Labour market training of new Canadians and limitations to the intersectionality framework.
Hum, Derek ; Simpson, Wayne
ABSTRACT/RESUME
This essay considers the labour market integration of immigrants
while distinguishing and assessing the importance of other identity
markers including gender, visible minority status, and disability. Since
much literature on the intersectionality of diversity markers is within
a multiculturalism framework, we "map" the commonly mentioned
diversity markers to mainstream economic research practices, pointing
out limitations associated with the small case study as well as
quantitative approaches. We sketch current economic understanding about
labour market integration of Canadian immigrants and summarise recent
research on their work-related training activities. We suggest an
expanded framework to accommodate policy complications that result from
Canada's federal-provincial division of powers. We conclude with
remarks on the limitations as well as opportunities afforded by the
intersectionality framework.
L'essai traite l'integration des immigrants dans le
marche du travail tout en reconnaissant et en evaluant l'importance
des autres marqueurs de l'identite, incluant le sexe,
l'appartenance a une minorite visible et l'incapacite. Puisque
la litterature sur l'intersectionalite des marqueurs de la
diversite se situe dans un cadre de multiculturalisme, nous traons les
marqueurs de la diversite les plus souvent mentionnes dans un contexte
des pratiques de recherche economique traditionnelles, en soulignant les
limites associees a une petite etude de cas ainsi qu'aux approches
quantitatives. Nous dressons un portrait de la comprehension de la
situation economique actuelle relative a l'integration des
immigrants dans le marche du travail au Canada et resumons la recherche recente portant sur leurs activites de formation professionnelle. Nous
proposons un cadre elargi pour composer avec les complications
d'ordre politique resultant de la division des pouvoirs entre
l'administration federale et les provinces du Canada. Nous
concluons avec des commentaires sur les limites ainsi que les
possibilites decoulant du cadre d'intersectionalite.
INTRODUCTION
Canada enjoys an advanced economy with progressive social programs,
and it takes pride in welcoming immigrants. It is also a society that
extols its multicultural character, even as it contends with its image
of an officially bilingual country of two founding peoples and the
perennial tensions that exist between English and French, East and West,
the have and have-nots, and Ottawa and the provinces. Canada, then, is
nothing if not diverse, and for this reason, it faces a daunting challenge to forge social cohesion and to promote inclusion, both civic
and economic. Lambertus (2002:4) neatly summarises the policy evolution:
Multiculturalism grew out of objections to the dualistic view of
Canada in the 1969 Report of the Royal Commission on Bilingualism
and Biculturalism. The resultant 1971 multicultural policy
acknowledged Canada's ethnic diversity by recognising equal status
of all cultures, and by protecting individual rights. In the 1980s,
the focus shifted to managing diversity through institutional
multiculturalism to provide employment equity and deal with systemic
discrimination. Multiculturalism was incorporated into the 1985
Canadian Charter of Human Rights and Freedoms, and the
Multicultural Act [sic] was passed in 1988. For the past decade,
multiculturalism remains committed to managing diversity through
institutions, and more recently emphasizing citizenship
participation of minority members, with an eye to enhancing society
at large.
Although Canadians are multicultural and diverse, some are more
multi- or more diverse than others. All of us have a "constellation
of identities", including some "socially constructed" by
others (Frideres, 2002:3). An individual's identity, it is argued,
is defined by the social category to which one belongs. But some would
add there are "fundamental traits" that determine the core
identity of an individual; these may be the result of birth, history, or
external factors and remain central in defining individual identity even
under changing contexts. In short, there are many "identity
markers" but these markers "intersect", thereby tempting
us to consider how Canadian policies and programs can achieve inclusion
and responsiveness to this intersecting nature of diversity. (1)
The markers of diversity enumerated in Canada typically include the
customary ones of gender, official language spoken, visible minority
status, age, immigrant status, Aboriginal status, disability status, as
well as heritage language knowledge, ethnic ancestry, religious
affiliation, region of residence, socio-economic status, racial
category, sexual orientation, and marital situation, to name a few. One
could stretch the list to include economic markers, such as occupation,
sector of employment, or labour force status indicators such as
employment, wage rate, and the like although this is uncommon. For the
most part, discourse on diversity is largely absent from
economists' conversations. (2)
This long list of identity markers speaks either to our limitless
capacity in Canada to celebrate our individual differences, or else our
collective need to manage our highly variegated multiculturalism
(perhaps both!). Either way, a conundrum arises with respect to public
policy. Intersectionality of diversity is predicated on the notion that
simultaneous membership in two (or more) social categories can (may)
have attendant consequences that are either unique to that combination
of memberships, or alternatively, cannot be efficiently inferred from
considering diversity markers either in isolation or in seriatim. This,
if true, coupled with Canada's present population structure and
changing mix of immigrant intake, raises the spectre of necessary policy
adjustments to "make multicultural Canada work".
