Understanding the relationship between uncertainty and international information technology sourcing strategy: a conceptual framework.
Ahsan, Mujtaba ; Haried, Peter ; Musteen, Martina 等
INTRODUCTION
The inherent economic advantages of international offshore sourcing
(offshoring) work to cheaper offshore locations have made offshoring a
business necessity for many enterprises. More and more organizations are
relying on offshoring to provide critical information technology (IT)
products and services and this phenomenon is likely to continue into the
future (Davis, Ein-Dor, King & Torkzadeh, 2006). Significant cost
savings are not the only or major objective for IT offshoring. Many
companies are forced to offshore due to the lack of available technical
talent in their home country (Ernst, 2006). However, the decision to
offshore involves a certain degree of uncertainty for the firm (client)
entering the offshoring arena. The question is not always about whether
it is better for a company to insource or outsource. Rather, the
question is increasingly becoming--how can companies reduce the
uncertainties associated with IT offshoring and fit their IT offshoring
strategies to the uncertainties encountered? To date, there has been
little research investigating how IT managers address and match
uncertainty with their IT offshoring strategy.
Much has been written about the management of and the decision to
adopt IT outsourcing and offshoring (i.e., Lacity & Willcocks, 1996;
Wang, 2002). Generally, when examining the IT outsourcing decision, the
literature has focused on costs and control structures (Kern &
Willcocks, 2000; Kim & Kim, 2008). Relatively few studies have
investigated the uncertainties that surround the IT offshoring decision
(i.e., Saunders, Gebelt & Hu, 1997). This is somewhat surprising
given that nearly all international investments, including IT
offshoring, are impacted by uncertainty and dealing with this
uncertainty is crucial for success. Recent research by Hahn, Doh and
Bunyaratevej (2009) suggests a significant need to examine the
determinants of firm IT offshoring behavior with respect to offshoring
location risk.
Given the predicted growth of the offshoring phenomenon, and the
significant role of risk with a firm's performance, there is ample
opportunity and an essential need for academics and practitioners to
understand the impact of uncertainties in regards to the IT offshoring
decision. Previous research has failed to fully capture and explain the
role of uncertainties involved in IT offshoring. A framework that would
synthesize the role of uncertainty in the context of the IT offshoring
decision has yet to fully emerge. Moreover, much of the existing
research on offshoring has assumed that the different forms of
uncertainties (i.e., political uncertainty, cultural uncertainty,
macroeconomic uncertainty, etc.) have the same (or similar) effect on a
client firm's offshoring decision (i.e., Aspray, Mayadas &
Vardi, 2006; Hahn et al., 2009; Kleim, 2004). We argue that this not
true as some uncertainties can only be resolved through learning (i.e.,
a client firm's activities) and other uncertainties evolve
independent of a client firm's activities. Drawing on the real
options and organization learning theories we develop a framework that
incorporates uncertainty in explaining the IT offshoring model decision.
To parsimoniously assess the uncertainty inherent to IT offshoring our
proposed framework distinguishes between endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties in relation to the IT offshoring decision. Specifically,
we argue the level of endogenous and exogenous uncertainty surrounding
IT offshoring determines whether a client firm adopts a captive
offshoring, joint-venture, third-party or onsite IT offshoring model. In
doing so, we seek to fill an important gap in the IT offshoring
literature.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next
section reviews the extant IT offshoring literature in regards to
uncertainty. Next, we develop a theoretical framework used to examine
uncertainty in the IT offshoring environment. The third section
discusses the propositions regarding the role of uncertainty and the IT
offshoring decision. We then present an illustrative case example
demonstrating how our framework captures the evolution of a client
firm's IT offshoring strategy to fit the uncertainties faced by the
client firm. We conclude with sections presenting the research
limitations, suggest implications for both academics and practitioners
and provide recommendations for future IT offshoring uncertainty
research.
IT OFFSHORING
Organizations today follow a variety of approaches when entering
into an IT offshoring arrangement. These approaches include: the use of
foreign subsidiaries, foreign acquisitions, offshore development
centers, joint ventures or alliances, and foreign contracting (Carmel
& Agarwal, 2002). The ambiguity in the definition and many forms of
IT offshoring complicate an already challenging decision for
organizations. An expanded definition by Davis et al. (2006) indicates
offshoring to be accomplished in one of two ways. First, the
organization may outsource some of its activities to service providers
in other countries who hire, train, supervise and manage its (i.e., the
client's) personnel. Second, the client organization may set up
service operations in other countries where the operations are managed
by its own staff located in those countries rather than by the outside
service provider. Barthelemy and Geyer (2005) also define outsourcing as
either (1) a contract with an outsourcing vendor or (2) a client setting
up their own IT subsidiary offshore (i.e., captive-outsourcing). For the
purpose of this paper, we apply a general definition to offshoring where
we focus on the IT offshoring decision to include the client firm
utilizing a selected IT offshoring model.
Specifically, in this paper we focus on the following offshoring
models: joint ventures, captive offshoring, third party offshoring, and
an offshoring arrangement located onsite (i.e., onsite captive
offshoring model). The offshoring models differ based on the amount of
equity or investment that is made by the client firm and also on the
degree of learning occurring as a result of the investment. In an
offshore captive model the client firm invests, owns and operates a
subsidiary in an offshore location. The client firm is in charge of
hiring and operating the offshore facility utilizing the offshore
resources. In an onsite captive offshoring model, the client firm brings
offshore resources to work at the onsite location by collaborating with
a third party. That is, the third party offshore vendor will provide the
human capital resources by relocating the vendor employees to the
client's location to perform the IT activities. The vendor
resources will be managed by and report to the client's project
leaders. In a joint-venture model, the client and vendor firm share the
investments needed to operate offshore. Client firms may also choose to
hire a third party offshore vendor to supply the IT activities to the
client firm. The vendor is located offshore and performs the IT
activities outside of the home country of the client firm. Hiring a
third party vendor requires less equity or upfront investment when
compared to the equity-based offshore models.
IT OFFSHORING AND ENDOGENOUS VS. EXOGENOUS UNCERTAINTY
In this paper uncertainty in the offshoring setting refers to the
prospect of unanticipated developments in the technological, business,
or political environments of the offshore vendor country which are of
particular concern in the offshoring decision, given the global nature
of IT offshoring (Mirani, 2006). Studies often cite a wide variety of
uncertainty definitions. For example, Miliken (1987) defines uncertainty
as a "perceived inability to predict accurately" due to a lack
of "sufficient information." Uncertainty can also be defined
as a condition in which one cannot ascertain the probability of an event
and therefore cannot insure against its occurrence (Miller &
Shamsie, 1999; North, 1990). In order to develop a parsimonious
theoretical framework to effectively capture the various uncertainties
involved in the IT offshoring decision, we introduce and rely on the
distinction between endogenous and exogenous uncertainty (Dixit &
Pindyck, 1994; Folta, 1998). Uncertainty is endogenous when a client is
able to reduce or dispel the uncertainty through its own actions. For
example, uncertainty associated with operating in a very culturally
different environment diminishes as a firm gains experience about
cultural norms and business practices (i.e., customer preferences,
partner relationships, supplier network etc.). That is, the reduction of
endogenous uncertainty is dependent on the client firm's learning
process (Folta, 1998; Roberts & Weitzman, 1981). In contrast,
exogenous uncertainty arises externally to the firm and is mostly
independent of the firm's actions; it includes factors such as
unforeseen actions by external entities (i.e., regulatory bodies,
governments etc.) (Folta, 1998). Firms have little or no control over
the evolution of exogenous uncertainty. Client firms have to deal with a
variety of exogenous uncertainties while operating in a host country
(Hill, Hwang & Kim, 1990). These include political uncertainty
(Kobrin, 1982; Miller, 1992), legal and regulatory uncertainty (Teece,
1986; Teisberg, 1993), and macroeconomic uncertainty (Hassett and
Metcalf, 1999; Miller, 1992). For example, a client firm's actions
have marginal or no effect on reducing exogenous uncertainty (i.e.,
political regime change). However, it can be reduced by a passive
observation and a general learning of the host country's
environment.
