Oil and political freedom in third world petro states: do oil prices and dependence on petroleum exports foster authoritarianism?
Tarzi, Shah M. ; Schackow, Nathan
INTRODUCTION
Why are so many oil-rich states so frequently undemocratic? Is
there a link between an oil-rich state's reliance on natural
resource exports as the primary source of government revenue and
autocracy? Interest in this topic is in large measure due the
persistence of despotism in the oil-rich Middle East. At first glance,
there appears to be some degree of correlation. For instance, amongst
all the oil-rich states that depend on oil exports for at least 25
percent of their total annual revenue, only Norway is a genuinely
functioning democracy. Whereas Mexico and Indonesia have maintained an
electoral democracy with some degree of success over the years, the vast
majority of oil export-dependent countries have been unable to translate
vast oil resources and revenue into either democratization or
sustainable economic growth. Regarding economic development and growth
in Gross Domestic Product, several authoritative studies have
demonstrated an inverse relationship between natural resource export
dependence and sustained economic growth. For instance, Jeffrey D. Sachs
and Andrew M. Warner conducted a study of 97 countries over a 19-year
period, and found that high ratios of natural resource exports to GDP
effectively translated into markedly slower rates of economic growth.
(1) Several other studies have arrived at similar conclusions. (2) To be
sure, as the experiences of Botswana and Norway indicate, natural
resource abundance does not drive down economic growth in a linear,
deterministic fashion. (3) Rather, the booming oil section potentially
discourages investment in ... agricultural and manufacturing exports by
raising their prices on international markets". (4) To make matters
worse, oil revenue funds monopolies, crowds out entrepreneurship, and
increases corruption. The consensus is that in relatively large samples,
"higher natural resource dependency is associated with lower
economic growth." (5)
In contrast to the issue of economic growth, the empirical data
concerning the linkages between natural resources' export
dependence and authoritarianism, often referred to as the "resource
curse," is not well-established and is subject to debate. (6) In
particular, there is a void in the literature regarding the impact of
natural resources' price changes, petroleum in particular, and the
relative validity of the resource curse hypothesis. (7)
In this study, we will focus on democratic rights and civil
liberties in oil-rich states whose economies are most reliant on
petroleum exports. Accordingly, the study will address the following key
questions: (1) Are governments highly dependent on revenue from the
export of oil less likely to embrace political freedoms? If so, has this
always been the case?; (2) To what extent do significant changes in oil
prices translate into decreased levels of political freedom in such
states? The second question is especially important because it points to
a dynamic perspective on the relationship between natural resource
prices over time and governments' degree of receptivity (or lack
thereof) to political freedom. Indeed, most studies on the subject tend
to take a snapshot of the resource curse at certain crucial periods.
Yet, the prices of natural resources fluctuate dramatically over time.
Unless we account for such fluctuations and their subsequent impact on
the pace of democratization, a resource curse study of this kind is
likely to be incomplete. Thus, a gap exists in the resource curse
literature, and we hope to offer preliminary insights to help fill this
void. (8) A study of this type is especially warranted because of the
dramatic fluctuations in the price of oil and concomitant political
changes and. in some instances, upheavals, in oil rich Third World
countries, the Middle East in particular. As such this study will help
fill a void in the literature.
Specifically, this study will track changes in the price of oil
over a significant period of time, pinpoint major oil price swings, and
relate these price swings to changes in the level of political freedoms,
thereby shedding light on whether changes in oil prices affect political
liberalization. However. before addressing the aforementioned key
questions, a general overview of the literature is warranted to
highlight the degree to which this study may contribute to addressing
gaps in the existing literature. The next section offers such an
overview. Section three details the methodology of the study. Section
four contains data and analysis concerning the link between changes in
the price of petroleum and political freedom. A concluding section
highlights key findings and offers suggestions for future research.
RESOURCE CURSE AND POLITICAL FREEDOM IN THE THIRD WORLD: AN
OVERVIEW
The dependent variable in our study is oil export-dependent
countries, variously referred to as "petro-states,"
"petrolist' states," "oil-rich' states",
and "rent-seeking" states. Naim favored the term
'petro-state'. According to him, these oil-rich countries are
plagued by weak institutions, and high concentration of power and wealth
in conjunction with a poorly functioning public sector, glaring economic
inequalities and frustrated populations. Nigeria is a good example. (9)
In contrast, Thomas Friedman preferred "petrolist state," or
states which were "dependent on oil production for the bulk of
their exports or gross domestic product and have weak state institutions
or outright authoritarian governments." (10) Gwen Okruhlik adopted
the term "rentier state," defined as a country that
"depends on external sources for a large portion of its
revenue". (11) According to this interpretation, revenue from the
international sale of petroleum is a form of rent that accrues to the
government.
Regardless of which definition one adopts, it is readily apparent
that all these states are endowed with oil wealth, and international
sales of petroleum constitute the bulk of government revenue. In
addition, these countries usually share several other attributes:
relatively weak political institutions, a wasteful public sector, and an
extreme concentration of economic and political power.
Following Michael Ross' seminal work on the subject, in this
study we adopt the term "oil-rich state." (12) This term
appears most appropriate because it is less inflammatory, has common
usage, and conveys the significance of international sale of petroleum
as the predominant source of revenue with the caveat that the government
acquires the revenue rather than citizens, private corporations, or
other members of the civil society.
