The new architecture of state government administration: key questions and preliminary answers.
Moynihan, Donald P.
INTRODUCTION
How are we to understand the changing architecture of state
government administrative reform? To do so, the article poses the
following basic questions about what has changed, why it changed, the
implications for management, and what the future will look like.
* What are the patterns of administrative reform among state
governments?
** What explains the adoption of administrative reforms?
* What are the implications of the constrained model of
administrative reform?
** Can managers make use of the new model?
** What factors foster the use of performance management reforms?
** What are the potential negative impacts of the constrained
model?
* What is the future of administrative reform?
** Will the market model will lead to more gaming and opportunistic
behavior?
** Will the market model crowd out intrinsic incentives?
** Will the market model foster partisan goals over management
values?
** Will the market model lead to better motivation and higher
performance?
** How might state governments reconsider authority?
I draw on my own research and that of others to offer preliminary
answers to the above questions. Where these answers fall short and are
speculative, there is a pressing need for additional research. A primary
goal of this article, therefore, is to consider the research agenda for
state government scholars interested in administrative reform.
This article proposes that the pattern of administrative change in
state government reflects a constrained model of reform. Aspects of New
Public Management (NPM) doctrine that emphasized building performance
information systems were adopted by state governments, while doctrinal
recommendations for increasing managerial authority were largely
overlooked. Performance information systems offered an attractive reform
for elected officials who valued the symbolic benefits of reforming
government, but who were reluctant to engage in a more contested fight
to dismantle the traditional civil service. This left state managers
with a constrained model of management, with new expectations in terms
of performance but little additional authority to fulfill those
expectations. Managers can make use of the constrained model, if they
have sufficient resources and can find a way to tie performance
information systems to their broader policy and management agenda.
It is possible that the constrained model of reform will remain in
place for some time, but there are indications that state governments
have found ways to weaken traditional employee protections without
directly overturning civil service legislation. This suggests the
displacement of the constrained model with a market model of
administration. The market model is expected to lead to better
performance and increased motivation, although some evidence suggests
that it will not always do so. The market model also brings dangers,
including gaming of performance measures, greater politicization of the
public service, and the crowding out of intrinsic motivation. Some of
these dangers might be averted if governments grant managerial authority
to career employees when there is a demonstrable benefit, rather than
granting large swathes of discretion to political appointees without a
clear sense of how this authority will be used. The article concludes by
considering some of the methodological challenges facing scholars of
administrative reform.
What are the Patterns of Administrative Reform among State
Governments?
Arguments about administrative reform have been characterized as a
series of doctrinal claims (Hood and Jackson, 1991). Doctrines are a
theoretical explanation of cause and effect, often presented as factual
and widely applicable, and designed to prompt actions consistent with
their preferred explanation. In recent decades, public management
doctrines have argued that traditional bureaucratic structures were
essentially broken, and should be replaced. The core elements of
administrative reform doctrine, reflected in the NPM, have been
considered in detail elsewhere (Gruening, 2001; Osborne & Gaebler,
1992; Schick, 2002). The NPM emphasizes the relative advantages of
markets over government monopolies as the model for efficient service
delivery.
The direction of state government reform in recent decades has very
much reflected the market bias of NPM doctrine. States have frequently
privatized or contracted out services that were traditionally directly
provided by government (Brudney, Frenandez, Ryu & Wright, 2005).
This article focuses primarily on those services that remain a part of
the core public service, while recognizing and sometimes referring to
third party government as an equally pressing subject of research
interest.
For the core public sector, NPM doctrine has argued that
traditional bureaucracies were overly controlling, fostering rule
compliance rather than performance. Without the price mechanism of a
market system, elected officials enjoyed poor control over bureaucrats.
NPM doctrine argued for encouraging innovation by reducing controls on
inputs, while holding bureaucrats more accountable via performance
measures. Managerial authority and the existence of performance
information therefore offer two benchmarks that we can look to when
examining the implementation of reform at the state level. The different
configurations of these two variables are illustrated in figure 2.1.
This figure illustrates an interpretation of public management history
as a gradual and logical transition from pre-bureaucratic spoils systems
(box 1) to bureaucratic systems (box 2) to the NPM-inspired market model
(box 3). Box 4 represents a constrained performance system, where
managers have limited authority but are expected to produce results.
Pre-bureaucratic systems are represented in box 1 of figure 2.1. In this
configuration, the combination of high levels of managerial authority
with lack of a focus on results creates the potential for public
officials to usurp the power of public organizations for goals unrelated
to effectiveness, such as maintaining political power, rewarding
political supporters, friends and relatives, or personal enrichment. The
spoils system in US government exemplified such characteristics. The
spoils system led to the introduction of input controls that limited how
public officials could use their human and financial resources. By
limiting managerial authority, governments created traditional
bureaucracies, as represented by box 2 of figure 1.