As seen from the above discussion, a client firm may face both
endogenous and exogenous uncertainties when examining its own IT
offshoring decision. Viewing IT offshoring models as a special kind of
real options, we draw on the real options and organizational learning
literature to develop a theoretical framework that allows for effective
differentiation and understanding of uncertain environments and its
effects on the IT offshoring decision.
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND
Traditionally, offshoring has been viewed as a unique form of
foreign market entry; one that is focused on access to labor markets.
There are several theoretical perspectives in this body of literature
that provide valuable insights into the offshoring model choice. For
example, the transaction cost theory (TCT) (Williamson, 1975) has been
widely applied to analyze the IT outsourcing decision from an economic
perspective (i.e., Lacity & Willcocks, 1996; Wang, 2002). It
suggests that when asset specificity is low, and transactions are
relatively frequent, the transactions will tend to be governed by
markets and the offshoring decision will move towards utilizing an
offshore third party. On the other hand, high asset specificity and
uncertainty will lead to transactional difficulties and transactions
will be held internally within the firm, or vertically integrated
through a client sponsored offshore subsidiary (captive offshoring).
The proponents of the internalization theory (Buckley & Casson,
1976) posit that multinational enterprises (MNEs) internalize their
operations when faced with uncertainty surrounding a transfer of their
proprietary knowledge. In the context of offshoring, a client might
choose to open and operate their own offshoring subsidiary instead of
partnering with a host country vendor when the risk of opportunism by
the partner is high. This view draws on the organizational learning
literature and suggests that cumulative international experiences enable
MNEs to reduce uncertainty. Likewise, a stage model of offshoring
elaborated by Carmel and Agarwal (2002) suggests that client firms
manage uncertainty by choosing offshoring models based on their learned
experiences. Specifically, their field work identified four IT
offshoring stages adopted by US firms: Stage 1-Offshore Bystanders are
firms that do not offshore at all, but may have a few advocates pushing
the idea, Stage 2-Offshore Experimenters are pilot testing sourcing of
non-core IT processes offshore., Stage 3--Proactive Cost Focus are
companies that take a proactive cost focus and seek broad,
corporate-wide leverage of cost efficiencies through offshore work, and
Stage 4--Proactive Strategic Focus--are companies that take a proactive
strategic focus and view offshore sourcing as a strategic imperative.
While the IT offshoring research has grown into a large body of work,
the existing literature has not sufficiently explained the relationship
between the degree and type of uncertainty and offshoring model choice.
Specifically, each of the previously mentioned theoretical approaches
tends to focus on only one kind of uncertainty and its impact on the
choice of the IT offshoring model.
The real options theory provides a framework that overcomes such
limitation. The theory can be used to explain IT offshoring choices and
help managers to account for the uncertainties that arise in such
evolving environments (Trigeorgis, 1996). The strength in the real
options theory is in recognizing the impact of uncertainties on
investment decisions and the flexibility it provides to managers in
making strategic decisions. Researchers have conceptualized real options
as a theoretical framework in various environments such as equity joint
ventures (Kogut, 1991), investments in emerging markets (Kogut &
Kulatilaka, 1994), R&D projects (Mitchell & Hamilton, 1988) and
IT infrastructure (Balasubramanian, Kulatilaka, & Storck, 2000;
Fichman, 2004). One of the primary reasons for the growing interest in
real options theory is the practical concern that strategic investment
decisions are often made under uncertainty (Dixit & Pindyck, 1994).
The primary advantage of holding a real option is that it offers
flexibility to its holders by conferring them the option to defer
(McDonald & Siegel, 1986), or an option to abandon (Myers &
Majd, 1990). In order for real options to be viable, two conditions must
be met. First, the decision must be characterized by uncertainty and
second, the investment should not be easily irreversible. That is, once
the decision is made, it cannot be reversed without incurring cost. IT
offshoring can be viewed as a real option as it meets both criteria. The
decision to offshore is surrounded by uncertainty (i.e., uncertainty
dealing with foreign vendors, uncertainties arising from local
environment) that is typically not associated with traditional domestic
IT outsourcing or internal sourcing. In addition, the decision of a
client to back-source (i.e. bring IT back in-house) or switch vendors
(Lacity & Willcocks, 2000) can have serious financial implications.
Thus, the offshoring decision is not easily reversible. Under conditions
of uncertainty and irreversibility, holding an option represents the
right to postpone the decision in order to resolve some of the
uncertainty. In our case, this can be uncertainty surrounding the
client's offshore vendors or the subsidiary's offshore host
country environment. Once the IT offshoring model decision has been made
(i.e., the option has been exercised by making an investment in a
subsidiary to be operated in another country), the resources spent to
implement the strategy cannot be easily recovered if the IT offshoring
decision is often revealed to be suboptimal.
IT offshoring usually involves higher complexity and risks when
compared to insourcing or domestic outsourcing because of the need to
control the project remotely and to interact cross-culturally (Carmel
& Agarwal, 2002). In addition, the client firm is also exposed to
additional levels of uncertainty in regards to managing security across
country and organizational boundaries. IT offshoring often entails IT
assets and information to be in possession of an offshore vendor in
another country and thus making the client's assets much more
difficult to protect. Firms engaging in offshoring may also face
uncertain political and economic instabilities of the offshore
locations. One example is India (a leading provider of IT offshoring)
and their unstable political relationship with Pakistan, where the two
have been on the brink of war on a number of occasions. Economic
uncertainties can also be substantial. An example is the
Philippines' government's pressure to eliminate the generous
tax incentives, which could eventually push up prices in the region
(Carmel & Nicholson, 2005).
We should note that uncertainty is only one of many factors that
influence a client's choice of offshoring model. Factors such as
strategic alignment, cost, technology etc. all can have an impact on the
clients' choice of offshoring model (i.e., Carmel & Agarwal,
2002; Kakabadse & Kakabadse, 2000; King & Malhotra, 2000). These
factors, however, are beyond the scope of this paper whose primary focus
is to gain a better understanding of the effects of uncertainty on IT
offshoring model choice.