It is impossible to be anything but selective when considering
intersecting diversity markers. Much writing on this issue posits such
aims as promoting social inclusion, respecting differences to combat
discrimination, or fostering citizenship participation within a paradigm
that sees these diversity markers as fundamentally socially constructed.
Our focus is somewhat different. Though also couched in terms of social
equity, our attention is on the Canadian labour market and immigrants.
One might even suggest that immigrants are the par excellence
intersection of multicultural diversity. Immigrants comprise men, women,
and children of different abilities and different religious beliefs;
they settle in different parts of Canada, and possess different
histories, socio-economic status, and official language fluency.
Increasingly, immigrants to Canada are visible minorities. (3) For
narrative convenience, we choose "new Canadians" as a core
identity marker, and then further "intersect" immigrant status
with such other diversity markers as gender, visible minority
membership, age, etc.
Recently landed immigrants face many disadvantages in the Canadian
labour market. The often-heard comment that immigrants are denied the
same opportunities as other Canadians is sometimes countered by the
claire that they do not have the same credentials as native-born
Canadians, or alternatively, do not undertake the requisite training
(human capital) because of pressures to maintain family consumption
levels. But few studies exist beyond anecdotal evidence and small case
studies. Furthermore, it is also important to note the special context
and circumstances of the labour market integration of immigrants.
Immigrants work, as well as age, after arrival in Canada, as do
native-born Canadians. So how long must an immigrant remain in Canada
before this identity marker becomes irrelevant to labour market
expectation or outcomes? Do immigrants acquire human capital as easily
as do native Canadians? Are there additional barriers or social capital
deficits that afflict immigrants either temporarily or permanently? Are
any of these circumstances amenable by public policy, and if so, by
which level(s) of government?
This essay considers the training activities and labour market
integration of immigrants while distinguishing and assessing the
importance of other identity markers, including gender. Since much of
the literature on the intersectionality of diversity markers is within a
multiculturalist framework, the next section (Section 2)
"maps" the commonly mentioned diversity markers to mainstream
economic research practices, pointing out limitations associated with
the small case study as well as quantitative approaches. Section 3
sketches current economic understanding about labour market assimilation
by Canadian immigrants and summarises recent research on their
work-related training activities. We propose an expanded framework in
Section 4 to accommodate policy complications that result from
Canada's federal-provincial division of powers. We conclude with
remarks on the limitations as well as opportunities afforded by the
intersectionality framework.
THE INTERSECTIONALITY PARADIGM AND MAINSTREAM ECONOMIC METHODS
Intersectionality refers to individuals with simultaneous
membership in two or more social categories. The paradigm accordingly
grants significance to the social category constructed by its own
members, or in many instances, constructed by society itself. The group
may often view itself as a community with a distinct culture, shared
objectives, and specific aspirations as well as particular barriers and
restraints. This contrasts with the dominant practice in mainstream
economics in which the individual agent is centered. The basis for group
construction in economics is usually homogeneity among
"representative" individuals, rather than the
"intersecting" diversity of individual characteristics.
Heterogeneity among individuals often poses difficulties for empirical
economic research. It is instructive to glimpse the relationship between
the conceptual (non-economic) language of the intersectionality
formulation and mainstream economic empirical research. Additionally,
such an exercise highlights the contribution that different research
programs can make, in addition to affording an appreciation of
limitations. Despite their different language, there is much common
ground.
The intersectionality paradigm uses some combination of diversity
markers to define a group with a putatively shared objective or shared
socio-economic condition. Economists, however, prefer to see these
markers as simply individual characteristics or personal traits that are
exogenous to the issue being examined, typically some economic outcome.
