Informal workers & the economy.
Jhabvala, Renana
Although informal workers were always a majority in India, they
were only 'discovered' with the advent of liberalization.
Their vulnerabilities and insecurities need to be addressed through
social security policies which recognize their specific needs and
through laws which are not confined to labor, but include commercial law
as well as regulations which cover specific sectors of the economy.
However, organizing and advocacy of the informal workers cannot be
confined to specific needs but must be a movement towards a better
society and a fairer economy.
Discovering the Informal Economy
The informal economy has always existed in India, but it was seen
neither as an important part of the economy, nor as a theoretical
category that needed to be developed and explored. Although, the term
"informal sector" was adopted internationally by the ILO in
the mid-1970s, it retreated to the margins of both research and
policies, until only a little over a decade ago. In 2002, the
International Labor Conference finally debated a recommendation, which
coined the term "informal economy", and recognized both self
employed and wage workers to be part of this economy. It also recognized
the unprotected and insecure nature of work in this economy and
committed the ILO to working towards social security and various forms
of protection of these workers.
In India, the term "unorganized" rather than
"informal" has been used when referring to these unprotected
workers. This has caused considerable confusion as
"unorganized" implies a lack of organization, and many
commentators have in fact used it this way. The same term
"unorganized" has also been used by the Central Statistical
Organization to describe enterprises rather than workers, and it defines
unorganized enterprises as those employing 10 or more workers with
power, and 20 or more if there was no power being used (NCEUS, 2007:2).
However, a lot of this confusion was cleared up by the seminal work of
the National Commission on Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector, when
it clearly conflated the terms "informal" and
"unorganized" and defined both terms to mean those workers in
unorganized enterprises, including the self employed, and those in the
organized formal sector without any employment or social security
benefits (NCEUS, 2007:2).
It has been a long journey for these workers from the margins
towards the centre, which has happened not because of any changes in the
conditions of the workers and but far more due to the changes in
perception that have come about with the historical shifts due to
globalization.
The attitudes which marginalized the informal workers reflected a
larger perspective, which defined a worker as one who conformed to the
image of the 'laboring or industrial man'. This was a full
time, generally male worker, with one skill and one occupation, working
for a well defined employer in a factory or office, a workplace under
the control of the employer. This worker, or employee, sold his labor to
the employer and received a wage or salary in return. It was the
security of this 'industrial worker' around which the systems
of security or social protection were based. Although, it was recognized
that most workers in India did not fit this model, the general wisdom
was that as the Indian economy grew and in dustrialized, the informal
economy would gradually shrink and most workers would conform to the
industrial prototype.
But in the eighties and nineties there were rapid changes taking
place internationally with the ascendancy of the forces of globalization
and trade liberalization. The macro-economic changes in industrialized
countries were supported by the rise of neo-liberalism which shifted the
emphasis from security to growth. Regulations which promoted security
were seen as inimical to economic growth, and 'deregulation'
was to be promoted in order to facilitate the working of the market.
According to the Chicago School of law and economics, statutory or
institutional regulations can be justified only if they promote, or do
not impede growth. If they do not do that, they are impediments to
efficiency, and therefore, because efficiency and growth are equated
with improvements in social welfare, most regulations are suspect. This
perspective was to become pervasively influential (Standing, 2002:75).
In India, this school of thought gradually began to gain ascendancy
in the mid to late eighties, and became the dominant school of thought
with the debt crisis in 1991. The main target of this new school of
thought was the public sector undertakings, the visible face of the
socialist economy. In addition, there were persistent demands for the
'deregulation' of markets, which included delicensing of
industry, lowering import and excise taxes and removal of reservations
and quotas for categories such as small scale industries. The popular
image of the 'Li cense-Permit Raj' caught the imagination not
only of the industrialists, but of middle classes as well as the poor,
all of whom continually suffered under the highhanded treatment and
corruption of the entrenched bureaucracy.
The statutory regulatory system for labor too came under attack
with demands for 'exit' policy to increase the
'flexibility' of firms and allow them to compete
internationally. More and more came to be written about the privileged
position of formal sector labor. The focus began to shift towards
workers who were not part of the formal sector.
