Internet pricing: best effort versus quality of service.
Shin, Seungjae ; Cope, Robert F., III ; Cope, Rachelle F. 等
ABSTRACT
This research uses Bertrand methodology to examine the influence of
competition between companies that utilize Quality of Service (QoS)
pricing strategy versus Best Effort (BE) pricing strategy for Internet
Service Providers (ISPs). The Bertrand duopoly price competition model
is effective at determining customer's willingness-to-pay and level
of internet usage patterns in relation to price paid for service. The
model also makes use of a two-part tariff consisting of a fixed rate for
Best Effort (BE) service, and a usage-sensitive rate structure for
premium QoS. Initial results indicate that an equilibrium market
position for each ISP depends on a customer's preference for QoS
and the price of BE service. Implementation of this research using a
game simulation revealed an analytical framework for iterative,
short-term, future QoS Internet pricing strategies.
INTRODUCTION
Since the commercialization of the World Wide Web (WWW), Internet
Service Providers (ISPs) have expanded their service simply by
increasing their number of subscribers. Traditionally, ISPs offered only
one class of service for all types of traffic. They treated traffic
indifferently with no discrimination among the types of traffic, no
guarantee for timely delivery, and a realistic possibility of traffic
loss. This type of Internet service has generally been known as
"Best Effort" (BE).
With the rapid growth of e-commerce, demand for various classes of
Internet services is expected to grow and diversify. Customers with real
time and business-critical data applications are searching for improved
levels of service, or Quality of Service (QoS) connections to the WWW.
Compared to BE, ISPs are now looking to premium QoS class connections
for customers. These new classes could include, but are not limited to,
a class to guarantee timely delivery, a class to ensure no traffic loss,
a class for delivery confirmation, or any combination of all classes.
These developments are harbingers for the future. First, there will
be at least two classes of service in the Internet market: BE and QoS.
Since QoS includes BE service as its lowest class of service, the
superiority of QoS to BE results in vertical product differentiation.
Second, it is reasonable to expect a change in the pricing paradigm from
non-metered, flat rate, unlimited access user pricing to usage-sensitive
metered pricing for higher valued QoS.
ISPs are simultaneously competitors and cooperators. On one hand,
they are competitors for market share. On the other hand, they are
cooperators that provide universal, global connectivity. Thus, one
ISP's actions influence another's actions. Furthermore,
end-to-end QoS could not be established without strong cooperation among
ISPs. To behave accordingly suggests game theoretic modeling, i.e., each
player in the game is a competitor, and their interactions provide
motivation for strategic decisions. Under traditional Internet pricing
with unlimited access and flat rate monthly payments, users want to take
as much bandwidth as they can within their access capacity. This leads
to a "tragedy of the commons" phenomenon which can be overcome
through usage-sensitive pricing. Therefore, we propose a simulation
methodology to explain an ISPs' equilibrium behavior in a
futuristic QoS market. To implement our approach, we employ a Bertrand
price competition model to determine a customer's
willingness-to-pay and Internet usage patterns. The Bertrand model also
includes two different pricing schemes: one for an ISP with traditional
unlimited access, flat rate pricing for BE, and another for an ISP with
a two-part tariff consisting of a fixed rate for BE, plus a
usage-sensitive pricing strategy for QoS.
The research is structured as follows. First, we present the
differentiated service initiative of AT&T and WorldCom. Then, we
provide a literature review forming a foundation for the research
extension, followed by economic assumptions for pricing, consumer demand
and usage for the industry. Next, cost, revenue and profit functions for
the methodology are discussed. Finally, the proposed simulation and
optimization approach, as well as the behaviors of ISPs at an
equilibrium point are presented. To conclude, preliminary results and
issues for future research are offered.
SUPPORTING INDUSTRY ACTION
Recently, large service providers like AT&T and WorldCom
announced in the summer of 2001 that they would start providing Internet
customers with "Class of Service" (CoS) connections using
Multi-Protocol Label Switching (MPLS) and Differentiated Services. These
CoS-based services consisted of four priority level classes: Platinum,
Gold, Silver, and Bronze. Customers requiring applications for voice and
video would probably choose the Platinum, or highest priority level of
service, while other customers requiring only applications for HTTP and
e-mail traffic might choose the Bronze, or lowest priority level of
service (i.e. BE). Customers with business critical data applications
might choose an intermediate priority level, namely Gold or Silver.