IT OFFSHORING-UNCERTAINTY FRAMEWORK
The impact of uncertainty on the IT offshoring decision has been
suggested to be critical to organizational performance (Hahn et al.,
2009). Companies whose offshoring initiatives fail to meet their
expectations typically make one of the following mistakes (Aron &
Singh, 2005). First, companies do not spend enough time evaluating which
aspects (i.e., processes, application development, and customer service)
they should offshore and those that they shouldn't. Second, firms
do not take into account all of the risks that are inherent within the
offshoring context. Client firms often fail to realize that once they
transfer their processes, their vendors could gain the upper hand as the
power in the relationship shifts from the clients to the vendors. There
is no guarantee that offshored projects will be any more successful
given the time delay, cultural, financial, technical and legal issues.
The complications of IT offshoring can make it very easy for firms to
underestimate the difficulty of the offshoring engagement and eventually
terminate the offshoring relationship. Offshoring usually involves
higher complexity and risks because of the need to control the project
remotely and to interact cross-culturally (Carmel & Agarwal, 2002).
As a result, a framework is necessary to support client firms in
managing the uncertainties inherent to IT offshoring.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The suggested framework (Figure 1) considers uncertainty to consist
of two dimensions endogenous and exogenous--which are independent and
capture wholly different types of uncertainty. Although the occurrence
of uncertainty is a continuous phenomenon, we use a dichotomous
categorization for the sake of simplicity. A firm can be perceived to be
experiencing either high or low levels of endogenous uncertainty or high
or low levels of exogenous uncertainty. An illustrative exercise to
introduce the relationship between the uncertainties is to consider
moving along various paths from any given point in a hypothetical
two-dimensional space as depicted in Figure 1. Consider first moving
eastward along line A, increasing exogenous uncertainty while holding
endogenous uncertainty constant at a relatively low level. Firms
experience constant endogenous uncertainty along this path and
correspondingly increased levels of exogenous uncertainty. Likewise,
when moving northward along line B from the midpoint of the exogenous
uncertainty axis and, increasing endogenous uncertainty while holding
exogenous uncertainty constant a firm could also simultaneously
experience an increase in both endogenous and exogenous uncertainties
(i.e., moving in the northeast direction along line C). Advancing along
both the dimensions of uncertainty increases the challenges a client
faces when compared to the previous two scenarios. In the following
sections, we discuss the unique problems encountered by client firms
within each quadrant in making strategic decisions regarding IT
offshoring. We identify examples of offshoring models for each scenario
that could provide effective means to manage these uncertainties. These
examples are not a comprehensive list of possible IT offshoring models,
but to an extent represent a selection of those that are prominently
discussed in the existing literature.
QUADRANT I: LOW ENDOGENOUS UNCERTAINTY AND LOW EXOGENOUS
UNCERTAINTY
From the client firm's perspective, Quadrant I (Figure 1)
represents the most desirable uncertainty case. In this situation, the
client firm has a good understanding of the host country culture,
technology and the outsourced activity. Moreover, it also has a good
understanding of the host country macroeconomic environment (i.e.,
legal, political, etc.). An example of this scenario would be a US
located client firm offshoring its quality management task (i.e.,
application testing) to an IT firm located in Canada. In such a case,
because of relatively low levels of endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties, client firms have all the information needed to make a
decision regarding their offshoring model. To the extent that the client
firm is already familiar with the partner firm, host country culture and
institutional framework, there is no need for the client firm to delay
its decision to invest. Viewing the offshoring decision from the real
options perspective, under conditions of both low endogenous and low
exogenous uncertainty, client firms do not have to take an option to
defer the action to offshore (McDonald & Siegel, 1986). That is, the
client firms do not have to delay or postpone the offshoring decision to
another time period as both endogenous and exogenous uncertainties are
low. In addition, given the low need to proactively manage uncertainty,
they are likely to choose a "captive offshoring model" that is
an offshoring subsidiary owned and operated by the client firm that is
located in a foreign location. When both endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties are low, the client firm tends to have accurate
information about the host country's culture and institutional
framework. This enables the client firm to pursue captive offshoring
which tends to have the lowest coordination and production costs (Cha,
Pingry & Thatcher, 2008). Achieving effective collaboration is
difficult in global offshoring projects as there are often multiple
boundaries that must be bridged simultaneously (Espinosa, Cummings,
Wilson & Pearce, 2003; Hinds & Bailey, 2003).
Captive offshoring models avoid the need for a partner and costs
including search costs associated with looking for and screening of
potential local vendors and costs associated with contract monitoring
and enforcement. Offshore captive operations also tend to have low
operating costs. Rao (2004) also suggests that captive offshoring models
provide firms with the benefits of tax incentives offered by the local
offshore governments and access to skilled labor force all contribute to
the growth in the captive offshore model. Thus, when there is little
need to manage either exogenous or endogenous uncertainty, a captive
offshoring model is the most desirable option.
In sum, the scenario represented in Quadrant I represents the most
favorable situation for the client firm. Ceteris paribus, client firms
are likely to pursue captive offshoring model based in a foreign
location when endogenous and exogenous uncertainty is low. Thus we
suggest:
P1. A captive offshoring model will be favored over other
offshoring models (i.e., joint venture offshoring) by client firms when
operating in host countries with low endogenous and low exogenous
uncertainty environments.
QUADRANT II: HIGH ENDOGENOUS UNCERTAINTY AND LOW EXOGENOUS
UNCERTAINTY
Quadrant II (Figure 1) depicts a more challenging situation for
client firms than Quadrant I. In this scenario client firms face many
endogenous uncertainties that could influence their IT offshoring model
selection. Endogenous uncertainties as defined earlier include
uncertainties that the firm has the ability to take action to reduce or
dispel through their learning and development of capabilities. The
proprietary knowledge and capabilities developed as a result of coping
with endogenous uncertainties can then be used by the firm to manage the
endogenous uncertainty in other host countries (Luo, 2002).
One endogenous uncertainty faced by offshore client firms includes
the offshore location's cultural uncertainty. Cultural uncertainty
is related to the difficulty of operating in a host country due to lack
of understanding of the foreign location's values, beliefs, and
customs. Cultural incompatibility has been cited as a major stumbling
block and concern in international sourcing (Carmel & Nicholson,
2005), but the effects can be mitigated by the intercultural competence
of the client and vendor firms (Haried & Ramamurthy, 2009). Research
indicates that the lack of cultural readiness could have serious
negative effects (Barkema, Bell & Pennings, 1996; Delmonte &
McCarthy, 2003). The rate at which the client can learn about the host
country culture depends on the "distance" of this culture to
the client. The more distant the culture of host country, the harder it
is for the local firm to quickly learn that culture as it lacks the
absorptive capacity to assimilate this new knowledge (Cohen &
Levinthal, 1990). Under such conditions, it is prudent for the local
firm to undertake sequential learning so that it could develop the
requisite absorptive capacity to develop knowledge about the host
country culture (Folta, 1998). Indeed, in order to understand
"distant" cultures, firms generally form collaborative
ventures with host country partners to help navigate and understand the
ways of doing business in these countries (Kogut & Singh, 1988).