If one is investigating employment earnings, for example, a marker
(variable) such as religion or sexual orientation is regarded as
"outside" the main determinants of earnings. Since there are
so many marker/variables to consider, both in isolation and in
combinations, the standard econometric approach is multivariate analysis
methods. Intersectionality in the sense already noted--simultaneous
membership in two (or more) social categories--is typically addressed
formally by examining the so-called "interaction terms". (4)
The detection of influence (if any) and measurement of the contribution
arising from this "intersectionality" is thereby assessed in
addition to whatever impact each marker/variable contributes
individually. No simple model or single study can examine every possible
influencing factor. There are, inevitably, special circumstances of
history, or policy, or context to consider. For economists, markers of
subsidiary interest to the main line of inquiry are included mainly for
reasons of statistical control.
Writers within the post-structuralist framework frequently assert
that identity markers are fluid and depend upon social construction or
current negotiation. But despite shifting boundaries, the category
itself will still retain currency, such as, for example, "female
gender" or "Mainland Chinese". Pragmatic economists are
content to adopt the social category label without worrying too much
about changing interpretations that abound among separate sub-groups.
Rather, economists worry more about distinguishing between those markers
or tags that remain fixed (e.g., gender, ethnic heritage) and those that
are more fluid, whereby individual behaviour can affect membership in
the social category. For instance, one may become disabled through
accident or advancing age, or cease to be illiterate through language
training. The fluid markers, we shall see, have special significance for
some lines of economic inquiry, since "exit" or voluntary
entry is possible with certain social categories, such as disability
(See Hum and Simpson, 2002a).
Another important distinction for econometricians is whether
identity markers are observable or latent (unobservable). Some markers
are easily observed (e.g., colour); others might be concealed by
individual choice (e.g., sexual orientation) or semi-hidden
(misdiagnosis of learning disability). Foreconomists, most troublesome
are markers that are latent, such as individual motivation, ambition,
attitudes, and the like that can play important roles in determining
behavioural response.
One difficulty of a multicultural society in accounting for the
myriad of diversity markers is the harsh reality of what may be termed
"progression to the small", by which attempts to include more
markers of diversity quickly reach a limit. This has implications for
research as well as policy. The social circumstances of a small and
narrowly defined group may not offer many lessons for a wider
population. From a more practical level, a narrowly constituted group
may be ineffective in marshalling voice for their circumstances or
garnering political support to influence policy. The 'progression
to the small" can be quite unforgiving.
Suppose the proportion of the population having identity marker of
diversity 1 is P1, and that the proportion having identity marker of
diversity 2 is P2, and so forth with P3 and P4 ... Then the population
proportion simultaneously having diversity markers 1, 2, 3 ... will be
the product of each individual population proportion; that is, P1 x P2 x
P3 (if the markers are independent). This can be a very small number
indeed. For example, consider gender as an identity marker of diversity,
so the proportion of females in the population is roughly one half; that
is, P1 = 0.5. Next, consider the population segment whose income is
below the median, thus P2 is also one half, or 0.5. Finally, consider
the population segment that is below the median age, so that P3 is 0.5.
The "intersecting diversity" group of Canadians who are female
with below median income and below median age is .5 x .5 x .5 = 1/8. In
other words, after considering just three identity markers, in which the
markers evenly divide the population, we obtain a group representing
only 12.5% of the Canadian population. This is simply an example
constructed for arithmetic convenience.
In fact, the identity markers of interest (besides gender) are
typically very much lower in terms of population proportion (see Table
1). For instance, the proportion of the Canadian population that is
disabled, or a member of a particular visible minority (say Chinese), or
is an immigrant, or whose sexual orientation is homosexual, is much
lower than the 50 percent in our example. Consequently, any attempt to
consider more than three identity markers to constitute an
intersectionality group is likely to be unproductive. One typically
starts with a group that is small to begin with, for example, Canadians
with disabilities (about 14% of the population). As soon as one
incorporates the gender marker (P = 0.5) to examine, say, females with
disabilities, the number drops by one half to 7 percent immediately.
Finer grain contemplation of visible minority group membership, age
bracket, region of residence, or language, shrinks the group rapidly.