However, these announced service levels were limited to connections
completely contained in the carriers' own networks.
Also in 2001, the Florida Multimedia Internet Exchange (FMIX),
managed by Bell South, announced a plan to be the first Network Access
Point to use an MPLS interconnection among different providers. To do
this, FMIX faced many new challenges with QoS interconnections, such as
pricing, class matching between providers, as well as managing the
disclosure of network information for end-to-end quality guarantees.
SUPPORTING LITERATURE
Our work builds upon recent research by Stahl, Whinston and Zhang
as well as Gupta, Linden, Stahl and Whinston, where a simulation-based
approach to a duopoly ISP environment was studied. Both studied the
affects of BE, flat rate versus usage-based pricing. Stahl et. al (1998)
found that when a company like AOL imposes a fee to maximize profits,
dynamic usage pricing increased profits five times, while network-wide
social benefits increased seven times. Gupta et. at. (2001) also showed
that usage-based pricing enhanced system-wide benefits overall. We
extend these research efforts to incorporate pricing guidelines for
premium QoS choices for ISPs which could easily become a de-facto
environment for the Internet in the near future.
In addition, we utilize Bertrand's competitive model to
analyze what is considered to be an industry of narrow competition
(Bertrand, 1883). Other researchers make use of a Cournot model to
analyze the Internet industry, which is a reasonable assumption if a
homogeneous service with limited capacity exists (Baake and Wichmann,
1988; Shin et. al., 2002a; Shin et. at., 2002b). Like Stahl et. al. and
Gupta et. al., our model also assumes a duopoly in the Internet Access market. However, in our analyses, the service is not homogeneous and
capacity is only briefly limited by its chosen queuing medium. We
therefore believe that a Bertrand model better suits our approach.
Finally, it is generally known that when one firm's market
penetration reaches approximately 60%, the market usually experiences
price competition. This has been shown to exist in the radio, television
and video cassette recorder markets. With this in mind, recent research
indicates that U.S. online households were expected to surpass the 60%
mark by the end of 2002 (Vanston, 2002). Hence, there is a strong
probability that ISPs will wage a price war in the near future.
ECONOMIC CONDITIONS
In the following three subsections, information pertaining to the
development of price, demand and usage functions is presented for model
formulation. All are considered parameter inputs for simulation.
Pricing Functions
One important characteristic of the industry is that ISPs are
competing with each other for market share. Thus, they are trying to
maximize their own profits based on the belief that the other ISP's
price is fixed. To model this behavior, we assume that there are only
two service classes, a BE class and a premium QoS class. In addition,
there is no quality difference among each ISP's QoS class, thus
customers are indifferent as to whether they will consume QoS from ISP1
or ISP2. It is also assumed that there are two prices to enter the
Internet access market:
(1) Access Price (F) for a right to connect to an ISP's
network (a fixed price), and
(2) Usage Price (r) for the volume of Internet usage per hour (a
variable price).
The price structure for each ISP can be expressed as:
(1) P1(F1, r1) for ISP1, and
(2) P2(F2, r2) for ISP2.
We further assume that ISP1 uses a flat rate pricing scheme, which
can be reduced to P1(F1, 0), where the customers of ISP1 pay only
$F1/month regardless of traffic type and volume of their connection
hours, while the premium QoS of ISP2 incurs both access and usage price
components.
Some have called this type of pricing inefficient because the added
fixed charges may deter some users who, at marginal cost prices, would
be willing to join the network and consume (Cawley, 1997). Cable
television pricing refutes this charge. In that industry there is a
fixed price to watch "basic" programming and an additional
usage charge for high-valued programs that are handled on a
"pay-per-view" basis.
The two-part tariff in our methodology has a similar form to the
pricing scheme used by the Cable Television industry. The fixed part
lump-sum fee is the right to use the lowest class of service, and the
variable part is for the consumption of the premium class of service.