Using local partners to overcome cultural uncertainty presents a
firm with another type of endogenous uncertainty--the partner
uncertainty. This is typically because of the possibility of
opportunistic and self-seeking behavior on the part of the host country
partners (Hennart & Zeng, 2002; Williamson, 1975). The uncertainty
surrounding partner opportunism is further heightened due to information
asymmetry and difficulty in evaluating potential partners (Balakrishna
& Koza, 1993; Woodcok, Beamish & Makino, 1994). However, over
time, firms become better at assessing their local partners and as they
develop alliance management capability (Ireland, Hitt & Vaidyanath,
2002), the information asymmetry gradually decreases.
The real options literature posits that in order to resolve
endogenous uncertainty firms must undertake projects in stages so that
learning can occur incrementally (Chang 1995; Folta, 1998). Research on
real options and related work on organizational learning suggests that
joint ventures are especially suited for learning about new markets and
building capabilities (Kogut & Kulatilaka, 1994; Luo, 2002). In the
context of foreign market, joint ventures represent a real option
(Kogut, 1991). They help client firms to proactively manage
uncertainties by giving them the strategic flexibility to increase
commitment if their understanding of the host country market improves
and, correspondingly, increasing their ability to exit the market
quickly without incurring substantial loss should the host country
market situation worsen.
From the point of view of the IT offshoring literature, the client
firm's investment in a joint venture (JV) represents an important
mechanism by which a client can leverage and acquire new competencies
and learn to handle the inherent endogenous uncertainties. Thus, based
on the above discussion we argue that clients will undertake a joint
venture when utilizing host countries with high endogenous uncertainty
and low exogenous uncertainty because the initial costs (due to loss of
control) will be more than offset by the gains in learning and strategic
flexibility. By opting for equity joint venture offshoring model,
clients can manage and limit the effects of the endogenous uncertainties
by relying on the partners' resources, including their knowledge of
the host country culture, market, and suppliers (Inkpen & Beamish,
1997). Thus, ceteris paribus, we state:
P2: A joint venture offshoring model will be favored over other
offshoring models (i.e., third party offshoring model) by client firms
when operating in host countries with high endogenous and low exogenous
uncertainty environments.
QUADRANT III: LOW ENDOGENOUS UNCERTAINTY AND HIGH EXOGENOUS
UNCERTAINTY
In Quadrant III (Figure 1), the client firms experience high
exogenous uncertainty and relatively low endogenous uncertainty. This
situation is more ambiguous than the previous situation because in
contrast to endogenous uncertainty, client firms have little or no
control over the evolution of exogenous uncertainty. Client firms have
to deal with a variety of exogenous uncertainties as introduced earlier:
political, legal, regulatory, and macroeconomic uncertainty. Client
firms engaging in IT offshoring face uncertainties through the threat of
major disruptions arising from political upheaval or war in an offshore
host country. Typically, businesses prefer to operate in offshore
location countries that are politically stable. However, wage rates tend
to be lower in less stable countries, thus organizations are often
tempted to operate in relatively unstable environments (Davis et al.,
2006). Firms also face increased intellectual property issues when
offshoring sensitive software development and maintenance to unstable
offshore locations. When their resources are not well protected due to
weak intellectual property rights regime, firms are more likely to
undertake a wait-and-see approach rather than committing large equity
upfront (despite the desire to increase control over the venture).
Another important exogenous uncertainty that could impact the
client is the macroeconomic uncertainty of the host country. Miller
(1992) defines macroeconomic uncertainty as the unpredictability of
fluctuations in economic activities and prices in a host country. For
example, the global economic crisis and the 2008 terrorist attack in
Mumbai, India produced significant uncertainties for the client firms
who have offshored IT activities to India and for those considering
offshoring to India (Srivastava, Lakshman & Hamm, 2008). These
uncertainties are prompting the client firms to consider limiting or
discontinuing their offshore investments in India.
A number of studies have supported the view that firms can reduce
their exposure to exogenous uncertainties by limiting their levels of
direct ownership (Brouthers, 2002; Kobrin, 1983). In the IT outsourcing
literature, when contractual hazards are perceived to be high, meaning
that the formal contract cannot cover or address the uncertainties
involved in the relationship, client firms tend to prefer a
client-vendor relationship (Barthelemy, 2003). When the exogenous
uncertainties are high, it is prudent for firms to limit their
vulnerability by lowering their resource commitment and making sure that
they can exit the market quickly without incurring substantial loss
should the conditions worsen. Under conditions of high ownership levels,
such as in an offshore captive offshore subsidiary, the large
investments are not as desirable as they would lead to a commitment
level that is difficult to reverse. Previous research indicates firms
entering countries with high macroeconomic volatility are less likely to
undertake large commitments (Goldberg & Kolstadt, 1995) as
flexibility becomes paramount in mitigating this type of uncertainty
(Sutcliffe & Zaheer, 1998). Similarly, when political uncertainty is
high, firms tend to make lower commitments (Delios & Henisz, 2000).
Rather than be constrained by a high ownership offshoring model a firm
should engage in an IT offshoring model that allows it to respond to the
exogenous uncertainties. The more adaptive mode of entry is the third
party offshoring model when compared to other offshoring models.
Although the third party offshoring model is associated with less
control, the model offers increased flexibility to adapt to changing
environments. Furthermore, while a joint venture offshoring model is
important when learning and developing new capabilities for dispelling
endogenous uncertainty under conditions of exogenous uncertainty; firms
have minimal control over the reduction of exogenous uncertainty. In
other words, exogenous uncertainty evolves independent of the client
firm's actions. Moreover, as the endogenous uncertainty is
relatively low in this situation, firms do not have to take any actions
to reduce endogenous uncertainty. This suggests that, ceteris paribus:
P3: A third party offshoring model will be favored over other
offshoring models (i.e., captive offshoring model) by client firms when
operating in host countries with low endogenous and high exogenous
uncertainty environments.
QUADRANT IV: HIGH ENDOGENOUS UNCERTAINTY AND HIGH EXOGENOUS
UNCERTAINTY
At times client firms experience the situation depicted in Quadrant
IV (Figure 1). Here endogenous and exogenous uncertainties jointly
describe the state that offshore client firms experience during the
offshore model selection. We have already discussed that while building
capabilities that minimize endogenous uncertainties is possible, it is
extremely difficult, if not a significant challenge to accomplish the
same as in case of exogenous uncertainty. We argue that learning in
environments with high levels of exogenous uncertainty is less
manageable and transferable as the decision makers are ignorant of the
underlying causes of the uncertainty and the ex post environment is
unclear. The ability to build new capabilities is hindered when the
firms cannot predict the outcome or assign a probability to it. Indeed,
Luo (2002) observed that capability building is negatively related to
environmental complexity (which contained macroeconomic, political/legal
and socio-cultural dimensions).
