Responding to a one-time-only sale (OTOS) of a product subject to sudden obsolescence.
Joglekar, Prafulla ; Lee, Patrick
ABSTRACT
With advancing technologies and shrinking life cycles, today many
products are subject to sudden obsolescence. Manufacturers and vendors
of products that are subject to sudden obsolescence often announce a
one-time-only discount on these products. In this paper, we study a
retailer's optimal response to such one-time-only sales (OTOS) of
products subject to sudden obsolescence. We build a comprehensive model
based on two relevant bodies of literature: the literature on
one-time-only sales of non-perishable, non-obsolescent products, and the
literature on inventory and pricing decisions for obsolescent products
in the absence of any one-time only considerations.
Our model allows for price elasticity, accounts for a various types
of inventory holding costs, and deals with obsolescence costs and
capital costs separately from the holding costs. Our model also allows
for the ordering cost of the special one-time only order to be different
from the retailer's regular ordering cost. The model is general
enough to accommodate non-obsolescent as well as obsolescent products in
situations that do or do not involve an OTOS. A numerical example shows
that the use of our model can provide some long-term gain and a
particularly attractive short-term improvement in a retailer's
profit. Sensitivity analysis shows that the benefits of our model are
greatest when the discount is sizable; demand is highly price sensitive;
and the retailer's ordering cost for the special order is small.
INTRODUCTION
With rapid advances in technology, abrupt changes in global
political situations, and instantaneous dissemination of information in
the worldwide market, today product life cycles have decreased
dramatically, and a number of products are at risk of becoming obsolete
overnight. Swiss watches, computer chips, world maps, breast implants,
and Milli Vanilli records are some of the classic examples of this
phenomenon. This phenomenon also affects a large number of products
whose designs were historically stable for many years, if not decades.
For example, fuzzy logic chips have shrunk the lifecycles of such
products as washing machines and today's ergonomic focus has
rendered obsolescence on older designs of office furniture.
For prudent inventory and pricing decisions on products subject to
sudden obsolescence (hereafter called S-Obs products), a retailer must
account for the costs of obsolescence carefully. Traditionally,
obsolescence costs were treated as a component of the holding costs in
the economic order quantity (EOQ) model (Hadley & Whitin, 1963;
Naddor, 1966; Silver & Peterson, 1985). Then, some authors dealt
with obsolescence costs separately from other inventory carrying costs (Barbosa & Friedman, 1979; Brown, 1982; Hill, Girard & Mabert,
1989). However, these early works were focused on gradual rather than
sudden obsolescence.
Masters (1991) defined sudden obsolescence as a situation when a
product's lifetime is negative exponentially distributed, and
consequently, the probability of obsolescence is constant at any time.
Using an approximate model, Masters (1991) concluded that for S-Obs
products, the use of the EOQ model was appropriate, provided that the
obsolescence component was computed as the reciprocal of the
product's expected life. Joglekar and Lee (1993, 1996) pointed out
that the then current industry practice of estimating annual
obsolescence costs at 1 to 3% of a product's cost represented a
serious underestimate of the true cost. By Master's (1991) formula
even a 3% obsolescence cost implies an expected life of 33 years!
Masters (1991) warned that in cases of short-life products, failure to
use the proper formula could lead to costs that were five to forty
percent higher than the optimal costs.
Masters' (1991) model was an approximate one. Using an exact
formulation, Joglekar and Lee (1993) showed that Masters' model
also underestimated the true lifetime costs of his optimal policy while
overestimating the optimal order quantity. The associated errors were
substantial particularly in the cases of S-Obs products with very short
expected lives. Joglekar and Lee (1996) developed a profit maximization model to determine a retailer's optimal order quantity in the face
of a manufacturer's quantity discount for S-Obs products. Unlike
cost minimization models, a profit maximization model also warns a
retailer not to stock a product at all when such a stock results in loss
for the retailer.
Not too different from situations of quantity discounts are the
commonly observed situations of one-time-only sales (OTOS) of many
products. An OTOS occurs because a manufacturer/wholesaler wants to
reduce some excess inventory caused by factors such as incorrect
forecasts, deliberate excess production, or the threat of impending obsolescence. OTOS allow manufacturers to pass on reduced raw material
costs to the reseller, to meet short-term sales goals, to maximize
capacity utilization, and/or to add excitement to otherwise mature and
mundane products (Abad, 2003). Aucamp and Kuzdrall (1986) have also
observed that the situation of an announced permanent price increase,
with one last opportunity to buy before that price increase, is
mathematically equivalent to an OTOS. Fashion clothes, pop music, and
trendy toys are examples of S-Obs products where at the time of a
product-introduction, a manufacturer often offers a substantial
one-time-only discount to the retailer. Yet, available literature has
not studied a retailer's optimal response to such OTOS offers for
S-Obs products.