Agency & Organizing
Self Employed Women's Association (SEWA), was perhaps the
first trade union to consciously begin to organize workers in the
informal economy. Initially, in the early seventies, SEWA found a great
deal of resistance even to the idea of organizing women in this sector.
Most people believed that to qualify as a worker a person had to be an
employee, the problem being compounded by the belief that women were not
workers but only wives and mothers. The initial resistance to SEWA came
from the Labor Commissioner who refused to register SEWA as a trade
union. Firstly, he said, these workers had no definite employer, so they
did not fit the traditional definition of a worker. Who would they bar
gain with? Secondly, these workers had no fixed occupation. They went
from one kind of work to another; they did a number of different types
of work together. A proper worker had only one permanent occupation, and
Trade Unions were formed by occupation. And finally, these workers often
had no fixed place of work, such as a factory, so how would it be
possible to organize them. Interestingly, the Trade Union Act does not
in fact specify all these conditions, but the officials had a certain
type of worker in mind and the women we brought to them did not fit into
their idea of a worker.
In fact, women did not fit into anyone's idea of a worker. In
India there is a very large category of home -based workers making a
variety of goods in their own homes either for direct sale or for a
contractor or employer. When we first started organizing the women
garment stitchers we were told by the employers that these women were
not workers but just housewives who were stitching in their
'leisure time'; whereas we found that they were working
anywhere between eight to ten hours a day. We were also told by the
labor commissioner's office that since there was no direct
employer-employee relationship between the employer and the women, they
were not covered by any labor laws, although we found that there was a
complete control of production by the employers. Even the husbands of
the workers said 'my wife does not work' but only does this as
a 'hobby'. Statistical agencies too ignored these women and
their work did not appear in population censuses.
These attitudes towards women informal workers reflected the
general thinking. Within the prototype of the "industrial" or
"laboring" man, is subsumed the housewife woman. The
industrial man through his earnings supports a family, and the
woman's role is nurturing the worker and his children. These norms
were reflected even in the labor laws for example, the recommended
guidelines for fixing the minimum wage, was that one wage earner should
support three consumption units, which would include the man himself,
his wife and two children. (Man is one consumption unit, woman is .8
consumption unit and children are .6 consumption units each).
Unfortunately, even today, in spite of the changes that have taken
place in the world economies, and in spite of the changed thinking at
academic and policy levels on the informal workers, the attitudes of the
Labor Departments remain rooted in the last century. This is not
surprising considering that the role of the officials remains to be
enforcing labor laws, and that the majority of labor laws in India were
passed over 50 years ago, some as old as in 1920!
Nevertheless, many organizations of informal workers have come up,
and have consolidated the voice of informal workers, having in the
process to invent themselves to suit the needs of informal workers. Many
new organizations have been trade unions in various sectors--the
contract workers, casual workers and daily-wagers who had been excluded
from formal sector benefits formed their own trade unions; street
vendors who were being displaced from the selling spots and needed
protection against municipality and police; agricultural workers who
were exploited not only in wages but also on basis of caste;
construction workers, who were usually migrants; domestic workers whose
employers were middleclass households; bidi workers in their homes; and
many more. The labor movement as a whole in India recognized that
informal workers were over 90% of the economy and needed to organize.
Today most of the mainstream labor federations-INTUC, BMS, AITUC,
CITU--claim about half of their members are informal workers.
The result of these organizing attempts was reflected in various
legislations. Nationally, various Acts were passed for protection of
Construction Workers and for Social Security of the Unorganized Sector,
while a National Policy on Street Vendors was approved by the Government
and a National Minimum Wage was proposed. At state level social security
boards of different types were set up and social security schemes
directed primarily to unorganized workers were implemented, at the same
time minimum wages for agricultural workers and many other informal
workers were proposed.
However, it has been very difficult to organize informal workers
purely along traditional union lines. Many of the work ers are self
employed and need many different services, like credit and marketing.
Skill development is another major need of workers which is not easily
provided by trade unions. So, many new ways of organizing have come up.
