Contract employees.
Sridhar, R. ; Panda, S.
Introduction
Post the onset of economic liberalization in the early 1990s, many
Indian companies relied on the conventional wisdom that "the only
way to succeed in an era of global competition is to take advantage of
the benefits of a largely unregulated, non-unionized, and low-wage
environment" (Pfeffer, 1998). This conventional wisdom, along with
a host of other commonly held beliefs, predicated the employment
practices that companies followed in order to leverage numerical labor
flexibility. Numerous employment types were deployed to obtain labor
cost advantages--temporary, trainee, casual, contract. Fast forward to
recent times and we find that these employment practices are now the
major cause of labor unrest and industrial strife. While the arguments
in favor of deploying multiple employment types are familiar --surplus
labor, uncertain market demand, the ambiguity and inconsistencies in the
Contract Labor Act--the fact is that employees and unions perceive this
practice of multiple employment types as pure exploitation.
While companies should explore the use of different employment
modes to allocate work in view of the pressure of achieving both
efficiency and flexibility, it is important that a logical and
consistent approach be taken to arrive at decisions pertaining to the
nature of employment at the company level. It is also appropriate that
as with other capital investments, the management of human capital
should be categorized into "make" or "buy"
decisions. Although the make-or-buy distinction may appear simplistic,
the growing number of subtle variations on this theme makes the
effective management of employment modes at once complicated,
contentious, and more directly related to company effectiveness (Lepak
& Snell, 1999).
In this paper, we discuss the logic that companies could use to
arrive at an employment policy. We also describe an approach adopted by
our company to manage contract employees that is proving effective. We
consider contract employees to be an integral part of the workforce
contributing to company operations. Moving beyond the immediate benefit
of cost arbitrage, an "investment" approach is being adopted
for this segment of the workforce. Apart from managing basic issues of
compliance, the principles of industrial democracy, equality, and equity
are core elements in our management of this segment of employees.
Another critical shift in our approach in this area is to partner with
specialized agencies (Professional Service Providers) to ensure a more
holistic and professional approach towards managing non-core jobs.
However, before discussing employment mode selection logic and the
management of contract employees, we consider it pertinent to briefly
examine India's formidable labor legislative framework and its
impact on employment and industrial progress.
Indian Labor Legislation
The World Bank in its India Country Overview (2008) states:
"India's labor regulations--among the most restrictive and
complex in the world--have constrained the growth of the formal
manufacturing sector where these laws have their widest application.
Better designed labor regulations can attract more labor-intensive
investment and create jobs for India's unemployed millions and
those trapped in poor quality jobs. Given the country's momentum of
growth, the window of opportunity must not be lost for improving the job
prospects for the 80 million new entrants who are expected to join the
workforce over the next decade." There are over 50 national laws
and many, many more state-level laws. Traditionally, Indian governments
at the central and state levels have sought to ensure a high degree of
protection for workers. For instance, a permanent worker can only be
terminated for proven misconduct or habitual absence and the legal
process could, and usually does, take years to complete.
While the Indian legislature fully endorses the general view of
employers that the legislative framework requires drastic amendments,
the political will to bring about changes has been absent. Indian
employers find that efficiency and flexibility are fettered by three
labor enactments in particular: The Industrial Disputes Act, 1947; The
Trade Union Act, 1926; and The Contract Labor (Regulation &
Abolition) Act, 1970.
The Industrial Disputes Act (IDA), though meant to promote
industrial harmony by resolving disputes, in reality slows down change
and impedes labor numerical flexibility. Particular attention has been
paid to its Chapter V-B, introduced by an amendment in 1976, which
requires companies employing 300 or more workers to obtain government
permission for layoffs, retrenchments and closures. A further amendment
in 1982 (which took effect in 1984) expanded its ambit by reducing the
threshold to 100 workers. It is argued that since permission is
difficult to obtain, employers are reluctant to hire workers whom they
cannot easily get rid of. Job security laws thus protect a tiny minority
of workers in the organized sector and prevent the expansion of
industrial employment that could benefit the mass of workers beyond its
compass. It is also argued that the restriction on retrenchment
adversely affects workplace discipline, while setting the threshold at
100 has discouraged factories from expanding to economic scales of
production, thereby harming productivity. Several other sections of the
IDA allegedly have similar effects, because they increase workers'
bargaining strength and thereby raise labor costs either directly
through wages or indirectly by inhibiting work reorganization in
response to changes in demand and technology.
