The creative destruction of labor policy.
Diamond, Arthur M., Jr.
THE BENEFITS OF CREATIVE DESTRUCTION in terms of new products and
more efficient processes are substantial (Schumpeter, 1950; DeLong,
2000). The person responsible for producing these benefits is the
innovative entrepreneur (Schumpeter, 1950). On the other side of the
ledger, the main costs of creative destruction are in terms of the
effects of job loss. Schumpeter (1950) and DeLong (2000) present
persuasive argument and evidence that the benefits of creative
destruction are widely distributed in a capitalist society, and in fact
primarily accrue to the poor and middle class. (1)
The main costs are borne by those who lose a job because their
skills have been made obsolete by creative destruction, especially the
job losers who remain unemployed for a long time or whose new jobs are
less satisfying or lower paid. Although the changes wrought by creative
destruction are arguably not Pareto optimal, the benefits are great
enough that a large majority of us would arguably assent to the changes
from behind a Rawlsian veil of ignorance (Rawls, 1971), especially
insofar as the costs can be made less onerous.
Because the benefits of creative destruction outweigh the costs,
wise governments and workers will seek to enable the benefits and reduce
the costs. The labor policies enacted by governments and workers can
greatly affect the success of creative destruction in two important
ways. First, they can make it easier or harder for the innovative
entrepreneur to bring us the benefits of creative destruction. Second,
they can lessen the frequency or severity of job loss caused by creative
destruction.
In the next two sections I discuss government labor policies on a
general level, arguing first that flexible policies enable the
innovative entrepreneur, and second, that rigid policies hurt the
macroeconomy--the latter, ironically, by increasing unemployment. Then
in an interlude section, I ask a crucial question: in the absence of
rigidifying government job protection and regulation, does
entrepreneurial capitalism provide the worker any security? My answer
will be that in a well-functioning macroeconomy and labor market, the
robust redundancy of job opportunities will provide workers the best
possible safety net. After this interlude, there follow four sections
discussing four specific policies intended to encourage creative
destruction either by enabling the innovative entrepreneur or by
obtaining buy-in from worried workers. Finally, I devote three sections
to some personal policies that workers themselves can adopt that will
increase their benefits and decrease their costs of working in a
flexible labor market. In a brief concluding section, I argue that in
the long-run of entrepreneurial capitalism, the labor market is not a
zero-sum game. In plain English, this means that in the process of
creative destruction it is possible for everyone to find jobs or
entrepreneurial projects that will allow them to flourish.
1. Enabling the Innovative Entrepreneur
Steve Jobs was one of the great innovative entrepreneurs of our, or
any, time. Yet during key moments in his entrepreneurial projects,
success depended on his being able to fire workers based on his
intuition of who would make 'genius' contributions. (Even in
the humble hamburger business, Ray Kroc argued that a good entrepreneur
develops intuitions about which workers will be able to do a good job,
and which not (Kroc, 1977, pp. 9192).) In the case of Steve Jobs,
biographer Walter Isaacson shows (2011) that Jobs's being able to
act on intuition was crucial to quickly and efficiently building and
keeping a team of "A" players from whom much was expected.
Sometimes another type of firing was required, as at Pixar. Jobs had
bought Pixar for $5 million, and he invested an additional $50 million
before it became profitable. Even though Pixar eventually became an
exemplar of successful breakthrough innovation, its survival once
required the firing of some "A" players to reduce costs
(Price, 2008, p. 116). The firings were unpopular, but Price claims they
were necessary for the firm to survive and for the innovative Toy Story
to enter the world.
Firings to maintain an "A" quality team and those to
reduce costs were important for the success of the projects Jobs was
pursuing. In these cases, as in his product design choices, part of his
success was due to the fact that he usually made quick intuitive
decisions that often enough, although not always, proved correct. But
these decisions were not easy to articulate when innovating at the far
edge of 'the adjacent possible' (Johnson, 2010). The firings
were possible because the policy in the United States of "at-will
employment" did not require that Jobs take the time to articulate
and document his decisions.
The success of entrepreneurial projects depends, not only on the
entrepreneur being free to hire and fire, but also on her being free to
set the conditions of the workplace. Tracy Kidder in The Soul of the New
Machine (1981) describes how the employees of Data General worked long
and intense hours for months in order to develop one of the first
minicomputers. The project might not have succeeded, or even been tried,
if there had been regulations mandating vacations, or setting maximum
work hours. The larger the number of such regulations, the more rigid,
or sclerotic, the labor market: the fewer, the more flexible. (2)
One of the key ways in which an economy can be open to creative
destruction is to have a flexible labor market. This would not come as a
surprise to most defenders of rigid labor policies--they know that they
are not enabling the entrepreneur; instead, they believe they are
achieving the more important goal of reducing costs for workers. The
main cost of creative destruction is job loss when a new technology
replaces an old one. In response to job loss due to creative destruction
and other causes, governments often regulate how firms fire workers.
Other regulations aim to improve the condition of workers. These may
consist of minimum wages, maximum hours, required vacation days,
required retirement age, and mandatory unionization, to name only a few.
2. The Macro Effects of Labor Market Rigidity
At the macro level, labor market rigidity slows the reallocation of
labor to more productive uses. Caballero has argued that the
restructuring of the micro economy through reallocation is a major
driver of economic growth that needs to be incorporated in macroeconomic
models (Caballero and Hammour, 2001; Caballero, 2007). Specifically:
"In Western Europe, the heavy weight of labor market regulation has
caused persistently high unemployment and sclerosis" (Caballero,
2007, p. 4). (3)
Cox and Alm have illustrated the point by noting that in 1900 about
40 in 100 workers in the United States were employed in producing food,
while in 1992 only three in 100 were needed (1992, p. 5). If rigid
government labor market policy had "protected" the 40 jobs in
1900, labor would not have been freed to produce all of the wonderful
new products that made the 20th century exceptional. (4) Petra Moser
similarly suggests that the mobility of inventors moving from declining
industries to expanding industries is important in explaining the
vitality of innovation in the United States (as quoted in Rampell,
2008).
Paradoxically, greater labor regulations cause higher unemployment,
and lower labor force participation (Botero et al., 2004), each of which
most strongly affects the young. In France, laws limiting the work week
to 35 hours were intended to increase employment, but did not do so
(Chemin and Wasmer, 2009). Edward Lazear (2006) summarized his 1990
paper by saying "I found that job security provisions were
instrumental in limiting employment in developed countries." More
broadly and recently, other researchers have used cross-country
comparisons to reach a similar conclusion (Botero et al., 2004;
Lafontaine and Sivadasan, 2009). Within the United States, Texas has one
of the most flexible labor markets. From June 2009 to June 2011, roughly
half of the net new jobs created in the United States were created in
Texas (Davidson, 2011).
Although labor market regulations have grown in the United States,
they remain less rigid there than in most European countries. This is
true for a wide variety of regulations. A study in 2013, for instance,
found that the United States was the only "advanced economy in the
world" that does not legally mandate that companies provide workers
with a paid vacation (Ray, Sanes, and Schmitt, 2013, p. 1). The United
States also has less rigid rules for parental leave than many other
countries (Ray, Gornick, and Schmitt, 2010).
Qualifications to the employment at-will doctrine, which were
intended to benefit workers, often have unintended consequences that
hurt them. Although creative destruction creates more jobs than it
destroys (Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh, 1996), in the short-run some
workers suffer because job destruction comes disproportionately during
recessions, while job creation is spread more evenly throughout the
business cycle. This implies that if you lose your job in a recession
you may need to wait longer to find another than you would if job
destruction was also spread more evenly.