The "micro-finance movement" has become well-known
world-wide as a means to enhance livelihoods, and in fact, micro-finance
was started and lead by women, with new organizing structures being
developed by them. SEWA was started in India in 1972, and a few years
later SEWA Bank was started as a cooperative bank where all shareholders
were members of SEWA who then elected their own board. In 1979 Grameen
Bank was started in Bangladesh. In the 1980s Myrada and other
organizations such as CDF in India found that women were spontaneously
getting together into groups, saving their earnings, and taking loans
from their own savings. Thus was launched the "Self Help
Group" in India. These groups were so successful that the
Government of India recognized their potential and began using them as
the building blocks for developmental programs. Private sector
micro-finance too recognized their potential and small women's
groups became the basis for India's growing micro-finance movement.
In the urban areas organizing has taken place around basic services
such as water and sanitation and against overcrowding and crime. The
struggle for water, sanitation and tenurial rights has lead to
shack-dwellers coming together to change policies. Another form of
organizing is the "People's Movement" which has no
structure but is organized to protest dispossession. The Chipko Movement
was an early spontaneous people's movement which was followed by
people's movements against big dams which displaced thousands of
people, and again against land acquisitions for big industries. These
movements came up as people in a particular area faced extreme change
which would disrupt their lives and perhaps bring them into a cycle of
poverty. Women, whose way of life is rooted in the land and in their
homes feel the threat even more than men, and are willing to take, join,
or often take the lead in long drawn out protests.
The changing world of work has led to the many different forms of
organizing around the needs associated with work and livelihoods. But
organizing is never easy. The workers are usually poor, belong to
unprivileged castes, and are afraid to lose whatever little they have
acquired. Women are perhaps the most vulnerable and disempowered within
these groups. Organizing required empowerment, and the quest for
economic justice is seeking the path towards change, towards an economic
system where people have a certain level of security, at least of their
basic needs, where work is fulfilling and not back-breaking and
exploitative and where people feel a sense of community and empowerment.
Movement towards new economic systems requires direction, and it is
those who have the most to lose within the existing systems, the most
insecure, the vulnerable, the poor, who can become the agency for
change.
However, agency of the weak requires some form of coming together
or of organizing before people can feel empowered to act. Empowerment is
the desire of people who feel powerless to have more control over their
lives. People feel powerless in many ways. They feel that their lives
are ruled by forces over which they have no control, which are too
powerful for them. People are confronted by powerful figures in their
lives who control them, they also face forces which are far away and
they cannot identify. Powerlessness causes fear that their lives might
be crushed or destroyed or reduced any time. It kills the human spirit.
Empowerment through organizing is the process by which the
disempowered, or powerless, people can change their circumstances and
begin to have control over their lives. Empowerment results in a change
in the balance of power, in the living conditions, and in the
relationships. In many ways empowerment is not only the means to achieve
better incomes, better livelihoods or better social security, it is the
means to the renewal of the human spirit.
Quest for Social Security
The earnings of informal workers tend to be low and their
employment opportunities are insecure. These insecurities are compounded
by their lack of social security, so that their contingent expenses in
times of ill health or unemployment or disaster can send them down into
a spiral of poverty or even destitution.
In any country the social security system should respect the
prevailing character of economic insecurity. In an industrial society,
based on a vast majority having stable full-time employment with
contracts and union-backed collective bargaining, one could make a
reasonably good estimate of which groups are in need, and which are not.
This is not India today, and it will not be India in the future. In a
globalising, open economy, more and more people will be subject to
economic shocks and have to put up with systemic uncertainty, against
which they will be unable to insure properly. Many more will be
vulnerable to sudden declines in income.
The need for social security is well recognized by governments who
attempt to alleviate their conditions, entitlements and schemes. There
are presently a number of entitlements which are provided by the
government (1) either to all citizens or to those who are poor. The
approach of the citizen based entitlement is a 'rights'
approach, that is, as a citizen of the country, every human being has a
right to satisfaction of certain basic needs and it is the duty of the
State to provide for those needs. There are presently a number of
citizen based entitlements which are provided by the Government either
to all citizens or to those who are poor, on a 'means tested'
basis. These are drinking water, health care, education, food security,
housing and social assistance schemes. The State is required to finance
the services as well as undertake the provision.