The implication of the above discussion is as follows. Those who
fix their gaze on intersecting diversity markers by considering too many
social categories will face the unrelenting logic of progression to the
small. (5) The risk is that the resulting group becomes irrelevant for
analysis of political network building as well as program delivery. On
the other hand, a multivariate analysis of intersectionality of the sort
favoured by econometricians will need very large and complex data sets.
Although census data provide coverage of the entire Canadian population
and can be used to construct profiles of different diversity-combination
groups, its drawback is that the response of interest for policy (e.g.,
wages or training) is often not available from the Census information.
Panel data, on the other hand, are ideal for investigating processes
through time, including changes in social category membership when
individuals enter or exit particular groups. Additionally, this type of
data can accommodate latent markers (see Hum and Simpson, 2000).
However, this rich detail comes at a cost. Given the expense of
gathering these types of data, sample sizes in panel data sets are often
smaller than wished.
LABOUR MARKET PERFORMANCE OF IMMIGRANTS AND TRAINING
What is the state of knowledge about the labour market performance
and identity markers of diversity? Consider work-related training
activities of adult Canadians, focusing, first of all, on immigrant
status as the main marker of interest. One is immediately urged to
consider other identity markers, such as gender, age, language, region
of residence, and the like, including, especially, visible minority
membership, since a majority of Canada's new immigrants are
non-white. Should visible minority membership or immigrant status be the
core trait for labour market policy? Or something else?
Hum and Simpson (1999) examined wage offers for men and women using
individual panel data to study the importance of the visible minority
identity marker in determining labour market outcomes. They found
immigrant status to be a more important diversity marker than visible
minority status (except for black men). Hum and Simpson also included
interaction terms between immigrant status and visible minority status
and found it significant in revealing disadvantage for men (but less so
for women). This therefore gives some credence to the notion that
identity markers of diversity can have significance in particular
combinations. Since immigration status appears to "dominate"
in determining labour responses, we concentrate on this marker, allowing
others such as gender to play secondary roles as necessary. (6)
Many studies report that immigrants face economic disadvantage in
the Canadian labour market (Abbott and Beach, 1993; Baker and Benjamin,
1994 and 1997; Bloom, Grenier and Gunderson, 1995; Grant, 1999; Hum and
Simpson, 1999; Li, 2000; McDonald and Worswick, 1998; Meng, 1987;
Miller, 1992). Using cross-sectional data, these studies uniformly find
an earnings gap (termed "the entry effect") at the time of
landing relative to native-born Canadians with comparable
characteristics. Many of these studies also find evidence of
"economic assimilation" with time spent in Canada. More
recently, however, Hum and Simpson (2000) find little evidence of wage
convergence for immigrants when examining panel data from the Survey of
Labour and Income Dynamics (SLID). They conclude that economic
assimilation was largely absent or extremely slow in Canada during the
1990s. Hum and Simpson did find that acquiring additional training and
work experience has a substantial effect on wage growth, thereby raising
the further question regarding whether or not immigrants have the same
training opportunities as the native-born.
We summarise preliminary research comparing immigrant and
non-immigrant training patterns to illustrate the impact of several
markers of diversity, bearing in mind that we have already pre-assigned
priority to the markers of immigrant status and gender. Our
"response" of interest is adult training (post formal
schooling) for the workplace. (7)
We illustrate with a sample from the Adult Education and Training
Survey (AETS) partitioned on the basis of immigrant status and the
gender marker as shown in Table 1 (adapted from Hum and Simpson, 2003).
We report training activity (defined as the duration of training in
hours) for immigrant and native-born men and women on the basis of
several personal characteristics including ethnic classifications (8)
and disability status, plus a number of job characteristics and some
core economic considerations such as education, age, and labour force
attachment. Although we start with a large sample, Table 1 reveals that
the intersection of only three categories (gender, immigrant status, and
Black) results in very small sub-samples. For instance, only 54 of the
full sample of 28,129 are male, black immigrants; this represents just
0.2 percent of the Canadian population. Nonetheless, through regression
analysis we are able to estimate differences in training activity
between diversity groups. We find that Blacks surfer a distinct
disadvantage in the sense that they have significantly fewer annual
hours of training that do non-Blacks, but that this disadvantage differs
only across gender. While there is a distinctly greater disadvantage for
black men than for black women, the disadvantage was no greater for
immigrants than for the native-born: In fact, native-born black women
have a greater training disadvantage vis-a-vis immigrant black women,
once other personal and job-related factors have been considered.