So why is job loss so concentrated during recessions? Part of the
reason is that during a recession, managers face a lower cost of firing
workers. A great many firms avert their eyes from poor performing
employees during upswings. Managers do not want to bear the ill-will of
those they fire (Munger as quoted in Quick, 2010), and they do not want
to go through the internal firing processes, or bear the risk of
lawsuits if it is alleged they have violated some restriction on at-will
firing. But when firings can be blamed on a downturn, many of these
costs are reduced. During the exit interview, it appears that the
manager is not at fault for the firing, but rather the economy. And
fewer reasons or documentation need be given internally or to the
government if firing occurs during a recession. So if there was less
regulation of at-will employment, managers would have less incentive to
concentrate firings during recessions, and workers who are fired would,
on average, find new jobs more quickly.
3. The Robust Redundancy of Entrepreneurial Capitalism
Allowing greater labor market flexibility will enhance the
innovative entrepreneur's ability to experiment, start new
projects, and respond to new information or opportunities. But many will
worry that such flexibility leaves workers vulnerable to unexpected and
unwelcome task assignments, work conditions, or firings.
The most general and powerful response to these concerns is that
entrepreneurial capitalism, when it is allowed to function freely,
creates a redundant robustness that largely protects workers from the
worst-feared outcomes. What I mean by 'redundancy' can best be
understood by an extended analogy. My understanding of the analogy
derives mainly from an under-appreciated reporter and commentator on
entrepreneurial capitalism: George Gilder (in Telecosm, 2002). Some
aspects of the analogy are also discussed in Gleick's much
acclaimed best seller: The Information (2011).
The Ethernet is a preposterous technology that should not work. You
take a message, disassemble it into many discrete packets, send them by
different, unpredictable routes to their destination, and then
re-assemble them. (5) It would take a miracle for it to work. But it
does. (6) And not by a miracle, by redundancy: if a packet does not make
it through, it can be quickly re-sent.
Entrepreneurial capitalism can work this way. When one job is
destroyed, another is created. Even better, Davis, Haltiwanger, and
Schuh (1996) have shown that capitalism creates more jobs than it
destroys. Creating more jobs than are destroyed is important both for
the moral justification of creative destruction and for its political
viability. Nozick notes that for the original acquisition of property in
land to be justified there must be as much, and as good, left remaining
for others to acquire, what he calls "the Lockean proviso"
(Nozick, 1974, pp. 178-179). For the spirit of the Lockean proviso to be
satisfied, there must be opportunity (Nozick, 1974, p. 177). In a modern
society, a main form of opportunity is the availability of jobs.
(Another form of opportunity consists in allowing people to create their
own jobs through entrepreneurship.) Beyond moral justification, the
political viability of creative destruction depends on voters seeing
that in the long run, creative destruction creates opportunities for
all. Again, a key form of opportunity is the availability of jobs.
Thomas Friedman is right in observing that "there is no better
safety net than a healthy economy with low unemployment" (Friedman,
2000, p. 445).
Not only are there more new jobs created than old jobs
destroyed--Autor, Levy, and Murnane (2003) have shown that on average
the new jobs are better than the old ones, in the sense that they
involve less routine, less physical exhaustion, and less danger, and
further, that they involve more variety, creativity, and cognitive
challenges. And a worker can take actions to increase the odds that her
new job will be better, and that she will find it more quickly. The
redundancy of the labor market has implications beyond reducing the pain
from creative destruction. One implication is that since jobs are more
numerous and diverse in large cities, the redundancy is greater there,
which explains in part why cities are particularly conducive to creative
destruction.
Another implication is that workers have a greater hope of being
paid what they deserve. Standard economic price theory suggests that
workers in competitive markets will be paid the value of their marginal
product. (7) But judging the value of a worker's marginal product
is often hard, even when managers are attentive, when they are willing
to make tough calls, and when they work closely with a small number of
direct reports; this explains why pay so often is based more on
seniority, job titles, legacy pay levels, and educational credentials,
than on actual observed value of marginal product.
Like many policy makers, Schwartz and Sharpe (2010, p. 181) assume
that any defensible pay system will be based on a calculable algorithm,
in the absence of which, pay would depend on prejudice, affection, or
whimsy. They plausibly assert that no calculable algorithm exists, or
will exist, that results in workers being paid what they deserve. Their
cynical conclusion is that to be productive and innovative, workers must
sometimes become "canny outlaws," and at the very least must
give up the expectation of being paid what they deserve.
But the stories of Steve Jobs and Ray Kroc illustrate that through
experience and intuition, entrepreneurs and managers can develop an
accurate sense of the pay a worker deserves. Human Resource (HR)
departments and government regulators would be appalled at relying on
such intuitions, because of the possibility of discrimination. But if
the redundancy of the labor market provides an alternative to rigid
rules as a protection against discrimination (Becker, 1971), then the
market can take advantage of the informal knowledge of entrepreneurs,
not only to make firms more productive and innovative, but also to make
pay more accurately reflect what workers deserve.
In the next four sections of this paper, I discuss four labor
policies of government that arguably may enhance creative destruction,
either by enabling the innovative entrepreneur or by obtaining buy-in
from worried workers. Then in three sections of the paper I discuss some
of the personal policies that workers can adopt for themselves. These
personal policies advance creative destruction by decreasing the costs
to workers by better preparing them for job market changes.
4. Let Entrepreneurs Employ At-Will
For the innovative entrepreneur, flexible policies are better than
rigid policies. A great example is contained in entrepreneur Ray
Kroc's autobiography, where he explains an intuition he had that a
certain manager could not do his job, and should be let go. Kroc allowed
himself to be talked out of it, but eventually was proven right (1977,
pp. 91-92). In the meantime, the firm was less productive, and the
manager delayed the day when he could find a job where his skills were a
good match with what was needed. I argue elsewhere (Diamond, 2012) that
innovative entrepreneurs often benefit from informal
knowledge--knowledge that is real, often based on experience, but that
cannot be quickly or easily put into words. An entrepreneur in a
flexible labor market can act on such knowledge by employing-at-will.
When workers' jobs are "protected" by government
policies, the entrepreneur cannot act on such knowledge, and the firm is
less productive and innovative.
Case law and legislative statutes have restricted
employment-at-will in the United States, but the United States remains
closer to having an employment-at-will policy than countries in Europe.
The employment-at-will policy has been identified by Epstein (1984) and
by Posner (1995) as one of the primary reasons for the higher
productivity of the United States economy in earlier decades. Martins
(2009) finds that when the rules for firing are more flexible, workers
work harder (and to some extent, more workers tend to be hired). Note
also that when workers are made secure through job protection, rather
than through redundant job opportunity, the incompetent and unmotivated
are frozen into jobs that are then no longer available for the upward
mobility of the competent and the diligent.
Alan Hyde (2003) has studied the labor market in Silicon Valley,
arguably the epicenter of entrepreneurial activity in the United States
over the past three decades. He concludes that labor mobility, furthered
by employment-at-will-type policy, has been a key feature of the Silicon
Valley labor market. Virginia Postrel (2005) has made the case that in
Silicon Valley frequent job changes may benefit both labor and firms.
(8) The worker benefits by acquiring a greater diversity of human
capital, and possibly achieving a better match between the job and the
worker's preferences. The firm benefits by the infusion of new
ideas and skills. (9)
Steve Wozniak writes with regret of Apple's transition from
the flexible processes of an entrepreneurial startup to the rigid
processes of a mainstream corporation (Wozniak and Smith, 2006, pp.