NPM doctrine argued that a shortcoming of the bureaucratic model is
that managers had no reason to focus on effectiveness and also lacked
the authority to improve service provision. Therefore, the next logical
stage in the development of public management systems was to convert the
bureaucracy into a quasi-market, by replacing controls over inputs or
process with the type of managerial authority seen in the private
sector, while developing performance indicators that could be used as a
public sector substitute for the private sector "bottom line."
This market model of management is represented by box 3 of figure 2.1.
In such a system, incentives can be matched to authority. Employees are
left to figure out how to juggle inputs and processes to achieve the
outputs the system requires. The market model represents the full
implementation of NPM doctrine, and assumes that financial incentives
and performance measures are appropriate measures to control behavior.
In such settings, spurred by competition and self-interest, employees
are expected to deliver enhanced performance for the promise of
financial reward.
NPM doctrine did indeed influence state governments, leading to new
configuration of governmental systems. But rather than reflecting the
market model called for by NPM doctrine, state governments shifted
towards a constrained model characterized by a high focus on results,
but limited managerial authority (box 4 in figure 2.1).
There are a variety of empirical sources to support evidence of the
move toward this constrained model of reform. There is evidence of
dramatic adoption of performance information systems in all states via
statute or administrative reform (Moynihan, 2006). With very few
exceptions, such systems were created in the 1990s and 2000s (Melkers
and Willoughby, 2004). There was remarkable consistency in the design
and state intent of these systems (Moynihan and Ingraham, 2003). Like
the federal Government Performance and Results Act of 1993, these
systems emphasized connecting strategic planning and performance
measurement, and called for agency level reporting of data to the
central budget office, usually as part of the budget process. Despite
the similarity of the formal structure of such systems, their
implementation varied a good deal. A content analysis of the range of
information generated by performance information systems found a great
deal of variation, with some states providing a wide range of high
quality information, often with audit systems to verify this data, while
other states produced very little data (Moynihan, 2006).
The widespread adoption of performance information systems was not
accompanied by vast delegations of authority to managers. With a number
of notable exceptions (Georgia, Texas and Florida), most state
governments chose to retain traditional civil service systems and
traditional control on inputs. While Selden, Ingraham and Jacobson
(2001) argued that significant decentralization was taking place in
personnel matters, such decentralization was not as radical as called
for by NPM doctrine, and did not place authority in the hands of
managers. Such authority remained with central government personnel
agencies, or increasingly, with agency level personnel offices. Even in
areas where managers have significant autonomy, they were constrained by
a broader framework established by personnel offices and civil service
guidelines. Moynihan (2006) reports that state government managers enjoy
high levels of autonomy in some areas, such as establishing performance
expectations and administering performance appraisals. However, they are
closely guided by centralized performance appraisal instruments and
scoring systems, and have little control in determining compensation to
reflect performance. Similarly, classification systems that detail the
duties and status of employees are largely centralized at the state
level, beyond the control of individual managers. In terms of hiring,
managers are usually involved in approval to fill a position,
interviewing candidates, recommending appointments and making
appointment decisions. However, a mixture of the agency and statewide
personnel agencies first establish the screening, ranking and selection
of a candidate pool.
Managerial authority means more than personnel authority. NPM
doctrine also argued for providing managers with greater control over
financial inputs. Surveys of state government officials suggest little
provision of such flexibility. Significant ex-ante controls continue to
limit agency discretion in procurement, contracting, the ability to
switch money between programs, and the ability to carryover unspent
funds from one year to another (Moynihan 2006).
Other research provides support for the claim that state
governments pursued a constrained model of administrative reforms.
Senior state administrators surveyed by Brudney, Hebert and Wright
(1999) reported that the most intensively adopted reforms of the 1990s
were related to creating performance information systems, while the
least intensively adopted reforms were the reduction of personnel and
financial management controls. Burke, Cho, Brudney and Wright (this
issue) provide further confirmation of this finding. Anders (2006)
surveyed state government officials in 1996 and 2004, and found a strong
and increasing belief that performance information systems had not been
accompanied by grants of new discretion. Instead, managers complained
that the new procedures to create performance data created a net
increase in the rules that had to be followed.
What Explains the Adoption of Administrative Reforms?
A natural question that emerges is why did state governments arrive
at a constrained model of administrative reform? Case research on
performance management in three states--Alabama, Vermont and
Virginia--offers some insights (Moynihan, 2005a). Each state had created
performance information systems, and had ignored doctrinal arguments for
reducing traditional managerial controls. The findings that emerged from
the cases emphasized the role of central agencies in defining the
reform, and the motivation of elected officials selecting the reform.