On the other hand, how a retailer should respond to an OTOS of a
non-perishable, non-obsolescent product has been studied by a number of
authors over the last three decades. Using standard EOQ assumptions,
earlier works (Naddor, 1966; Brown, 1967; Tersine & Grasso, 1978;
Taylor & Bradley, 1985; Lev & Weiss, 1990) developed
prescriptive models for determining an optimal special order quantity
for a retailer in a variety of OTOS situations. These works assumed a
constant demand. Considering price-elasticity, Ardalan (1994; 1995)
suggested that, in OTOS situations, in addition to using a special order
quantity, a retailer could increase his demand and profits by charging a
lower retail price for it. Ardalan (1994) also focused on maximizing the
net present value (NPV) of a retailer's cash flows rather than
maximizing the per-period profit.
In this paper, we combine Joglekar and Lee's (1996)
methodology of analyzing order quantity decisions pertaining to S-Obs
products with Ardalan's (1994) approach of simultaneously
determining the special price and the special order quantity in the face
of an OTOS. In what follows, we establish our notation and develop a
model for a retailer's optimal price and order quantity decisions
for a price-sensitive S-Obs product in the regular situation, i.e., in
the absence of an OTOS. Our model allows for price elasticity, accounts
for various types of inventory holding costs, and deals with
obsolescence costs and capital costs separately. The model is general
enough so that it can be used for obsolescent as well as non-obsolescent
products.
Next, we extend the regular situation model to accommodate an OTOS
situation. Unlike other available models, we do not assume that a
reseller's cost of ordering the special quantity in an OTOS
situation will be the same as his regular cost of ordering. We believe
that decision-making under special circumstances requires a new model,
additional data and greater analytical effort. Hence, the cost of
ordering the special quantity is often substantially greater than the
regular ordering cost. In order to obtain an accurate estimate of the
net advantage of our model's optimal decisions, we use a comparison
of the lifetime NPV of the no OTOS situation with the lifetime NPV of a
situation involving an OTOS. To gain a clearer perspective on the long
term and short-term significance of the net advantage, we look at the
net advantage as both, percentage of lifetime NPV and percentage of one
cycle NPV.
A numerical example, along with a fairly exhaustive sensitivity
analysis, is provided. The numerical example shows that, in many OTOS
situations, the use of our model can provide some long-term gain and a
particularly attractive short-term improvement in the retailer's
NPV. Our analysis also identifies situations where the retailer may be
better off not accepting the OTOS discount. The final section provides
the conclusion along with some directions for further work.
THE MODEL
Consider a retailer dealing in an S-Obs product characterized by a
price sensitive demand function that is time-invariant until
obsolescence. Product obsolescence occurs abruptly and completely at a
random point in time, which is negative exponentially distributed. At
obsolescence, the product is disposed off at a salvage value. Other than
these characteristics, standard EOQ assumptions, such as known and
constant ordering and carrying costs, zero lead-time, and no stockouts
are applicable. In a "regular" situation, i.e., in the absence
of an OTOS, the retailer seeks to maximize the NPV of his lifetime cash
flows by determining the optimal order quantity and the optimal selling
price. Similarly, when faced with an OTOS, a retailer seeks to maximize
his lifetime NPV from the special price and order quantity of the OTOS
followed by all regular cycles for the rest of the product's life.
To evaluate the exact advantage of the optimal OTOS decisions, we look
at the difference between these two NPVs.
Throughout this paper, we use the following notation.