232-233). One main piece of evidence of this transition is the
abandoning of employment-at-will. In writing of the pre-1983 management
troubles at Apple, Wozniak highlights that large companies usually lose
flexibility in hiring and firing. Good managers who have tacit (or just
insufficiently documented) knowledge about who the best employees are
have limited ability to act on that knowledge. It is unclear how much of
the transition away from flexible processes is due to internal standards
of what constitutes good corporate practice, and how much is due to a
desire to comply with laws and regulations and avoid potentially costly
lawsuits. How much of it is due to an inevitable disadvantage of size,
or to a doctrine learned in human resource courses in business schools,
or to other constraints from our laws, customs, and institutions?
Wozniak describes how then-Apple-CEO Mike Scott fired a large
number of engineers, and was then himself fired by the board for acting
without "a lot of backing and due process" (Wozniak and Smith,
2006, p. 231). Another leader of the company, Mike Markulla, told
Wozniak that "Mike Scott had been making a lot of rash
decisions" (p. 231). But Wozniak says that Mike Scott had
researched which engineers had been working and which not, and that with
Mike Scott running Apple, Wozniak "didn't see many things fall
through the cracks" (pp. 231-232). Most importantly, Wozniak, who
was in a position to know, thought that Mike Scott "fired all the
right ones. The laggards, I mean" (p. 231).
Wozniak's observations at Apple have been confirmed more
broadly. Bird and Knopf (2009) have looked at the effects in the banking
industry of court limitations on the employment-at-will doctrine. States
in the U.S. differ in how many, and which, of three common exceptions to
the doctrine they enforce (the public policy exception, the good-faith
exception, and the implied-contract exception). Controlling for state
economic conditions, they look at the effect of more exceptions on bank
profitability, and find that the greater the exceptions to the
employment-at-will doctrine, the lower the profitability of banks.
In Europe, and most famously France, laws and culture have made it
harder for firms to fire workers. In 2009, workers for Caterpillar, Inc.
in France literally held managers hostage (i.e., detained them against
their will) after the managers announced a plan to fire some of the
workers (Gauthier-Villars and Abboud, 2009, p. B1). When 3,000 French
firms were surveyed in 2004, 18 reported that managers had similarly
been held hostage by workers (Gauthier-Villars and Abboud, 2009, p. B1).
The situation in Europe has gone so far that Rob Grant has satirized it
in his novel Incompetence (2003), in which a government modeled on the
European Union (EU) passes a law to make it illegal to discriminate
against the incompetent by firing them.
Gust and Marquez (2004) have delved deeper into the effects of
employment protection. They find a negative correlation between
employment protection and information technology (IT) expenditures, and
a positive correlation between IT expenditures and labor productivity
growth (2004, p. 35). The causal chain suggested is that employment
protection leads firms to invest less in IT, and less investment in IT
leads to lower growth in labor productivity. Feldstein (2001) proposed a
motivation behind the causal chain. One main source of benefit from
personal computers is that they can substitute for some forms of routine
labor (e.g., Levy and Murnane, 2004a, 2004b). But if jobs are protected,
these benefits cannot be realized. So if job protection forecloses the
benefits from IT investment, entrepreneurs will invest less in IT.
5. Do Not Regulate Pay and Workplace Practices
To get their projects done, entrepreneurs make their best judgments
about who to hire, how much to offer them, the hours and environment of
work, the kind and number of meetings to hold, and a host of other
variables. Some process innovations consist mainly in trying new or
unpopular ways of deploying, supervising, and rewarding labor. Wal-Mart,
for instance, has been praised for the meetings in which associates
communicate with each other about what items are selling well (e.g.,
Walton, 1992, p. 222), and for having executives travel to visit stores
more frequently than competitors (Walton, 1992, p. 224). (10) Southwest
Airlines developed deliberately unpretentious (sometimes silly)
gatherings so that employees would not have too great a fear of those
further up in the company hierarchy (Freiberg and Freiberg, 1996, pp.
202-215). (11) When the government adds regulations to the labor market,
they close off entrepreneurial options. They may thus keep some projects
from getting done. Others will be done more slowly, or less well, or at
greater cost.
The evidence from particular cases is also supported by analysis of
broader data on many firms. For example, Autor, Kerr, and Kugler (2007)
find lower productivity when there are more regulations protecting
labor. Bird and Knopf (2009) show the same result for the banking
industry. Hallward-Driemeier and Rijkers (2013, p. 1805) find that
higher minimum wage laws (interpreted as labor market rigidity) resulted
in the exit of the more productive firms.
One reason minimum wage laws would reduce the productivity of firms
is that they induce entrepreneurs and managers to use a more costly or
less efficient mix of skilled and unskilled labor, or mix of labor and
machines. In weighing the pros and cons of the policy, these cons might
be justified, if there were sufficient benefits for workers. Card and
Krueger (1994) caused a substantial stir among economists by suggesting
that increases in the minimum wage benefit workers without causing a
rise in unemployment. But their conclusions have been credibly
challenged, and most economists still believe that increases in the
minimum wage hurt some of the poorest among those seeking entry to the
labor force (Deere, Murphy, and Welch, 1995; Becker and Posner, 2007;
Neumark and Wascher, 2008). Mayor Daley of Chicago accepted this belief
when he vetoed an increase in the Chicago minimum wage on the grounds
that it would increase unemployment (Hudson, 2006).
Besides restrictions on employment at-will, and minimum wage laws,
one of the other main sources of labor market rigidity consists of labor
union work rules. Guilds and labor unions, at their worst, stop the
efficient reallocation of labor that is part of the process of creative
destruction. Patrick Allitt (2002) suggests that labor union work rules
provided significant and increasing constraints on productivity and
efficiency during the Victorian era in Britain. (12) Allitt gives as a
specific example the continued enforcement of work-rules from decades
earlier in British ship-building facilities. The increase in union
rigidities would be supporting evidence for McCloskey's defense
(McCloskey and Sandberg, 1971) of British Victorian entrepreneurs
against the charge that their failings were the cause of the decline of
British industry. British Victorian entrepreneurs had been accused of
laxity in initiating and adopting technological advances, leading to
declines in inventiveness and productivity relative to the United
States. If Allitt is right, then the problem might not have been that
British entrepreneurs failed, but rather that British entrepreneurs
faced labor rigidity constraints that were absent in the United States.
(13)
6. Reduce "Creeping Credentialism"
The government increasingly interferes in the labor market by
requiring that a person have a certain set of credentials before they
are allowed to be employed in a certain occupation, or set themselves up
in a certain business. Several academics and intellectuals have observed
that this "credentialism" is on the rise. The phrase
"creeping credentialism" is often used to describe the
phenomenon. (14) Economist Richard Vedder describes it more colorfully
as "credentialing gone amok" and suggests that, "In 20
years, you'll need a Ph.D. to be a janitor" (as quoted in
Pappano, 2011, p. 17). Dwight Garner, reviewing a book by
"Professor X," dares to doubt that college is beneficial for
everyone. He observes that college "drives many young people into
debt. Many others lack rudimentary study skills or any scholarly
inclination. They want to get on with their lives, not be forced to
analyze the meter in "King Lear" in night school in order to
become a cop or a nurse's aide" (Garner, 2011, p. C3). This
credentialism can be implemented both directly and indirectly.