Elected officials were guided by the costs and benefits of reforms,
particularly symbolic benefits.
Central agency officials, especially those in the state management
or budget office, were key figures in translating doctrinal ideas into
specific policy proposals. These officials were broadly aware of
doctrinal ideas from a variety of sources--popular publications such as
Osborne and Gaebler's (1992) Reinventing Government, the
recommendations of professional groups, and the reforms adopted by other
states and the federal government. All of these sources suggested
building performance information systems. State governments also faced
coercive pressure to pursue performance measurement to maintain their
bond ratings and as a condition of receipt of federal grants. In the
minds of these officials, performance information systems became a norm
that signified a professionally run government.
Central agency staff did not push for providing managers with
greater authority, partly because this aspect of NPM doctrine was not
emphasized strongly by professional organizations, and has not seen
widespread adoption by a critical mass of US governments that could
provide a safe exemplar for other states to follow. Arguing for greater
managerial authority would also require central agencies to challenge
their own norms and re-imagine their roles. While performance
information represents a means centralized control, providing greater
discretion to managers means eliminating many of the traditional
controls on inputs that central agency officials have exerted throughout
their professional life.
Elected officials who called for greater bureaucratic
accountability and performance were therefore generally given a reform
option that emphasized performance information systems. For elected
officials, this was a relatively attractive proposal. Performance
information systems offer a relatively low cost reform option, requiring
little additional funds, and with the burden falling chiefly on the
agency bureaucrats who collect and disseminate information. By contrast,
eliminating traditional management controls over financial and human
resources have real costs. These traditional controls on bureaucracy are
still valued by state legislatures. While the introduction of
performance information was sometimes billed as performance budgeting,
appropriations committees continue to rely on input information to
determine budgets and are wary of giving executive branch officials
greater discretion. Civil service systems are also valued by public
service unions, who worry about the potential loss of benefits to their
members and of abuses of power. This means that efforts to change state
civil service systems encounter political opposition. By contrast,
performance information systems do not threaten any particular
constituency.
Performance information systems also offer some benefits to elected
officials. They provide an additional source of oversight and control
over bureaucratic activity, although it is not clear that elected
officials or even central agency staff frequently use such information
(Melkers & Willoughby, 2004; Moynihan, 2006). The primary benefit of
performance information systems for elected officials appears to be
symbolic. March and Olsen (1983) noted that administrative reforms allow
elected officials to express symbolic beliefs that appeal to the
public--a shared frustration with bureaucracy, and an emphasis on
efficiency and rationality. While the public may be uninterested in the
specific performance information, the adoption of such performance
management reforms offers symbolic reassurance that there is some effort
to make government more accountable, effective and efficient. Elected
officials hoped that reforms would help them to accrue benefits such as
a positive public image in the media, improved re election chances, and
through those political advantages, a greater capacity to implement
their policies.
WHAT ARE THE IMPLICATIONS OF THE CONSTRAINED MODEL OF
ADMINISTRATIVE REFORM?
This section explores the implications of the restructured
architecture of state government administration for practice.
Can Managers Make Use of the New Model?
One of the themes apparent from examining recent state
administrative reforms is the tension between the formal reforms adopted
and actual implementation. As noted previously, this is reflected in the
fact that though states have adopted strikingly similar performance
information requirements, the range and quality of the information
produced varied a great deal. Another tension between adoption and
implementation is how managers actually use this information. Formal
requirements can force managers to collect and distribute performance
information, but cannot require use. To understand if reforms are having
an impact requires studying the role of performance data in
decision-making, and the most realistic and compelling place to look is
among agency managers (Joyce & Tompkins, 2002).
There are examples of managers making use of the new architecture
of state government administration. For example, Franklin (2000)
compares quite different agency-level implementation of similar
performance management reforms in Arizona and Texas. Managers in Texas
took a cynical view of the reforms as an exercise in control, while
managers in Arizona were more likely to use the information. In Florida,
Berry, Brower and Flowers (2000) reported considerable variation between
agencies in terms of their use of performance management.
Studies of corrections managers in Vermont, Virginia and Alabama
offered similar findings (Moynihan, 2005a). While managers in Alabama
saw little benefit in the reforms, managers in Vermont and Virginia
found ways to use information. Many of these uses were not classic
performance management examples of direct efficiency improvement through
reengineered processes, but reflected a desire to use performance
management to improve the capacity of the organization. For example,
managers in Virginia saw strategic planning and performance measurement
training as a mechanism to train a new generation of agency managers,
build a results-oriented culture and improve communication across
different parts of the agency. In Vermont, managers used performance
management to reexamine the basic assumptions of their organization,
develop a new philosophy for corrections, and measure the efficacy of
this new approach.