A = a constant for the demand function, representing the
theoretical maximum demand at zero price
c = retailer's regular unit cost
[C.sub.r] = retailer's regular ordering cost per order
[C.sub.s] = ordering cost per order during special cycle
Note: We believe that the commonly used assumption [C.sub.s] =
[C.sub.r] is unrealistic. [C.sub.s] is likely to be substantially
greater than Cr for three reasons: (i) OTOS policy determination
requires the use of a different model, (ii) The OTOS order quantity is
likely to be several times the regular order quantity, and (iii)
[C.sub.s] must also include costs of announcing the special retail
price, [P.sub.s] to the retailer's customers.
d = the OTOS discount per unit
H = annual holding costs (such as storage space, and material
inspection and handling costs) that are fixed per unit, regardless of
the unit cost of the product.
h = annual holding costs (such as deterioration, damage, and
pilferage costs) that are fixed per dollar of inventory, but that vary
in per unit terms with the unit cost of the product.
Note: Most inventory models assume all holding costs to be of
either the H type or of the h type. In real life, one encounters both
types. Note also that we deal with the obsolescence costs and the
capital costs explicitly and separately. Consequently, neither H nor h
includes them.
[H.sub.r] = total annual holding costs (all except the obsolescence
cost) per unit of regular purchase [H.sub.r] = [H + (h + i)c].
[H.sub.s] = total annual holding costs (all except the obsolescence
cost) per unit of special OTOS purchase [H.sub.s] = [H + (h + i)(c -
d)].
i = cost of capital per dollar per year (used as both, the cost of
capital factor in the inventory holding cost and the discount rate for
NPV calculations).
[k.sub.r] = probability, at the beginning of a regular inventory
cycle of Qr/Rr years, that the product does not become obsolete during
the cycle. [k.sub.r] = [e.sup.-Qr/(RrL)] (Joglekar & Lee, 1993,
288).
[k.sub.s] = probability, at the beginning of the special OTOS
inventory cycle of Qs/Rs years, that the product does not become
obsolete during the cycle. [k.sub.s] = [e.sup.-Qs/(RsL)] (Joglekar &
Lee, 1993, 288).
L = expected life of the product in years
[N.sub.r] = NPV factor for a cashflow occurring at the end of a
regular inventory cycle. Nr = [e.sup.-iQr/Rr].
[N.sub.s] = NPV factor for a cashflow occurring at the end of the
special OTOS inventory cycle. [N.sub.s] = [e.sup.-iQs/Rs].
[P.sub.r] = selling price per unit during regular cycle prior to
obsolescence
[P.sub.s] = selling price per unit during special cycle prior to
obsolescence
[Q.sub.r] = order quantity per order during regular cycle
[Q.sub.s] = order quantity for the OTOS special order
[R.sub.r] = demand per year during regular cycle, given by the
function [R.sub.r] = A - [epsilon][P.sub.r].
[R.sub.s] = demand per year during special cycle, given by the
function [R.sub.s] = A - [epsilon][P.sub.s].
[S.sub.o] = salvage value per unit after obsolescence, [S.sub.o]
< (c - d).
t = the time at which the product becomes obsolete
[DELTA][[pi].sub.L] = the difference between the expected lifetime
profit resulting from the special OTOS [P.sub.s] and Qs policies
followed by all regular cycles and the expected lifetime profit of all
regular cycles in the absence of an OTOS. [DELTA][[pi].sub.L] =
[[pi].sub.Ls] - [[pi].sub.Lr].
[epsilon] = price-elasticity constant of the demand function
[[pi].sub.cr] = expected profit, in NPV terms, from the first
regular inventory cycle
[[pi].sub.Lr] = expected lifetime profit, in NPV terms, from all
regular cycles
[[pi].sub.cs] = expected profit, in NPV terms, from the special
OTOS cycle
[[pi].sub.Ls] = expected lifetime profit, in NPV terms, from the
special OTOS cycle followed by all regular cycles
THE REGULAR SITUATION
The following costs and benefits are in terms of a retailer's
expected NPV of lifetime cash flows as expected at the beginning of an
inventory cycle. First, the ordering costs and the inventory purchase
costs are incurred, representing an NPV of
[C.sub.r] + [Q.sub.r]c (1)
Product revenues and holding costs depend upon whether and when the
product becomes obsolete during an inventory cycle. If the product does
not become obsolete, the entire order quantity is sold at the regular
price. Subtracting the relevant inventory holding costs from these
revenues, the corresponding expected NPV is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Integrating and simplifying this expression by using several
equalities established in the notation section, we get
[P.sub.r][R.sub.r](1 - [N.sub.r]) + [H.sub.r][[R.sub.r][N.sub.r]/i
+ [R.sub.r]/i - [Q.sub.r]]}[k.sub.r]/i (2)
If obsolescence occurs during the cycle, then the corresponding
expected profit contribution is:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Integrating and simplifying, this expression can be written as