The direct type of credentialism takes different forms. One is to
require the receipt of a particular higher education degree, or a
particular degree with a particular major. Another is to require an
occupational license. Occupational licensing makes it more costly for
people to become free agent entrepreneurs by creating barriers to entry
(Buchholz, 2004, pp. 97-117; Kleiner, 2000). For one particularly
bizarre example, consider the California law stating that stylists need
to have a cosmetology license in order to legally braid hair (Postrel,
1997). Other states require licenses for personal trainers, florists,
and tour guides (Simon, 2011).
The indirect type of credentialism occurs when the government makes
entrepreneurs more vulnerable to charges of discrimination, wrongful
firing and the like, if they cannot articulately justify their actions.
In such situations the entrepreneur can more easily defend their actions
if the worker they want to hire is credentialed and if the worker they
want to fire is uncredentialed. Gilder (1993) discusses how this
cover-your-rear credentialism on the part of firms reduces opportunity.
To reduce the odds of a lawsuit, firms rely on credentialism rather than
their real judgment of who best fits the job. Immigrants, poorer blacks,
dyslexics, and felons, are less likely to have the credentials, and are
thus less likely to obtain jobs or be able to set themselves up as free
agent entrepreneurs.
Credentialism, whether of the indirect or direct type, increases
the costs and reduces the flexibility of innovative entrepreneurs.
Experience often makes it possible for innovative entrepreneurs to make
bets on new combinations of inputs and new ways for workers to interact
and create. One form of process innovation involves hiring employees who
others would shun. One example is Nucor hiring rural workers who lack
credentials, but who come from a culture of hard work (Collins, 2001).
Another case is Sam Walton thinking that with the right management
process a wide range of workers, including the shy and unsophisticated,
but friendly, workers who were his base, could be very productive
associates (Walton, 1992, p. 138). (15) A third example would be the
Southwest process summarized as "hire for attitude, train for
skills" (Freiberg and Freiberg, 1996, p. 64).
These labor market process innovations provide opportunities to
various disadvantaged groups of workers. Sometimes entrepreneurial firms
that hire "risky," less-educated workers, and then offer more
training, expect in compensation to be able to pay lower wages, or to
otherwise ask more in terms of working conditions (e.g., Wal-Mart asking
for longer hours). So it is not only credentialism that will discourage
these labor market experiments in process innovation. They will also be
discouraged by previously discussed restrictions of at-will employment,
as well as by minimum wage laws.
Although credentialism discourages entrepreneurial innovation and
reduces opportunities for workers, it still might be justified if it
provided substantial protection for consumers. The evidence, however,
suggests otherwise. For example, Kleiner and Kudrle (2000) compare the
performance of licensed and non-licensed dentists and found no
difference. More generally, Kleiner (2006) concludes from the literature
that there is not much evidence that licensing has any major effect on
the quality of services provided by the licensed occupations. Licensing,
however, raises the wage rate in licensed occupations by about 15% on
average (Kleiner and Krueger, 2010). According to Kleiner, those already
practicing an occupation "prefer to be licensed because they can
restrict competition and obtain higher wages" (Kleiner as quoted by
Simon, 2011, pp. A1 & A16). And unlike unions, which have diminished
in strength over time, occupational licensing has been growing
substantially (Kleiner and Krueger, 2010). In 1950, only 5% of workers
in the U.S. needed a license to practice their occupation; by 2008, the
percentage had more than quadrupled to 23% (Simon, 2011, p. A16). The
licensing of occupations adds at least $116 billion every year to the
cost of services in the U.S. (Kleiner as quoted by Simon, 2011, p. A16).
Many have described how the Crystal Palace in Victorian England was
a symbol of hope for a bright future in which new technologies would
make life better (Beaver, 1986). (Walt Disney included a downsized
replica of it in the Magic Kingdom as a sit-down dining location.) The
breakthrough design took advantage of the strength of new building
materials and was loved by visitors, in part because of the way it let
in the light. Surprisingly, the designer of the building was a gardener
who had no credentials in architecture (Bryson, 2010, pp. 10-11).
7. A Bigger Government Safety Net?
A plausible, and often advocated, government policy response to the
labor costs of creative destruction would be a safety net for those who
lose their jobs. Thomas Friedman, for instance, suggests that the
innovations from creative destruction are threatened by workers who fear
their job skills will become obsolete, thereby increasing the risk of
job loss (Friedman, 2000, p. 444). This threat leads Friedman to
advocate a safety net for workers, in order to obtain workers'
buy-in for an unimpeded process of creative destruction. Other advocates
of creative destruction, who also support a safety net, include Gene
Sperling (2005a, 2005b) and Robert Reich (2007).
Hayek argued (1976, pp. 122-124; see also pp. 207-208), to the
contrary, that the more generous the worker safety net, the more slowly
workers acquire new skills and move to new jobs, and the more slowly the
economy will grow. This is perhaps the main difference between
government "safety nets" and the private safety nets provided
by families--the government nets provide workers with incentives to
delay taking the steps necessary to transition to new jobs.
Concerns similar to Hayek's have been expressed by Polish
economic reformer Leszek Balcerowicz, famous for his shock therapy
transformation of the Polish economy from Communism to free markets. He
pondered human psychology and concluded: "People are more likely to
change their attitudes and their behavior if they are faced with radical
changes in their environment, which they consider irreversible, than if
those changes are only gradual" (Balcerowicz as quoted by Yergin
and Stanislaw, 1998, p. 271). A similar view has been expressed by
Michael Mandelbaum, Professor of Foreign Affairs at Johns Hopkins:
"People don't change when you tell them there is a better
option. They change when they conclude that they have no other
option" (Mandelbaum as quoted by Friedman, 2005, p. 462).
In the end, a government safety net may be implemented, either out
of a belief in its economic desirability, or out of a belief in its
political necessity. It would then be useful to analyze what forms of a
safety net would be least costly and most beneficial. The safety net
proposal of Thomas Friedman (2005), for example, attempts to preserve
the workers' incentive to seek new jobs. Rajan and Zingales (2003,
p. 300) pursue the same goal when they suggest that safety net payments
should take the form of lump-sum side payments to workers, rather than
the form of subsidies to firms. Unlike some other versions of a safety
net, they believe their version would neither slow the exit of dinosaur
firms, nor discourage the growth of "sunrise" firms. Payments
to workers, rather than subsidies to firms, would "prevent the
victims of creative destruction from being transformed into human
shields for special interests" (p. 300).
8. Workers Can Become More Entrepreneurial
In the earlier sections of the paper, I focused on policies the
government should adopt to enable innovative entrepreneurs to carry out
successful projects in an environment of creative destruction. In most
of the following sections, I focus on some personal policies that
workers themselves can adopt in order to ease their pains, and enhance
their gains from creative destruction.
One broad personal policy we can adopt as workers is for each of us
to become more personally entrepreneurial. What does that mean? I argue
elsewhere (Diamond, 2012) that entrepreneurs are willing to learn. When
jobs are creatively destroyed, those who are willing to learn will
bounce back sooner and at a higher wage than those who are less willing
to learn. Another way to become more personally entrepreneurial is to
adopt an attitude of courage, strength, and resilience.
