The puzzle of trade union strength in Western Europe since 1980.
Kelly, John ; Hamann, Kerstin
Introduction
The period between 1945 and the early 1970s has been referred to as
the 'Golden Age of Capitalism' (Marglin & Schor 1990).
Most countries that comprised what was then known as the advanced
capitalist world Western Europe, North America, Japan and Australasia
recorded sustained and substantial rates of economic growth for over two
decades. Living standards, measured by real incomes, ownership of
consumer goods and health indices increased dramatically for millions of
people (Marglin & Schor 1990). This period also represented a golden
age of trade unionism in which membership, density, strike activity and
economic and political bargaining power reached hitherto unprecedented
levels (Shalev 1992, Western 1997). Some European governments in the
1970s in Ireland, Italy and the United Kingdom for example--responded to
union power by creating corporatist policymaking committees designed to
negotiate union wage restraint in exchange for improved legal rights and
welfare provision (Schmitter & Lehmbruch 1979). Since the early
1980s however unions across the advanced capitalist world have witnessed
prolonged membership decline, a reduction in bargaining power in the
context of a globalizing economy and neo-liberal government policies,
and a significant decline in strike rates. The world recession that
began in 2008 appears to have dealt a further blow to unions already
weakened by years of membership loss.
However, we argue that whilst recent economic and political
developments have undoubtedly posed serious threats to trade unions,
these can also be viewed as opportunities for trade union revitalization
(Behrens, Hamann & Hurd 2004). We show that unions' weakening
in organisational strength and economic bargaining power has in some
cases been counterbalanced by the re-emergence of tripartite relations
between governments, unions and employers and by the resurgence of
general strikes against government policies. We interpret union
involvement in tripartite talks and their continuing capacity to
mobilize members and supporters in general strikes as evidence that some
union movements have recognized the existence of opportunities in the
midst of adversity. After a brief recap of the familiar dimensions of
trade union decline we set out a number of theoretical propositions that
enable us to identify contemporary sources of trade union power. We also
present fresh evidence on recent patterns of union-government
negotiations in Western Europe and on general strikes designed to
influence government policy.
Parameters of Trade Union Decline
Evidence from 16 Western European countries as well as the USA,
Canada, Australia and New Zealand shows that trade union density
declined between 1980 and 2007 in all but two cases: Finland (up one
percentage point from 69% to 70%) and Spain (up eight points from 7% to
15%) (Barratt 2009, Hamann & Kelly 2008). The mean, unweighted rate
of density decline 1980-2007 is 15.4 percentage points. It is true that
the decline has been far more pronounced in the private sector compared
to the public sector and that the overall rate of decline has been quite
modest in some countries, such as Belgium (- 1 point, from 54% to 53%),
Norway (- 4 points, from 58% to 54%) and Canada (6 points, from 35% to
29%) but these national cases are unusual. It is also true that between
1980 and 2004 collective bargaining coverage has remained remarkably
stable in most of Western Europe at approximately 80-90% of employees
(Hamann & Kelly 2008). However, this institutional stability masks a
significant erosion of trade union power, made evident by trends in
national income distribution and in strike rates. Between 1960 and 1980
the wage share of value added in manufacturing industry in 15 OECD
countries rose from 66% to 74% as union militancy shifted the
distribution of national income away from profits and into wages and
salaries. However between 1980 and 2000, as trade union membership
declined, the distribution of national income shifted radically back in
favour of owners of capital: wage share fell steadily and by 2000 had
reached 65%, despite the economic growth and low unemployment of the
mid-late 1990s (Glyn 2006: 7). Theory suggests that unions are able to
push up wages and salaries at the expense of profits by the use (or
threat) of collective action and it is therefore not surprising to
observe that the redistribution of income from labour to capital over
the past 20-30 years has coincided with a dramatic reduction in levels
of strike activity, whether measured by days lost, numbers of strikes,
or workers involved. Between 1970 and 1979 an average of 419 working
days per 1000 employees were lost to strike action each year in the
major OECD countries, but by 2000-2004 days lost to strikes had
decreased by almost 90 per cent to just 51 days per 1000 employees
(Piazza 2005: 290, Scheuer 2006: 144, 149, van der Velden et al. 2007).