Several studies stress the linkage between natural resource export
dependence and the lack of democratic freedoms. (13) One genre of
literature posits that because revenue from the sale of petroleum
displaces ordinary tax revenue, it makes it easier for governments to be
less accountable to public demands. (14) Ross correlated a high ratio of
oil and mineral exports to GDP with lower levels of governance. He
observed that wealth generated from extracting natural resources does
not increase the probability that a state will be a democracy. (15) In
addition, Friedman maintained that "the price of oil and the pace
of freedom always move in opposite directions in oil-rich petrolist
states." (16) Korhonen holds that the resource curse applies to
various extractive industries, in addition to petroleum, such as copper
and bauxite. (17) Similarly, the Economist reports that in Africa,
several resource-rich governments have used the considerably large
revenue amassed from the recent commodity boom to maintain control and
brutally silence domestic regime critics. (18)
On the other hand, a competing interpretation rejects the
afore-stated resource curse interpretation and concludes that there is
no significant causal linkage between reliance on revenue from the sale
of natural resources abroad, democracy and the state of political and
civil liberties in Third World countries. An influential study by Haber
and Menaldo offers pivotal arguments. Employing time-series centric
methods, they examine the long-term relationship between resource
reliance and regime type "both on a country by-country basis and
across several different panels." They find that "...
increases in resource reliance are not associated with
authoritarianism." (19) While these and other studies offer
insights regarding the degree to which increases in resource rents
affect political developments, the causal mechanism that links resource
curse to regime types is ambiguous. (20) Further, these studies fall
short of accounting for changes in the prices of petroleum over time and
their contemporaneous impact on political development in
resource-reliant regimes, a relationship that affects the causal
linkages.
Yet another genre of literature holds that oil wealth neither
hinders nor promotes democratization and political freedom. Still, a
fourth strand of research holds that natural resources, oil in
particular, improves political liberalization, provided that private
ownership of petroleum industries prevails. (21) Regarding the
relationship between changes in oil prices and political freedom,
contributors tend to conflate improvements in economic well-being or
level of modernization with improvement in political and civil
liberties. This line of reasoning does not square with ample empirical
evidence. Egypt, Iraq during Saddam's reign, Libya, Azerbaijan, and
Kazakhstan, to mention a few, are glaring examples where
authoritarianism is fully entrenched in spite of a modicum of economic
development. Saudi Arabia has yet to experience socio-cultural
modernization and political liberalization. Iran has made strides in
electoral democracy without concomitant progress in civil liberties,
individual rights, and cultural freedom for women. Finally, scholarship
often fall short of disentangling changes in resource income due to
fluctuations in the price of the petroleum from the general resource
curse proposition. (22)
To understand the causes of the resource curse phenomena, three
separate explanations stand out, the 'rent seeking',
'repression' and 'modernization' interpretations.
First, the "rent-seeking" interpretation holds that "as
oil revenues increase to the point at which they dominate a
government's revenue sources the government evolves from an
extractive state into a distributive one". (23) Since the
government enjoys a fairly large and stable stream of revenue from
international petroleum sales used to purchase patronage, it has less
incentive to tax its citizens, and in return, its citizens have less
incentive to hold their leaders accountable for their actions. Further,
strategically allocated bribes, especially to favored social groups, are
often used to quell political discontent and buy off political
consensus. (24)
According to Karl, 'rent seeking' has pernicious impact
on the quality of governance and administrative institutions in less
developed countries. He summarizes this dynamics well:
"Ineffective and inefficient governance, perhaps more than any
other factor, may explain the extent of poverty in oil-dependent
country, but this too is related to the presence of oil. Because the
revenue base of the state is the state, oil rents affect state capacity.
Oil dependence skews the institutional development of the state because
oil rents weaken agencies of restraint. In resource poor countries,
intense population pressure on scarce resources reduces the tolerance
for inefficiency and predation, and the economy cannot support extensive
protection or an over-expanded bureaucracy. But in oil states, the brake
of scarcity does not exist. Instead, oil dependence encourages the
expansion of states into new arenas while weakening opportunities to
strengthen administrative capacities, especially non oil-based tax
systems, merit-based civil services, and the rule of law--fundamental
elements for creating efficient states. (25)
Second the 'repression' thesis put forth by Ross, among
others, maintains that oil-rich natural resource and export-dependent
states use huge earnings from the sale of oil abroad to build their
police and security forces which, in turn, is unleashed to stifle
popular discontent and quell dissent and challenges to the regime. (26)
Unlike other interpretations, in this thesis the normal pathway of
causality is reversed--while oil wealth itself is often postulated to
cause an erosion of democracy, repression theory holds that autocratic
rulers use the wealth generated from oil exports to protect preexisting
undemocratic institutions. As the noted Harvard scholar Smith has
observed, the relative validity of this interpretation is in large
measure a function of demonstrating that "highly repressive regimes
that confront opposition during a crisis are more likely to survive
..." compared to less aggressive and repressive governments. (27)
The third perspective is the "modernization"
interpretation whose origin is rooted in the seminal works of Rostow,
Inkles and Huntington. It holds that regimes in oil rich Third World
states fail to use the accumulated oil wealth to promote development and
economic modernization. The underlying premise is that development
triggers social and cultural modernization which, in turn, promotes
democracy. (28) Unlike previous explanations, it is not so much the
regime type that matters. Rather, capitalist economic development (and
consequent socio-cultural modernization) is seen as a vehicle for
political liberalization and the push for electoral democracy.
