Informal employment revisited: theories, data & policies.
Chen, Martha Alter ; Vanek, Joann
Introduction
Informal employment is back on the policy agenda. (1) It represents
a major share of the workforce in most developing countries and is on
the rise in developed countries. Across the developing world, the
majority of informal workers are poor; and the majority of working poor
are informally employed. Adding to these policy concerns are the
lingering impacts of the Great Recession on employment and the global
crisis of youth unemployment.
This paper seeks to provide a summary overview of recent rethinking
and recent data on informal employment, particularly in developing
countries. Section I details two international statistical
definitions--of "informal sector" and "informal
employment"--and presents recent data on non-agricultural informal
employment. Section II discusses to "formalize the informal
economy" debate and presents a comprehensive framework for
responding to informal enterprises and informal employment. Section III
analyzes why existing labor market models and regulations need to be
re-examined in light of the reality and complexity of informal
employment today. The paper concludes that employment should be the
cornerstone of the development agenda and that economic diversity should
be the cornerstone of the future economy.
I. Statistical Definitions & Data
International Statistical Definitions: In 1993, the International
Conference of Labour Statisticians adopted an international statistical
definition of the "informal sector" to refer to employment and
production that takes place in unincorporated small and/or unregistered
enterprises. But soon thereafter, beginning in 1997, the International
Labor Office (ILO), the international Expert Group on Informal Sector
Statistics (called the Delhi Group), and the global network Women in
Informal Employment: Globalizing and Organizing (WIEGO) began working
together to broaden the concept and definition to incorporate certain
types of informal employment that had not been included in the
enterprise-based concept and definition of the informal sector. They
sought to include the whole of work-related informality, as it is
manifested in industrialized, transition and developing economies and
the real world dynamics in labor markets today, particularly the
employment arrangements of the working poor.
The expanded definition focuses on the nature of employment in
addition to the characteristics of enterprises and includes all types of
informal employment both inside and outside informal enterprises. This
expanded definition was endorsed by the International Labor Conference
(ILC) in 2002 and the International Conference of Labor Statisticians
(ICLS) in 2003: statisticians refer to this expanded notion as
"informal employment."
Informal employment is, by design, a large and heterogeneous
category. For purposes of analysis and policymaking it is useful to,
first, sub-divide informal employment into self-employment and wage
employment, and then within these broad categories, into more
homogeneous sub-categories according to status in employment, as
follows: (2)
Informal self-employment including:
* employers in informal enterprises
* own account workers in informal enterprises
* contributing family workers (in informal and formal enterprises)
* members of informal producers' cooperatives (where these
exist)
Informal wage employment: employees hired without social protection
contributions by formal or informal enterprises or as paid domestic
workers by households. Certain types of wage work are more likely than
others to be informal. These include:
* employees of informal enterprises
* casual or day labourers
* temporary or part-time workers
* paid domestic workers
* contract workers
* unregistered or undeclared workers
* industrial outworkers (also called home workers)
This expanded definition extends the focus from enterprises that
are not legally regulated to include employment relationships that are
not legally regulated or socially protected. It also serves to focus
attention on informal workers: i.e., those who are informally employed.
(3) This employment-centered focus has been accompanied by significant
rethinking of the composition, causes, and consequences of informal
employment. Today, informal employment is widely recognized to include a
range of self-employed persons, who mainly work in unincorporated small
or unregistered enterprises, as well as a range of wage workers who are
employed without employer contributions to social protection.
To sum up, there are three related official statistical terms and
definitions which are often used imprecisely and interchangeably: the
informal sector refers to the production and employment that takes place
in unincorporated small or unregistered enterprises (1993 ICLS);
informal employment refers to employment without legal and social
protection --both inside and outside the informal sector (2003 ICLS);
and the informal economy refers to all units, activities, and workers so
defined and the output from them. Together, they form the broad base of
the workforce and economy, both nationally and globally.