[[P.sub.r][R.sub.r] - [Q.sub.r][h.sub.r] + RrHr/i] [1 - [k.sub.r] -
1/(1+iL)]/i + [[Q.sub.r][S.sub.o] +
[P.sub.r][R.sub.r][N.sub.r][k.sub.r]/i +
[R.sub.r][H.sub.r][N.sub.r][k.sub.r]/i2]/(1 + iL) - [[R.sub.r]L/[(1 +
iL).sup.2]] [[H.sub.r] + [S.sub.o]] [1 - [N.sub.r][k.sub.r]] (3)
The NPV of the profit provided by a regular cycle, as expected at
the beginning of that cycle, is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
Given a constant obsolescence rate, and a time-invariant order
quantity, the NPV of the product's lifetime profit as expected at
the beginning of an order cycle is identical to that expected at the
beginning of the next order cycle. Hence,
[[pi].sub.Lr] = [[pi].sub.cr] + [k.sub.r] [[pi].sub.Lr][N.sub.r]
(5)
This can be simplified as
[[pi].sub.Lr] = [[pi].sub.cr]/(1 - [N.sub.r] [k.sub.r]) (6)
The retailer wants to determine his price and order quantity of the
regular cycle so as to maximize expected lifetime NPV from all regular
cycles. From Joglekar and Lee (1996) we know that this problem is best
solved numerically by using the solver function of software such as
Excel. Hence, we do not pursue any further manipulation of Equation (6)
for a closed form optimization. In our numerical examples, we simply use
Excel 's solver function.
THE OTOS SITUATION
We assume that the OTOS discount is available at the beginning of
what would have been a regular inventory cycle. Given the discount, the
question is whether the retailer should take the discount, and if he
does, what special order quantity, he should use, and at what special
price he should sell that quantity. We develop a model for calculating
expected lifetime NPV of using the special ordering quantity and price
at the OTOS followed by regular policies until the end of the
product's life. When an inventory cycle of a special order quantity
begins, the corresponding ordering costs and the costs of the goods are
given by
[C.sub.s] + [Q.sub.s](c - d) (7)
Product revenues and holding costs depend upon whether and when the
product becomes obsolete during an OTOS cycle. If the product does not
become obsolete during the OTOS cycle, all order quantity units of the
special cycle will sell at the special price. Subtracting the relevant
inventory holding costs from these revenues, we obtain the corresponding
NPV by the expression:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Integrating and simplifying, this expression can be written as
{[P.sub.s][R.sub.s](1 - [N.sub.s]) + [H.sub.s]
[[R.sub.s][N.sub.s]/i + [R.sub.s]/i - [Q.sub.s]]}[k.sub.s]/i (8)
If obsolescence occurs during the cycle, the corresponding expected
profit contribution, in NPV terms, is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Integrating and simplifying, this can be expressed as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
Thus, the NPV of all the cashflows of the OTOS cycle is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
While it is tempting to compare this special cycle NPV with the
regular cycle NPV, these NPVs are not comparable since the two cycles
involve two different time durations. To determine whether the special
order quantity and price policies are more desirable, one must compare
the lifetime NPV of those special policies followed by regular policies
with the expected lifetime NPV of using only regular policies
throughout.
Expected lifetime NPV from all regular cycles has already been
modeled in Equation (6). The expected lifetime NPV of the special OTOS
cycle followed by all regular cycles is given by:
[[pi].sub.Ls] = [[pi].sub.cs] + [[pi].sub.Lr][k.sub.s][N.sub.s]
(11)
Thus, in the OTOS situation, the retailer wants to determine his
special price and order quantity so as to maximize Equation (11). As in
the case of the regular situation, we use Excel 's . solver
function to solve this problem.
Once the optimized values of the special OTOS cycle are
established, the net NPV advantage of the special OTOS policies is given
by:
[DELTA][[pi].sub.L] = [[pi].sub.Ls] - [[pi].sub.Lr] (12)
If the net advantage is negative, the retailer would reject the
OTOS discount. Only if net advantage is positive, the optimal price and
order quantity values will be implemented. In that case, for a long-term
perspective, we examine the net advantage as a percent of the lifetime
NPV with all regular policies. For a short-term perspective, we examine
the net advantage as a percent of the NPV resulting from the first
regular inventory cycle. It is these values that provide the proper
perspective on both the long-term and the short-term gains associated
with the use of our model in an OTOS situation. As we see it, while a
long-term positive gain is important, the relative magnitude of the
short-term gain is the most important consideration. After all, by
definition, an OTOS is a one time, short-run deal.