There are substantial academic literatures on the causes of
declining union membership and of falling strike rates. A wide range of
causal variables have been linked to union membership, including changes
in worker attitudes, away from collectivism and towards individualism;
the limited effectiveness of trade unions caused by high unemployment
and competitive, international product markets; the constraints placed
on unions by deregulatory, neo-liberal economic policies; the opposition
of employers to trade unionism, particularly in the private service
firms that now dominate most Western economies and where traditions of
trade unionism are weak; and the limited resources devoted by trade
unions to organizing in the service sector of the advanced economies
(see for example Fernie & Metcalf 2005, Martin & Ross 1999,
Waddington & Hoffmann 2000, Western 1997). So far as strikes are
concerned, the globalization of the economy has played a significant
role in depressing overall levels of strike activity in Western Europe.
Piazza's (2005) study of 15 OECD countries 1952-2001 found that two
measures of globalization, increased international trade and reduced
controls on capital mobility are strongly associated with a decline in
days lost to strikes, especially in countries with low (below-median)
union density. Declining trade union density since 1980 is also
associated with strike decline over the same period although the
relationship between levels of strikes and density (as distinct from
changes) is more complex: the most strike-prone countries in Europe
(2002-06) include high-density Finland, modest-density Italy and
low-density Spain (Hale 2008).
Overall therefore, as is well known, the union movements in the
advanced capitalist world are losing members and appear to be
experiencing a decline in bargaining power and mobilizing capacity
despite stable bargaining coverage.
Trade Unions, Electoral Volatility & Political Party
Competition
However if we turn our attention from the roles of product and
labour markets and employers to developments in governmental behaviour
and electoral politics, it can be argued that a series of far-reaching
changes in the attitudes and behaviour of voters and in the behavior of
political parties has created new prospects for contemporary trade
unionism. In the first place, since 1980 many West European governments
have embarked on major reforms to their systems of welfare, labour
markets and wage determination in order to enhance the competitiveness
of their national economies. For example, we have witnessed attempts to
reduce entitlements to unemployment benefits; raise the retirement age
and increase levels of pension contributions; reduce legal protections
for workers against dismissal or redundancy; and restrain the growth in
real wages. Governments with a majority of seats in their legislature
could in theory enact many of these reforms through legislation but in
practice many of them, irrespective of party family, have chosen to
engage trade unions in bipartite or tripartite (government, unions and
employers) talks in an attempt to reach agreement (Hamann & Kelly
2010). Why would governing parties, either without strong ties to trade
unions or with weakening ties, seek out agreements with trade unions,
organizations whose membership base and bargaining power is supposedly
eroding?
Broadly speaking, one main reason is that political parties are
themselves facing a series of electoral problems because of the growth
in party competition and because of the declining allegiance among
voters to any particular party. Electoral volatility--the percentage of
voters switching parties from one election to the next--has increased
since the 1970s due to a wide range of factors including changing
demographics, rising educational levels, the growing importance of mass
media, the rise of new political issues, and softening class lines as an
outgrowth of changing employment and production patterns. For example,
while only 20% of Dutch respondents professed in 1971 they would
sometimes vote for a different party, over two-thirds did so in 1991
(Dalton 2000). Parties therefore may see the need to reach out to voters
that did not traditionally form their core support group. In this
context, social pacts with trade unions and employers may thus present
themselves as a useful strategy to seek broad support for potentially
unpopular policies in an attempt to minimize the anticipated electoral
costs of implementing such policies. Moreover if pact negotiations run
into problems or the reforms prove to be especially unpopular, pacts may
serve as a mechanism of 'blame avoidance', allowing the
government to divert voter criticism onto trade unions (Hamann &
Kelly 2007, 2010). We can therefore hypothesize that the more strongly
governments are committed to reaching agreement with unions on a social
pact, the more power unions may be able to wield in their relations with
government. Moreover, in seeking to influence governments we would
expect unions not only to deploy the kinds of arguments they would
normally use with employers but to deploy various forms of pressure,
including collective action.