Clearly, therefore, even without new delegations of discretion,
some agency managers were able to make use of performance information to
make positive changes, although not in the revolutionary way promised by
NPM doctrine. Across states, and even within states, the same reforms
elicited different types of responses from agency managers. This
suggests the importance of agency level variables in answering another
critical question: what factors foster the use of performance management
reforms?
Resources are clearly an important factor. While some have made the
argument that limited resources will spur agencies to pursue performance
management, the opposite appears to be true (Berry, 1994; Seong, 2004).
Moynihan (2005a) found that lack of resources was the primary factor in
limiting the ability of Alabama in implementing reforms. The
availability of resources matters in two ways. First, reforms need
resources if they are to be implemented properly. In Virginia and
Vermont specialist staff were tasked with ensuring the implementation of
the reform--collecting and reporting information, but also organizing
training sessions, and finding ways to make use of information. In
Alabama, by contrast, no additional staff were available to focus on
performance management. The task was left to already overtaxed budget
staff that did the minimum necessary to satisfy external reporting
requirements, but no more. More broadly, resources affect the strategic
stance of the agency. Alabama was in a constant reactive stance, doing
its best to maintain overcrowded prisons with inadequate resources and
under constant threat of judicial intervention. The only way that staff
saw performance management as useful to them was in communicating their
needs to the legislature. Once they saw that such needs would not be
satisfied, they viewed performance management as pointless.
Leadership is another key factor in performance information use.
Agency managers look to political leaders to determine if administrative
reform is a genuine political priority or merely rhetoric. Agency
leaders are even more important. Berry, Brower and Flowers (2000)
emphasize the role of agency leadership in using performance management
processes to identify agency mission and improve agency capacity, while
managing the agency's external stakeholders. When agency leaders
give prominence to performance management reforms, employees are more
likely to use performance information in decisions (Moynihan and
Ingraham, 2004). In the three states examined by Moynihan (2005a), the
agenda of senior managers was a critical factor in determining whether
agency staff devoted energy and resources towards implementing
administrative reform. Agency leaders had an agenda they wish to pursue,
informed and constrained by the organizational environment. They used
performance management reforms when it allowed them to pursue this
agenda.
Given the central importance of performance data to government
reform, we need better and broader theories of information use that
incorporate both organizational and individual factors. The literature
on organizational learning offers one basis for such theories. Some of
this literature emphasizes the importance of organizational learning
mechanisms: "institutionalized structural and procedural
arrangements that allow organizations to systematically collect,
analyze, store, disseminate, and use information that is relevant to the
effectiveness of the organization" (Lipshitz, Popper and Oz, 1996,
p.293). While state governments have done well in building
organizational learning mechanisms that collect, store and disseminate
information, they have struggled to establish routines to analyze and
use this information. Managers are expected to make use of information,
but offered little provision or guidance for doing so.
One routine to facilitate information use is a learning forum,
which is a routine where actors collectively examine information,
consider its significance and decide how it will affect future action.
State managers sometimes use such routines, perhaps as part of a
strategic planning process, sometimes as part of a regular review of
performance data (Moynihan 2005b). These routines tended to work best
when there were clear ground-rules or norms that allowed an exchange of
views in a non-confrontational fashion, when there was collegiality
among participants, and when standing in the forum was based on
expertise rather than hierarchical position. These factors helped to
reduce the type of defensive reactions that generally inhibit learning.
Overcoming defensiveness enables actors to identify, examine and suspend
basic assumptions, which is especially important for organizations
seeking to radically change how they perform their tasks. By
incorporating a diverse set of set of organizational actors, the forum
reduced the risk of groupthink, and incorporated multiple perspectives
on the same information. Such forums worked best when they moved beyond
simply reviewing quantitative information, but also incorporated
experiential knowledge of process and work conditions that explain
success, failure and the possibility of innovation. All of this requires
an organizational culture that encourages learning and challenging
existing assumptions and processes.
What are the Potential Negative Impacts of the Constrained Model?
This section examines the possible negative implications of the
constrained model for management, focusing on the potential for
frustration and compliance, gaming and opportunistic behavior.