NUMERICAL EXAMPLE
Consider a product with the following parameters:
c = $10/unit [C.sub.r] = $100/order
i = 12%/year [S.sub.o] = $2/unit
[epsilon] = 6,000 units/$.
H = $1/unit/year
[R.sub.r] = 100,000 - 6,000[P.sub.r]
L = 1 year h = 5%/year
A = 100,000 units/year
We believe these parameter values are fairly realistic. The unit
cost and the demand constant are arbitrary and may be different from
situation to situation. An ordering cost of $100/order is within a range
of values observed in real life. Together, the assumed holding costs
(both fixed and variable) and the assumed cost of capital, result in an
assumption of an annual inventory cost (excluding the cost of
obsolescence) of 27% of the value of inventory. This is also well within
the observed range of values in real life. Because we are focusing on
S-Obs products, we assume a salvage value of only 20% of the unit cost
and we assume an expected life of only 1 year. We consider a
price-elasticity constant implying a reduction 6,000 units in demand for
every dollar increase in price. We believe this is also within typically
observed range of price-elasticity values.
As Table 1 shows, under our parameter values, in the regular
situation, the retailer's optimal retail price works out to be
$13.43/unit. The corresponding demand is 19,419 units/year, and the
optimal order quantity is 516 units/order (or less than two weeks'
supply). These optimal decisions result in a regular cycle profit (in
NPV terms) of $1,545 and a lifetime NPV of $52,706.
Now, assume that the manufacturer has offered an OTOS discount of
$1/unit (i.e., 10% of the regular unit cost), available at the time of
the retailer's next order. Also assume that because it requires the
use of a different model and involves the need to communicate a special
price to the customers, the retailer's ordering cost for the
special order, is $500, instead of the regular $100. Table 1 shows that,
in this situation, the retailer's special order quantity would be
2,097 units and his special selling price would be $13.16/unit. Given
the special price, during the OTOS cycle, the retailer would experience
a demand rate of 21,031 units/year. Thus, the special order quantity
will last for approximately five weeks. The retailer's profit (in
NPV terms) from the OTOS cycle will be $6,456.
However, this special cycle NPV is not directly comparable with the
regular cycle NPV of $1,545 since the two cycles involve different
lengths of time. The product's lifetime NPV from the special cycle
followed by all regular cycles is $53,592. Thus, the retailer's net
increase in lifetime NPV due to the OTOS is $886. In comparison to the
NPV of all regular cycles ($52,706), this net advantage looks small
(1.68%). However, $886 is 57% of a single regular cycle's NPV of
$1,545. This short-term advantage is very attractive. After all, the
OTOS decisions are short term, one-cycle decisions. In short, our
numerical example shows that if a retailer adopts our model, he would
obtain some long-term gain and a particularly attractive short-term
gain.
Of course, conclusions from a numerical example are only as valid
as the assumed parameters. Hence, in what follows, we provide an
analysis of the sensitivity of our results to each one of the assumed
parameters. The numerical example in Table 1 serves as the base case for
this sensitivity analysis.
SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS
The only parameter we hold constant throughout the sensitivity
analysis is the retailer's regular unit cost of the product.
However, changes in some of the other parameters could be seen as
relative changes in the unit cost.
Holding other assumed parameters at their values in Table 1, in
Table 2 we vary the assumed amount of discount offered by a supplier to
the reseller. As can be seen, when the discount is only $0.40 (or 5% of
the normal unit cost), using special OTOS policies would result in a net
loss to the reseller. Thus, the reseller is better off continuing to use
his regular policies during the OTOS period and simply benefiting from
the windfall gain from the discounted cost. However, as the amount of
discount (and its percentage of normal unit cost) increases, the OTOS
strategies become increasingly attractive, both, from the long term and
the short-term perspective. When the discount is as large as 25% of the
normal unit cost, the reseller may want to use a special order quantity
that is 8 times his regular order quantity and pass on more than a
fourth of his unit cost saving to his customers. Such a one-time
opportunity can increase the reseller's lifetime NPV by 7.66% and
his single cycle net advantage can be several times his normal single
cycle profit.