Social Pacts & General Strikes
Social pacts almost disappeared with the onset of the world
recession around 1980; yet, one of the most striking developments in the
industrial relations and political economy of Western Europe has been
their re-emergence after this brief hiatus (Hamann & Kelly 2010).
Between 1980 and 1991, 29 social pacts were signed in a variety of
Western European countries; during the years 199298, in the run-up to
European Monetary Union (EMU), 40 social pacts were agreed on; yet, in
the eight years after EMU, a further 41 social pacts were signed (Hamann
& Kelly 2010). Although some commentators assumed that social pacts
were strongly influenced by the fiscal and public spending requirements
of EMU and dealt primarily with wages, the numerous pacts that both
preceded and followed the EMU years 1992-98 suggests this
'political economy' approach is unconvincing (e.g. Hancke
& Rhodes 2005). In terms of content, only 50% of the 110 agreed
social pacts between 1980 and 2006 dealt with wages; the remainder
covered labour market and welfare reforms.
In contrast, both quantitative and qualitative analyses of 16 West
European countries between 1980 and 2006 show that electoral and party
political factors played a significant role in shaping governmental
offers of social pacts (Hamann & Kelly 2010). Such pacts were more
likely to be offered by governing parties that had recently enjoyed
electoral success and gained votes; by center or leftist governing
parties rather than conservative parties, presumably because of their
traditionally stronger ties to trade unions; by broad coalitions
comprised very different party families (compared to single-party
administrations); by governments that were relatively weak in the
legislature, measured by seat share; and by governments working with
legislatures that were highly fragmented, i.e. that included a large,
effective number of political parties. Broad and weak coalitions in
fragmented legislatures may experience considerable difficulty in
legislating unpopular reforms. Social pacts with unions and employers
may therefore assist such governments to overcome these problems as well
as providing enhanced legitimacy for their policies. We also found that
political parties responded to vote changes in different ways: vote
losses, for example, were more likely to lead to pact offers from left
parties (e.g. the Social Democrats in Sweden in the 1990s) but this was
not the case for parties of the right (e.g. the Conservatives in Denmark
in the 1980s). Legislation was more likely to be pursued by Conservative
parties with a high proportion of seats, particularly where the
legislature contained only a small number of effective parties (e.g.
France since the 1990s).
Approximately 70% of social pact offers by West European
governments have resulted in negotiated agreements on wages, labour
market and welfare reforms. Whilst some unions have negotiated from
positions of weakness, there is evidence in many cases that unions have
secured significant concessions from governments. To illustrate, the
most comprehensive study of pension reform in Western Europe provides
many examples where unions have exerted significant influence on issues
such as levels of contribution, reference periods for pension
calculation and retirement age (Immergut et al 2007). Unions have
therefore been able to exercise political influence on important issues
despite membership losses and the erosion of bargaining power vis-a-vis
employers.
However, many governments have shunned union inclusion in social
pacts and have sought to legislate reforms, often in the face of union
opposition. Although more often than not it is Conservative governments
that have opted for trade union exclusion, as in France or Italy for
example, we found that governments led by other party families also
excluded unions from time to time: Social Democrats in Spain in the
1980s and Sweden in the 1990s, Centre Party governments in Finland in
the 1990s and Christian Democratic governments in the Netherlands and
Belgium at various times. Ongoing research suggests that union exclusion
from government policymaking on wages, welfare systems and labour
markets is strongly associated with a variety of union protests
including general strikes. There is no generally agreed definition of
the term 'general strike' or its various synonyms, such as
'political strike' or 'protest strike' (see for
example Walsh 1983) but Hyman's (1989: 17) definition of a strike
can be suitably revised, as follows:
'A general strike is a temporary, national stoppage of work by
workers from many industries, directed against the executive or
legislative arms of government, to enforce a demand or give voice to a
grievance.'
Working days lost and workers involved per 1000 employees are the
most commonly used measures of strike activity in preference to simple
frequency counts (see for example Monger 2005, van der Velden et al
2007). In the case of general strikes, as with all large,
multi-workplace strikes, data on days lost and workers involved are
extremely unreliable (Lyddon 2007). Since the number of general strikes
can be measured very accurately, the frequency measure is used here.