To be sure, no single explanation can account for the complex
processes that lead to democratization. Ross, for example, examined
"all sovereign states with populations over one hundred
thousand" and found tentative support for all three effects. (29)
Further, any combination of these interpretations can be valid in
explaining aspects of the resource curse phenomena. Alternately, when it
comes to the linkage between resource wealth and regime durability in
the developing world, as opposed to resource wealth and democratization
in the Third World, each explanation has certain limitations. As
Benjamin Smith, a keen scholar on the subject has noted, the oil busts
of the late 1980s and early 1990s pose a question for the rentier effect
since the durability of authoritarian regimes was evidently
"independent of consistent access to rents with which regimes can
buy legitimacy". (30) Similarly, the repression effect falls short
of providing a persuasive account for the fact that despite decreases in
state revenue and increases in political unrest during busts, oil-rich
states faired much better, and failed significantly less often than the
developing nations in general. (31)
Finally several studies have addressed the linkage between resource
curse and oil related corruption. Terry Karl in particular offers
stunning evidence of extraordinary high level of corruption in oil
exporting countries notably Mexico, Venezuela and Nigeria. According to
him, a combination of oil rents, ineffective governance and
institutional weakness form a vicious circle leading to 'corruption
trap', a situation "... where payoffs at the top of political
and business institutions encourage the corruption of others until a
large percentage of public and private sector figures are
involved." (32) Consequently economic and public policy choices
that enhance opportunities for rent-seeking and huge payoffs such as
huge public sector investments imbued with massive regulations and mega
projects are adopted at the expense of those that maximize public
welfare and free markets. (33)
Apparently most studies provide a strong rationale for the resource
curse hypothesis, short of empirically testing the key hypothesis. This
study helps ameliorate the lack of empirical testing of the resource
curse theorems. Specifically, the next two sections will offer
preliminary empirical tests of the resource curse hypothesis. Among
others, a snapshot of the 25 states that relied most on oil exports in
1980, 1995, and 2009 will be offered, and will be paired on the degree
of political freedom using the Freedom House data. The comparative data,
in turn, will be compared to the so-called "petrolist states"
referenced by Thomas Friedman. Finally, for the period of 1980-2005, we
will reflect on democratic freedoms in these countries with references
to variations in crude oil prices to see if there is correlation between
changes in oil prices and democratic freedom, thereby offering a dynamic
picture of the relationship between oil-rich states' petroleum
export dependence and the importance of oil price changes as a key
driver for political liberalization.
METHOD
To determine whether oil export-dependent states are less likely
than other countries to democratize over time, we first need to
determine which states most rely on oil export revenues. Data from the
World Bank on fuel-based exports (as a percentage of merchandise
exports), GDP, and the value of merchandise exports, all in current US
dollars, can be used to measure a nation's reliance on oil. In
particular, the following formula captures the afore-stated statistical
metrics used to calculate oil exports as a percentage of GDP, an oil
dependence metric referred to here as the Oil Reliance Factor. or ORF.
(34)
(% Fuel Exports to Merchandise Exports/100) x (Value Merchandise
Exports)/Gross Domestic Product = ORF
For the years 1980, 1982, 1995, 2004, and 2009, the ORF of each
country with a fuel-based export percentage at or above 10%, a
conservative benchmark, was calculated and recorded. (35) As a result, a
list of the top 25 countries according to the ORF was generated. Several
caveats are worth noting. First, while data sets for some states were
incomplete, the World Bank report of 208 states offered ample coverage.
(36) Second, the dates were chosen to take advantage of somewhat robust
data sets offered by the World Bank during this time period, and to
allow comparison with previous research. (37)
After the top 25 lists for each of the years were completed, our
next task was to assign a value to each state that would measure the
extent of that state's political liberalization in a given year.
This was determined by using data from the widely respected Freedom
House, Freedom in the World survey (2006). The survey classifies
countries as Free (F), Partly Free (PF), or Not Free (NF), using a scale
of numerical ratings ranging from 1 (highest) to 7 (least) degrees of
political freedom for political rights and compatible ratings for civil
liberties. Countries with an average combined rating (between political
rights and civil liberties) of 1.0-2.5 were classified "free,"
those between 3.0-5.5 as "partially free," and those between
5.5-7.0 as "not free." We were able to trace and retrieve
country classifications since 1972. The ratings for each state appearing
in our top 25 lists were recorded for the relevant year; the overall
results appear in Figure l of our appendix.
A glance at the list of top 25 countries suggests several
interesting findings. First, the largest percentage of countries on four
of the five top 25 lists appear to be in the Freedom House
'NF' category, confirming the reputation of many oil-rich
countries for undemocratic governance. We also noted an apparent trend
towards 'Not Free' over time frame of several years. The data
from 1982, 1995, and 2004 clearly exhibit this trend, as well as a trend
towards decreased representation of "F" states. Moreover, the
data from 1980 and 2009 show that "NF" states rose by 8% in
these two years, while "F" states fell 4%.