The symbolic motivation for reform may signal a familiar narrative
of reform failure, as politically motivated reforms fail to make
meaningful changes, and are greeted with cynicism by public employees
who have seen such reforms come and go, and know how to satisfy formal
requirements without changing their behavior (Downs & Larkey, 1986;
Wildavsky, 1975). There is empirical support for this view. Anders
(2006) reports a growing sense of cynicism among public employees who
see performance management reform as failing to add a great deal of
value for managers. Melkers and Willoughby's (2004) surveys of
state officials find, at best, limited belief that performance
information is being used for decision-making. Even case studies that
have reported positive uses of performance management in some settings
have also found frustration and a compliance mentality in others
(Franklin, 2000; Moynihan, 2005a).
If we assume that employees passively resist the spirit if not the
letter of the new reforms, frustration and compliance is the most likely
outcome. Another possibility is that employees pursue the incentives of
the new system but in ways that are ultimately damaging. A critique of
the traditional bureaucratic system is that it fostered goal
displacement, as employees became so focused on rules that they lost
sight of organizational goals. But performance management regimes can
engender their own form of goal displacement when employee focus on
improving measured performance at the expense of actual performance.
Governments frequently have difficulty in finding measures that
perfectly reflect the underlying missions they pursue (Heinrich, 1999).
In addition, most public services seek to achieve many goals, some of
which may conflict with one another, and it is likely that not all of
these goals will be adequately measured or rewarded. This allows
opportunistic actors to focus on advancing the performance measures that
they are being rewarded for, while neglecting unmeasured aspects of
performance. As a result, efficiency goals are often pursued at the
expense of program quality, short-term goals over long-term measures of
effectiveness, easy-to-measure goals over more ambiguous goals
(Heinrich, 2003). As actors devote more energy to improving measured
performance, they may develop strategies that fall into the category of
gaming (Hood, 2006; Talbot, 2004):
* Cream-skimming: focusing effort on sub-groups of clients most
likely to provide greatest impact on performance measures while
effectively denying services to others.
* Ratchet effects: curbing productivity in one time period to avoid
the setting of more challenging targets in another.
* Output distortion: manipulation of measurement processes to
improve measured performance.
* Measure selection: selecting measures that will offer the most
favorable portrayal of a service.
* Spinning: uncritically accepting positive performance
improvements caused by other factors, or pleading for extenuating
circumstances when performance is poor.
* Churning: frequently adopting different targets of measures to
prevent comparison across time.
* Cheating: Simply making up numbers, though rare, does occur. For
example, in 2003, a California for-profit contractor working for the
federal government reported as processed approximately 90,000
immigration documents. The contractor had shredded the documents (Broder
2003).
Another consequence of measurement-driven goal displacement is to
overlook rules-based forms of accountability such as due process
guarantees. Performance measures emphasize service outcomes, leading
them to overlook and fail to target guarantees of equity of service
(Radin, 2006), or transparency (Piotrowski & Rosenbloom, 2002).
The most egregious examples of opportunistic behavior appear to
occur when performance targets are accompanied by strong financial
incentives (Hood, 2006). Given that most state governments do not, for
core government services, tie such incentives to performance measures,
this reduces the potential for opportunistic behavior. In addition, core
services are usually protected by traditional rules to ensure due
process and equity considerations. However, one area where state
governments do tie high-powered incentives to measured performance, and
generally fail to replicate traditional due process protections, is
where they contract out services. In particular, the devolution of
welfare services to state government has led to a large market where
third-party government, often for-profit providers, are likely to engage
in the opportunistic behavior. There has been some notable case-study
and large-n work that has recently began to document such problems (Dias
and Maynard-Moody 2007; Fording, Schram and Soss 2006; Heinrich and Choi
forthcoming).
WHAT IS THE FUTURE OF ADMINISTRATIVE REFORM?
State governments have arrived at a model with well-developed
performance information systems, but usually married to traditional
civil service systems. Even though the NPM no longer looks all that new,
there are not obvious rival doctrines that offer an alternate model for
administrative reform. One possibility is that given the recent period
of considerable change, public management reform policy at the state
level will settle into an incremental pattern (Buamgartner & Jones,
1993). If this is the case, the primary challenges for state governments
will be to figure out how to make use of the performance information
systems that they have built.
An alternate vision of the future is that reform will continue
rather than stop. Given the absence of an alternative to NPM doctrine,
future reforms are likely to see a greater effort to implement the
previously neglected aspect of this doctrine, i.e. greater managerial
authority. For the moment, the leading states are Florida, Georgia and
Texas; states that have essentially done away with their civil service
systems, making most if not all of their employees "at will"
and therefore lacking any protections beyond those afforded to private
employees. (Given that these states may offer a glimpse of the future of
state administrative reform, there has been precious little serious
empirical analyses of the implementation of these reforms, and in
speculating on the future I rely a great deal on survey work of
locally-based scholars: Coggburn (2006) in Texas, Bowman and West (2006)
in Florida, and Kellough and Nigro (2002; 2006) and Condrey and
Battaglio (2007) in Georgia).