This response to worries about job loss from creative destruction
might be termed the 'courage, strength, and resilience'
answer. Yes, losing a job is painful, but the gains from flexible labor
markets are great, and it is noble to display courage, strength, and
resilience. Key entrepreneurs have exemplified an attitude of courage,
strength, and resilience. When Brunelleschi lost the sole right to
design the Gates of Paradise, he bounced back by building the Duomo of
Florence (King, 2000); when Edison failed time-after-time to find a good
filament for his light bulb, he kept trying (Nye, 1991); and when Ford
bankrupted two start-up auto companies, he used what he learned for his
successful third try (Nye, 1991). (16)
Workers may be more willing to pursue the virtues of courage,
strength, and resilience when they see how the practice of those virtues
puts them more in control of their lives. Inglehart's survey
research (Inglehart and Welzel, 2005, p. 288) suggests that people want
freedom to choose, to feel in control of their lives. Other surveys,
along with the reports of individual entrepreneurs, show that
self-employed entrepreneurs experience a greater sense of control over
their work time than do employees (Shellenbarger, 2009, p. D1; Barrier,
2007, p. 152; Erdbrink, 2012, p. A12). Once employees experience being
entrepreneurs, they find it harder to go back to being employees; they
have learned to handle, enjoy, and derive satisfaction from the choices
and sense of control of entrepreneurship.
Finally, the case for resilience is easier to make than it might at
first seem, because usually workers do not have to be too resilient in
order to thrive in a labor market of entrepreneurial capitalism
characterized by creative destruction, with its robustly redundant
opportunities.
9. Frugality and Hard Work Can Reduce the Labor Pains
Fortunately, besides the redundancy of the labor market, there are
often actions workers can take to reduce the amount of courage,
strength, and resilience they need to do well. Such actions reduce the
pain from the destructive side of creative destruction. For example,
Stanley and Danko (1996) have argued that most workers have it within
their power to achieve significantly higher levels of financial
security. (17) The method is not surprising--primarily, the
"secret" is frugality. This does not mean a life of stoic
self-denial. One can live quite comfortably, with many material and
psychic pleasures. But to be frugal, you do need to forego some of the
pleasures of conspicuous consumption and expensive tastes.
There are a variety of ways to live frugally. You can forego new
wardrobes every year or two. You can buy from discount and
"club" stores. You can buy big-ticket items (e.g., cars) used
rather than new. You can buy a somewhat more modest home, with a
mortgage you can afford to pay during a period of lower earnings.
Stanley and Danko provide many examples that those who live below,
rather than above, their current means, thereby achieve a level of
savings that gives them peace of mind, even in a changing labor
environment. A person's own personal savings can also serve as a
resource (or safety net) for entrepreneurial activities.
Besides frugality, there are other policies workers can adopt to
reduce the pain from creative destruction. The family can serve as a
form of unemployment insurance (Di Tella and MacCulloch, 2002). One
member can have a 'safe' standard job, while another takes
greater risks as a free agent entrepreneur, or as the employee of a
fragile start-up. Part time jobs can serve as a safety net, especially
during the early start-up period for a free agent entrepreneurial
enterprise. Apparently, increasing numbers of retirees from standard
corporate jobs are using some of their savings to follow their dreams to
open entrepreneurial ventures (Pink, 2001; Olson, 2006). So policies
that increase the ability of workers to increase savings also increase
their entrepreneurship.
The Nucor and Southwest Airlines examples discussed earlier
illustrate that in landing good jobs a personal policy of hard work may
matter more than training. Recall that Nucor did well by locating in
rural areas. They found that it was more important to have workers who
showed up early and worked hard than to have workers with high levels of
relevant skills. (They knew how to train them for the skills; they did
not know how to induce them to have a work ethic.) Particular job skills
may be made obsolete by creative destruction, but creative destruction
will never make obsolete the value of showing up on time, working hard,
and being willing to learn.
Malcolm Gladwell (2008) emphasizes that to get really good at
something often seems to require spending about 10,000 hours working at
it; a similar point is made in Colvin (2008). Collins (2001) emphasizes
that the slow, constant pushing of the flywheel usually matters much
more than the sudden epiphany or stroke of good luck. Charles Murray
(2012) has recently presented evidence for the United States that only
the well-off are practicing a work ethic, while no one is preaching it.
He turns the usual aphorism on its head by advising that the well-off
should, "preach what they practice" (Murray, 2012, pp. 295 and
299).
Being more entrepreneurial means perfecting the character traits
that make entrepreneurial success more likely: resilience, frugality,
and hard work. But it also means using good judgment to pursue an
entrepreneurial project, or to work at a job that permits greater
creativity and autonomy. Even in hard economic times, free agent
entrepreneurs report higher levels of happiness than those in other
occupations (Shellenbarger, 2009).
10. Human Capital Investment
If parents anticipate their children will live in an environment
where creative destruction is common, they can give advice and make
choices that will help them acquire the human capital that will most
help them in a changing environment. Pink (2001) and Peters (2003) each
have chapters on education in which they point out that the current
Dewey-inspired educational systems are designed to turn children into
obedient amd static organization men and women. (18) Other forms of
education are more likely to aid and abet budding entrepreneurs and free
agents. Pink suggests that home schooling is one constructive
alternative. I believe that some versions of Montessori education
provide another. (19) Montessori education provides children with the
opportunity to constructively make choices and develop the skills and
confidence to allow them to better function as free agents. Resiliently
educated children will as adults be better able to bounce-back from
job-loss, and the bounce-back will be faster, and higher. And at higher
levels of education, Gary Becker has argued (1975, p. 190) for liberal
education as a means to acquire the general human capital that consists
of 'learning how to learn.' Such human capital is less likely
to depreciate through unpredictable changes in the job market.
As indicated elsewhere (Diamond, 2010), most episodes of
obsolescence through creative destruction, happen gradually and with
some advance warning. This gives some time for the alert to begin
retooling in anticipation of jobs becoming obsolete. To facilitate the
retooling of specific human capital, Alan Greenspan has advocated an
expanded role for community colleges. Also aiding worker retooling are
the growing offerings of within-company courses, and the growing array
of online learning tools (Christensen and Raynor, 2003, pp. 244-246).
Formal education is not the only way to acquire skills and
experiences that are useful as an employee or entrepreneur (Ellsberg,
2011). Information technology entrepreneurs Sean Parker and especially
Peter Thiel have been urging high school graduates to forego college,
and immediately try their hands at becoming entrepreneurs (Ellsberg,
2012). (20) Peter Thiel has gone so far as to set up a $100,000
"scholarship" for young entrepreneurs who pledge not to attend
college for two years (Miller, 2011). And as mentioned in an earlier
section, one unexpected form of human capital investment, in the context
of creative destruction, may be job-hopping (as observed especially in
Silicon Valley).
Conclusions
Capitalism is sometimes compared to sports, because both involve
competition. In the short-run competition of capitalism, sometimes one
"team" wins and another "team" loses. But in the
longer run, the essential fact about capitalism is not competition, but
innovation. And in the longer run triumph of innovation, all can win.
Certainly, as consumers we win from the new products and processes that
creative destruction creates.
In the labor market, there will be short-run losers. But we can
adopt government and personal policies to reduce the duration and
severity of the short-run losses. When Ghiberti and Brunelleschi
competed to design the Gates of Paradise, Ghiberti ended up designing
the Gates. But it would be a mistake to see him as the winner and
Brunelleschi as the loser. Brunelleschi moved on to build the Duomo, and
everyone won. (21)
References
Allitt, Patrick N. Victorian Britain. Chantilly, VA: The Teaching
Company, 2002.
Ansalone, George. Exploring Unequal Achievement in the Schools: The
Social Construction of Failure. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, 2009.
Autor, David H., Frank Levy, and Richard J. Murnane. "The
Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical
Exploration." Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 4 (Nov. 2003):
1279-333.