Similarly, those with disabilities (yet another identity marker) were at
a disadvantage in training, and men with disabilities at a slightly
greater disadvantage than women with disabilities, but immigrants
actually fare better than their native-born counterparts.
The Canadian literature on immigrant economic assimilation is quite
diverse despite its small size. Nevertheless, a few patterns emerge
which we summarise as follows. Upon entry, male immigrants appear to
work fewer hours at less secure jobs and for lower wages (compared to an
equivalent native). This is especially true of later cohorts, most
likely because they contain fewer immigrants from Britain, Europe, and
the United States (and thus more visible minorities). On balance, the
literature does indicate some assimilation along most dimensions,
although the pace of assimilation is unclear. For the most part, female
immigrants follow roughly the same pattern. However, women in
two-immigrant marriages appear to work high initial hours in dead-end
jobs, possibly to finance human capital investment activities by their
husbands (see Hum and Simpson, 2000).
INTERSECTIONS OF DIVERSITY: OMISSIONS FOR POLICY STUDIES
How illuminating is a recasting of multiculturalism in terms of
individual markers of diversity for addressing issues of public policy
in Canada? The essentials of the intersectionality formulation of
markers of diversity are captured in the Venn diagram of Figure 1. One
dimension (horizontal axis) denotes a marker of diversity, and another
(vertical axis) is labeled "response/goal" to denote the
policy objective; for example, inclusion or citizenship or economic
outcome. Separate circles depict individual diversity markers such as
visible minority membership (e.g., Asian), gender (e.g., female), and
immigrant status. Members of a particular social category, such as
immigrants, are represented within the circle, and others
(non-immigrants) lie outside the circle. The intersection or area common
to all three circles (shaded in Figure 1) represents simultaneous
membership in all three social categories. In this instance, the
intersectionality group comprises females, Asian, and immigrants.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The premise of intersectionality is that this combination
constitutes a unique group. Whatever the validity of the claire, the
crucial point to note for policy design and program delivery is that
initiatives targeted toward this putative "multiple jeopardy"
group would then miss or exclude males (who may be immigrants and
Asian), other Asians (who are not immigrants or female), and other
immigrants (who are male and European or African or North American).
Policies and programs directed at all females, or all immigrants, or all
visible minority members would, of course, include the intersectionality
group. Consequently, a strong onus will be on this particular
intersectionality group to demonstrate the ineffective nature of the
programs applied jointly, or the greater social (as opposed to
recipient) benefits of such program targeting. This may be easy or
difficult, depending on the particular group. Is a program restricted,
say, to black immigrants to be preferred (by society as a whole) to
separate general programs aimed at all immigrants and all visible
minority groups? In sum, too literal and too aggressive a pursuit of
intersectionality can result, ironically, in greater exclusion rather
than more inclusion. Combined with the logic of the progression to the
small, it is easy to see why this is so. But why cannot each group have
its own special targeted program? There are many complications
associated with program design and delivery.
Canada's federal constitution has implications for
intersectionality as it relates to policy responsibility. This dimension
appears largely absent in present-day discussions of
intersectionality--a grave omission from a policy, public
administration, and political perspective. In addition to the
traditional wrestling over constitutional jurisdiction with respect to
program responsibility and fiscal matters, additional issues should be
noted for policy development and administration. In the situation of
multiple diversity markers, one important requirement is that there must
be as many policy instruments (programs) as there are diversity markers.
For example, if one wishes to address issues pertaining to official
language as well as immigrant economic integration, it will not be
possible to do so with a single program for the simple reason that a
program targeted primarily toward the concerns of immigrants may be
ineffective in achieving the different aim of the official languages
policy, and similarly, concentrating on promoting official languages may
not pinpoint and address all the needs of immigrants. In the context of
the markers of diversity, policies and programs from the
multiculturalism policy sector alone will be ineffective. This is the
well-known Tinbergen Principle (after the first Nobel Laureate in
economics, Jan Tinbergen), whereby one must have at least as many policy
instruments as there are policy targets.