Our contention is that client firms that experience high exogenous
uncertainty and high endogenous simultaneously will first choose the
onsite offshoring model. By bringing resources onsite client firms can
reduce some of endogenous uncertainty (i.e., cultural uncertainty) and
lower the level of endogenous uncertainty experienced. That is, the firm
can learn about partner, host country culture, etc., by interacting with
the third party resources onsite. This arrangement also allows the
client firms to mitigate the influence of exogenous uncertainty as the
job tasks are being performed in the client's location. In other
words, this allows the client firms to learn and resolve endogenous
uncertainty without being distracted by exogenous uncertainty. After
they have developed the necessary capabilities to lower endogenous
uncertainty (i.e., reduce the endogenous uncertainty through
experience), client firms will pursue one of three offshoring models
that we discussed earlier (i.e., captive offshoring, third party
offshoring or joint venture offshoring) depending on the exogenous
uncertainty in the host county at that time. Ceteris paribus, when
dealing with both high endogenous and exogenous uncertainties
simultaneously, offshore client firms will first choose onsite
offshoring arrangement with a third party vendor.
P4: When dealing with both high endogenous and high exogenous
uncertainty environments client firms will first prefer to enter
offshoring relationship with an onsite captive offshoring model. After
developing capabilities to deal with the endogenous uncertainty, client
firms will choose another offshoring model (i.e., captive offshoring)
depending on the exogenous uncertainty in the host country at that time.
ILLUSTRATIVE CASE EXAMPLE
To further illustrate the relationship between IT offshoring
strategy and endogenous and exogenous levels of uncertainty we present a
case that demonstrates a shift in offshoring strategy as classified in
our offshoring uncertainty framework. The case example is taken from a
series of interviews conducted during December 2006 through June 2007
with a client firm who shifted their offshore strategy from Quadrant IV
to Quadrant I due to the realization of endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties. For each case, we included interviewees from business and
technology functions along with both managerial (i.e., senior business
and technology managers) and operational (i.e., business analysts,
system engineers) level stakeholders. For the purpose of this paper, the
selected case example demonstrates an offshore model strategy shift from
Quadrant IV to Quadrant I (i.e., the most dissimilar types in terms of
their uncertainty combinations of low to high) allows us to highlight
the role of uncertainty and IT offshoring strategy. Upon the request of
the client firm involved, the client name has been changed to maintain
anonymity.
HEALTHCENTER--OFFSHORE MODEL STRATEGY SHIFT FROM QUADRANT IV TO
QUADRANT I
HealthCenter is a diversified industrial corporation, operating in
a number of segments: from infrastructure, finance, healthcare, and
industrial manufacturing. In 2004, HealthCenter started to investigate
different offshore strategies to provide technical and network support
utilizing resources in India. The offshore initiative provides initial
network and technical support, 24 hours a day, 7 days a week. Examples
of the support provided include: network security, infrastructure
issues, connectivity, database, applications and general security
issues. The goal was to offload the troubleshooting and support issues
to India and reduce the turnaround time for issue resolution. The
utilization of India resources for support would allow the US based
employees to concentrate on design and major projects originating from
the U.S.A based HealthCenter. Over the lifetime of the offshore
initiative, HealthCenter underwent a shift in their offshore strategy.
They initially selected the onsite captive offshoring strategy (Quadrant
IV) and evolved into the captive offshore strategy located offsite
(Quadrant I) to better fit the uncertainties present in their offshore
relationship. Early on in the project, the plan was to bring offshore
personnel provided by an offshore vendor firm to the US location to work
side by side with the US HealthCenter personnel. The goal was to learn
about the Indian culture, test the waters and leverage the intellectual
capital of India. However, as HealthCenter matured in their offshore
operations and learned to deal with the endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties involved, they were able to shift their offshoring
strategy to better fit the uncertainties present in the relationship.
Early on from an uncertainty perspective, HealthCenter viewed both
the exogenous and endogenous uncertainties to be extremely high. Since
this was one of the first offshore experiences of HealthCenter,
endogenous uncertainty at this point was seen as high and
uncontrollable. They had little understanding and experience in working
in the Indian cultural context. From an exogenous standpoint in Quadrant
IV, a major uncertainty from the client's perspective was the
macro-economic situation of India. Offshore workers were jumping jobs
frequently, resulting in loss of productivity and performance due to all
of the retraining that was necessary. The senior business manager
pointed out that "there was a lot of job hopping... turnover was
very high in the IT area.... what people would do is they would ramp
their skills up, boom jump a job and get another 30% increase, then
boom, go to another job, get another 30%, you can't blame them for
trying to increase their standard of living. But we would have to keep
retraining, and that became an issue for us." Overtime,
HealthCenter determined that opening and operating their own captive
offshore center (Quadrant I) would be a strategy to help minimize the
exogenous macroeconomic uncertainty.
In addition, cultural issues appeared to play a key role in the
initial concerns HealthCenter had in regards to their selected offshore
model strategy. However, as HealthCenter garnered experiences in working
with the offshore resources, alternatives were uncovered that could
limit the effects of cultural issues. The systems engineer noted
"one thing that I learned early on was that they don't like to
confront us at all. Even though they disagree with us, they nod, say
yes, so later on we found out that we basically have to tell them that
it is ok to tell us that you don't agree. in their culture you
don't go against your boss or manager, you don't argue back
with them, whatever they say is right, were not always right and we know
that, but sometimes it is good to disagree with the boss." Onsite
HealthCenter personnel indicated concerns over the passive nature of the
offshore resources. The senior business manager noted that a challenge
was "taking a passive culture and making the people a little bit
more aggressive to fit the HealthCenter style." The senior business
manager noted "people are more passive, because everything is very
polite and that is just to me the Indian culture... they need to be
aggressive, when they grab that problem, take it and solve it."
HealthCenter was able to control some of the endogenous uncertainties by
confronting the offshore personnel and explaining to the expectations of
open communication in the relationship that appeared to be drastically
different due to the offshore culture.
Communication challenges also arose due to cultural issues.
HealthCenter had to play an active role in managing and reducing this
endogenous uncertainty. The senior IT manager noted "understanding
them was a challenge.so chat was used. it was better if they were typing
rather than speaking." Non-verbal communication challenges also
emerged due to the cultural differences. During our discussions, the
client's business staff noted that "I had them saying yes to
me, but they were shaking their heads to me in the American way as no,
and then another group of them were saying no to me and shaking their
heads to me in an American way of yes." As the offshore experiences
of HealthCenter matured they were better able to address and manage
these differences by directly addressing the communication challenges
that were not understood early on during their offshore relationship.
Economics was another driving force behind the offshore model
shift. Early on, bringing Indian personnel onsite to the US location was
a cheaper economic strategy than staffing the IT troubleshooting
department with US based employees, due to the labor arbitrage that
existed among the two countries. The senior business manager pointed out
that "the deal was where we would have people come here initially,
and then as they did the knowledge transfer they would go back to India
and do the work. But what really ended up happening was because there
were different rates. If you work onshore at HealthCenter the vendor was
charging a certain rate, if the personnel were located and worked
offshore the rate went way down. It actually worked for a good couple
years, and then the contract kind of went sour, due to the fact that we
had way too many people being onshore instead of offshore." At this
point in time HealthCenter reevaluated their offshore strategy to better
fit the uncertainties that were learned over their initial offshore
experiences.
After a few years of experience and an increased understanding of
the uncertainties involved, they reevaluated their perceptions of the
endogenous and exogenous uncertainties involved to better fit their
offshoring strategy to their specific environment. They determined that
the early concerns over the cultural issues were not as extreme as
initially believed. They also determined that they could influence some
of the wage rate issues and job hopping/turnover issues that were
rampant in India. As a result, HealthCenter shifted their offshore model
into Quadrant I, thus running their own offshore captive center.