Someone who only wants to use the "basic" service pays only
the fixed part lump-sum fee. To obtain high-valued programming, the user
must first purchase "basic" (BE) service to incur the premium
"pay-per-view" (QoS) service.
Demand as a Function of a Customer's Willingness-to-Pay
To capture consumer demand, a recent United States General
Accounting Office report was used. Its purpose was to study Internet
usage. One of the questions asked was: "About how much do you pay
per month to access the Internet from your home?" Although this
question does not provide a customer's willingness-to-pay for
Internet access, we can use the data as a proxy for consumer demand.
Table 1 presents the distribution of respondents.
In addition, demand must be differentiated between BE service and
premium QoS class. According to Gal-Or (1983; 1985), when a product is
differentiated on the basis of quality, and each consumer is assumed to
purchase only one unit of the product, the consumers'
willingness-to-pay (W) is assumed to be dependent upon their taste
factor (X) and a quality level (M) for the product. As a function, a
consumer's willingness-to-pay takes the form:
W(X,M) = f(X)*M, where
[W.sub.X] > 0, [W.sub.M] > 0, [W.sub.MX] > 0, [W.sub.MM]
[less than or equal to] 0, and [W.sub.XX] [less than or equal to] 0.
We further assume that the bandwidth needed for a specific class
determines the quality level of that service, and we assume the
bandwidth of the high quality class is at least twice as much as that of
low class service, i.e, [M.sub.QoS]/[M.sub.BE] = 2. Therefore, in our
model the willingness-to-pay for QoS ([W.sub.QoS]) is twice as much as
that of BE service ([W.sub.BE]).
Customer Usage
The methodology proposed by this research also heavily depends on
Internet usage patterns. To capture consumer usage, the same United
States General Accounting Office report was consulted. One of the other
survey questions asked: "On average, how many hours per week do you
and all your members of your household spend on the Internet from your
home?" Table 2 presents the distribution of respondents, which
directly reflects usage data.
COST, REVENUE AND PROFIT FUNCTIONS
First, we know that cost is highly dependent upon the number of
usage hours in each of the two classes. Previous research suggests that
in the absence of price-based differentiation, users will choose the
highest quality level regardless of traffic type (MacKie-Mason and
Varian, 1995). Under this scenario all of the customers of ISP1 should
choose the premium QoS class. However, according to parameter r2 of our
model, customers of ISP2 choose a% for premium QoS class service and
(1-a)% for BE class service.
Also, the cost structure of the Internet industry is characterized
by a large, up-front sunk cost and near zero short run marginal cost. It
is well known that, with a congestion-free network, the cost to carry or
process an additional minute of Internet traffic approaches zero,
because the incremental cost is near zero (Frieden, 1998). When an ISP
provides for QoS traffic, he needs additional equipment, higher skilled
labor, and must plan for a significant increase in operating cost
(mainly for monitoring, billing and collection). Hence, we assume that
each ISP incurs the same amount of equipment and human cost, so we do
not include these two cost factors in our model. However, we have
already assumed that the bandwidth requirement of QoS is twice that of
BE service, but the cost difference between the two is far more than
double. Considering a scaling effect, we propose $0.01 per hour as the
cost of BE service, and $0.10 per hour as the cost for premium QoS.
Formulations for the two ISP cost functions, ISP1 Cost and ISP2 Cost,
are developed below.
(1) ISP1 Cost=$0.1/hr*4.3 wks/mon*S(ISP1's hrs/wk usage)
(2) ISP2 Cost=[($0.01/hr*(1-a)%)+($0.1/hr*a%)]*(4.3wks/mon*S(ISP2's hrs/wk usage)
Next, revenue functions for the two ISPs are developed. Each
revenue function simply price multiplied by quantity.
(1) ISP1 Revenue = F1 * q1, where F1 is the unlimited QoS
connection flat rate, and q1 is the number of ISP1's subscribers.