Autor, David H., William R. Kerr, and Adriana D. Kugler. "Does
Employment Protection Reduce Productivity? Evidence from U.S.
States." Economic Journal 117 (June 2007): F189-F217.
Barrier, Michael. The Animated Man: A Life of Walt Disney.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 2007.
Beaver, Patrick. The Crystal Palace. Andover, UK: Phillimore &
Co. Ltd., 1986.
Becker, Gary S. The Economics of Discrimination. 2nd Rev ed.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1971.
Becker, Gary S. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical
Analysis; with Special Reference to Education. 2nd ed. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1975.
Becker, Gary S., and Richard A. Posner. "How to Make the Poor
Poorer." The Wall Street Journal (Fri., Jan. 26, 2007): A11.
Bird, Robert C., and John D. Knopf. "Do Wrongful-Discharge
Laws Impair Firm Performance?" Journal of Law and Economics 52, 2
(May 2009): 197222.
Block, Walter. "The Discounted Marginal Value Product-Marginal
Value Product Controversy: A Note." The Review of Austrian
Economics 4 (1990): 199-207.
Botero, Juan C., Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, Lopez-De-Silanes,
and Andrei Florencio; Shleifer. "The Regulation of Labor."
Quarterly Journal of Economics 119, 4 (Nov. 2004): 1339-82.
Bryson, Bill. At Home: A Short History of Private Life. New York:
Doubleday, 2010.
Buchholz, Todd G. Bringing the Jobs Home: How the Left Created the
Outsourcing Crisis--and How We Can Fix It. New York: Sentinel, 2004.
Caballero, Ricardo J. Specificity and the Macroeconomics of
Restructuring, Yrjo Jahnsson Lectures. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press,
2007.
Caballero, Ricardo, and Mohamad Hammour. "Institutions,
Restructuring and Macroeconomic Performance." In Advances in
Macroeconomic Theory, edited by Jacques Dreze. Houndmills, New York:
Palgrave, 2001, pp. 171-93.
Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. "Minimum Wages and
Employment: A
Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and
Pennsylvania." The American Economic Review 84, 4 (Sept. 1994):
772-93.
Chemin, Matthieu, and Etienne Wasmer. "Using Alsace-Moselle
Local Laws to Build a Difference-in-Differences Estimation Strategy of
the Employment Effects of the 35-Hour Workweek Regulation in
France." Journal of Labor Economics 27, 4 (Oct. 2009): 487-524.
Christensen, Clayton M. and Michael E. Raynor. The Innovator's
Solution: Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth. Boston, MA: Harvard
Business School Press, 2003.
Collins, Jim. Good to Great: Why Some Companies Make the Leap...
and Others Don't. New York: Harper Business, 2001.
Colvin, Geoff. Talent Is Overrated: What Really Separates
World-Class Performers from Everybody Else. New York: Portfolio, 2008.
Cox, W. Michael and Richard Alm. "The Churn: The Paradox of
Progress." 1992 Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Davidson, Paul. "Need a Job? Move to Texas." USA Today
(Tues., July 20, 2011): 1A.
Davis, Steven J., John C. Haltiwanger, and Scott Schuh. Job
Creation and Destruction. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1996.
Deere, Donald, Kevin M. Murphy, and Finis Welch. "Employment
and the 1990-1991 Minimum-Wage Hike." The American Economic Review
85, 2 (May 1995): 232-37.
DeLong, J. Bradford. "Cornucopia: The Pace of Economic Growth
in the Twentieth Century." NBER Working Paper No. 7602, March 2000.
Diamond, Arthur M., Jr. "The Epistemology of
Entrepreneurship." Advances in Austrian Economics 17 (2012):
111-142.
Diamond, Arthur M., Jr. "Review of Andersen, Esben Sloth.
Joseph A. Schumpeter: A Theory of Social and Economic Evolution."
EH.Net Economic History Services (Aug. 20, 2012). Available at:
http://eh.net/book_reviews/joseph-a-schumpeter-a-theory-of-socialand-economic-evolution.
Diamond, Arthur M., Jr. "Schumpeterian Labor Economics: The
Labor Pains (and Labor Gains) from Creative Destruction." Presented
to International Schumpeter Society Meetings in Aalborg, Denmark, June
24, 2010.
Di Tella, Rafael, and Robert J. MacCulloch. "Informal Family
Insurance and the Design of the Welfare State." Economic Journal
112, 481 (2002): 481503.
Ellsberg, Michael. The Education of Millionaires: It's Not
What You Think and It's Not Too Late. New York: Portfolio
Hardcover, 2011.
Ellsberg, Michael. "Sean Parker and Peter Thiel Introducing Me
at a Book Event." Group email received by Arthur Diamond, 2012.
Epstein, Richard A. "In Defense of the Contract at Will."
University of Chicago Law Review 51, 4 (Autumn 1984): 947-82.
Erdbrink, Thomas. "Tehran Journal; Pinched Aspirations of
Iran's Young Multitudes." The New York Times (Tues., May 8,
2012): A4 & A12.
Faber, David. "The Age of Wal-Mart." CNBC, 2004.
Fallick, Bruce, Charles A. Fleischman, and James B. Rebitzer.
"Job Hopping in Silicon Valley: The Microfoundations of a High Tech
Industrial Cluster." Review of Economics and Statistics 88, 3 (Aug.
2006): 472-81.
Feldstein, Martin. "Economic Policy for the Information
Economy: Overview." Presented at the Jackson Hole Conference of the
Kansas City Federal Reserve Bank, Aug. 2001, available at:
http://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2001/papers/S02feld. pdf
Freiberg, Kevin, and Jackie Freiberg. Nuts! Southwest
Airlines' Crazy Recipe for Business and Personal Success. Austin,
TX: Bard Press, 1996.
Friedman, Thomas L. The Lexus and the Olive Tree. Updated and
expanded ed. New York: Anchor Books, 2000.
Friedman, Thomas L. The World Is Flat: A Brief History of the
Twenty-First Century. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2005.
Garner, Dwight. "Books of the Times; an Academic Hit Man
Brings More Bad News." The New York Times (Wed., April 6, 2011):
C3.
Gauthier-Villars, David, and Leila Abboud. "In France, the
Bosses Can Become Hostages." The Wall Street Journal (Fri., April
3, 2009): B1 & B5.
Gilder, George. Microcosm: The Quantum Revolution in Economics and
Technology. Paperback ed. New York: Touchstone, 1990.
Gilder, George. Telecosm: The World after Bandwidth Abundance. New
York: Touchstone, 2002.
Gilder, George. Wealth and Poverty. 3rd ed. New York: ICS Press,
1993.
Gladwell, Malcolm. Outliers: The Story of Success. New York, NY:
Little, Brown, and Co., 2008.
Gleick, James. The Information: A History, a Theory, a Flood. New
York: Pantheon Books, 2011.
Grant, Rob. Incompetence. London, UK: Gollancz, 2003.
Gust, Christopher J, and Jaime R. Marquez. "International
Comparisons of Productivity Growth: The Role of Information Technology
and Regulatory Practices." Labour Economics 11, 1 (Feb. 2004):
33-58.
Hallward-Driemeier, Mary, and Bob Rijkers. "Do Crises Catalyze
Creative Destruction? Firm-Level Evidence from Indonesia." Review
of Economics and Statistics 95, 5 (Dec. 2013): 1788-810.
Hayek, Friedrich A. The Road to Sefdom. Chicago: University of
Chicago, 1976.