Drawing on a recent survey of state government personnel
administrators, Hays and Sowa (2006) argue that state governments are
indeed following the example of Florida, Georgia and Texas. Changes
appear to be largely driven by Governors who have used executive
authority to weaken unions, renegotiate contracts, and pursue
outsourcing, but without explicit legislative support. While still
reluctant to eliminate civil service laws, state governments are finding
alternate ways to erode traditional employee protections by
decentralizing personnel functions, declassifying employees from civil
service to at-will status, and reducing employee ability to appeal
adverse decisions. The result, according to Hays and Sowa (2006) is that
"many public servants today work in settings that are not too
different from their private sector counterparts. Those inside the
"protected" service enjoy some due process rights, but nowhere
near the number that is commonly believed" (Hays & Sowa 2006,
p.111). The evidence presented by Hays and Sowa suggests another example
of the disjunction between formal reform and implementation. While most
states have kept civil service legislation "on the books",
they have undermined these laws in practice.
The pattern of reduced employee protections, occurring alongside
increased contracting out of services, suggests an evolution from the
constrained model to a market model of administrative reform. Reforms
which give more authority to managers to hire, promote and fire have
also provided greater potential for introducing significant financial
incentives. The market model raises its own research questions.
Will the market model will lead to more gaming and opportunistic
behavior? As discussed in the last section, the application of
performance measures raises the potential for actors to behave
opportunistically, improving measured performance at the expense of
unmeasured aspects of performance and other forms of accountability. The
potential for such gaming increases as performance is tied to
high-powered incentives such as performance pay or organizational
budgets (Heinrich, 2007).
Will the market model crowd out intrinsic incentives? Scholarship
on motivation among public employees has found a strong sense of public
service motivation (Perry & Wise, 1990). Research has suggested that
extrinsic rewards tend to devalue and crowd out intrinsic motivation
(Moynihan, forthcoming). Administrative systems built on assumptions of
self interest will struggle to attract and retain those who see the
public sector as a noble calling and will weaken the intrinsic
motivations of those who remain. There is some indirect empirical
evidence from state government of a crowding out effect. Kellough and
Nigro (2002) report that short term turnover intention increased from
17.5% to 25% after the introduction of reforms in Georgia, suggesting
that the new system is increasing turnover. They also found that,
relative to the new unclassified employees, significantly higher numbers
of classified employees believed that the new system placed too great an
emphasis on money as an incentive, suggesting that employees hired
without protections were more motivated by extrinsic motivators
(Kellough & Nigro, 2006). Comments from different Florida employees
interviewed by Bowman and West (2006) emphasize the declining sense of
intrinsic motivation: "It used to be that we belonged to a
fraternity of public service. People never considered job offers to
leave. Now they are actively looking," (p.149); "Morale is
down the drain" ... "There is no loyalty in the workforce;
everyone feels like a free agent. We are day labor" (p.153).
Will the market model foster partisan goals over management values?
One of the oddities of agency theory that underpins NPM is that it
assumes that political principals are naifs taken advantage of by
all-knowing bureaucratic agents. In reality, political principals may
act to implement partisan political goals which may weaken the capacity
of the public service as a whole. One tradition of US administration,
unlike the countries that have most enthusiastically embraced NPM ideas,
is to rely on relatively large numbers of appointees to ensure political
responsiveness. The civil service system was built as a bulwark against
excessive political partisanship and the spoils system. By removing
employee protections, and contracting out significant portions of state
government activity, the market model provides considerable opportunity
for partisan-minded political operatives to build a new spoils system.
This is certainly a challenging research question. Because of the
sensitivity of the topic and lack of transparency of useful information,
survey responses may be biased or uninformed. In-depth case studies
would be beneficial, but difficult because they seek to uncover behavior
that some political principals would prefer to remain hidden. It may be
because of such research challenges that there is a dearth of compelling
evidence one way or another. In Georgia, Kellough and Nigro (2002) did
not ask directly about partisanship, but did report that large
majorities felt that office politics and favoritism played a major role
in determining performance appraisals. They also found that just over
44% of unclassified employees believed that the civil service reform
made them more responsive to the goals of agency administrators
(Kellough & Nigro, 2006), with Condrey and Battaglio (2007) finding
that only 47% of HR professionals also felt that employees had become
more responsive under the new system.