Moreover, it is not simply a matter of having more policies and
programs or requiring more government departments to adopt the
intersectionality framework. There is also the matter of what is known
as effective market classification, a principle due to another Nobel
Laureate in economics, Canadian-born Robert Mundell. (9) Briefly, this
principle demonstrates that program impact is maximised by assigning
responsibility to the policy instrument or program that has the most
direct, as opposed to indirect, influence on the goal. For example, one
should not assign responsibility for employment equity to an agency
devoted to protecting the environment, or even to local municipal
government.
A further consideration relates to the nature of Canada's
constitution. Immigrant matters happen to be a concurrent jurisdiction under the Canadian Constitution, so Ottawa and the provinces both have
authority to act. The needs and preferences of each province respecting
immigration intake must be coordinated and enforced by federal authority
since immigrants, once landed, are free to move from one region to
another, one city to another, one economic sector to another. The
federal government must be responsible for setting an overall limit to
the number and types of immigrants Canada accepts in the interests of
all Canadians. On the other hand, labour market training is often best
undertaken on a sub-national basis, thereby arguing for a provincial
focus, as evidenced by the separate Labour Market Development Agreements
(LMDA). What does this imply, then, for a coherent policy to assist new
immigrants to acquire training for the Canadian labour market? Which
order of government ought to deliver, or coordinate, programs directed
toward particular intersectionality groups? In one form or another, this
is the perennial tussle in Canada known as federal-provincial relations.
(10)
The above points relate to policy responsibility and the design of
program delivery. A comment can also be made from the perspective of the
diversity groups themselves vis-a-vis government at both levels. Put
bluntly, what is the best basis for securing voice, political attention,
and policy action? Specifically, are the rights and entitlements of
visible minorities better guaranteed through provincial auspices or
federal policies? Should rights of women be considered independent of,
or mainly alongside, the markers of age, or language, or sexual
orientation? Are the aims of the disabled better achieved by
disregarding the markers of region? These questions are partly
rhetorical; they address the issues of "to whom" and
"with which different others" ought a diversity-marked group
to direct its political activities. There is no universal answer, but it
is arguable that some groups may see their best course of action to lie
in deliberately de-emphasising intersectionality to achieve as broad a
voice as possible by limiting their goal to fostering advancement for
their single diversity-marked group, or to direct their energy to a
single (either federal or provincial) government order.
Our outlined extensions to the intersectionality framework can be
glimpsed in Figure 2. Figure 2 incorporates Figure I (previously
discussed) as a two-dimensional fiat plane, representing the
relationship between identity markers and response. A third axis,
denoting policy design and delivery, is now shown, and its space
includes the two main orders of government in Canada. Lines emanating
from each order of government and directed to different social
categories, including possibly an intersectionality sector, are shown
for illustrative purposes of the many possibilities of program delivery.
Note especially, however, that responsibility for immigrants is shared
between Canada and the provinces, and both orders of government may
choose to deliver programs to the same group. Finally, local government,
indirect agencies, NGOs, and the like are omitted from the diagram for
simplification, although their roles may be important. However, it bears
emphasising that the entire interacting relationship between orders of
government and diversity-marked groups is "mediated" through
the economy (in our specific application). The central point, then, is
simply to warn that considering intersectionality of diversity in Canada
in a policy context--even absent the complications of a complex and
changing economic structure--must incorporate the fundamental fact of
Canadian political and economic life, its federal constitutional nature,
and what this means for promoting social equity, however viewed and
pursued.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
CONCLUSIONS AND CHALLENGES
The myriad of identity markers reminds us of the diverse and
multicultural nature of Canada, and why the need to construct a tolerant
civil society that respects differences should command our attention.
But as the number of diversity markers increases, there is the danger
that groups who claire "too special" a status by combining too
many diversity markers will find their concerns ignored and their
presence further marginalised. The possibility of multiplying social
category enclaves is unattractive. At the same time, not all diversity
markers may be equally relevant, and some markers may have greater
importance in particular policy areas. Although virtually all diversity
markers are, or ought to be, on a par with respect to such aims as
social participation, the franchise, human rights, and the like, other
more limited objectives justify ignoring some diversity markers as
irrelevant. As well, the concerns of competing diversity groups will
often conflict and need to be reconciled. Still other markers of
diversity might claim greater relevance in particular policy areas, such
as labour markets and economic outcomes.