Hof, Robert D. "The Torrent of Energy Behind Amazon."
Business-Week (Dec. 14, 1998): 119.
Hudson, Kris. "Chicago's Daley Vetoes Bill Aimed at Big
Retailers." The Wall Street Journal (Thurs., Sept. 12, 2006): A4.
Hyde, Alan. Working in Silicon Valley: Economic and Legal Analysis
of a High-Velocity Labor Market. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 2003.
Inglehart, Ronald, and Christian Welzel. Modernization, Cultural
Change, and Democracy: The Human Development Sequence. New York:
Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Isaacson, Walter. Steve Jobs. New York: Simon & Schuster, 2011.
Jenkins, Holman W., Jr. "Business World; the Land (and
Antitrust Case) That Time Forgot." The Wall Street Journal (Wed.,
April 26, 2006): A17.
Johnson, Steven. Where Good Ideas Come From: The Natural History of
Innovation. New York: Riverhead Books, 2010.
Kidder, Tracy. The Soul of a New Machine. Boston: Little Brown,
1981.
King, Ross. Brunelleschi's Dome: How a Renaissance Genius
Reinvented Architecture. London: Chatto & Windus, 2000.
Kirzner, Israel M. "Creativity and/or Alertness: A
Reconsideration of the Schumpeterian Entrepreneur." The Review of
Austrian Economics 11, 1-2 (March 1999): 5-17.
Kleiner, Morris M. "Occupational Licensing." The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 14, 4 (Autumn 2000): 89-202.
Kleiner, Morris M. Licensing Occupations: Ensuring Quality or
Restricting Competition? Kalamazoo, Michigan: W.E. Upjohn Institute,
2006.
Kleiner, Morris M., and Alan B. Krueger. "The Prevalence and
Effects of Occupational Licensing." British Journal of Industrial
Relations 48, 4 (Dec. 2010): 676-87.
Kleiner, Morris M., and Robert T. Kudrle. "Does Regulation
Improve Outputs And. Increase Prices? The Case of Dentistry."
Journal of Law & Economics 43, 2 (Oct. 2000): 547-82.
Knight, Frank H. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Augustus
M. Kelley, 1964.
Kroc, Ray. Grinding It Out: The Making of McDonald's. Chicago:
Henry Regnery Company, 1977.
Lafontaine, Francine, and Jagadeesh Sivadasan. "Do Labor
Market Rigidities Have Microeconomic Effects? Evidence from within the
Firm." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1, 2 (April
2009): 88-127.
Lazear, Edward P. "A Success Story: American
Productivity." Remarks at the National Economists Club, Washington,
D.C., July 13, 2006.
Lemieux, Thomas. "Review of Lipset and Meltz's the
Paradox of American Unionism." Journal of Economic Literature 45, 3
(Sept. 2007): 761-63.
Levy, Frank, and Richard J. Murnane. "Book Excerpt: The New
Division of Labor." Milken Institute Review 6, 4 (2004a): 61-82.
Levy, Frank, and Richard J. Murnane. The New Division of Labor: How
Computers Are Creating the Next Job Market. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 2004b.
Lipset, Seymour Martin, and Noah M. Meltz. The Paradox of American
Unionism: Why Americans Like Unions More Than Canadians Do but Join Much
Less. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2004.
Malseed, Mark. "The Story of Sergey Brin; How the Moscow-Born
Entrepreneur Cofounded and Changed the Way the World Searches."
Moment Magazine, Feb. 2007.
Martins, Pedro S. "Dismissals for Cause: The Difference That
Just Eight Paragraphs Can Make." Journal of Labor Economics 27, 2
(April 2009): 257-79.
McCloskey, Deirdre N., and Lars G. Sandberg. "From Damnation
to Redemption: Judgments on the Late Victorian Entrepreneur."
Explorations in Economic History 9 (Fall 1971): 89-108.
Miller, Claire Cain. "Changing the World by Dropping
Out." The New York Times (Mon., May 30, 2011): B4.
Mises, Ludwig von. Human Action, the Scholar's Edition.
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998.
Murray, Charles. Coming Apart: The State of White America,
1960-2010. New York: Crown Forum, 2012.
Neumark, David, and William L. Wascher. Minimum Wages. Cambridge,
MA: The MIT Press, 2008.
Nozick, Robert. Anarchy, State, and Utopia. New York: Basic Books,
1974.
Nye, John Vincent. "Lucky Fools and Cautious Businessmen: On
Entrepreneurship and the Measurement of Entrepreneurial Failure."
In The Vital One: Essays in Honour of Jonathan R. T. Hughes, edited by J
oel
Mokyr. Greenwich, Conn. and London: JAI Press, 1991, pp. 131-52.
Olson, Elizabeth. "Small Business; in Life's Second Act,
Some Take on a New Role: Entrepreneur." The New York Times (Thur.,
Sept. 28, 2006): C6.
Pappano, Laura. "The Master's as the New
Bachelor's." The New York Times, EducationLife Section (Sun.,
July 24, 2011): 16-17.
Peters, Tom. Re-Imagine! London: DK, 2003.
Pink, Daniel H. Free Agent Nation: How America's New
Independent Workers Are Transforming the Way We Live. N.Y.: Warner
Business Books, 2001.
Posner, Richard A. Overcoming Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1995.
Postrel, Virginia. "Economic Scene; in Silicon Valley, Job
Hopping Contributes to Innovation." The New York Times (Thur., Dec.
1, 2005): C4.
Postrel, Virginia. "Hair-Raising Laws." Reason (April
1997); Available at: http://www.reason.com/news/show/30215.html.
Price, David A. The Pixar Touch: The Making of a Company. New York:
Alfred A. Knopf, 2008.
Quick, Rebecca (interviewer). "A Conversation with Charlie
Munger." University of Michigan Ross School of Business, Sept. 14,
2010, Available at: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=K6RS_PqudxU.
Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. Saving Capitalism from the
Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of Financial Markets to Create Wealth
and Spread Opportunity. New York: Crown, 2003.
Rampell, Catherine. "Ideas & Trends; How Industries
Survive Change. If They Do." The New York Times (Sun., Nov. 15,
2008): 3.
Rawls, John. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press, 1971.
Ray, Rebecca, Janet C. Gornick, and John Schmitt. "Who Cares?
Assessing Generosity and Gender Equality in Parental Leave Policy
Designs in 21 Countries." Journal of European Social Policy 20, 3
(July 2010): 196-216.
Ray, Rebecca, Milla Sanes, and John Schmitt. "No-Vacation
Nation Revisited." Centerfor Economic and Policy Research, May
2013.
Reich, Robert B. Supercapitalism: The Transformation of Business,
Democracy, and Everyday Life. New York: Knopf, 2007.
Richtel, Matt. "The Youngest Technorati." The New York
Times (Fri., March 9, 2014): 1 & 6.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. 3rd ed.
New York: Harper and Row, 1950.
Schwartz, Barry, and Kenneth Sharpe. Practical Wisdom: The Right
Way to Do the Right Thing. New York: Riverhead Books, 2010.
Shellenbarger, Sue. "Plumbing for Joy? Be Your Own Boss."
The Wall Street Journal (Weds., Sept. 15, 2009): D1-D2.
Simon, Stephanie. "A License to Shampoo: Jobs Needing State
Approval Rise." The Wall Street Journal (Mon., Feb. 7, 2011): A1
& A16.
Sperling, Gene. "The Early-Warning Economy; the Time to Think
About Helping Displaced Workers Is before They Lose Their Jobs."