Data were collected from a variety of sources for the EU 15 plus Norway
(Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland,
Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the UK) for
the period 1980-2008. The frequency of general strikes to protest
against government policy has risen since 1980. Fig. 1 shows that
between 1980 and 1989, unions staged 18 general strikes against
governments in Western Europe, a number that increased to 29 strikes in
the following decade; and between 2000 and 2008, the number of general
strikes grew again to 38 (Kelly & Hamann 2010). In addition, unions
issued a total of 11 credible general strike threats, once during the
1980s, eight times in the 1990s, and twice after 2000. While Greece
certainly contributed substantially to the large number of general
strikes, the overall pattern of general strikes persists even if we
exclude Greece. However a general strike in Greece (38 such strikes in
29 years) may have a different meaning and very different causes and
consequences from a general strike in the Netherlands or Austria, where
such actions are extremely rare. In terms of issues, it is reforms to
welfare systems, pensions and labour market regulation that have
precipitated the majority of general strikes.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Table 1 reveals the national distribution of general strikes and
documents their concentration in the Southern European economies of
France, Greece, Italy, Spain, and to a lesser degree Portugal. These
five countries alone account for 82% (70) of the 85 strikes in this
period. The remaining strikes (15) were organized in countries that have
for many years recorded some of the lowest levels of industrial conflict
in Europe: Austria, Belgium, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and Norway,
whilst several countries that have recently ranked high on economic
strikes stand out for their absence of general strikes, e.g. Denmark and
Ireland.
Theories developed to explain the existence, rise, or decline of
economic strikes are poorly equipped to account for general strikes. For
one, the empirical patterns displayed in Figure 1 demonstrate that
patterns of general strikes diverge from those of economic strikes. In
addition, general strikes differ fundamentally from economic strikes:
general strikes are directed against governments and their (proposed)
policies rather than employers; they are often organized around broad,
rather than sectional or occupational, issues, of concern to large
segments of the population beyond those employed in specific firms or
sectors; the issues that motivate general strikes, such as welfare or
labour market reform, are not generally those that are subject to
regular collective bargaining processes; and general strike
mobilizations may well extend beyond the unions' membership and
activist base to include many non-union employees. Thus, it makes little
sense to expect that explanations developed to account for workplace,
company, or even industry-wide strikes will also be able to illuminate
the causes of general strikes.
One of the most significant predictors of general strikes is
government exclusion of unions from policymaking. The scatterplot in
Fig. 2 reveals that the more often the government pursues legislative
acts to address reforms in the areas of welfare, pensions, and labour
markets (and to a lesser extent wages), the higher the propensity of
unions to stage general strikes (Denmark, Germany, Ireland, Sweden and
the UK are outliers because there were no general strikes in these
countries during the period under study). Since governments led by
Conservatives are most likely to exclude unions it is not surprising to
find that the majority of general strikes has been launched against
Conservative governments, 51% (43 out of 85). Yet a significant minority
of strikes 23 out of 85 was also called to protest the policies of
Social Democratic governments, in France, Greece, and Spain. Linked to
union inclusion or exclusion are the formal channels available to unions
for involvement in government policymaking, or 'opportunity
structures' (e.g. Tarrow 1994). It could be argued that well
developed structures for union involvement would reduce the propensity
of unions to challenge government policies through general strikes.
Using Siaroff's (1999) composite index of bargaining and tripartite
institutions, it appears that there is a correlation between opportunity
structures and the level of general strike action. Five of the seven
countries with below-average scores on opportunity structures have the
highest general strike totals: France, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain
(Ireland and the UK are the two exceptions).
In addition to government policy and party family of the
government, a third factor linked to general strike mobilizations is the
structure of the trade union movement. Four of the six countries with
the highest levels of general strikes have trade union confederations
divided on ideological lines between 'communist' and
'socialist', i.e. France, Italy, Portugal and Spain. Although
general strikes have often been called by all the union confederations
in a particular country, some general strikes were staged only by the
communist confederation: CGT (France), CGIL (Italy), CGTP (Portugal),
and CC.OO (Spain). Since general strikes have occurred in six other
countries with very different union structures, we know whilst the
presence of leftist confederations is highly conducive to general
strikes, such action does still occur even in their absence.