The other approach to providing security for workers is the
work-based entitlements which supplement the citizens based ones. The
work based entitlements are statutory and apply to all workers in an
employer-employee relationship. The finances for these entitlements are
provided by statutory contributions from the employers and the
employees. The role of the Government is to enforce and implement the
schemes.
The main statutory work-based entitlements in India are the old age
benefit schemes (in particular the Employees Provident Fund) and the
health services (in particular the Employees Social Insurance Scheme).
In addition, there are schemes for particular sectors covered by the
Welfare Funds. In the Welfare Funds scheme, funds are raised by levying
a cess on the production, sale or export of specified goods, or by
collecting contributions from the various sources including the
employer, employee as well as the government. The Welfare Funds are used
to meet the expenditure of the welfare of the workers. The Central
Funds, set up by the Government of India, are for Bidi, Mines, Cine
workers, dock workers and Building and Construction workers. Among the
states, Kerala State has many such funds, one for each sector while
Tamil Nadu and Maharashtra and Gujarat have funds constituted under the
Manual Workers Acts.
It was earlier believed that the work-based entitlements would
become universal as the organized sector grew and the unorganized sector
shrunk. It has now become obvious that in fact the opposite is
happening. More and more workers are being left out of the social
security net, and the coverage of both ESIS and EPF is shrinking, as are
the number of workers covered by the provisions of various welfare Acts
such as the Maternity Benefit Act. There is therefore a need to think
afresh on how to devise work-based social security systems particularly
targeting the unorganized sector.
Many unorganized sector workers do avail of the citizenship based
entitlements like health services from Primary Health Centers, free
primary education and public distribution systems. However, these
services remain highly inadequate. Therefore, though work based
entitlements are meant to supplement the citizenship based ones, in
actual fact, where the work based entitlements work well, such as in the
organized sector, workers use these services rather than the public
sector services. This is because, the work related benefits are better
financed, better targeted and remain more in the control of the users.
Also, increasingly these services are being used to make the best
possible use of both public and private available services. Many
companies, for example, which have health insurance will now allow their
employees to choose health providers from the market.
Nevertheless it is still the Government systems of entitlements
that reach out to the largest numbers of the vulnerable. Unfortunately,
the efficiency of these systems has become very low. In India, the base
of the state benefit system in most parts of the country is the ration
card, consisting of the BPL (Below Poverty Line) and many studies have
shown that this form of targeting, means testing and provision of
particular schemes have led to large scale inefficiencies. For example,
it has been shown that nearly 50% of the really poor in rural areas do
not receive BPL or Antyodyay cards (Report of the Expert Group), and
that only 27% of the subsidized grain in the PDS system actually reaches
those who need it (Planning Commission, 2005). The implementing
machinery of the Government is too bureaucratic and full of leakages and
corruption. The pipes of Government are clogged, and so alternative
implementing systems are needed.
Solutions are still to be found, but a number of promising trends
are emerging. One solution that has been proposed, but not yet
implemented by the Government is to help the unorganized sector or poor
population set up its own organizations and run its own social security
schemes with financial aid from the Government. These organizations
could be the existing ones like trade unions, cooperatives, federations,
village mandals, micro-finance institutions which could be supported by
government as well as voluntary organizations to become self-sufficient
and well-managed.
In order to decentralize this process, Worker Facilitation Centers
had been proposed during the discussions on the Unorganized Workers
Social Security Act (2). These centers would:
a) Disseminate information on available social security schemes for
the workers.
b) Facilitate the filling, processing and forwarding of application
forms for registration of workers.
c) Obtain registration from the District Committee and deliver the
Identity Cards to the registered workers.
d) Facilitate to enroll the registered workers in social security
schemes.
e) Act as an authorized intermediary in collecting contributions
from the workers and employers to the social security schemes and remit
them with the designated institutions.
f) Ensure the delivery of social security benefits in co-operation
with institutions designated to deliver such social security (insurance
companies, post offices, Departments of the State/Central Government and
other institutions concerned).
g) Any other function as may be prescribed by the State Social
Security Board.
