was the Deflation during the Great
Depression Anticipated? Evidence from the Commodity Futures
Market," American Economic Review, vol. 82 (March 1992), pp.
157-78.
Lucas, Robert E. "Some International Evidence on
Output-Inflation Tradeoffs," American Economic Review, vol. 63
(June 1973), pp. 326-34.
McCallum, Bennett T. "Rational Expectations and Macroeconomic
Stabilization Policy: An Overview," Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, vol. 12 (November 1980), pp. 716-46.
Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. "Rational Expectations,
the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply
Rule," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 83 (April 1975), pp.
241-54.
Sims, Christopher A. "Macroeconomics and Reality,"
Econometrica, vol. 48 (January 1980), pp. 1-48.
Taylor, John B. "Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered
Contracts," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 88 (February 1980),
pp. 1-23.