To explore these findings in greater depth, we undertook an
elementary statistical analysis for the years 1980 and 2009 to see if
any correlations emerged (see Figure 2 in the appendix). For both years,
the median of the sample space was determined (0.131 for 1980, 0.161 for
2009). The data points were then organized into subsets of
"NF," "PF," and "F" states, and the
percentage of states lying above the median in each category were
recorded. We then calculated the sample mean and standard deviation for
each category. In particular, we found that, in 1980, six out of nine
"NF" states tell above the global median, and that this
represented a distance of more than six standard deviations away from
the expected value of 50%. Similarly, in 2009, eight out of 11
"NF'" states were above the median--just over 14 standard
deviations away from 50%. While we found no evidence of a correlation
between ORFs and either the "PF" or "F" rankings for
1980, 2009 exhibited inverse correlations ranging from 7 to 15 standard
deviations, respectively.
The afore-mentioned statistical analysis yielded several
interesting findings. First, the data suggest that oil export-dependent
oil-rich states are more likely to be undemocratic at any given time
than those not dependent on oil exports. For example, Figure 3
highlights the preponderance of oil rich Arab Middle East and the
resource rich states of Central Asia. Second, the data tentatively and
cautiously suggests that, over a sustained period of time, the class of
heavily oil export-dependent oil-rich states tends to show a propensity
to move toward undemocratic governance. In other words, over a period of
several years the greater the shift of oil-rich countries toward using
international petroleum sales and exports as source of income for the
regime, the higher the propensity toward undemocratic forms of
governance. Thus, a tentative, albeit important portrait that requires
additional research is one of oil export-dependent oil-rich states
gradually evolving into autocracies over time. Conversely, we can
cautiously stipulate that oil-rich "free" states tend not to
rely on the earnings from international petroleum sales for regime
durability or for generating economic growth. To be sure, we cannot draw
conclusions from the data with any degree of certainty. However,
preliminary findings suggest that both themes are plausible and
sufficiently interesting to warrant further research.
Finally, a new finding is that a level of ORF exists at which a
state's export-dependent practices are deemed unhealthy for
promoting democratic practices. We find that an ORF above 0.161 may be a
cause of concern, since such values are associated with decreased
freedom. Specifically, in the NF categories, in 2009, eight out of 11
states (72.73%) had an ORF above 0.161, significantly exceeding the
average of 5.5 (50%). Therefore, this finding suggests a direct positive
correlation between higher ORF values and the NF (Not Free) ranking.
(38)
RESOURCE EXPORT DEPENDENCE, OIL PRICE CHANGES AND THE EFFECT ON
POLITICAL FREEDOM
Thomas Friedman (2006) hypothesized that the "the price of oil
and the pace of freedom always move in opposite directions in oil-rich
petrolist states". Our task, therefore, was to illuminate whether,
and to what extent, changes in oil prices affect democratization in
resource export-dependent states. Accordingly, we began by investigating
the world's crude oil prices, using Brent (the world benchmark),
and accounting for pricing two-thirds of the world's
internationally traded crude oil supplies, as the measuring metric. (39)
Below is a graph depicting the yearly average Brent crude oil prices
from 1980 to 2005.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
All oil prices in the above graph appear in constant 2005 US
dollars. The time frame in the graph above covers periods of oil booms,
busts, and price stability, thereby permitting comparative observations
across all relevant scenarios. Thus, in 1980, the average price of a
barrel of Brent crude oil was $36.83; adjusting for inflation, this is
the equivalent of $87.65 in 2005. Between 1980 and 1986, there was a
significant price decline (in effect, an oil bust) followed by a period
of relative stability between 1986 and 2003 when prices (adjusted for
inflation) fluctuated within a $15-$36 band. In 2004, prices surged to
an average of $39.57, and thereafter skyrocketed to high of $54.52 in
2005.
Next, to test this proposition on the inverse relationship between
changes in the price of oil and the pace of political freedoms, we used
the sum of Freedom House basic data with each nation given a rank
between 2 and 14, and 2 being the most free and 14 the least.
Correlation coefficients between Brent oil prices and the freedom data
sets were calculated for each country appearing on Friedman's list
of "petrolist' states or oil-rich autocracies, covering the
periods 1980-2005 and 2002-2005 (See figure 3 in the appendix). It is
interesting to note that, at first glance, the countries present in our
snapshots also appear on Friedman's list, Venezuela and Saudi
Arabia being notable exceptions. Beyond these general observations, the
findings provide a mixed and complex picture that does not readily
support the widely accepted proposition that higher oil prices support
autocracy. Thus, for example, at one extreme, Iran exhibited the weakest
negative correlation at -0.409 value, whereas at the other end of the
spectrum, Russia (0.642) displayed the strongest positive correlation.
(40)
In order to lend support to the resource curse hypothesis, one
would expect positive correlation coefficients, since a high score from
the Freedom House statistics indicates a low level of actual freedom.
However, the data suggest a complex relationship between changes and
variations in oil prices and their effect on political liberalization.