The recent general strikes have produced a range of outcomes for
unions and raise interesting questions about the role of political
action in union revitalization (Hamann & Kelly 2004). For example,
the Spanish general strike of 2002 (with the threat of more to follow)
forced the conservative (Popular Party) government to abandon almost all
of its proposals for the reform of unemployment benefits. The Italian
general strikes of 1994 against pension reforms led to the conservative
government's resignation and its defeat at the next general
election. On the other hand Austrian trade unions staged general strikes
in 2000 and again in 2003 in protest at the unilateral implementation of
pension reforms by the conservative-far right coalition government but
extracted very few concessions. Even this limited evidence on variation
in outcomes suggests that general strikes cannot simply be dismissed as
futile protests by weak and declining union movements. Because of the
weaknesses of governments, discussed earlier, some general strikes do
appear to have elicited significant concessions from governments. Given
our focus on governments' electoral considerations, this is perhaps
not surprising as general strikes can present massive social and
economic disruption and express widespread opposition of the electorate
to governmental policies.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Conclusions
Union problems in bargaining with employers, particularly
multinational employers in industry and financial services, have been
well documented. Both this problem and the associated decline in
economic strikes throughout most of Western Europe since 1980 have often
been traced to a shift in the balance of power between increasingly
mobile and powerful corporations and their unionized but vulnerable
employees. Whilst the capacity and willingness of unions to strike
against corporations has declined, relations between unions and
governments look very different. Since the early 1980s there has been a
re-emergence of union-government negotiations on issues of welfare and
labour market reform and wage determination. The problems faced by
political parties in gaining support from an increasingly volatile
electorate and forming stable governing coalitions have provided
opportunities for trade union movements in some countries to establish a
key role as bargaining agents on behalf of the workforce as a whole.
Governments that have sought to implement potentially unpopular reforms
have sometimes found it helpful to secure the support of trade unions
through negotiating a social pact. The dependency of government on such
support provides unions with a degree of bargaining power outside of the
regular workplace-related bargaining structures and many union movements
in Western Europe have welcomed this opportunity to demonstrate their
continuing relevance. At the same time government exclusion of unions
from policymaking has proved to be a significant factor contributing to
the resurgence of general strikes in Western Europe since 1980. From the
vantage point of labour and product markets, unions' bargaining
power in relation to employers often seems limited in its scale and
impact. However, if we change our focus and examine union relations with
governments in the context of party politics, a rather different picture
of union power and vitality starts to emerge. Union strength is thus a
multi-faceted and multi-dimensional concept that needs to be understood
in a context that goes beyond the regular bargaining structures and
instead also assesses unions' influence on government policies.
References
Barratt, Craig (2009), Trade Union Membership 2008, London:
Department for Business, Enterprise and Regulatory Reform.
Behrens, Martin, Kerstin Hamann & Richard Hurd (2004),
"Conceptualizing Labour Union Revitalization", In Carola Frege
& John Kelly (eds), Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Union
Revitalization in a Globalizing Economy, Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Bird, Derek (1991), "International Comparisons of Labour
Disputes in 1989 and 1990", Employment Gazette, 99(12): 653-58.
Dalton, Russell J. (2000), "The Decline of Party
Identifications", In Russell J. Dalton & Martin P. Wattenberg
(eds), Parties Without Partisans: Political Change Advanced Industrial
Democracies. New York: Oxford University Press.
Fernie, Sue & David Metcalf (eds) (2005), Trade Unions:
Resurgence or Demise? Abingdon: Routledge.
Glyn, Andrew (2006), Capitalism Unleashed: Finance, Globalization,
& Welfare, Oxford University Press.
Hale, Dominic (2008), "International Comparisons of Labour
Disputes in 2006", Economic and Labour Market Review, 2(4): 32-9.
Hamann, Kerstin & John Kelly (2010), Parties. Elections and
Policy Reforms in Western Europe: Voting for Social Pacts, Abingdon:
Routledge.
Hamann, Kerstin & John Kelly (2008), "Varieties of
Capitalism and Industrial Relations". In Edmund Heery, Nick Bacon,
Paul Blyton and Jack Fiorito (eds), The Sage Handbook of Industrial
Relations, London: Sage.