As to the question of direct partisanship, the evidence is mixed,
although suggestive that it partisan actions are taking place, they are
not blatant. In Texas, Coggburn's (2006) survey found that human
resource directors agreed that the lack of civil service protections
made employees more receptive to agency administrator priorities, but
overwhelmingly rejected that the new system had led to partisan
influences on personnel matters. In Georgia, Condrey and Battaglio
(2007) report data from a survey of agency human resource professionals
that lead to state that "there appears to be no wholesale rush to
spoils in the state" (p.436). However, this positive view may be a
function of the survey population. Condrey and Battaglio acknowledge
that human resource professionals and program managers may have
differing views. Bowman and West (2006) provide evidence of these
differing views. Florida human resource staff also report little
partisanship, but these views were strikingly at odds with the
perspectives of senior managers in the state, who generally saw the
reforms as weakening nonpartisan service. What was most striking in the
comments of Florida interviewees was not the relatively rare mention of
explicit partisan reprisals, but of the broader and more pernicious
influence the reforms have had on employee perceptions of appropriate
behavior. Because, as one employee put it "most perceive that if
they don't tow the party line that their job is at risk"
(Bowman & West, 2006, p.153), political appointees generally do not
need to make explicit threats for public employees to become more
responsive to partisan goals.
Will the market model lead to better motivation and higher
performance? The risks associated with the market model may be worth
taking if it does, indeed, provide the improvements in motivation and
performance promised by NPM doctrine. There are, however, a number of
reasons to doubt that market model will deliver such benefits. First,
because of the potential for gaming, measured performance may improve at
the expense of other aspects of performance (Heinrich, 2007). Second,
the crowding out effect may reduce motivation and performance: in
situations where individuals have high initial endowments of intrinsic
motivations, extrinsic rewards may actually reduce performance (Weibel,
Rost & Osterloh, 2007). Third, employees operating under greater
managerial authority do not report higher levels of motivation. In
Texas, Coggburn's (2006) survey of human resource specialists found
no clear agreement that the decentralized system led to higher
motivation or efficiency, and found general disagreement with the claim
that the new system made employees more productive. In Florida, senior
managers reported no changes in productivity, but believed that morale
and loyalty had suffered (Bowman & West, 2006). Indeed, Berry Brower
and Flowers (2000, p.354) report that where performance improvement
efforts did take place in Florida, they tended to occur in spite of the
performance incentive system in place rather than because of it. In
Georgia, Kellough and Nigro (2006) report that only 28% of employees
believed that their new pay for performance system was effective at
motivating employees, while Condrey and Battaglio (2007) found human
resource professionals only slightly more optimistic, with 35% agreeing
that the new system motivated employees. The vast majority of Georgia
employees felt that the purpose of bonus systems was to control the
state payroll, and that their pay was not connected to performance
(Kellough and Nigro 2006). In addition, Kellough and Nigro (2002) report
lower job satisfaction after reforms were implemented, and found that
cynicism toward the reforms was a significant negative predictor of job
satisfaction.
A final reason that the market model will not lead to greater
performance is that state governments continue to see personnel reforms
and performance management reforms as largely disconnected, adopted at
different times for different purposes. NPM doctrine portrayed
performance information systems and managerial authority as mutually
dependent aspects of successful reform. While the state level promoters
of increased managerial authority argue that it will foster greater
performance, state governments have not connected the use of such
authority to agency-level performance goals as part of one coherent
management system. For instance Georgia's much lauded pay for
performance system relies on an individual performance appraisal system,
an approach which has been tried, tested and failed in the public
sector, and does not clearly connect to program or organizational
performance. Condrey and Battaglio (2007) suggest that the devolution of
authority is generally not used to streamline human resource processes,
and find that only 43% of Georgia human resource professionals believe
that their new system has made personnel processes more efficient.
In some respects, the disconnect between managerial authority and
performance information systems may be a good thing, since it reduces
the potential for high-powered incentives to lead to negative outcomes
such as opportunism or crowding out. However, the absence of this link
does increase the risk that states will slide back to box 1 in figure 1,
where authority will be used for nonperformance reasons such as
partisanship, and generally reduced the potential to see the performance
benefits promised by NPM doctrine.
How Might State Governments Reconsider Authority?
The concern with the failure to link authority to performance
raises a final object of speculation. Is it possible for state
governments to find another approach to authority that is better tied to
performance, but limits the dangers of politicization inherent in any
system that relies so much on political appointees? The varying
conceptualizations of authority under the Clinton and George W. Bush
Administrations at the federal level illustrate two different ways in
which authority might be understood. We might call the Clinton approach
an empowerment approach to authority, while the Bush approach is a more
political understanding of authority.