Specifically, we find this to be the case in roughly half of the
countries included in this analysis. As a group several countries
demonstrated high absolute correlations in the period 2002-2005.
However, there were also instances of strong positive to strong negative
correlations during this period. In the period 1980-2005 the country
with the strongest negative correlation was Syria with -0.725, and one
of the weakest, in addition to Iran, was Egypt also at -0.409. The
weakest positive correlation was recorded for Kazakhstan with 0.060.
Angola, another oil rich state with overwhelming dependence on petroleum
export as the primary source of government revenue exhibited the weakest
correlation.
As such, it seems that the widely held public view regarding
oil-rich autocracies, as embodied in Friedman's thesis, is modestly
supported. However, the presence of negative correlations provides
evidence that oil revenues often move in the same direction as freedom.
Seen from the perspective of the modernization interpretation, one could
reasonably stipulate that some oil-rich nations direct the rising stream
of revenue due to higher prices to create strong state institutions and
regime durability. (41) Likewise, the findings do not negate the rentier
state proposition which holds that as oil revenue gain dominance over
government financing the state increasingly engage in distributive
policies to sustain political power. A safe conclusion to draw is that
the presence of both positive and negative correlations indicates that
different regimes use their oil wealth in diverse ways.
CONCLUSION
This study offered an empirical test of the "resource
curse" theorem according to which there is an inverse relationship
between high dependence on revenue from exports of natural resources,
petroleum in particular, and political freedoms. A study of this kind
was especially warranted because of the dramatic fluctuations in the
price of oil and contemporaneous political changes in oil rich Third
World countries, an issue largely ignored in the resource curse
literature.
This study formulated an Oil Reliance Factor (ORF) to measure
reliance on earnings from international petroleum sales and related
these to the Freedom House data on freedom. We found that the ORF score
suggested a negative correlation between political freedom and
dependence on international petroleum sales, indicating that
undemocratic states are more likely to be amongst the most reliant on
oil exports in any given year. In addition to oil rich Arab states,
Iran, Egypt under Mubarak rule, Angola, Nigeria, Kazakhstan stand out as
relevant examples and the Central Asian states. In addition, our
findings cautiously and tentatively suggest that, over a sustained
period of time, the class of heavily oil-export dependent states tends
to show a propensity to move toward undemocratic governance. At the very
least, the study points to an intriguing question for future research:
To what extent are oil-rich states that exhibit long-term and growing
dependence on oil exports likely to morph into petrolist states? A
complementary hypothesis is: Over time, the greater the move by oil-rich
countries toward using international petroleum sales and exports as a
source of income for the purpose of regime durability and survival, the
higher the propensity toward undemocratic forms of governance. The
proposition that petroleum export-dependent oil-rich states can evolve
into autocracies over time is a valuable point of departure for future
research.
Additionally this study yields refreshing and new policy-relevant
information; namely, that a level of ORF exists at which the magnitude
of oil revenue from an oil-rich state's exports hinders the
promotion of democratic practices and political freedom. We find that an
Oil Reliance Factor above 0.161 may be a cause for concern since such
values are associated with decreased freedom. It is, in effect, a red
flag for oil-rich states that either reach or exceed this ORF score. In
addition, we compared changes in freedom levels to changes in crude oil
prices over the 1980-2005 period. We found that the two variables were
correlated in many key states. However, the study did not support any
single interpretation, as the incidence of positive and negative
correlations were essentially the same. In short, this study gave
credence to the widely held proposition that the level of freedom and
the price of oil move ha opposite directions for petroleum
export-dependent oil-rich states. However, the findings can also be
interpreted to support competing modernization and rentier state
perspectives as nations choose to spend their oil wealth in different
ways; some leaders invest in the modernization of the country and its
citizenry, while others invest in the durability and survival of an
undemocratic regime.
Finally, while this study avoided a thorough assessment of the
linkage between oil-rich countries' dependence on international
petroleum sales and oil-related corruption, a careful study of this
linkage is clearly warranted. Indeed, in states suffering from the
resource curse often the flow of revenue from natural resources flow
straight to the coffers of the governing elite. As a result, corrupt
elite become more powerful.
NOTES
(1.) Jeffrey D. Sachs and Andrew M. Warner "National Resource
Abundance and Economic Growth" (November, 1997). Available at
:http://www.cid.harvard.edu/ciddata/warner_files/natresf5.pdf.
(2.) R.M. Auty, Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The
Resource Curse Thesis (London: Routledge, 1993).
(3.) Iikka Korhonen, "Does Democracy Cure a Resource
Curse?", BOFIT Discussion Papers, Vol. 18 (2004), 1-36.
(4.) Benjamin Smith, "Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the
Developing World, 1960-1999." American Journal of Political
Science. Vol. 48, No. 2 (2004), p. 234.
(5.) Iikka Korhonen, "Does Democracy Cure a Resource
Curse?", p.31. See also the Economist, issue 12-17, February 2011,
p. 12.