HealthCenter invested and constructed a dedicated building just for
technology and network support that employed around 300 people who were
considered full HealthCenter employees. Factors driving the shift
according to the senior business manager "we were actually able to
reduce our costs a lot. the big difference was that early on we were
spending a million dollars on contracting costs, and we were in the
80-20 model. So we would be 20% HealthCenter and 80% contracted. as we
learned more about the opportunities in India we thought we were
spending way too much on contractor costs. So what we would do is
leverage the intellectual talent on India, by opening our own location
in India and make the resources that were contractors HealthCenter
employees, which really helped lower our turnover and job hopping."
Overall, HealthCenter according to its business manager indicated that
"I just think it has proved out to be a cost effective way to lower
cost of ownership as well as running operations." As a result, it
appears that HealthCenter was able to select an offshore model that best
fit the uncertainties that were present in their offshoring
relationship.
The case of HealthCenter provides a valuable early investigation
and demonstration of the role uncertainty plays in a firm's
offshore strategy selection. The case also illustrates how a firm's
IT offshoring strategy may shift after exogenous and endogenous
uncertainties are learned. Further case investigations and empirical
work are highly recommended to illustrate the use of our framework to
guide firms in matching their selected offshoring model to the
endogenous and exogenous uncertainties faced by a client firm.
DISCUSSION
In this paper, we sought to develop a theoretical framework that
would help explain IT offshoring model choices. In doing so, we sought
to contribute to the literature on international IT sourcing, commonly
referred to as IT offshoring, by highlighting how uncertainty affects a
client's IT offshoring decision. In addition, in our theoretical
approach (drawing on the real options theory) we overcame some of the
limitations with current theoretical approaches that relied on a
one-dimensional view of uncertainty. We suggest that the nature of
uncertainty is a combination of two different dimensions: endogenous and
exogenous. Using the two-dimensional framework to describe the client
host country environments allows us to meaningfully and parsimoniously
understand the challenges faced by clients while operating in uncertain
host country environments. Our illustrative example demonstrates the
importance of incorporating uncertainty into the offshore strategy
decision and the importance of fit in regards to offshore strategy and
the uncertainties present in offshoring. This framework allows for a
more precise, theoretically grounded description of uncertainties facing
IT offshoring clients in their IT offshoring strategy selections. In
particular we suggest that endogenous uncertainty can be influenced by
the actions of clients (i.e., by forming joint venture offshoring
relationship a client can develop capabilities to mitigate the effects
of endogenous uncertainty on the firms operations and performance). In
addition, we argue that client actions have little influence on
exogenous uncertainty as the environments are too ambiguous for
capability development to take place.
Prior research findings on uncertainty and offshoring client firm
behavior support our theory. Client firms desiring greater control
(i.e., decreasing uncertainty) prefer a subsidiary IT offshore entry
mode (Jagersma & van Gorp, 2007). Fitzgerald and Willcocks (1994)
suggest that more strategic partnerships are ideal when business and
technical uncertainty are high and loose contracts are written. Lee,
Miranda, and Kim (2004) observed that firms desiring cost efficiency in
their outsourcing relationships would be best served by arm's
length relationships whereas those wishing to derive strategic
competence or technology catalysis needed to develop network type
relationships with their providers. In practice all contracts contain
both complete and incomplete sections wherein the governance mechanisms
can be viewed as a range of alternatives from a very tight and lengthy
contract to no contract with a true partnership relationship. The
limitations of contract can be avoided with the use of the subsidiary
offshoring model since the client firm is operating the offshore
venture. In other offshoring models, a complete contract specifies all
of the actions that each party is responsible for in the relationship.
Such a contract might reduce the uncertainty faced by organizational
decision makers and the risk of opportunism created in the offshoring
agreement. However, situations will develop during the course of a
multi-year outsourcing contract (i.e., technological obsolescence,
political turbulence) that the contract might not cover. . Thus, it is
important to incorporate flexibility into an outsourcing contract
(Fitzgerald & Willcocks, 1994; Willcocks and Kern, 1998).
Flexibility includes the option for the client to change service
requirements and for the vendor to change the means by which service
requirements are met (Clark, Zmud & McCray, 1995). Often it is the
"unwritten contract" between the vendor and client that
strengthens the relationship to the point that it becomes an invaluable
partnership and relationship (Webb & Laborde, 2005).
Previous outsourcing research has also explored the relationship
between success and uncertainty. Research has hypothesized a negative
relationship between the level of environmental uncertainty and the
outcome of outsourcing (i.e., less successful outsourcing in volatile
environments). However, the findings are inconclusive (Dibbern, Goles,
Hirschheim & Jayatilaka, 2004). Wang (2002), following transaction
cost theory, finds a negative relationship between uncertainty and
outsourcing success, whereas Poppo and Zenger (1998) contradict this.
One reason for this could be the erroneous assumption in much of the
existing offshoring literature that different types of uncertainties
(i.e., political, cultural etc.) have similar effect on offshoring
decision. Thus, our framework provides valuable insight and extensions
to the offshoring literature examining the role of uncertainty and IT
offshoring success.
Additionally, the management literature also supports our
framework. Earlier studies have found that the greater the host country
uncertainty the greater the likelihood that firms will opt for licensing
rather than wholly-owned subsidiaries (Kim & Hwang, 1992), and joint
ventures rather than wholly-owned subsidiaries (Bell, 1996). This
suggests that clients are reluctant to commit resources and prefer to
maintain some degree of strategic flexibility when uncertainty is high.
Thus, as we posit throughout this study, uncertainty (both endogenous
and exogenous) plays a critical role in the IT offshoring decision and
should not be ignored.
RESEARCH IMPLICATIONS
We anticipate that the insights offered by this study will prove
useful to scholars interested in studying success and international IT
sourcing strategies. On a practical front, this study shows that
attention needs to be given to the role and types of uncertainty
inherent to the IT offshoring decision. Often the level and type of
uncertainty appears to have been ignored or, alternatively, studies
focused on only one of many types of uncertainties. Scholars need to
recognize that uncertainty needs to be accounted for and action may need
to be taken to support a successful offshoring initiative.
By integrating the organizational learning and real options theory,
our paper provides a significant contribution to the IT offshoring
arena. The extant management literature suggests that under uncertainty
firms must take collaborative ventures rather than investing in a wholly
owned subsidiary. The literature also stresses the importance of
developing "complete" contracts, which is unrealistic in most
offshoring circumstances. However, the same literature is less clear
regarding the "type" of offshoring model a firm must undertake
in a particular type of uncertainty (endogenous vs. exogenous).
Moreover, it understates the relationship between learning and
uncertainty. Our paper highlights the notion that firms can dispel
endogenous uncertainty through learning whereas they have no control
over exogenous uncertainty. It also provides not only a fuller, more
holistic explanation of the offshoring model choice but offers normative
recommendations to IT offshoring client managers.