(2) ISP2 Revenue = (F2 * q2) + S([h.sub.QoS] * r2), where F2 is the
fixed rate for the unlimited BE connection, q2 is the number of
ISP2's subscribers, [h.sub.QoS] is the S(total connection hours of
ISP2's subscribers)* a%, and r2 is the QoS connection rate per
hour.
Finally, profit functions are easily developed as revenue minus
cost. In our price model, we assume F1 to be higher than F2 since F1
covers both the fixed and variable pricing components. Each ISP's
profit function is shown below.
(1) ISP1 Profit = ISP1 Revenue--ISP1 Cost, and
(2) ISP2 Profit = ISP2 Revenue--ISP2 Cost.
PROPOSED SIMULATION AND OPTIMIZATION
Simulation of the methodology begins by determining consumer
demand. To do this, we employ a Random Number Generator (RNG) with the
empirical distribution of Table 1 to obtain specific willingness-to-pay
values. To determine consumer usage, we employ a two-stage RNG method
based on the empirical distribution from Table 1 and the piecewise
uniform distribution from Table 2.
Table 3 below summarizes the parameters and suggested ranges for
the proposed simulation model.
Next, customers are assigned willingness-to-pay values ([W.sub.BE]
and [W.sub.QoS]) along with a value for their Internet usage hours (h),
which are generated by the RNGs described above. We assume that
customers are aware of each ISP's pricing strategy, and that they
choose their premium QoS provider to optimize their benefit. At the same
time, each ISP also knows its competitor's pricing strategy and can
construct the best choice among all known combinations of pricing
strategies of ISP1 and ISP2.
With assigned values for [W.sub.BE], [W.sub.QoS] and h, each
consumer is able to calculate his net benefits from the consumption of
premium QoS, i.e., the difference between the willingness-to-pay for QoS
and price of each ISP. For example:
(1) Net1 = [W.sub.QoS]--F1 by consuming QoS from ISP1, and
(2) Net2 = [W.sub.QoS]--(F2 + ([h.sub.QoS] * r2)) by consuming QoS
from ISP2.
If both Net1 and Net2 are below zero, a customer will not buy from
either QoS provider. If Net1 or Net2 is greater than zero, the customer
will choose the ISP that will give him a higher net benefit value. Thus,
if Net1 > Net2, the customer will choose ISP1, otherwise he will
choose ISP2.
According to Bertrand's model, ISP1 will choose a price, F1,
for its optimal profit assuming ISP2's price is fixed. ISP2 will
also choose a price, F2 and r2, for its optimal profit under the
assumption that ISP1's price is fixed. Output from the simulation
calculates all possible profits of ISP1 and ISP2. The best response
profit for each ISP is then chosen (a Nash equilibrium by definition).
In our methodology, we strive to find an optimal pricing strategy
for total profit through access price competition (F1 and F2) holding r2
constant. We then iterate the process, each time using an increasing
value for r2 until equilibrium occurs. Lastly, the final equilibrium
point occurs at the intersection point of each ISP's best response
function. Thus, by comparing ISP1 Profit [F1*, (F2, r2)] and ISP2 Profit
[F1, (F2*, r2)], we find the simulation methodology's equilibrium
at (F1*, F2*).
Trials of the simulation methodology have been easily conducted
using the CSIM Simulation Package on the platform of Visual C++ 6.0.
CONCLUSIONS
Our proposed methodology indicates that an ISP's optimal QoS
pricing strategy can be determined by the price of BE service along with
a customer's preference toward the premium QoS option. Initial data
indicates F1 = $30, and F2 = $10 with r2 = $1.10. Generally speaking,
customers with small amounts of premium QoS usage prefer the two-part
tariff. Conversely, customers with larger amounts of QoS usage prefer a
flat rate pricing scheme. At what point and how we separate the two is
what matters.
Many scholars and industry experts indicate that over-provisioning
and traffic engineering cannot successfully provide premium QoS without
an appropriate pricing scheme. Therefore, the introduction of
usage-sensitive pricing into the Internet industry is probably
inevitable. Unfortunately, our simulation methodology cannot predict,
unconditionally, which pricing strategy would provide the best market
position for an ISP in the future. The problem is too dynamic. As prices
change and new competitors enter or leave the market, our methodology
can be implemented to determine an optimal, short-term pricing strategy.