Recent National Data & Regional Estimates: Since the expanded
definition of "informal employment" was adopted by the 2002
International Labor Conference and the 2003 International Conference of
Labor Statisticians, many countries have begun using this definition of
informal employment in the collection and tabulation of national labor
force data. What follows is a summary of recent analyses of available
data on the size and significance of non-agricultural informal
employment compiled by the ILO and the WIEGO Network for an update of a
2002 statistical publication called Women and Men in the Informal
Economy: A Statistical Picture. (4)
Analysis of the data compiled by the ILO and WIEGO suggests that
informal employment represents a significant share of non-agricultural
employment in developing regions: ranging from 45 per cent in the Middle
East and North Africa (5) to 51 per cent in Latin America to 65 per cent
in East and Southeast Asia to 66 per cent in sub-Saharan Africa
(excluding South Africa and other countries in Southern Africa with a
relatively low prevalence of informal employment) to 82 per cent in
South Asia (Vanek et al 2012).
There is significant variation by country within the regions: from
31 per cent (Turkey) to 57 per cent (West Bank and Gaza) in the Middle
East and North Africa; from 40 per cent (Uruguay) to 75 per cent
(Bolivia) in Latin America; from 33 per cent (urban China) to 42 per
cent (Thailand) to 73 per cent (Indonesia) in East and Southeast Asia;
from 33 per cent (South Africa) to 82 per cent (Mali) in sub-Saharan
Africa; from 62 per cent (Sri Lanka) to 83 per cent (India) in South
Asia.
In those countries and regions where agriculture still employs a
large share of the workforce, the share of total informal employment in
total employment is likely to be higher still (Ibid). In some countries
which measure informal employment in agriculture, for example India,
informal employment represents more than 90 percent of total employment.
Non-agricultural informal employment is about equally split between
wage employment and self-employment in urban China, Latin America and
the Caribbean, East and South East Asia, and South Asia; but dominated
by self-employment in sub-Saharan Africa (Vanek et al, 2012).
In many regions and in urban China informal employment is a more
important source of employment for women than for men. In sub-Saharan
Africa 74 per cent of women's employment (non-agricultural) is
informal in contrast to 61 per cent of men's; in Latin America and
the Caribbean, (6) 54 per cent in contrast to 48 per cent; in South
Asia, 83 per cent in contrast to 82 per cent; and, in urban China, 36
per cent in contrast to 30 per cent. However in all regions men comprise
a greater share of the informal workforce because women's labour
force participation rates are lower than men's.
II. Policy Responses
The Formalization Debate: At the heart of the policy debates on the
informal economy is the question of whether and how to formalize the
informal economy. Different observers have different notions of what
formalization of the informal economy means. To some, it means shifting
informal workers to formal wage jobs--but this requires creating more
formal wage jobs. To others, it means registering and taxing informal
enterprises. For informal workers, many of whom already pay taxes (such
as VAT) or fees of various kinds (e.g. license fees to operate and/or
site fees to operate in specific locations) or are willing to pay taxes
or fees in return for benefits, it means gaining access to legal and
social protection as well as support services (e.g. skills or business
training) and being allowed to organize and to be represented in
relevant rule-setting, policymaking, and collective bargaining
processes.
Further, it is important to ensure that formalization offers the
benefits and protection that come with being formal and does not simply
impose the costs of becoming formal. For the self-employed,
formalization should not mean just obtaining a license, registering
their accounts, and paying taxes: these represent, to them, the costs of
entry into the formal economy. What they would like is to receive the
benefits of operating formally in return for paying these costs,
including: enforceable commercial contracts; legal ownership of their
place of business and means of production; tax breaks and incentive
packages to increase their competitiveness; membership in trade
associations; protection against creditors and clear bankruptcy rules;
and social protection.
What about informal wage workers? To them, formalization means
obtaining a formal wage job--or formalizing their current job- with a
secure contract, worker benefits, membership in a formal trade union,
and employer contributions to their social protection. It is important
to highlight that formalizing wage work requires a focus on employers,
as employers are more likely than employees to avoid compliance with
labor regulations. In this context, it should be noted that many
informal wage workers work for formal firms and households, not just for
informal enterprises.