(6.) Several major works are reviewed in this essay. Among the most
recent notable exceptions, debating the linkage between natural resource
dependence and political freedom are: Thad Dunning, Crude Democracy:
Natural Resource Wealth and Political Regimes (Cambridge ; New York :
Cambridge University Press, 2008); Stephen Haber and Victor Menaldo,
"Do Natural Resources Fuel Authoritarianism? A Reappraisal of the
Resource Curse", American Political Science Review, Vol. 105, No. 1
(2011), 1-26. Two other works of distinction are, Terry Lynn, The
Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States (Berkeley, CA. 1997):
Leonard Wantchekon, "Why Do Resource Dependent Countries Have
Authoritarian Governments?" Journal of African Finance and Economic
Development, Vol. 2 (2002), 57-77. Two other works of distinction are:
Silje Alasken "Oil and Democracy: More than a Cross- country.
Correlation?", Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 47, No. 4, (2010),
pp. 421-431; and Ellis Goldberg, Eric Wibbels, and Eric Myukiyehe.
"Lessons from Strange Cases: Democracy, Development, and the
Resource Curse in the U.S. States", Comparative Political Studies.
Vol. 41 (2008), pp. 477-514.
(7.) There are a few studies which have addressed the linkage
between changes in oil prices and political freedom. In this genre
significant scholarship includes the works of Kristen Ardani and
Benjamin Jaques, "Petro-Dictators: Does the Price of Oil Impacts
Freedom?: A Re-Examination of the Political Dimension of the Resource
Curse". The Journal of International Policy Solutions, Volume 12
(Winter 2010), 32-40; Kristopher Ramsay, "Revisiting the Resource
Curse: Natural Disasters, the Price of Oil, and Democracy" a
Princeton University working paper available at:
www.princeton.edu/.../Site/ .../Revisiting the Resource Curse.pdf
(8.) Kristein Ardani and Benjamin Jaques address this issue. They
find a positive relationship between oil price hikes and political
freedom because, they argue, the government uses extra revenue from
higher oil prices to improve the welfare of its citizens. However, they
appear to conflate economic well-being funded by high oil prices with
increased political freedoms. Yet here are ample examples of oil rich
Third World Countries (Saudi Arabia, Libya and several other oil rich
countries in the Middle East) where governments co-opt opposition with
economic largess funded by high oil prices without offering meaningful
political and civil liberties. See Kristen Ardani and Benjamin Jaques,
"Petro-Dictators: Does the Price of Oil Impacts Freedom?: A
Re-Examination of the Political Dimension of the Resource Curse".
(9.) Moises Naim, "Russia's Oily Future." Foreign
Policy (January, 2004) Available at:
http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2004/01/01/ russias_oily_future
(10.) Thomas L Friedman, "The First Law of
Petropolitics", Foreign Policy, No. 5 (April 2006). Available at:
http://www.foreeign policy.com/articles/2006/04/25
(11.) Gwenn Okruhlik, Rentier Wealth, Unruly Law, and the Rise of
Opposition: The Political Economy of Oil States, Doctoral Dissertation
(1999), PhD. Program in Political Science of the City University of New
York, p. 295.
(12.) Michael L. Ross, "Does Oil Hinder Democracy?" World
Politics, Vol. 53 (2001), 325-361.
(13.) In addition to the seminal work of Ross, "Does Oil
Hinder Democracy?" and other sources referenced in note 6 above,
several other important pieces of scholarship shed light on the resource
curse debate are T. L. Karl, The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and
Petro-States. (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997); Nathan
Jensen and Leonard Wantchekon, "Resource Wealth and Political
Regimes in Africa", Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 37 (2004),
pp. 816-41; Kristopher N. D Ramsay, "Revisiting the Resource Curse:
Natural Disasters, the Price of Oil, and Democracy", International
Organization, Forthcoming.
(14.) Kristein Ardani and Benjamin Jaques, "Petro-Dictators:
Does the Price of Oil Impacts Freedom?: A Re-Examination of the
Political Dimension of the Resource Curse", p. 32.
(15.) Michael L. Ross, "Does Oil Hinder Democracy?"
(16.) Thomas Friedman, "The Firs Law of Petropolitics",
p. 31.
(17.) Iikka Korhonen, "Does Democracy Cure a Resource
Curse?", p. 7.
(18.) Economist, February 12-18, 2011, p. 12.
(19.) Stephen Haber and Victor Menaldo, "Do Natural Resources
Fuel Authoritarianism? A Reappraisal of the Resource Curse", p. 1.
(20.) Ibid. pp. 4-5. Ambiguity arise from Haber and Menaldo
treatment of the independent variable pivotal to their study's
findings. Specifically, they adopt 'Fiscal Reliance' and three
second-order metrics (Total Oil Income, Total Fuel Income, Total
Resource Income). Yet, neither 'Fiscal Reliance' nor the
secondary metrics collectively measure oil exports as a percentage of
merchandize exports or total petroleum exports as a percentage of total
exports, nor do these metrics measure the size of petroleum income as a
percentage of GDP. However, petroleum rent is an economic concept and
most economist studies use these later metrics. Their rationale is two
fold. First, they adopt these metrics for convenience sake because these
are in common usage in the literature. Ironically, the studies they cite
are those whose conclusion their findings question. Second, because the
afore-stated metrics, as they define it, lend themselves to the
study's method-time series and longitudinal data Thus, one almost
gets the impression that the methodology tail is wagging the dog.