Similarly, we carried out a detailed examination of the sensitivity
of our results to each one of the parameters of our model. In Table 3,
we provide a brief summary of the alternative values of parameters used,
the resulting indices of long term and short-term advantage of the
optimal OTOS strategies. As would be expected, the results are highly
sensitive to the price elasticity. The greater the price elasticity, the
greater are the advantages of optimal OTOS strategies.
The results are also highly sensitive to the ordering cost of the
special order. As the ordering cost of the special order increases, the
advantage of the special OTOS policies declines. From a practical point
of view this is rather important to understand. In the past, researchers
have assumed that, in an OTOS, there would be no change in the ordering
cost. That assumption is not only unrealistic; it inflates the advantage
attributable to optimal OTOS policies.
The results are moderately sensitive to the product's expected
life. As expected life increases, the short-term advantages of the OTOS
policies increase while the long-term advantages decline. Note also that
as a product's salvage value increases the OTOS decisions are
increasingly advantageous both in the long run and in the short run.
Thus, it seems that OTOS decisions are more beneficial for
non-obsolescent products than they are for obsolescent products.
Finally, Table 3 indicates that, from both, the long-term and the
short-term perspectives, the results are not very sensitive to changes
in regular ordering costs, holding costs, or cost of capital.
CONCLUSION
Today many products are characterized by price elasticity, sudden
obsolescence, and short expected lives. Drawing on the relevant
literature, first we built a model for a retailer's optimal price
and order quantity
decisions for such products in the regular situation, i.e., in the
absence of a one-time-only discount. Our model is comprehensive. It
allows for price elasticity, accounts for a variety of types of
inventory holding costs, and deals with obsolescence costs and capital
costs in precise and theoretically correct manner. Because manufacturers
and vendors of S-Obs products often offer a one-time-only discount for
such products, we then extended our model to accommodate the OTOS
situations. Because a special order requires the use of a different
model and additional costs of announcing a price change, our model used
an explicitly different ordering cost for the special OTOS order. A
numerical example showed that the use of our model could provide some
long-term gain and a particularly attractive short-term improvement in a
retailer's profit. A retailer stands to benefit the most from our
model if the discount is substantial, the product demand is highly price
sensitive, and the retailer's ordering cost for the special order
is substantial. Also, it seems that OTOS decisions are more beneficial
for non-obsolescent products than they are for obsolescent products.
There are several directions for further work on this topic. First,
we assumed a linear and deterministic demand function. A non-linear
function is likely to be more realistic in most situations. An extension
of our model to a non-linear demand relationship should be straight
forward, particularly since we do not derive any closed-form solutions
but depend on Excel[R] to solve the problem. Also, a stochastic demand
function is more likely to be encountered in real life. An extension to
allow for a stochastic demand function would be relatively more
complicated but doable.
A critical assumption in our model is that the fact that a
manufacturer has offered an OTOS does not in itself change a
retailer's assessment of the product's life expectancy and/or
salvage value. In real life, a retailer may assume, often correctly,
that an OTOS is a signal of an imminent obsolescence. Thus, in view of
the OTOS, a retailer's perceived life expectancy and/or salvage
value for the product may be reduced. On the other hand, as we have
pointed out, an impending price increase with one last opportunity to
buy at the lower price is a situation that is mathematically equivalent
to an OTOS. In such situations of impending price increase, a retailer
may deduce that the product's life expectancy may be greater than
his original estimate of that expectancy. In any case, an extension of
our model to allow for such a change in the perceived life expectancy of
a product offered on an OTOS would also be an interesting and productive
direction for further work. Finally, two recent models of OTOS
situations for non-obsolescent products suggest that a retailer's
optimal strategy is not to sell the entire special order quantity at the
special price. Instead, a retailer should sell only a portion of his
special order quantity at a special price, reverting to his regular
selling price for the remaining portion of the special order quantity
(Abad, 2003; Arcelus, Shah & Srinivasan, 2003). It seems that this
type of a strategy may be optimal also for products subject to sudden
obsolescence.
REFERENCES
Abad, P. L. (2003). Optimal price and lot size when the supplier
offers a temporary price reduction over an interval. Computers and
Operations Research, 30, 63-74.
Arcelus, F.J., N. H. Shah & G. Srinivasan. (2003).