Finally, therefore, it is important to note that formalization has
different dimensions beyond just registering and paying taxes,
including: receiving the legal and social protection enjoyed by formal
firms and formal workers; receiving the tax holidays and incentive
packages enjoyed by formal firms; being allowed to organize and to have
representative voice in rule-setting and policymaking processes; and
more. Policymakers should recognize these various dimensions of
formalization and the fact that formalization is not, therefore, a
one-step process but rather an ongoing process of extending benefits of
formalization incrementally to informal workers. In asking informal
workers to register and pay taxes, they should offer informal workers
one or more benefits of formalization: asking each group of workers
which benefit/s of formalization would be most important to securing
their livelihoods. In short, policymakers should consider the optimal
dimensions and sequence of formalization from the perspective of
different categories of informal workers.
In sum, what is required is an approach to formalization of the
informal economy which is comprehensive in approach but context-specific
in design and practice. A comprehensive approach for formalizing the
informal economy is outlined in Box 1:
Box 1 Formalization of the Informal Economy: A Comprehensive
Approach
1. Formalization of Informal Enterprises
* registration and taxation:
** simplified registration procedures
** progressive registration fees
* appropriate legal and regulatory frameworks, including:
** enforceable commercial contracts
** private property rights
** use of public space
** occupational health and safety regulation
* benefits of operating formally:
** access to finance and market information
** access to public infrastructure and services
** enforceable commercial contracts
** limited liability
** clear bankruptcy and default rules
** access to government subsidies and incentives,
including procurement bids and export
promotion packages
** membership in formal business associations
** access to a formal system of social security
2. Formalization of Informal Jobs
* legal recognition and protection as workers
* rights and benefits of being formally employed:
** freedom from discrimination
** minimum wage
** occupational health and safety measures
** employer contributions to health and pensions
** right to organize and bargain collectively
** membership in formal trade unions
As outlined above, formalization of the informal economy can and
should take different forms, including: shifting informal workers to
formal jobs; registering and taxing informal enterprises; providing
business incentives and support services to informal enterprises;
securing legal and social protection for the informal workforce;
recognizing the organizations of informal workers; and allowing their
representatives to take part in rule-setting, policymaking, and
collective bargaining processes.
However, the limits to formalization need to be understood. First,
it should be recognized that formalization is not a one-time process
involving a specified set of steps. Rather, formalization should be seen
as a gradual on-going process involving incremental steps and different
dimensions leading towards varying degrees and types of formality.
Second, it should be recognized that formalization will not proceed
quickly or automatically for all those who choose to formalize. The
bureaucratic procedures and incentives for registered informal
businesses need to be retooled and streamlined. Labor standards and
benefits for informal workers need to be carefully negotiated by
employers, workers, and government. Third, it should be recognized that
formalization will not be feasible or desirable for all informal
enterprises or all informal wage workers. Rather, it should be assumed
that many informal enterprises and informal wage workers will continue
to do what they do and remain informal or semi-formal (at least in some
dimensions) for the foreseeable future.
A Comprehensive Policy Framework
Clearly, no single, overarching policy goal or prescription can
address the concerns of all categories of informal enterprises and
informal workers. What is needed is a comprehensive policy framework to
address informality with the following broad goals:
1. Create more formal jobs--through employment-centered growth
2. Regulate informal enterprises and informal jobs--through
appropriate regulations and incentives
3. Extend state protection to the informal workforce, especially
the working poor--including both social protection (health, pensions,
and disability) and legal protection (property rights, commercial
rights, and labor rights)
4. Increase the productivity of informal enterprises and the income
of the informal workforce, especially the working poor--through
financial services, enterprises support, and basic infrastructure
services but also through a favourable policy and regulatory environment
and more equitable terms of trade
5. Promote participatory policy-making, rule-setting, and
collective bargaining processes- involving representatives of
organizations of informal workers, especially the working poor
There is growing consensus worldwide around these five broad goals,
especially in support of the working poor in the informal economy. These
five goals are depicted as a "3 by 3" framework in Box 2: with
the first two goals as # 1 and 2 and the last three goals under # 3.