(21.) This section draws heavily on Kristein Ardani and Jaques,
"Petro-Dictators: Does the Price of Oil Impacts Freedom?: A
Re-Examination of of the Political Dimension of the Resource
Curse", pp. 32-34. According to Ardani and Jaques, the works of
Jones Luong and Weinthal (2006) exemplifies this particular line of
reasoning.
(22.) In our judgment Ardani and Jaques thesis suffer from this
shortcoming. They find that "... as oil revenue increases in
oil-reliant states, the level of freedom in oil-reliant states increases
as well." These authors suggest a positive relationship between
higher oil prices and political freedom which they attribute to the
ability of leaders to payoff bribes and co-op opposition. While it is
true that higher oil prices enable repressive regimes to payoff
opposition, it does not follow that, as a result, democracy will
prevail. Otherwise Saudi Arabia, Libya, Iraq during Saddam's reign
and Khamenie's Iran would have already made transition to
democracy. See Ardani and Jaques, "Petro-Dictators: Does the Price
of Oil Impacts Freedom?: A Re-Examination of The Political Dimension of
the Resource Curse", p. 7.
(23.) Benjamin Smith, "Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the
Developing World, 1960-1999", American Journal of Political
Science. Vol. 48, No. 2 (2004), p.33.
(24.) Ibid.
(25.) Terry L. Karl, "Oil-Led Development: Social, Political
and Economic Consequences", Center on Democracy, Development, and
The Rule of Law, Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies,
Number 80 (2007), p. 16
(26.) Michael L. Ross, "Does Oil Hinder Democracy?", 357.
(27.) Benjamin Smith, "Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the
Developing World, 1960-1999." As Smith has amply demonstrated, in
the absence of empirical data to show a connection between the build up
and use of the repressive apparatus of the state and regime stability,
it seems less plausible that oil rich governments will allocate too many
resources to repressive state instruments of state power. Because, as
history has shown, these repressive institutions and structures can be
used to unseat the very leaders they are meant to protect.
(28.) Walt W. Rostow, Stages of Economic Growth: A Non Communist
Manifesto (Cambridge University Press, 1969); Samuel P. Huntington,
Political Order in Changing Societies (Yale University, Press, 2006);
Alex Inkles, "Industrialization, Modernization and the Quality of
Life", International Journal of Comparative Sociology, Vol. 34,
Nos. 1-2 (1993), 1-23.
(29.) Michael L. Ross, "Does Oil Hinder Democracy?", 351.
(30.) Benjamin Smith, "Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the
Developing World, 1960-1999.", 234.
(31.) Ibid. Apparently a 'rentier effect' occurs between
social groups favored by the regime so that such groups, including
favored tribes receive financial support. These social groups collect
'rents' somewhat akin to what the respective government garner
on the world resources market. In this sense the internal process of the
state mimics, albeit imperfectly, the state's external
'rentier' endeavors
(32.) Terry L. Karl, "Oil-Led Development: Social, Political
and Economic Consequences" p. 18).
(33.) Ibid. pp. 18-20. Terry L. Karl offers illuminating
country-based evidence of oil-related corruption in both the private
sector and the state. As he puts it, "The former president of the
French state oil company, Elf Aquitaine, is charged with presiding over
the commission payments on oil deals with African countries. Mobil oil
executives are charged with illegal payments in Kazakhstan. In Angola,
more than $1 bill ion per year of oil revenues has disappeared between
1996-2001--a full one sixth of the national income--in a country where
more than 70 percent of the population lives on less than $1 per
day." I bid. P. 19.
(34.) In this formula the ORF value is derived by dividing the
World Bank (WB) compiled statistic "% Fuel Exports to Merchandise
Exports" by 100 (i,e, a number between 0-100, as we need a number
between 0-1), multiplied by "Value of Merchandising Exports"
(another WB statistic) to give the value of fuel exports alone. The
final number is in turn divided by total GDP to yield the proportion of
the country's wealth which depends on fuel export. This measurement
is consistent with the methods used by Ross, Smith and others. As
Benjamin Smith points out, measuring oil reliance in this way makes it
feasible to transcend the general importance of exports to a given
country's macro economic performance and GDP. Smith writes,
"The oil dependence variable (OIL/GDP) is a measure of the ratio of
the value of oil exports to gross domestic product in a given
year." Sec Benjamin Smith, "Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in
the Developing World, 1960-1999", p. 236. In a similar vein, Ross
writes that "Oil reliance is measured by the value of fuel-based
exports divided by GDP". See Michael L. Ross, "Does Oil Hinder
Democracy?", p. 326.
(35.) The careful reader may notice that the 10% benchmark could
potentially discriminate against countries that have a fuel-based export
percentage under 10% but a high ratio of total export values to GDP.
However, our lists may underestimate the overall reliance on oil towards
the bottom of our top 25 lists. As such our estimates are rather
conservative.
(36.) We made minor adjustments, albeit sparingly, so that if
information wasn't available for a particular nation in a
particular year, data for the next closest year to within six years was
used instead. If even this adjustment didn't yield information the
state was excluded from the study--such was the case with Equatorial
Guinea in 1980, Egypt and Yemen in 2009. Incidentally, these states are
not major raw material exporters and thus not germane to this study.