Retailer's Pricing, Credit and inventory policies for deteriorating items in response to temporary price/credit incentives. International
Journal of Production Economics, 81-82, 153-152.
Ardalan, A. (1994). Optimal prices and order quantities when
temporary price discounts result in increase in demand. European Journal
of Operational Research, 72, 52-61.
Ardalan, A. (1995). A comparative analysis of approaches for
determining optimal price and order quantity when a sale increases
demand. European Journal of Operational Research, 84, 416-430.
Aucamp, D. C. & P. J. Kuzdrall. (1986). Lot sizes for
one-time-only sales. Journal of Operational Research Society, 37, 79-86.
Barbosa, L. C. & M. Friedman. (1979). Inventory lot size models
with vanishing markets. Journal of the Operations Research Society,
30(2), 1129-1132.
Brown, G. W., J. Y Lu & R. J. Wolfson. (1964). Dynamic modeling
of inventories subject to sudden obsolescence. Management Science,
11(1), 51-63.
Brown, R. G. (1967). Decision rules for inventory management. New
York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.
Brown, R. G. (1982). Advanced Service Parts Management. Norwitch,
VT: Materials Management Systems, Inc.
Hadley, G. & T. M. Whitin. (1963). Analysis of Inventory
Systems. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Hill, A. V., V. Girard & V. A. Mabert. (1989). A decision
support system for determining optimal retention stocks for service
parts inventories. IIE Transactions, 21(3), 236:248.
Joglekar, P. & P. Lee. (1993). An exact formulation of
inventory costs and optimal lot size in face of sudden obsolescence.
Operations Research Letters, 14, 283-290.
Joglekar P. & P. Lee. (1996). A profit maximization model for a
retailer's stocking decisions on products subject to sudden
obsolescence, Production and Operations Management, 5(3), 288-294.
Lev, B. & H. J. Weiss. (1990). Inventory models with cost
changes. Operations Research, 38, 53-63.
Masters, J. M. (1991). A note on the effect of sudden obsolescence
on the optimal lot size. Decision Sciences, 22, 1180-1186.
Naddor, E. (1966). Inventory Systems, New York: John Wiley &
Sons.
Nahmias, S. (1974). Inventory depletion management when the field
life is random. Management Science, 20, 1276-1284.
Nose, T., H. Ishii & T.Nishida. (1984). Perishable inventory
management with stochastic lead-time and different selling prices.
European Journal of Operations Research, 18, 322-338.
Silver, E. A. & R. Peterson. (1985). Decision Systems for
inventory management and production planning. New York: John Wiley &
Sons.
Taylor, S. G. & C. E. Bradley. (1985). Optimal ordering
strategies for announced price increases. Operations Research, 33(2),
312-325.
Tersine, R. J. & E. T. Grasso. (1978). Forward buying in response to announced price increases. Journal of Purchasing and
Materials Management, 14(2), 20-22.
Prafulla Joglekar, La Salle University
Patrick Lee, Fairfield University
Table 1
Assumptions, Decisions, and Lifetime Profits of Regular and OTOS
Situations
Assumptions:
c = $10/unit, [C.sub.r] = $100/order, H = $1/unit/year, h = 5%/$/year,
i = 12%/year, [epsilon] = 6000 units/$, [S.sub.o] = $2/unit, L = 1
year, [C.sub.s] = $500/order, d = $1/unit (or 10% of regular unit cost)
Optimal Decisions and Results
Regular Results
Regular Decisions
[[product] [[product]
[P.sub.r] [Q.sub.r] [R.sub.r] .sub.cr] .sub.Lr]
13.43 516 19,419 1,545 52,706
OTOS Results
OTOS Decisions
[[product] [[product]
[P.sub.s] [Q.sub.s] [R.sub.s] .sub.cs] .sub.Ls]
13.16 2,097 21,031 6,456 53,592
[DELTA] [DELTA]
[[product] [[product]
.sub.L] .sub.L]