Box 2 "3 x 3" Policy Framework
# 1 - Expand formal employment opportunities
# 2 - Regulate as many informal enterprises
and informal jobs as desirable and feasible:n
* Create incentives for informal enterprises
to formalizen
* Create incentives for employers, both for
mal & informal, to hire workers with for
mal contracts, protections, and benefits
# 3 - Increase returns to labor of the informal
workforce through...n
* Protection of the informal workforce: lagal
and social protectionn
* Promotion of the informal workforce:fair
policy and regulatory environment & sup
portive infrastructure and servicesn
* Participation of the informal workforce:
participatory policy-making, rule-setting,
and collective bargaining institutions and
processes that include representatives of
informal workers
To illustrate how this framework should be implemented in practice,
consider the urban informal workforce. In most cities around the world,
there is an acute shortage of jobs due to various factors, including
increased population but also investment decisions that favor relocation
of industries outside cities and/or use of capital-intensive
technologies. Government and the private sector need to rethink their
investment decisions and place a priority on generating urban jobs.
Meanwhile, in most cities around the world, existing employment
opportunities in the informal economy are being undermined or destroyed
due to urban renewal schemes that demolish the places of work of the
urban informal workforce; urban planning that fails to incorporate urban
informal livelihoods in city plans; and municipal procurement policies
that exclude urban informal operators from bidding for contracts for
goods and services.
In this context, most of the urban informal workforce pays taxes,
fees, or bribes of various kinds to various local authorities simply to
be able to pursue their livelihoods. What they receive in return is
negligible--often negative. Most home-based producers do not receive the
basic infrastructure that would make their home-cum-workplace more
productive; they pay residential (rather than commercial) rates for
utilities, and are subject to zoning regulations that restrict
commercial activities in residential areas. Most street vendors are
treated as criminals subject to evictions, confiscations, and
harassments. Few waste pickers are recognized for their contributions to
waste management and recycling, many are denied access to waste, and
most are not allowed to bid for solid waste management contracts. All
three groups would be willing to register and pay appropriate taxes to
the city, if they would receive benefits in return--including the right
to pursue their livelihoods.
Urban planners and local authorities need to embrace the informal
economy--it is the main generator of jobs and livelihoods in most cities
in the developing world. They need to include urban informal
livelihoods, not just urban informal settlements, in their urban plans
and local economic development. This will require urban planners and
city officials to develop an approach to urban policies, planning, and
practices that includes rather than excludes--urban informal livelihoods
and the urban informal workforce. To begin with, they need to stop doing
harm to urban informal livelihoods.
III. Rethinking Labor
Historically, neo-classical economists have assumed that labor
markets include the employed (thought to be employees) and the
unemployed and functioned through the interaction of employees and
employers. However, development economists pointed out that labor
markets in developing countries are dualistic: consisting of a
traditional/informal and a modern/formal sector (Lewis, 1954). Some
development economists, notably the Nobel Laureate W. Arthur Lewis,
predicted that economic development in developing countries would, in
the long-term, generate enough modern jobs to absorb surplus labor from
the traditional economy. By the mid-1960s, however, this optimism began
to give way to concerns about persistent widespread unemployment and
under-employment, even in countries that were growing economically
(Singer, 1970; ILO, 1972).
These concerns persist even today. Informal employment appears to
be on the rise in both developed and developing countries. In most
developing countries today, the self-employed constitute a large share
of the labor force; the informal wage employed another large share: and
formal wage workers a relatively small share. This reality calls for a
fundamental rethinking of labor markets.
Self-employed workers behave in fundamentally different ways than
dependent wage workers: they both supply and demand labor. They compete
in markets for goods and services, not in labor markets. Their
employment--and productivity --is driven by a demand for their goods and
services, not their labor. Labor regulations and labor market policies
have limited salience for the self-employed: as the vast majority of
them are own account operators who do not hire others. What matters to
the self-employed are macropolicies that help shape the demand for their
goods and services and sector-specific policies that regulate who can do
what, and where, as well as who receives government support and
protection.
Even for informal wage workers, existing labor laws and regulations
have limited salience. This is because historically, around the world,
the "employment relationship" has represented the cornerstone
- the central legal concept--around which labor law and collective
bargaining agreements have sought to recognize and protect the rights of
workers. Whatever its precise definition in different national contexts,
it has represented "a universal notion which creates a link between
a person, called the 'employee' (frequently referred to as
'the worker') with another person, called the
'employer' to whom she or he provides labor or services under
certain conditions in return for remuneration" (ILO, 2003: 2).