Some organizations which could become Worker Facilitation Centres
were.
a) Existing Worker Welfare Boards and their local offices.
b) Local Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRI) or urban local bodies.
c) Organizations of workers including trade unions, associations
and co-operatives in the unorganized sector.
d) Self-help Groups (SHGs).
e) Non-profit organizations working among the unorganized sector
workers.
f) Such other organizations as may be designated by the State
Boards.
Another set of solutions concern the types of benefits that can be
made available to people to ensure some form of security. In India today
we have a variety of schemes. These schemes include the cash line
(benefits in terms of cash such as pensions or scholarships), the food
and commodity line (provision of goods and services for free or at
subsidized prices for those designated as 'the poor') and the
labor line (provision of labor to be performed by those designated as
poor, in return for monetary payment or food).
These are the three main ways by which Government tries to cut
poverty and economic insecurity directly through providing goods needed
by people, through providing labor for a payment from which they can buy
the goods they think they want, and through providing money from which
they can buy such goods and develop work opportunities (Standing, 2012.)
In recent times, direct cash transfers have been discussed as a
means of ensuring social security. Pensions is a form of cash transfers
as are scholarships and surveys have found that these forms of social
security tend to be more reliable than other forms which require
continuous intervention. In the case of pensions for example, although
getting registered and approved as a pension beneficiary is time
consuming and often expensive, once the person is registered and the
benefit starts to flow, it is much more reliable than other forms of
social benefits including subsidized grain or right to labor.
Other countries such as Brazil and Mexico too have found that cash
transfers are an important source of social protection especially for
the vulnerable. However, in India there are many reservations and
hesitations about cash transfers as a form of social protection. First,
there is the fear that the money received will be "mis-spent",
the most common cited being that "men will drink it away".
Another hesitation is that inflation will erode the value of the cash
and so will reduce the efficacy of the protection. Unlike other medium
income countries, India has a poor record of financial inclusion, with
less than 40% of people having bank accounts. In the case of informal
workers, who are generally poor, this is even lower, so that until bank
accounts, or accounts in other financial institutions are opened, the
implementation of cash transfers would be difficult.
However, research experiments with cash transfers have shown that
they tend to be successful as a means of social protection. In an
experiment conducted by SEWA in Delhi, it was found that substitution of
Public Distribution System led to better nutrition and health outcomes.
In an on-going larger rural study on cash transfers also run by SEWA, a
small cash transfer is provided to every individual each month and is
universal in that every person identified by an independent survey as a
resident of the village at the outset of the pilot will be eligible to
receive the grant. Further it is to be be unconditional, i.e., the
recipients will not be obliged to spend the money in any preconceived or
externally determined way.
In this experiment the cash transfer scheme is not offered as a
panacea, and it is recognized that successful social policy requires a
multitude of interventions. However, lack of money is a major source of
insecurity and poverty and the sub-optimal decisions poor people have to
make. This project starts from the premise that low-income people are
just as rational as high-income people, and therefore can be expected to
act rationally and in their long-term interests. The objective is to
identify a policy instrument that could substantially reduce poverty and
economic insecurity in low-income areas, whereby the population living
there would gain and build sustainable livelihoods in a more dynamic
economic environment. Apart from the issue of corruption and leakages,
one of the failures of many state policies supposedly helping the poor
is that they have very low local multiplier effects.
Although the results of this experiment are still being analyzed,
the first indications are that regular, and unconditional cash transfers
are quite transformative in that it provides families flexibility to
attend to their actual needs, which leads to better nutrition, better
health care, better schooling outcomes, more productive work and release
from a cycle of bondage caused by debt.