as % of as % of
[DELTA] [DELTA] [DELTA]
[[product] [[product] [[product]
.sub.cr] .sub.Lr] .sub.cr]
886 1.68% 57.33%
Table 2
Sensitivity to d, the OTOS Discount Per Unit
Regular Results
Regular Decisions
[[product] [[product]
d [P.sub.r] [Q.sub.r] [R.sub.r] .sub.cr] .sub.Lr]
0.4 13.4 516 19,419 1,545 52,706
0.8 13.4 516 19,419 1,545 52,706
1.0 13.4 516 19,419 1,545 52,706
2.0 13.4 516 19,419 1,545 52,706
OTOS Results
OTOS Decisions
[[product] [[product]
d [P.sub.s] [Q.sub.s] [R.sub.s] .sub.cs] .sub.Ls]
0.4 13.33 1,098 20,049 3,060 52,629
0.8 13.22 1,746 20,698 5,248 53,202
1.0 13.16 2,097 21,031 6,456 53,592
2.0 12.87 4,170 22,776 13,811 56,746
[DELTA] [DELTA]
[[product] [[product]
.sub.L] .sub.L]
[DELTA] as % of as % of
[[product] [[product] [[product]
d .sub.L] .sub.Lr] .sub.cr]
0.4 -77 -0.15% -4.98%
0.8 496 0.94% 32.11%
1.0 886 1.68% 57.33%
2.0 4,040 7.66% 261.48%
Table 3
Sensitivity Analysis
[DELTA] [DELTA]
[[product].sub.L] [[product].sub.L]
Changed as % of as % of
Parameter [[product].sub.Lr] [[product].sub.cr]
[epsilion] = 5,000 1.09% 41.72%
[epsilion] = 6,000 1.68% 57.33%
[epsilion] = 7,000 2.75% 80.48%
[C.sub.s] = 200 2.25% 76.74%
[C.sub.s] = 500 1.68% 57.33%
[C.sub.s] = 800 1.11% 37.91%
L = 0.75 1.80% 51.46%
L = 1.00 1.68% 57.35%
L = 1.50 1.47% 64.46%
[S.sub.o] = 1.00 1.55% 54.67%
[S.sub.o] = 2.00 1.68% 57.35%
[S.sub.o] = 3.00 1.83% 60.24%
[C.sub.r] = 50 1.25% 60.16%
[C.sub.r] = 100 1.68% 57.33%
[C.sub.r] = 200 2.41% 58.08%
H = 0.5 1.82% 60.01%
H = 1.0 1.68% 57.33%
H = 1.5 1.56% 54.85%
h = 0.02 1.75% 58.53%
h = 0.05 1.68% 57.33%
h = 0.08 1.62% 56.17%
i = 0.08 1.77% 59.95%
i = 0.12 1.68% 57.35%
i = 0.16 1.61% 54.96%
Changed
Parameter Comment
[epsilion] = 5,000 The results are highly sensitive to this
[epsilion] = 6,000 parameter. The greater the price elasticity of
[epsilion] = 7,000 demand, the greater are the short term and
long term advantages of optimal OTOS
decisions.
[C.sub.s] = 200 The results are highly sensitive to this
[C.sub.s] = 500 parameter. The greater the cost of ordering an
[C.sub.s] = 800 OTOS order, the smaller are the short term and
long term advantages of optimal OTOS
decisions.
L = 0.75 The results are moderately sensitive to this
L = 1.00 parameter. As the expected life of the product
L = 1.50 increases, long term advantages of optimal
OTOS decisions decrease while short term
advantages increase.
[S.sub.o] = 1.00 Short term results are not too sensitive to this
[S.sub.o] = 2.00 parameter. However, long term results are
[S.sub.o] = 3.00 rather sensitive. As the salvage value of the
product increases, both short term and long
term advantages of optimal OTOS decisions
increase.
[C.sub.r] = 50 Short term results are not too sensitive to this
[C.sub.r] = 100 parameter. However, long term results are
[C.sub.r] = 200 rather sensitive. As the ordering cost of a
regular order increases, long term advantages
of optimal OTOS decisions increase, but short
term advantages decline.
H = 0.5 The results are not too sensitive to this
H = 1.0 parameter. The greater the fixed holding cost
H = 1.5 per unit of inventory, the smaller are the
short term and the long term advantages of
OTOS optimal decisions.
h = 0.02 The results are not too sensitive to this
h = 0.05 parameter. The greater the fixed holding cost
h = 0.08 per dollar of inventory, the smaller are the
short term and the long term advantages of
optimal OTOS decisions.
i = 0.08 The results are not too sensitive to this
i = 0.12 parameter. The greater the annual cost of
i = 0.16 capital, the smaller are the short term and
the long term advantages of optimal OTOS
decisions.