The concept of employment relationship has always excluded those
workers who are self-employed. But also an increasing share of wage
workers has no legal recognition or protection because their employment
relationship is either:
* Disguised: The employment relationship is deliberately disguised
by giving it the appearance of a relationship of a different legal
nature. For example, the lead firm in a subcontracting chain may claim
that it has a "sales-purchase"--or commercial relationship
with those who produce goods for it, rather than a subcontracted
employment relationship.
* Ambiguous: The employment relationship is objectively ambiguous
so there is doubt about whether or not an employment relationship really
exists. This is the case, for instance, with street vendors who depend
on a single supplier for goods or sell goods on commission for a
distributor.
* Not clearly defined: The employment relationship clearly exists
but it is not clear who the employer is, what rights the worker has, and
who is responsible for securing these rights.
For example, in value chain production, it is not clear who the
real employer is: the lead firm, the supply firm, or the subcontractor.
Similarly, in the case of temporary work, it is not clear who the real
employer is: the agency that supplies temporary workers or the firms
that hire them on a temporary basis (Ibid.).
It is important to note that, in some cases, the worker colludes
with the employer to avoid regulation. But it is also important to note
that, in many cases, it is the employer who seeks to disguise the
employment relationship or otherwise avoid regulations; and that many
such employers operate formal firms, not informal enterprises.
In sum, it is important to recognize that the relevance of existing
labor market models and labor regulations is decreasing around the
world. What is needed is a new model of the labor market that takes into
account different types of self-employment and different types of wage
employment. What is also needed is a thorough re-examination of which
laws, regulations, and policies impinge on which categories of informal
and formal employment in today's world, and with what impact. In
addition to labor laws and regulations, these are likely to include
laws, regulations, and policies that govern markets for goods and
services; specific sectors (e.g. agriculture, manufacturing, trade and
other services); urban planning; value chain dynamics and relationships;
government taxation, expenditure and procurement.
IV. Moving Forward
Moving Employment Center Stage: In 2000, 189 nations made a promise
to free people from extreme poverty and multiple deprivations. This
pledge was translated into eight Millennium Development Goals.
Surprisingly, more and better employment was not among the original
goals: it was not even a target under Goal # 1 to eradicate extreme
poverty and hunger. Yet the key pathway to reducing poverty and hunger
is to help people secure more and better employment opportunities.
Recognizing this lacuna, at the 2005 United Nations World Summit, the
member nations requested that "full and productive employment and
decent work for all" be added as a central objective of the
development strategies to meet the MDGs. Subsequently, "the
achievement of full and productive employment and decent work for all,
including women and young people", was added as a target under MDG
Goal # 1.
Today, employment is very much on the development agenda. For
instance, the World Development Report 2013 on "Jobs'"
calls for moving jobs center stage. It argues that employment--or
jobs--drive development and should not be considered an afterthought of
growth: that "(j)obs are the cornerstone of economic and social
development. Indeed, development happens through jobs. People work their
way out of poverty and hardship through better livelihoods" (World
Bank, 2012: 2). The WDR 2013 considers all types of jobs not just formal
wage employment--and highlights that a large share of the workforce is
self-employed. It concludes that three layers of policies are needed to
promote more and better jobs: policy fundamentals (e.g. macroeconomic
stability; enabling business environment; human capital; and rule of
law); labor policies which avoid misguided interventions, provide voice,
and extend protection; and development policies to address
context-specific employment challenges and constraints. But it also
concludes that that the appropriate policy responses will vary across
countries, depending on their levels of development, endowments,
demography, and institutions.
Hopefully, going forward, this recognition and validation of
employment as a driver of development will be reflected in the post-2015
Millennium Development Goals and in development policy more generally.
Re-Imagining the Economy: What is needed, most fundamentally, is a
new economic paradigm: a model of a hybrid economy that embraces the
traditional and the modern, the small scale and the big scale, the
informal and the formal. What is needed is an economic model that allows
the smallest units and the least powerful workers to operate alongside
the largest units and most powerful economic players. What is needed,
more specifically, is an economic model that allows:
* Home-based producers in global value chains to be able to bargain
with dominant players in those chains for their rightful share of value
added.