Informal Workers & the Law
Once it is recognized that the informal are workers too, the major
question is what are the methods and mechanisms, which would help them
to move towards greater security. The best forms of security tend to be
statutory regulations, however labor laws are generally designed in a
fairly detailed and inflexible way for industrial workers and it is
difficult to adapt them to informal workers. Most labor laws require
proving the existence of an employer-employee relationship, usually such
a relationship does not exist in its traditional form and even if it
exists it is often difficult to prove. For example, workers often have
accidents in the course of their work, SEWA went to court on behalf of a
cart-puller, who with a hired cart, in the process of delivering cloth
from a wholesaler to a retailer, was involved in a street accident and
broke both the legs. Although the cart-puller had been doing deliveries
for the wholesaler for more than twenty years, the court ruled that
there was no employer-employee relationship, and so no one could be held
liable under the Workmen's Compensation Act.
On the other hand there are a few labor laws which can be adapted
for the informal workers. For example the Bidi Workers Welfare Fund Act,
where there is no intrinsic need to prove an employer-employee
relationship and the employer is not directly liable for particular
employees, but pays contributions through a cess into a fund, which
provides social protection to bidi workers.
However, labor laws are only a small part of the problem. The
traditional industrial worker did not deal directly with the market, his
main relationship as a worker was with a specified employer. The
informal worker is subject to a variety of relationships, ranging from
market relationships to those with various statutory authorities, and is
subject to a wide range of laws from commercial law to municipal
regulations to laws relating to specific sectors such as forests or
oceans. For example, street vendors or waste collectors are subject to
municipal laws and police laws. Forest workers are subject to Forest
Acts and small farmers to various land-related laws such as land
acquisition Acts.
Decentralization & Co-operation
Informal workers constitute more than 90% of the workforce and when
we consider how the insecurity and vulnerability of this large working
population is to be reduced, we are in effect looking at how the
economic and social structures need to change in order to be a more just
and fairer system. In this section, we present some thoughts on a
"better society".
Work is part of, not separate from, life. It is embedded in social
and cultural processes and there is close interrelation between work,
social systems, local community, family and on an individual level, of
identity and self-worth. The nature and arrangement of work often
signals the relationships in society.
In India, the insecurities around work have been increasing as the
economy has been changing and opening itself to global markets. Economic
centralization in the form of large corporations which control their
environment and government regulations which encourage large companies
at the expense of small ones is rapidly increasing. Although it is
widely accepted that political decentralization is required for a
vibrant democracy, the opposite is seen as true for the economy.
Centralization of production (and ownership of resources and skills) is
viewed as leading to a more efficient economy. In opposition to this
favourable view of centralization, there are arguments for
decentralization of production and distribution of goods and services.
A just society requires that ownership of economic resources be
distributed more equitably. Within most countries and across nations,
the distribution and ownership of wealth tends to be concentrated in
certain areas, and generally the wealthier areas attract more resources
and the poorer areas lose them. Economic decentralization is one way
(although not necessarily the only way) of distribution of resources.
Economic decentralization also follows this idea of achieving
economic justice by focusing on the most vulnerable. In practice,
identification of the most vulnerable is a major exercise, where a
number of criteria have to be accepted and the people fitting those
criteria to be identified. Poverty or vulnerability criteria are not as
simple as for other vulnerable groups like the aged, widows or the
disabled. The most successful practices in these processes of
identification would occur at local level. Reaching the poorest has been
a major administrative exercise when organized on a national level
(centrally). A more efficient system would be one where food, clothing
and other minimum requirements are distributed locally. Even more
efficient would be local production of required needs. We are not
proposing that local areas disconnect with mainstream markets, but that
a minimum amount of basic needs goods be produced and distributed
locally. New technologies and inputs could boost this production and
encourage backward and forward linkages with mainstream markets.
Decentralization leads to a more satisfying type of work, often
called "holistic work". It is not only the quality of work
which gives satisfaction but also its purpose and the relationships
within the work process. Decentralized production gives communities
greater control over what they produce, and how it is to be used.
Furthermore, local organization of production links more easily with
local cultures and developed within a holistic and sustainable approach
to development. One good example of the holistic nature of decentralized
work is found among communities who live in areas rich in natural
resources such as forests. Where communities have a greater control over
these resources, they tend to preserve and regenerate these resources.
This holistic perspective requires that each individuals give back
something to the world, even as he takes away from it for his own
maintenance. Building such interdependence requires a strong sense of
local community and culture that integrates the economic and social
realms.