The Trade Union Act on its part is generally perceived as a
millstone and a costly distraction by employers. It allows seven or more
members to apply for union registration leading to multiple unions in a
work location which in turn hampers recognition of representative unions
by the management. Further, under the existing Act, up to 50 per cent of
the members of the executive of a union can be outsiders resulting more
often than not in the politicization of union leadership.
The Contract Labor Act (CLA) was legislated to regulate the
conditions under which contract labor are employed and abolish their
employment where unwarranted. Four guidelines in the Act are to be
considered by the government in deciding whether abolishment of
employment of contract labor is warranted: whether the work is of
perennial nature; incidental or necessary for the work of the
establishment; sufficient to employ a considerable number of whole-time
workmen; and whether the work is being done ordinarily through regular
workmen in that establishment or a similar establishment. Widespread
criticism of the Act focuses on the fact that it does not provide a
clear definition of contract labor, and when it comes to abolishment of
contract labor in industries or establishments, the guidance and
directives often come from judiciary rather than promulgated law. In
addition, the Act lays down onerous conditions that are meant to
regulate the employment of contract employees, which contractors and
employers find difficult to comply with. Hence, the CLA, paradoxically,
provides fecund breeding ground for labor problems and disputes. In the
recent past, the country has witnessed several incidents of major
industrial unrest, many of them arising due to the provisions of the
Act.
Determination of Employment Modes
Porter (1985) suggested that it is a company's valuable and
unique activities that are the primary components of its competitive
advantage, which help it to differentiate its value chain from those of
its competitors. Building on Porter's suggestion, Lepak and Snell
(1999) use the dimensions of value (human resource skills that help
companies to improve efficiency and effectiveness) and uniqueness
(company specificity) of human capital, to identify four employment
modes: internal development; acquisition; contracting and alliance.
Internal development and acquisition are internal employment modes
providing the benefits of stability and predictability of a
company's skills and capabilities, better coordination and control,
enhanced socialization and lower transaction costs. However, internal
modes may force companies to incur costs stemming from administering the
employment relationship and constrain a company's ability to adapt
to environmental changes, particularly those that influence the demand
for labor. Contracting and alliance are external employment modes that
enable companies to decrease overhead and administrative costs, balance
workforce requirements, and enhance flexibility. They also provide
companies with more discretion in both the number and types of employees
used while focusing critical resources on the development of core
capabilities.
More recently, Porter has argued (Magretta, 2012) that the logic of
core competences has led many companies to pursue outsourcing without
thinking through the strategic consequences. Instead of trying to
determine which activities are core, he asks a different question:
"which activities are generic and which activities are tailored?
Generic activities --those that cannot be meaningfully tailored to a
company's (strategic) position--can be safely outsourced to more
efficient external suppliers. Companies almost always make outsourcing
decisions for short-term cost savings. These decisions limit the
opportunities for uniqueness and fit in the company's strategy, and
push an entire industry into greater homogenization (Magretta, 2012). We
believe that companies should answer Porter's question before
reaching decisions on outsourcing or contracting.
In India, contract employees constitute a large part of the total
wage employment. Most of these workers are engaged in generic activities
(loading and unloading of goods and materials; catering including
canteen services; security services; civil and construction works;
electrical/air conditioning/painting/whitewashing; housekeeping
services; computer maintenance, etc.) and those necessitated by
seasonal/occasional requirement or in situations where there is a
temporary increase of work. However, many companies today engage
contract employees in regular and core activities, those that require
"tailoring" to fit with a company's strategy. Saini
(2010) cites studies that have found the share of contract employees in
wage employment to be as high as 60 to 70 per cent as against the
official claims of 15 to 26 per cent. There are also establishments
where the number of regular employees is just a few hundred, but that of
contract employees runs into several thousands. Although regular and
contract employees are often found to work on same or similar tasks,
regular employees earn between two and six times the wages earned by
contract employees. No wonder, employers are accused of
"misusing" and exploiting this category of employees.