Hamann, Kerstin & John Kelly (2007), "Party Politics and
the Re-emergence of Social Pacts in Western Europe," Comparative
Political Studies, 40(8): 971-94.
Hamann, Kerstin & John Kelly (2004), "Unions as Political
Actors: A Recipe for Revitalization?" In Carola Frege & John
Kelly (eds), Varieties of Unionism: Strategies for Union Revitalization
in a Globalizing Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hancke, Bob & Martin Rhodes (2005), "EMU and Labour Market
Institutions in Europe: The Rise and Fall of National Social
Pacts," Work and Occupations, 32(2): 196-228.
Hyman, Richard (1989), Strikes 4e, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Immergut, Ellen M., Karen M. Anderson & Isabelle Schulze (eds.)
(2007), The Handbook of West European Pension Politics, New York: Oxford
University Press.
Kelly, John & Kerstin Hamann (2010), "General Strikes in
Western Europe, 1980-2008", Paper to International Industrial
Relations Association European Regional Congress, Copenhagen, June.
Lyddon, Dave (2007), "Strike Statistics and the Problems of
International Comparison", In Sjaak van der Velden, Heiner
Dribbusch, Dave Lyddon & Kurt Vandaele (eds) (2007), Strikes Around
the World, 1968-2005: Case-Studies of 15 Countries, Amsterdam: Aksant.
Marglin, Stephen A. & Juliet B. Schor (eds.) (1990), The Golden
Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience, Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Martin, Andrew & George Ross (eds) (1999), The Brave New World
of European Labour: European Trade Unions at the Millennium, New York:
Berghahn Books.
Monger, Joanne (2005), "International Comparisons of Labour
Disputes in 2003", Labour Market Trends, 113(4): 159-68.
Piazza, James (2005), "Globalizing Quiescence: Globalization,
Union Density and Strikes in 15 Industrialized Countries", Economic
and Industrial Democracy, 26(2): 289-314.
Pierson, Paul (1994), Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan,
Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment, New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Scheuer, Steen (2006), "A Novel Calculus? Institutional
Change, Globalization and Industrial Conflict in Europe", European
Journal of Industrial Relations, 12(2): 143-64.
Schmitter, Philippe & Gerhard Lehmbruch (eds) (1979), Trends
Towards Corporatist Intermediation, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Shalev, Michael (1992), "The Resurgence of Labour
Quiescence", In Marino Regini (ed.), The Future of Labour
Movements, London: Sage.
Siaroff, Alan (1999), "Corporatism in 24 Industrial
Democracies: Meaning and Measurement". European Journal of
Political Research, 36: 175-205.
Tarrow, Sidney (1994) Power in Movement: Social Movements,
Collective Action and Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Van Der Velden, Sjaak, Heiner Dribbusch, Dave Lyddon & Kurt
Vandaele (eds) (2007), Strikes Around the World, 1968-2005: Case-Studies
of 15 Countries, Amsterdam: Aksant.
Waddington, Jeremy and Reiner Hoffman (eds.) (2000), Trade Unions
in Europe: Facing Challenges and Searching for Solutions, Brussels:
European Trade Union Institute.
Walsh, Kenneth (1983), Strikes in Europe and the United States,
London: Pinter.
Western, Bruce (1997), Between Class and Market: Postwar
Unionization in the Capitalist Democracies, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
John Kelly is from School of Management, Birkbeck College,
University of London. E-mail: j.kelly@bbk.ac.uk. Kerstin Hamann is from
Department of Political Science, University of Central Florida, Orlando,
USA. E-mail: khamann@mail.ucf.edu
Table 1: General 8 Economic Strikes by
Country
Country General Strike ranking
strikes (days lost/1000)
1980-2006 1980-2008
Greece 38 1
Italy 13 3
France 10 11
Belgium 7 12
Spain 6 2
Austria 3 13
Netherlands 3 15
Portugal 3 10
Luxembourg 1 16
Norway 1 8
Denmark 0 6
Finland 0 4
Germany 0 14
Ireland 0 5
Sweden 0 9
UK 0 6
TOTAL 85
Source: As for Fig. 1 plus Hale (2008), Monger
(2005), Bird (1991).