PRACTICE IMPLICATIONS
Our theory is particularly relevant to practitioners given the
exponential growth of IT offshoring investments made by client firms in
emerging global markets. As Luo (2001) observed, while uncertainty is
present in most markets, it is typically widespread in emerging and
under developed economies. Thus, our two-dimensional framework of
uncertainty has several implications for client managers making
strategic IT offshoring decisions. First, the framework highlights the
importance of distinguishing the uncertainty in a particular country
from those that are present in other countries. Second, it emphasizes
learning as a way of reducing or dispelling endogenous uncertainty and
underscores the difficulty that client firms face in developing
capabilities to counter exogenous uncertainty.
Clarifying the role and type of uncertainty inherent to the IT
offshoring decision should help client firms determine a fit between
their IT offshoring strategy and the associated uncertainties to help
ensure success. Client firms may start by clarifying the type of
uncertainty that they are experiencing or may experience due to context
of the offshoring relationship. Client firms who are able to predict and
address any uncertainties and fit their IT offshoring strategy to the
uncertainties that may be encountered will be in an improved position of
success probability when compared to firms who lack a preparation and
understanding of the uncertainties inherent to IT offshoring.
FUTURE RESEARCH
Several additional directions for future research present
themselves as a result of this analysis. Future research can empirically
examine the impact of different uncertainties on the IT offshoring model
decision in various regions. IT offshoring practices tend to be more
mature in the USA when compared to other locations and could lead to
potential differences in the desired client outcomes (Koh, Ang &
Straub, 2004). Future research may want to focus on the various offshore
vendor locations (i.e., India, China, and Brazil). In addition, research
may want to include various client locations that are purchasing the IT
offshoring (i.e., USA, Canada, and UK). By incorporating diverse client
and vendor locations, we may gain unique insight in regard to how
uncertainty is managed.
Our illustrative case example provides some indication that client
firms perceptions of endogenous uncertainty are resolved through
learning. An interesting venue for future research is the issue of
client's evaluation of uncertainty (endogenous and exogenous) and
how it manages the uncertainty. Such research might explicitly examine
the differences across various client stakeholder groups and trace their
evolution. As the relationship and experiences mature, client
firms/stakeholders may refine/redefine their assessment of uncertainty.
This suggests that longitudinal studies may be needed to consider the
uncertainty dimensions at different stages of the relationship. Future
research may also seek to explain why these evaluations change. For
example, is the change due to learning or is it due to institutional
effects (i.e., imitative behavior). In sum, our framework provides rich
avenues for future researchers to pursue.
CONCLUSION
The international sourcing of IT products/services is clearly a
phenomenon that will not disappear in the foreseeable future having
evolved from being a cost saving initiative to more of a survival
strategy for an increasing number of organizations in today's
economic climate. The study's expanded view of the uncertainties
involved in the IT offshoring decision offers some unique insights into
how client firms need to evaluate the various levels of uncertainty and
fit their IT offshoring strategy to both endogenous and exogenous
uncertainties. Our illustrative case study lends some support to our
conceptual uncertainty framework. We hope our this work will fuel
further research on the influence of uncertainty in international
sourcing decisions to help ensure organizations realize the most
effective fit for their IT sourcing needs.
REFERENCES
Aron, R. & Singh, J., V. (2005). Offshoring right, Harvard
Business Review, December, 135-143.
Aspray, W., Mayadas, F., & Vardi, M. Y. (2006). Globalization
and offshoring of software: A report of the ACM job migration task
force, New York: Association for Computing Machinery.
Balakhrishna, S. & Koza, M. P. (1993). Information asymmetry,
adverse selection, and joint ventures, Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 20, 99-117.
Balasubramanian, P., Kulatilaka, N. & Storck, J. (2000).
Managing information technology investments using a realoptions
approach, Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 9, 39-62.
Barkema, H. G., Bell, J. H. J. & Pennings, J.M. (1996). Foreign
entry, cultural barriers and learning, Strategic Management Journal, 17,
151-166.
Barthelemy, J. (2003). The seven deadly sins of outsourcing,
Academy of Management Executive, 17, 87-100.
Barthelemy, J. & Geyer, D. (2005). An empirical investigation
of IT outsourcing versus quasi-outsourcing in France and Germany,
Information & Management, 42, 533-542.
Bell, J. (1996). Single or joint venturing, Brookfield, VT: Ashgate
Publishing Limited.
Brouthers, K. D. (2002). Institutional, cultural and transaction
cost influences on entry mode choice and performance, Journal of
International Business Studies, 33, 203-222.
Buckley, P. & Casson, M. (1976). The future of multinational
enterprise, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Carmel, E. & Agarwal, R. (2002). The maturation of offshore
sourcing of information technology work, MIS Quarterly Executive, 1,
65-78.
Carmel, E. & Nicholson, B. (2005) Small firms and offshore
software outsourcing: High transaction costs and their mitigation,
Journal of Global Information Management, 13, 33-54.
Cha, H., Pingry, D. & Thatcher, M. (2008). Managing the
knowledge supply chain: An organizational learning model of information
technology offshore outsourcing, MIS Quarterly, 32(2), 281-306.
Chang, S. J. (1995). International expansion strategy of Japanese
firms: Capability building through sequential entry, Academy of
Management Journal, 38, 383-407.
Clark, T. D. Jr., Zmud, R. W. & McCray, G. E. (1995). The
outsourcing of information services: Transforming the nature of business
in the information industry, Journal of Information Technology, 10,
221-237.
Cohen, W. M. & Levinthal, D.A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A
new perspective on learning and innovation, Administration Science
Quarterly, 35, 128-152.
Davis, G. B., Ein-Dor, P., King, W. R. & Torkzadeh, R. (2006).
IT offshoring: History, prospects and challenges, Journal of the
Association for Information Systems, 7(11), 770-796.
Delios, A. & Henisz, W.J., (2000). Japanese firms'
investment strategies in emerging economies, Academy of Management
Journal, 43, 305-323.
Dibbern, J., Goles, T., Hirschheim, R. & Jayatilaka, B. (2004).
Information systems outsourcing: A survey and analysis of the
literature, ACM Data Base, 35(4), 6-102.
Dixit, A. K. & Pindyck, R. S. (1994). Investment under
uncertainty, Princeton, NJ Princeton University Press.
Ernst, D. (2006). Innovation offshoring: Asia's emerging role
in global innovation networks, East-West Center Special Reports, 10,
1-48.
Espinosa, J. A., Cummings, J. N., Wilson, J. M. & Pearce, B. M.
(2003). Team boundary issues across multiple global firms, Journal of
Management Information Systems, 19(4), 157-190.
Fichman, R. G. (2004). Real options and it platform adoption:
Implications for theory and practice, Information Systems Research,
15(2), 132-154.
Fitzgerald, G. & Willcocks, L. (1994). Contract and
partnerships in the outsourcing of IT, Proceedings of the 15th
International Conference on Information Systems, 91-98.
Folta, T. B. (1998). Governance and uncertainty: The tradeoff
between administrative control and commitment, Strategic Management
Journal, 19, 1007-1028.
Goldberg, L. & Kolstadt, C. (1995). Foreign direct investment,
exchange rate and demand uncertainty, International Economic Review, 36,
855-873.