Continued reliance on external modes of employment is almost certain to
lead to labor disputes and mitigates the development of core
capabilities for long-term company performance. Lepak and Snell (1999)
argue that the discussion on employment modes should not be reduced to
an either/or distinction, but companies should use the four employment
modes simultaneously, based on the dimensions of value and uniqueness in
their idiosyncratic contexts.
Within in our company, in our business division, contract employees
are engaged to perform generic activities such as housekeeping,
gardening, material loading and unloading and construction work, and are
not deployed in perennial production activities. Our efforts focus on
raising their productivity levels by providing them with automated tools
and training them to adopt efficient work methods. Whereas some years
ago the average ratio of regular to contract employees in our factories
was 2:1, this figure has improved to 3:1 today and our target is to
stabilize at 4:1. We believe that this approach is helping us consider
better wages and benefits to contract employees and reduce the level of
employee dissatisfaction. We urge companies to engage in activity
analysis, generic and tailored, and use both internal and external modes
of employment to allocate human capital. This will provide an
unassailable logic that could help companies explain and defend their
make-and-buy decisions on human capital. Though employee costs could
rise in the short-term, in the longer term companies would stand to gain
in better employment relations and more durable competitive advantage.
Management of Contract Employees
Lepak and Snell (1999) view each employment mode as an inherently
different form of employment relationship, shaped by the company, in
terms of an exchange agreement between individuals and their companies.
They also consider patterns of HR practices--or HR configurations--as
helping to define the employment mode, maintain the employment
relationship and support the strategic characteristics of human capital.
When contracting is chosen as the employment mode, a
"transactional" employment relationship comes into being and
the HR configuration is one of "compliance".
In India, employers emphasize arm's length relationships with
contract employees, focusing on the work to be done, the results to be
accomplished, the terms of the contract with contractors --and virtually
nothing else. Given the transactional nature of contract work, HR
activities tend to focus only on securing compliance with the terms and
conditions of the contract. Rules and regulations governing work are
strictly enforced and specific provisions regarding work protocols are
upheld with out any breach. This may sound reasonable, but in numerous
instances contract employment practices are found to be unreasonable and
unfair. We discussed the practice of deploying contract employees to
perform activities that reasonably should go to regular employees.
Though the principle of equity would dictate that contract employees be
paid at par with regular employees for performing the same or similar
nature of work, in practice, the wage differential tends to be steeply
inequitable, which labor activists term "naked capitalism".
The Contract Labor Act provisions and rules and other labor legislations
are often violated with employees not having access to basic amenities
at the work place; occupational health and safety standards not being
applied and enforced; overtime pay being denied; and medical and social
security contributions not being made. So many companies loudly and
often proclaim their zero tolerance for poor quality and waste. We
consider it time that they apply equal fervor to contract employment
violations. The consequences of not doing so are clear and present as
evidenced by contract employee agitations in some companies. There have
also been demands to provide contract employees with rights for
representation and dialogue.
We are of the view that even if contract employees are engaged to
perform generic activities they need to experience
"inclusion". If contract employees feel excluded and alienated
social tensions at the work place will rise, impacting the morale of
regular employees as well. Moreover, generic activities have a role to
play in the overall operations of the establishment; otherwise they
would have been entirely unnecessary. Porter and others have suggested
the classification of generic and tailored activities to arrive at
make-or-buy decisions on human capital, not to deny contract employees
their due. Though a "transactional" employment relationship is
found to prevail when the employment mode is one of contracting, we find
the study of Tsui, Pearce, Porter and Tripoli (1997) illuminating in
answering the question, "Does investment in employees pay
off?" They examined employee responses from ten companies under
four types of employee-company relationships, as defined from the
employer's perspective.