The intersectionality formulation of Canada's multicultural
character is useful. However, its limitations should be acknowledged. At
present, it is too much the captive of simply enumerating and layering
social categories without attention to alternative paradigms or
realpolitik. There is also an insufficiently developed consensus on a
hierarchy of markers and silence on the circumstance that might
privilege some diversity markers over others in policy applications.
There remains an inadequately developed confrontation of the
federal-provincial dimensions of intersectionality and, most of all, a
lacking in breadth in conversational partners. These are a few of the
challenges posed by the very important issues of intersectionality and
identity markers of diversity. Our progress in addressing them honestly
will largely determine whether 'intersectionality of
diversity" becomes a future guide-post for a multicultural Canada.
Table 1 Training Activity Among Canadian Men and Women by Immigrant
Status; Sample Size: 28,129
Men (n = 12,423)
Immigrants Canadian
born
By Gender &
Immigrant Status 1,468 10,955
Average Training Hours 23.4 29.8
Black (%) 54 (0.19) 44 (0.16)
Disabled (%) 191 (0.68) 1,677 (5.96)
Black Training Effect -43.4 -43.5
Disabled Training Effect -20.4 -24.9
Women (n = 15,706)
Immigrants Canadian
born
By Gender &
Immigrant Status 1,767 13,939
Average Training Hours 33.1 24.8
Black (%) 83 (0.30) 28 (0.10)
Disabled (%) 223 (0.79) 2,161 (7.68)
Black Training Effect -08.6 -24.0
Disabled Training Effect -16.5 -20.8
Source: 1998 Adult Education and Training Survey Master (Internal)
File; calculations by the authors
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
We thank the Prairie Centre of Excellence for Research on
Immigration and Integration (PCERII) for financial support. The views
expressed are solely those of the authors.
NOTES
(1.) This paraphrases the statement of purpose of the Intersections
of Diversity Seminar held in Niagara Falls, April 2003, sponsored
jointly by the Association for Canadian Studies, Canadian Heritage, and
the Metropolis Project.
(2.) As anecdotal (rather than compelling) evidence, the reviews
(authors) commissioned for the Intersections of Diversity seminar
covered the following "markers": Aboriginal peoples
(Lambertus), Age (Fieras), Disability (Stienstra), Gender (Cohen),
Immigration (Frideres), Official Languages (Quell), Region (Nurse),
Sexual Orientation (van der Meide), and Socio-economic Status
(Kazemipur). All the authors argue, with varying degrees of insistence,
that groups or society socially construct the markers of diversity. None
of the authors is an economist and it may simply be that no economist
was asked to write. Nothing sinister should be taken from this
description aside from the fact that economists are not prominent voices
in this discourse. Sec Hum (1995) for a discussion of how
multiculturalism can affect an economy's structure.
(3.) Two of every three immigrants to Canada arc visible
minorities. The Employment Equity Act defines visible minorities as
"persons, other than Aboriginal peoples, who are non-Caucasian in
race or non-white in colour." The regulations to the Act specify
the following groups as visible minorities: Chinese, South Asians,
Blacks, Arabs and West Asians, Filipinos, Southeast Asians, Latin
Americans, Japanese, Koreans, and Pacific Islanders.
(4.) These will include both "slopes" and
"intercepts" in a linear model, as well as other terms in more
complicated functional specifications.
(5.) It is also the case that not just any combination of diversity
markers will resonate with the public. Further, combinations comprising
too many markers will have no mass; e.g., it may be hard to find many
individuals in the social category of bilingual, non-immigrant, Chinese,
male, disabled, atheist from the Maritimes.
(6.) Gender is an important identity marker or "fundamental
trait" in labour economics. all economists acknowledge that labour
supply responses, as well as market opportunities, differ for men and
women, so no special pleading is ever necessary to prompt labour
economists to consider gender as a diversity marker in research or
policy concerning labour markets. We simply choose to focus on
immigrants for narrative presentation purposes.