Hahn, E. D., Doh, J. P., & Bunyaratevej, K. (2009). The
evolution of risk in information systems offshoring: The impact of home
country risk, firm learning, and competitive dynamics, MIS Quarterly,
33(3), 597-616.
Haried, P., & Ramamurthy, K. (2009). Evaluating the success in
international sourcing of information technology projects: The need for
a relational client-vendor approach, Project Management Journal, 40(3),
56-71.
Hassett, K. A. & Metcalf, G. E. (1999). Investment with
uncertain tax policy: Does random tax policy discourage investment? The
Economic Journal, 109, 372-393.
Hennart, J. & Zeng, M. (2002). Cross-cultural differences and
joint venture longevity, Journal of International Business Studies, 33,
699-716.
Hill, C., Hwang, P. & Kim, W.C. (1990). An eclectic theory of
the choice of international entry mode, Strategic Management Journal,
11, 117-128.
Hinds, P. J. & Bailey, D. E. (2003). Out of sight, out of sync:
Understanding conflict in distributed teams, Organization Science,
14(6), 615-632.
Inkpen, A. C. & Beamish P.W. (1997). Knowledge, bargaining
power and the instability of international joint ventures, Academy of
Management Review, 22, 177-202.
Ireland, R. D., Hitt, M. A. & Vaidyanath, D. (2002). Alliance
management as a source of competitive advantage, Journal of Management,
28, 413-446.
Jagersma, P. K. & van Gorp, D. M. (2007). Redefining the
paradigm of global competition offshoring of service firms, Business
Strategy Series, 8(1), 35-42.
Kakabadse, N. & Kakabadse, A. (2000). Critical
review-outsourcing: A paradigm shift, The Journal of Management
Development, 19(8), 670-728.
Kern, T. & Willcocks, L. (2000). Exploring information
technology outsourcing relationships: Theory and practice, Journal of
Strategic Information Systems, 9, 321-350.
Kim, W.C. & Hwang, P. (1992). Global strategy and
multinationals entry mode choice, Journal of International Business
Studies, 23(1), 29-53.
Kim, G. & Kim, S. (2008). Exploratory study on effective
control structure in global business process sourcing, Information
Resources Management Journal, 21(3), 101-118.
King, W. R. & Malhotra, Y. (2000). Developing a framework for
analyzing IS sourcing, Information and Management, 37(6), 323-334.
Kliem, R. (2004). Managing the risks of offshore IT development
projects, Information Systems Management, 21(3), 22-27.
Kobrin, S. J. (1982). Managing political risk assessment: Strategic
response to environmental change, Berkeley, CA: University of California
Press.
Kobrin, S. J. (1983). Selective vulnerability and corporate
management, In Moran T.H. (Ed), International Political Risk Assessment:
The state of the art. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.
Kogut, B. & Singh, H. (1988). The effect of national culture on
the choice of entry mode, Journal of International Business Studies, 19,
411-32.
Kogut, B. (1991). Joint ventures and the option to expand and
acquire, Management Science, 37, 19-33.
Kogut, B. & Kulatilaka, N. (1994). Operational flexibility,
global manufacturing, and the option value of a multinational network,
Management Science, 40, 123-139.
Koh, C., Ang, S. & Straub, D. W. (2004). IT outsourcing
success: A psychological contract perspective, Information Systems
Research, 15(4), 356-373.
Lacity, M.C. & Willcocks, L. P. (1996). Interpreting
information technology sourcing decisions from a transaction cost
perspective: Findings and critique, Accounting, Management and
Information Technology, 5(3/4), 203244.
Lacity, M.C. & Willcocks, L. P. (2000). Relationships in it
outsourcing: A stakeholder perspective. In R. Zmud (Ed.), in Framing the
Domains of IT Management: Projecting the Future through the Past (pp.
355-384), Cincinnati, OH: Pinnaflex.
Lee, J., Miranda, S. M. & Kim, Y. (2004). IT outsourcing
strategies: Universalistic, contingency, and configurational
explanations of success, Information Systems Research, 15, 110-131.
Luo, Y. (2001). Determinants of entry in an emerging economy: A
multilevel approach, Journal of Management Studies, 38, 443-72.
Luo, Y. (2002). Capability exploitation and building in a foreign
market: Implications for multinational enterprises, Organization
Science, 13, 48-63.
McDonald, R. & Siegel, D. (1986). The value of waiting to
invest, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 707-728.
Miller, K. D. (1992). A framework for integrated risk management in
international business, Journal of International Business Studies, 23,
311-331.
Miller, D. & Shamsie, J. (1999). Strategic responses to three
kinds of uncertainty: Product line simplicity at the hollywood film
studios, Journal of Management, 25, 97-116.
Mirani, R. (2006). Client vendor relationships in offshore
applications development: An evolutionary framework, Information
Resources Management Journal, 19(4), 72-86.
Mitchell, G. & Hamilton, W. (1988). Managing R&D as a
strategic option, Research Technology Management, 31, 15-22.
Myers, S. C. & Majd, S. (1990). Abandonment value and project
life, Advances in Futures and Options Research, 4, 1-21.
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and
economic performance, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Poppo, L. & Zenger, T. (1998). Testing alternative theories of
the firm: transaction cost, knowledge-based and measurement explanations
for make-or-buy decisions in information systems, Strategic Management
Journal, 19, 853-877.
Rao, M. T. (2004). Key issues for global IT sourcing: Country and
individual factors, Information Systems Management, 21(3), 16-21.
Roberts, K. & Weitzman, M. L. (1981). Funding criteria for
research, development and exploration project, Econometrica, 49,
1261-1288.
Saunders, C., Gebelt, M. & Hu, Q. (1997). Achieving success in
information systems outsourcing, California Management Review, 39,
63-79.
Srivastava, M., Lakshman, N., & Hamm, S. (2008). How risky is
India?' Business Week, 4112, 24-26.
Sutcliffe, K. M. & Zaheer, A. (1998). Uncertainty in the
transaction environment an empirical test, Strategic Management Journal,
19, 1-23.
Teece, D. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation:
Implication for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy,
Research Policy, 15, 285-305.
Teisberg, E. O. (1993). Capital investment strategies under
uncertain regulation, The Rand Journal of Economics, 24, 591-604.
Trigeorgis, L. (1996). Real options: Managerial flexibility and
strategy in resource allocation, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Wang, E. T. G. (2002). Transaction attributes and software
outsourcing success: An empirical investigation of transaction costs
theory, Information Systems Journal, 12, 121-152.
Webb, L. & Laborde, J. (2005). Crafting a successful
outsourcing vendor/client relationship, Business Process Management
Journal, 11, 437-443.
Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and
antitrust implications, New York: The Free Press.
Willcocks, L. P. & Kern, T. (1998). IT outsourcing as strategic
partnering: The case of the uk inland revenue, European Journal of
Information Systems, 7, 29-45.
Woodcok, C. P., Beamish, P. & Makino, S. (1994).
Ownership-based entry mode strategies and international performance,
Journal of International Business Studies, 25, 253-73.
Mujtaba Ahsan, Pittsburg State University
Peter Haried, University of Wisconsin--La Crosse
Martina Musteen, San Diego State University