These four types are: (a) Quasi-spot contract, where the employer
offers short term, purely economic inducements in exchange for
well-specified contributions by the employee; (b) Mutual investment
which involves a combination of economic and social exchange. In this
case, the employer offers an extended consideration of an
employee's wellbeing as well as an investment in the
employee's career within the company. In exchange, the
employee's obligations and contributions include working on job
assignments that fall outside of prior agreements or expertise,
assisting junior colleagues, accepting job transfers, and, in general,
being willing to consider the unit's or company's interests as
important as core job duties; (c) Under investment, where the employee
is expected to undertake broad and open-ended obligations, while the
employer reciprocates with short-term and specified monetary rewards,
with no commitment to a long-term relationship or investment in the
employee's training or career; and (d) Over investment, where the
employee performs only a well-specified set of job focused activities,
but the employer offers open-ended and broad-ranging rewards, including
training and a commitment to provide the employee with career
opportunities. The study found, in general, that employees performed
better on core tasks, demonstrated more citizenship behavior, and
expressed a higher level of affective commitment to an employer, when
they worked in a mutual investment or over investment (by the employer)
relationship than when they worked in a quasi-spot contract or under
investment relationship. The finding that both the mutual investment and
over investment approaches perform substantially better than the other
two employee-company relationships suggests that offering open-ended
inducements and a high level of social exchange to employees is more
important than balance in the exchange. This has important implications
for human resource management practices for regular and contract
employees.
Our Approach
The management approach that we are seeding in our business
division with regard to contract employees seeks inclusion of those
employees based on "investments" being made in them. Some key
features of our approach are:
--Contract employees are to be considered as a category of
employees just as regular, supervisory, front line, and managerial
categories would be. To reinforce this, we have attempted a name
change--from contract labor to employees of service providers (ESPs).
--Treat contract employees distinctly, but without discrimination.
No discrimination when it comes to employee amenities at the workplace,
shift timings, work breaks timings, etc. For instance, one of our
factories celebrated its centenary this year. All regular employees were
given a memento to commemorate the year. Nothing new there. But what was
a welcome "new" was that all the contract employees engaged in
the factory were given a memento as well--no discrimination.
--100 per cent compliance to laws applicable to contract employees
including work place safety, with zero tolerance for any violation. The
factory's HR department works with contractors to ensure that
contract employees are not denied their dues and their grievances, if
any, are redressed quickly. It is also our intent to conduct employee
satisfaction studies for this category of employees in the near future.
--Contract employees are to enjoy the freedom to form collectives.
Two of our factories have unions representing contract employees.
Periodic Long Term Agreements are entered into between the contractors
and the contract employees after due collective bargaining. The process
of negotiations is facilitated by managers of the factory's HR
department. These agreements ensure that contract employees enjoy the
same rights and obligations as regular employees. Where there are no
collectives, we ensure that contractors pay their employees fair wages,
determined on the basis of region-cum-industry surveys.
--We encourage and support contractors to have
"employee-connect" events; provide training for skill up
gradation; and consider them for regular employment when vacancies
arise.
Conclusion
We consider it apt to paraphrase Max Frisch, the Swiss playwright
and novelist, to sum up the discussion: "We asked for contract
labor. We got people instead." And people want a "Decent Work
Agenda" to be fulfilled--full and productive employment, rights at
work, social protection and promotion of social dialogue (ILO Manual,
2012). This isn't too much to ask and, therefore, certainly not too
much to give. Whether employees perform generic or tailored activities
is an important consideration in deciding their employment mode. But it
is more important to acknowledge that by working together they can boost
a company's performance and ensure its success.
R Sridhar & S Panda (E-Mail: Swarup.Panda@itc) are from ITC
Limited.
References
ILO Manual (2012), Decent Work Indicators: Concepts and
Definitions, International Labor Office, Geneva.
Lepak, D.P. & Snell, S.A. (1999), "The Human Resource
Architecture: Toward a Theory of Human Capital Allocation and
Development", Academy of Management Review, 24(1), 31-48.
Magretta, J. (2012), Understanding Michael Porter: The Essential
Guide to Competition and Strategy, Boston, Massachusetts. Harvard
Business Review Press.
Pfeffer, J. (1998), The Human Equation: Building Profits By Putting
People First, Boston, Massachusetts. Harvard Business Review Press.
Porter, M. (1985), Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining
Superior Performance, New York. Free Press.
Saini, D.S. (2010), "The Contract Labor Act 1970: Issues and
Concerns", Indian Journal of Industrial Relations, 46(1).
Tsui, A.S., Pearce, J.L., Porter, L.W. & Tripoli, A.M.
(1997)," Alternative Approaches to the Employee--Organization
Relationship: Does Investment in Employees Pay Off?" Academy of
Management Journal, 40 (5), 1089-1121.