(37.) In data gathering we came across an unexpected externality-
some states qualifying for our top-25 lists did not have oil production
capabilities. This is due to the fact that some states import fuel-based
products, refine them within their borders, and then sell them abroad.
To augment our data sets we used the CIA's World Factbook (2006) in
conjunction with country and regional profiles compiled by the United
States Energy Information Administration. If there was no evidence to
show that oil production or oil reserves exist within the territory of a
state, or it was explicitly stated that no oil reserves exist within a
state or that it re-exports petroleum-based products, then the state was
excluded from the list. See, Central Intelligence Agency, United States
Government, The World Factbook (2006); United States Government, Energy
Information Administration, EIA (2006).
(38.) The ORF is potentially a red flag as it is the value of the
median for the 2009 data set, the most recent and robust data set, hence
more conservative estimate. However, this 0.161 ORF value is offered as
a cautionary, note, not a definitive conclusion as the latter would
require elaborate statistical analysis far beyond the mandate of this
study.
(39.) Crude oil pricing differ depending on variety, quality, and
origin, including oil specific gravity, sulfur content and the weighed
system used in measuring a particular blend's production. That
said, Brent is the widely accepted benchmark. For an analysis of oil
pricing BBC. "Oil Markets Explained," 18 Oct 2007. Also, for
the purpose of this study, the data has been augmented by information
gleaned from the BP Statistical Review of World Energy. See a major
British Petroleum Global study, '"Quantifying Energy: BP
Statistical Review of World Energy June 2006." BP Global, 2006.
Because data was readily available, it permitted comparison across time.
Thus, 2009 was the year for which the latest data was available, 1980
the earliest, 1995 was chosen so that our figures could be compared to
the findings of other seminal works, notably those by Ross. The years
1982 and 2004 were chosen in part to take advantage of the somewhat
robust World Bank data sets for these years, also to offer additional
points of comparison. Further, the CIA World Factbook (2006) data base
and the United States Government Energy Information Administration
(2006) data bases were used to insure that only countries with
significant oil production and oil reserves were considered.
(40.) Regarding correlation coefficients, a brief description of
the origin of the statistical method is in order. If X = {[X.sub.1],
[X.sub.2], ..., [X.sub.n]} and Y = {[Y.sub.1], [Y.sub.2], ...,
[Y.sub.n]} are two random samples for different categories, then their
correlation coefficient can be attained by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Where [bar.X] and [bar.Y] are the sample averages. In our example,
X is tantamount to the Freedom House rankings for each year 1980, 1981,
1982, ... (example, [X.sub.1] would be the ranking in 1980, [X.sub.2]
the ranking in 1981. etc.). Let Y be the price of crude oil in each
corresponding year (example, [Y.sub.1] is the price in 1980, [Y.sub.2]
the price in 1981, etc.). We then calculate the correlation coefficient
using the above formula. The afore stated formula was adopted from
Wackerly, Menden Hall, and Scheaffer's "Mathematical
Statistics with Applications", 7th ed, p. 599. Access at:
http://www.thomsonright.com
(41.) Smith has suggested that regimes in oil rich countries can
use the extra increments of oil income to strengthen state institutions
that help extend regime's survival and durability. See Smith,
"Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the Developing World,
1960-1999".
By Shah M. Tarzi and Nathan Schackow *
* Shah M. Tarzi, PHD., is Lee L. Morgan Chair in International
Affairs and Professor of International Studies, Institute of
International Studies, Bradley University. Nathan Schackow holds a B.A.
degree from Bradley University.
Figure 1: Top-25 List Results
Freedo 1980 1982 l995 2004
m # # # # Countries
House Countries Countries Countries (% of Total)
Ranking (% of (% of (% of
Total) Total) Total)
F 8 (32) 11 (44) 3 (12) 1 (4)
PF 8 (32) 7 (28) 9 (36) 10 (40)
NF 9 (36) 7 (28) 13 (25) 14 (56)
Freedo 2009
m #
House Countries
Ranking (% of
Total)
F 7 (28)
PF 7 (28)
NF 11 (44)
Figure 2: ORF Statistics
Year Sample F F s.d. PF PF s.d. NF NF s.d.
Media Mean Mean Mean
n
1980 0.131 0.158 n/a 0.207 n/a 0.458 0.21
2009 0.161 0.127 0.0997 0.156 0.0651 0.290 0.173
Year Proportion F Proportion PF Proportion NF
above median above median above median
1980 4/8 4/8 6/9
2009 2/7 3/7 8/11
Figure 3: Freedom vs. Brent Crude Oil Prices
Country Correlation Correlation
1980-2005 2002-2005
Azerbaijan 0.061 -0.858
Angola 0.351 -0.432
Chad 0.512 no change
Egypt -0.409 0.985
Equatorial Guinea -0.491 -0.985
Iran -0.409 -0.912
Kazakhstan 0.060 0.902
Nigeria -0.657 0.948
Russia 0.642 -0.864
Saudi Arabia -0.711 0.797
Sudan -0.518 0.427
Uzbekistan 0.078 -0.944
Venezuela -0.430 -0.797
Algeria 0.094 0.962
Ecuador -0.455 0.725
Gabon 0.601 -0.916
Kuwait -0.418 0.905
Libya -0.537 -0.584
Syria -0.725 0.822