(7.) We employ data from the master (non-public) files of the 1998
Adult Education and Training Survey (AETS). Since the 1998 AETS
distinguished immigrants and the native-born for the first time, we are
able to compare the training activities of immigrants to comparable
Canadians (see Hum and Simpson (2002c) for details). Private sector
workplace training is examined in Hum and Simpson (1996), and
government-sponsored training programs are assessed in Hum and Simpson
(2002b)
(8.) Ethnic categories are limited and incomplete in the AETS, but
we were able to identify categories such as Blacks, which we use for
illustrative purposes here.
(9.) A large economic literature exists and continues on these
topics. See the relevant essays in Wahid (2002) for non-technical
explanations of the seminal Nobel contributions of Tinbergen and
Mundell.
(10.) The discussion in the main text is deliberately kept general
but the federal-provincial aspect is especially noteworthy in our
example respecting labour markets, since much of the program delivery is
sub-national or provincial. Occupational Health and Workers'
Compensation are administered provincially; minimum wage rates are set
by provinces; union certification and regulation is at the provincial
level, as is governance of the professional self-regulating bodies
(lawyers, doctors, etc.) that assess credentials; and employment equity
legislation, to name a few. For our particular focus, education and
training is delivered at the provincial level. Immigration is, of
course, a shared jurisdiction.
REFERENCES
Abbott, M. and C. Beach. (1993). "Immigrant earnings
differentials and birth-year effects for men in Canada:
Post-war--1972." Canadian Journal of Economics 26(3): 505-524.
Baker, M. and D. Benjamin. (1994). "The performance of
immigrants in the Canadian labour market." Journal of Labor
Economics 12(3): 369-405.
Baker, M. and D. Benjamin. (1997). "The role of the family in
immigrants' labor-market activity: An evaluation of alternative
explanations." American Economic Review 87(4): 705-727.
Beach, C. and C. Worswick. (1993). "Is there a double-negative
effect on the earnings of immigrant women?" Canadian Public
Policy/Analyse de Politique XIX(1): 36-53.
Bloom, D. E., G. Grenier, et al. (1995). "The changing labour
market position of Canadian immigrants." Canadian Journal of
Economics XXVIII(4b): 987-1005.
Frideres, J. (2002). "Immigrants, integration and the
intersection of identities." Paper commissioned for Seminar on
Intersections of Diversity.
Grant, M. (1999). "Evidence of new immigrant assimilation in
Canada." Canadian Journal of Economics 32(4): 930-955.
Hum, D. (1995). "Multicultural society and economic
structure." In H. Braun and W. Klooss (eds.), Multiculturalism in
North America and Europe: Social practices--Literary visions, Trier,
Germany: Wissenschaftlicher Verlag Trier.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (1996). Maintaining a competitive
workforce: Employer-based training in Canada. Montreal: Institute for
Research in Public Policy.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (1999). "Wage opportunities for
visible minorities in Canada." Canadian Public Policy 25(3):
379-394.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (2000). "Closing the wage gap:
Economic assimilation of Canadian immigrants reconsidered." Journal
of International Migration and Integration 1 (4): 427-441.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (2002a). "Disability onsets among
aging Canadians: Evidence from panel data." Canadian Journal on
Aging 21(1): 117-136.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (2002b). "Public training programs in
Canada: A meta-evaluation." Canadian Journal of Program Evaluation 17(1): 119-138.
Hum, D. and W. Simpson. (2003). "Job-related training activity
by immigrants to Canada." Canadian Public Policy 29(4): 1-22.
Lambertus, S. (2002). "Canada's Aboriginal peoples and
intersecting identity markers: Research and policy implications for
multiculturalism." Paper commissioned for Seminar on Intersections
of Diversity.
Li, P. S. (2000). "Earnings disparities between immigrants and
native-born Canadians." Canadian Review of Anthropology and
Sociology 37(3): 289-311.
McDonald, J. and C. Worswick. (1998). "The earnings of
immigrant men in Canada: Job tenure, cohort, and macroeconomic conditions." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 51(3): 465-482.
Meng, R. (1987). "The earnings of Canadian immigrant and
native-born males." Applied Economics 19:1107-1119.
Miller, P. (1992). "The earnings of Asian male immigrants in
the Canadian labor market." International Migration Review 26(4):
1222-1247.
Wahid, A., ed. (2002). Frontiers of economics: Nobel laureates of
the twentieth century. Westport, CN: Greenwood Press. 18-27; 381-389.