The Washington Monthly, Dec. 2005a. Downloaded from
http://www.washingtonmonthly.com/features/2005/0512.sperling.ht ml on
4/22/07.
Sperling, Gene. The Pro-Growth Progressive: An Economic Strategy
for Shared Prosperity. New York: Simon & Schuster, 2005b.
Stanley, Thomas J., and William D. Danko. The Millionaire Next
Door: The
Surprising Secrets of America's Wealthy Books. First ed.
Atlanta: Longstreet Press, 1996.
Walton, Sam. Made in America: My Story. New York: Doubleday, 1992.
Whyte, William H., Jr. The Organization Man. New York: Simon and
Schuster, 1956.
Wilcox, Ronald. Whatever Happened to Thrift? Why Americans
Don't Save and What to Do About It. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press, 2008.
Wozniak, Steve, and Gina Smith. iWog: Computer Geek to Cult Icon:
How I Invented the Personal Computer, Co-Founded Apple, and Had Fun
Doing It. New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 2006.
X, Professor. In the Basement of the Ivory Tower: Confessions of an
Accidental Academic. New York: Viking, 2011.
Yergin, Daniel, and Joseph Stanislaw. The Commanding Heights: The
Battle for the World Economy. New York: Simon & Schuster, 1998.
(1) Schumpeter was the first to identify creative destruction as
the process by which old products and modes of production are replaced
by new ones. in the many decades since Schumpeter first wrote of
creative destruction in 1942, accumulating evidence has supported the
basic idea of creative destruction, though not all of the details of
Schumpeter's original account. One interpretation of Schumpeter is
that he thought periods of creative destruction were interspersed at
regular, predictable intervals with periods of Walrasian circular flow
(see Diamond, 2012). In praising a Walrasian account of the
equilibrium-maintaining circular flow process, Schumpeter did not see
what Kirzner later did, that an entrepreneur alert to price differences
(what we now call a "Kirznerian entrepreneur") is required to
achieve the efficiency benefits of equilibrium. We now understand
creative destruction better than Schumpeter did and so we know that
efficiency-seeking activities, implemented by the Kirznerian
entrepreneur, can and should co-exist with the innovation-seeking
activities of the Schumpeterian entrepreneur. For Kirzner's own
nuanced account of these issues, see Kirzner (1999).
(2) A flexible labor market is one in which entrepreneurs and
workers face few government regulations that limit the types of work
arrangements that they are allowed to mutually agree on. But a flexible
labor market does not imply that individual work arrangements will
always be flexible in other possible senses. For example, employers may
offer flextime to an architect, but not to an air traffic controller.
(3) In the Wall Street Journal Editorial Board member and
commentator Holman Jenkins (2006) has gone so far as to say that the
Europeans have a "pathological revulsion" to the
"disorder" in the economy caused by such agents of creative
destruction as Apple. The source of such revulsion is not clear. Botero
et al. (2004) show that leftist political power and non-common-law legal
origins increase the extent of labor market regulations. Surprisingly,
of the two, non-common-law legal origins matter more. In contrast,
"the greatest single asset that the American economy has always had
is the flexibility and mobility of its labor force and labor laws"
according to Harvard economist Robert Lawrence (as paraphrased by
Friedman, 2005, pp. 284-285).
(4) For evidence on how exceptional the 20th century was, see Brad
DeLong's "Cornucopia" working paper (2000).
(5) Besides the Ethernet, Gleick also describes (2011, pp. 13-15)
the African talking drum language, which works because its rich detail
provides redundant paths to understanding the main message.
(6) Similarly, Frank Knight long ago observed that many problems
that the dominant theory says are unsolvable, are actually solvable in
practice: "Like a large proportion of the practical problems of
business life, as of all life, this one of selecting human capacities
for dealing with unforeseeable situations involves paradox and apparent
theoretical impossibility of solution. But like a host of impossible
things in life, it is constantly being done" (Knight, 1964 [1921],
p. 298).
(7) One source in the theory literature on the value of marginal
product is Block (1990).
(8) Postrel bases her discussion largely on Fallick et al. (2006).
(9) Notice that this example refutes the common belief that low
unemployment corresponds to long job tenure. When there is frequent
job-hopping, there can be both low unemployment, and short job tenure.
(10) The meetings were discussed, and part of one shown, in David
Faber's Peabody-award-winning documentary The Age of Wal-Mart,
produced in 2004 for CNBC.
(11) Freiberg and Freiberg document the silliness, but imply it is
intended mainly to make work "fun" for Southwest employees.
That may be, but I believe it serves a subtler purpose of easing
communication up the hierarchy.
(12) "Trade unions ... impaired British competitiveness by
designing rigid demarcation rules and fostering an environment of mutual
distrust between workers and management" (Allitt, 2002, p. 42 of
Course Guidebook).
(13) Lemieux (2007, p. 762) reports that Lipset and Meltz (2004)
attribute lower unionization in the U.S. to a greater individualism that
results in skepticism toward collective action.
(14) One source of the phrase "creeping credentialism" is
Ansalone (2009, p. 10).
(15) But he also thought that with the right management process,
more sophisticated city workers could be good associates too (Walton
1992, p. 138).
(16) Another person who exemplified the attitude was Masatoshi
Shima, a key developer of an early microprocessor chip (the 4004). Early
in life, as a chemical engineering student, he had experimented with
gunpowder in order to launch a small rocket. The gunpowder exploded,
blowing off most of his right hand. The loss made it hard for him to
function as a chemical engineer, so he switched to computer architecture
and helped create personal computing. (Shima's story is told in
Gilder, 1990, pp. 104105.)
(17) Other authors have made arguments similar to Stanley and
Danko, e.g., Wilcox (2008).
(18) In his influential sociology classic The Organization Man
(1956), William Whyte describes growing numbers of white-collar workers
at large organizations (be they corporate, governmental, or non-profit)
who lead secure comfortable lives of excruciating routine and
conformity.
(19) Jeff Bezos (Amazon) and Sergey Brin (Google) are two prominent
information technology entrepreneurs who participated in Montessori
education as children (see: Hof, 1998; and Malseed, 2007).
(20) Thiel must find it encouraging that the grandson of Gary
Becker is considering following Thiel's advice rather than that of
his grandfather (Richtel, 2014, p. 6). But of course, besides being
enthused about higher education, Becker was also enthused about gutsy
entrepreneurship, so either way he will be proud.
(21) My contrast between competition in capitalism and competition
in sports may, at first glance, appear similar to the contrast Mises
makes between "biological competition" and "catallactic
competition" (von Mises, 1998, pp. 273-277). But the contrasts are
not as similar as they seem. Mises's biological competition is a
zero-sum competition for food that has no spillover benefits for third
parties. Mises's catallactic competition is a zerosum competition
for social status that has large spillover benefits for consumers. For
him, all competition is zero-sum for those competing. In my account,
capitalism is non-zerosum for those competing, in the sense that those
who compete in the short-run, may all in the long-run find projects that
bring them satisfaction and happiness. Ghiberti beat Brunelleschi in the
short-run, but in the long-run Ghiberti had his Gates of Paradise and
Brunelleschi had his Duomo.
ARTHUR M. DIAMOND, JR. *
* Arthur M. Diamond, Jr. is Kayser Professor of Economics at the
University of Nebraska at Omaha. Earlier versions of this paper were
presented at the 2012 meetings of the Association of Private Enterprise
Education and the International Schumpeter Society. He is grateful for
very useful comments from two anonymous referees and for research
assistance from Godfred Amoah.