As conditions continue to change, the process can be iterated with newer
data to provide a more current strategy.
To conclude, this research provides a foundation for simulating
pricing strategies in the ISP market. In future empirical research, we
plan to incorporate more in-depth factors such as time-sensitive data,
more choices for usage prices, and consumer taste and quality for ISP
choice. Consumer taste and quality variables would provide us with other
elastic willingness-to-pay factors. We realize that our current
assumption of "2" for the willingness-to-pay factor is
somewhat rigid. This, along with several of the factors listed above
will certainly provide greater sensitivity analyses, and possibly lead
to an improved methodology.
REFERENCES
Baake, P. & T. Wichmann (1999). On the economics of Internet
peering. Netnomics, 1 (1), 89-105.
Bertrand, J.L.F. (1883). Theorie Mathematique de la Richesse
Sociale. Journal des Savants, 67, 499-508.
Cawley, R.A. (1997). Interconnection, pricing, and settlements:
Some healthy jostling in the growth of the Internet. In Kahin, B. &
J. Keller (1997). Coordinating the Internet (pp. 346-376). Boston,
Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Frieden, R. (1998). Without public peer: The potential regulatory
and universal service consequences of Internet Balkanization. 3 Virginia
Journal of Law & Technology 8, available at http:
//vjolt.student.virginia.edu/.
Gal-Or, E. (1983). Quality and quantity competition. The Bell
Journal of Economics, 14(2), 590-600.
Gal-Or, E. (1985). Differentiated industries without entry
barriers. Journal of Economic Theory, 37(2), 310-339.
Gupta, A., L. Linden, D. Stahl & A. Whinston (2001). Benefits
and costs of adopting usage-based pricing in a subnetwork. Information
Technology and Management, 2(2), 175-191.
MacKie-Mason, J.K. & H.R. Varian (1995). Pricing congestible
network resources. IEEE Journal of Selected Areas in Communications,
13(7), 1141-1149.
Shin, S., H. Correa & M.B.H. Weiss (2002a). A game theoretic
modeling and analysis for Internet access market. International Telecom
Society 2002 Conference, Seoul, Korea.
Shin, S., M.B.H. Weiss & H. Correa (2002b). Internet QoS market
analysis with product differentiation theory. International Telecom
Society 2002 Conference, Seoul, Korea.
Stahl, D. A. Whinston & K. Zhang (1998). A simulation study of
competitive Internet pricing: AOL flat rates versus GSW usage prices.
Proceedings of the first International Conference on Information and
Computation Economies, 68-76.
USGAO (2001). Characteristics and Choice of Internet Users. United
States General Accounting Office publication GAO-01-345.
Vanston, L.K. (2002). Residential Broadband Forecasts. A white
paper by Technology Futures, Inc., available at www.tfi.com.
Sengjae Shin, Mississippi State University--Meridian
Robert F. Cope III, Southeastern Louisiana University
Rachelle F. Cope, Southeastern Louisiana University
Jack E. Tucci, Mississippi State University--Meridian
Table 1: Household Expenditure for Internet Access
(USGAO, 2001)
$0 ~$5 ~$10 ~$15 ~$20
8.9% 1.4% 3.8% 8.3% 21.0%
~$30 ~$40 ~$50 $50 an up
31.7% 11.1% 8.7% 5.1%
Table 2: Internet Usage Distribution (hrs/wk)
(USGAO, 2001)
0-4 hrs 4-10 hrs 10-15 hrs 15-25 hrs
6.3% 12.1% 19.4% 29.3%
25-40 hrs 40-60 hrs 60-90 hrs
19.8% 6.3% 6.9%
Table 3: Suggested Simulation Input Parameters
Parameter Suggested Range
[W.sub.BE] $0 to $50
[W.sub.QoS] $0 to $100
F1, F2 $10, $15, $20, ..., $100
a 20%, 30%, 40%, 50%, 60%, 70%
r2 $0.3, $0.5, $0.7, $0.9, $1.1, $1.3
h 0 to 387 hrs/mon (4.3*90)