Local production and distribution also strengthens the economic
role of women. Much of their work is non-monetary and meant for use
within the family. Much community work that involves maintaining social
relationships is also done by women. Economic decentralization would
lead to two trends that would be beneficial to women. It would
strengthen local markets and local skills and make markets more
accessible to women. It would raise the value of non-monetary (or
reproductive) work, including all forms of community and service work,
as this would acquire a more holistic meaning and come to be understood
as work done for the maintenance of society.
Another form of production that is being disregarded in
today's competitive and individualistic economies is the
cooperative forms of work systems, where people work together to produce
results that are beneficial for all. There are many such forms in
existence today. They vary from small self-help groups being promoted in
India, to traditional roscas, to mutual-help groups found in many
African countries, to community grain banks and community social
protection systems, to large formal co-operative societies.
Co-operative forms of work are also more likely to be adopted by
the poor or by those who have few resources. Cooperation is one way of
pooling resources and hence increasing the control and bargaining power
of those who are weak. These forms can be seen as the best form to meet
minimum needs of every individual.
Formal registered co-operatives exist worldwide. Ranging from
small-scale to multi-million dollar businesses across the globe,
co-operatives are estimated to employ more than 100 million women and
men and have more than 800 million members. They operate mainly in
agricultural marketing and supply, finance, wholesale and retailing,
health care, housing and insurance, but are venturing into new fields
such as information and communication technology, tourism and cultural
industries. Co-operative organizations and groups are abundant in the
informal economy, especially in developing countries, although so far
there has been no attempt to measure them.
Co-operative economic organizations are not only feasible for
informal workers but bring about better work in several ways. First,
they give workers, especially those who are the most vulnerable, a new
identity based on respect for the contribution their work makes to
society and to their own families. Second, co-operative forms of work
allow them to build an enterprise and reach markets directly, instead of
being at the mercy of traders and others who exploit their lack of
access to markets. Third, they are able to pool their resources,
capital, knowledge and skills. Fourth, they are able to avail themselves
of government schemes and programmes, which would be difficult for them
to do individually. Finally, their coming together into a viable
organisation increases their voice and bargaining power in society and
in the marketplace.
Informal workers today are no longer invisible, but are getting
empowered. New policies are being formulated for them, their
organizations are gaining voice as they attempt to become part of the
mainstream. However, the mainstream economy as it exists today is an
informalizing force, and is unlikely to incorporate the needs of these
workers, unlikely to address their vulnerabilities. As informal workers
develop agency it is important for them to advocate for policies leading
to a more decentralized and co-operative economy, rather than only to
address their immediate needs. In this way they can become the vanguard
for a better and more just society.
References
Bhatt, Ela & Jhabvala, Renana (2013), The Idea of Work, Indian
Academy for Self Employed Women, Ahmedabad
Ministry of Labour website (2007), www.labour.nic.in Unorganized
Workers Social Security Bill
Ministry of Rural Development (2009), Report of the Expert Group to
Advise the Ministry of Rural Development on the Methodology for
Conducting the Below Poverty Line Census for the Eleventh Plan,
Government of India, New Delhi
National Commission on Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector(2007),
Report on Conditions of Work and Promotion of Livelihoods in the
Unorganized Sector, Government of India
Planning Commission (2005), Performance Evaluation of Targeted
Public Distribution System, Program Evaluation Organization, Planning
Commission, New Delhi.
Rawls, J. (2001), Justice as Fairness: A Restatement, Cambridge,
MA, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press
Standing, Guy. (2002), Beyond the New Paternalism, London, Verso
Standing, Guy, (2012), Cash Transfers: A Review of the Issues in
India, UNICEF, India
Virmani, A (2007), "Planning for Results", Planning
Commission Working Paper 1/2007PC, New Delhi.
Renana Jhabvala is with SEWA, Ahmedabad. E-mail: renanaj@vsnl.net
(1) For a more complete discussion of social security see RKA
Subrahmanya, "Social Protection of Workers in the Unorganized
Sector", this volume
(2) Labor Ministry website (2007)