* Street vendors to operate alongside retailers and
wholesalers--alongside shops, wholesale markets, and malls - in central
business districts.
* Waste pickers to access waste and to bid for solid waste
management contracts alongside large corporations.
* Informal construction workers to gain some of the protections and
benefits of formal construction workers.
* Informal transport workers to be integrated on equitable terms in
public and private transport systems.
* Small holders and agricultural day laborers to compete on
equitable terms with large holders and corporate farms; and
* Small-scale producers to compete in export markets on fair terms
alongside large-scale commercial farms.
Some years ago, the world embraced bio diversity--and still does.
Today, the world also needs to embrace economic diversity. Both are
needed for sustainable and inclusive development.
References
International Labor Organization (2003), Scope of the Employment
Relationship: Report IV, International Labor Conference, 91st Session,
Geneva: ILO.
International Labor Organization (2002), Women and Men in the
Informal Economy: A Statistical Picture. Geneva, Switzerland: ILO.
Written by Marty Chen and Joann Vanek using multi-country data analyzed
by Jacques Charmes and country studies by Debbie Budlender, Peter
Buwembo, Nozipho Shabala, Jeemol Unni, Marge Guerrero, Rodrigo Negrete,
Francoise Carre, and Joaquin Herranz, Jr.
International Labor Organization (1993), Resolution Concerning the
International Classification of Status in Employment (ICSE), adopted by
the Fifteenth International Conference of Labor Statisticians. Geneva,
Switzerland: ILO
International Labor Organization (1993, 2003), Reports of the
International Conference of Labor Statisticians., Geneva: ILO.
International Labor Organization (1972), Employment, Incomes and
Equality: A Strategy for Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya,
Geneva: ILO.
ILO-WIEGO database on informal employment
http://www.ilo.org/global/statistics-anddatabases/WCMS_179795/lang-en/
index.htm
Lewis, W.A. (1954), "Economic Development with Unlimited
Supplies of Labor", Manchester School of Economic and Social
Studies, 23(2)
Singer, H.W. (1970), "Dualism Revisited: A New Approach to the
Problems of Dual Society in Developing Countries", Journal of
Development Studies, 7(1 January)
Vanek, J, M. Chen, R. Hussmanns, J. Heintz, & F. Carre (2012),
Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical Picture, Geneva:
ILO & WIEGO.
World Bank (2012), World Development Report 2013 on Jobs,
Washington, D.C: World Bank.
Martha Alter Chen is International Coordinator, WIEGO Network
&Lecturer in Public Policy, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge, MA
02138. E-Mail: Martha_Chen@harvard.edu. Joann Vanek is Statistics
Program Director, WIEGO Network.
(1) In this paper, following international statistical practice, we
use the term "informal sector", rather than "unorganized
sector", to refer to unincorporated small or unregistered
enterprises. And we use the term "informal employment" to
refer to work without legal or social protection both inside and outside
informal enterprises. In India, the term "unorganized sector"
generally refers to enterprises having fewer than 10 workers, operating
on a proprietary or partnership basis. So defined, it closely
approximates the international statistical definition of the
"informal sector".
(2) Status in employment is used to delineate two key aspects of
labour contractual arrangements: the allocation of authority over the
work process and the outcome of the work done; and the allocation of
economic risks involved (ILO 1993).
(3) The term "informal workers" is used here in a broad
inclusive sense to include informal wage workers as well as the informal
self-employed.
(4) The ILO-WIEGO database on informal employment now contains data
for nearly 50 countries: see
http://www.ilo.org/global/statisticsand-databases/WCMS_179795/lang-en/
index.htm
(5) Public sector employment as a share of total employment is
still quite high, although decreasing, in the MENA region: as high as
20-25 per cent of total employment in some countries. When public sector
employment is excluded, informal employment represents around 80 per
cent of private sector employment (Ragui Assaad, personal
communication).
(6) No direct estimates of informal employment were available for
the Caribbean countries; however indirect estimates were included for
some of the countries of the sub-region.