The Reinvention initiative under Clinton emphasized empowering
frontline managers from specific rules that affected their ability to
implement performance-enhancing innovations. Frontline managers could
request waivers from rules if they could make the case that these rules
prevented more effective, efficient or customer-friendly operations. The
empowerment conception of managerial authority required an ability to
justify authority in the name performance.
While the Bush Administration has also adopted the rhetoric of
providing managerial flexibility, the manager they envisioned was not a
front-line official trying to solve operational problems, but senior
level political appointees. The Bush Administration argued that these
appointees needed broad swathes of discretion, but did not offer
justification for how this authority would be used. This political
approach to authority was typified by fierce battle the Bush
Administration waged to provide discretion to the Secretary of the
Department of Homeland Security over personnel matters, even as it
refused to offer a blueprint for how this authority would be used
(Moynihan 2005). This is the vision of authority pursued in Florida,
Georgia, and Texas, and increasingly in other states (Hays and Sowa
2006). The political approach arises as much from a frustration with
bureaucracy and public service unions as it does from a desire to make
bureaucracy work better. It effectively favors political appointees and
increases the possibility of partisan uses of authority. To better
connect authority and performance, and to reduce the potential for
flexibility to be used for partisan purposes, state governments should
strive to design an empowerment approach to authority, asking that
managers offer some justification for the provision of greater freedoms,
and focusing increased discretion to career staff.
CONCLUSION
The questions posed in this article are not intended to be
definitive. In particular, this article did not attempt to map out the
increasingly important role of third-party government. However, the
questions are broad, important and will continue to be of relevance. The
answers are limited by the shortcomings of existing research, and the
characteristics of the time that are being documented. They can always
be improved upon, and I conclude by considering challenges that
researchers face.
To provide more complete answers, we need additional research that
documents state government employee attitudes toward and behavior
engendered by reforms. One key point to emerge from research cited in
this article is that that while states may look similar when comparing
"on-the-books" administrative reform, they look much different
when research probes implementation. Research needs to get beyond
formalism, and incorporate views of officials and actual practice.
Survey approaches to administrative reform topics can provide
better information. Surveys of officials should less frequently ask
whether individuals view the reforms as worthwhile- this tends to foster
an upward bias in response, frequently because employees perceive that
these reforms may map out how government should be run, and because they
assume that someone else is finding them useful. Instead, surveys should
ask if and how employees use performance information, and the effect of
new reforms on motivation. Where possible, such data should form the
basis of quantitative analyses that provides more compelling insights
than simply reporting descriptive data. Other non-survey based
quantitative analyses of performance data can shed light on whether
performance is actually improving and whether gaming takes place (e.g.,
Heinrich, 2007).
Case studies can supplement quantitative research by offering
detail on how data is used, if at all, and portray the contextual issues
that foster use and/or lead to non-use, frustration, gaming and
crowding-out effects. A particular research question to test is whether
such gaming and crowding out effects only occurs in the context of
significant financial incentives. Some of the most insightful research
on state administrative reform has been detailed case histories of the
development and implementation of reforms, and the effects on public
services. While case research will always struggle with generalizability
problems, the richness of the contextual detail provides for compelling
hypotheses. There is not enough of this kind of scholarship given the
level of change that has taken place and continues to take place.
Up to now I have discussed research that will better document the
factors behind and the effects resulting from the new architecture of
state administration. But research on professional practice plays
another role, which is to suggest alternate reform ideas as the
shortcomings of existing approaches become apparent. This article has
offered some suggestions for alternate reform approaches that might
better achieve the goals of recent reforms in the form of learning
forums and an empowerment approach to authority. Other research should
examine these and other proposals, find out if they work, and under what
conditions. Public administration scholarship can best contribute to
practice not just by documenting current systems, but by develop
credible and evidence-based alternate doctrines of reform.
REFERENCES
Anders, K. (2006). "Performance Measures as Strategic
Management Tools: An Alternative View of the Latest Reform." Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of Management
Association, Atlanta, August 11-16.
Baumgartner, F.R. & Jones, B.D. (1993). Agendas and Instability
in America Politics. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
Behn, R. (2006). "The Varieties of Citistat." Public
Administration Review, 66(3), 332-341.
Berry, F.S. (1994). "Innovation in Public Management: The
Adoption of Strategic Planning." Public Administration Review,
54(4), 322-330.
Berry, F.S., Brower, R.S. & Flowers, G. (2000).
"Implementing Performance Accountability in Florida: What Changed,
What Mattered and What Resulted?" Public Productivity and
Management Review, 23(3), 338-358.
Bowman, J.S. & West, J.P. (2006). "Ending Civil Service
Protections in Florida Government: Experiences in State Agencies."
Review of Public Personnel Administration, 26(2), 139-157.
Broder, J.M. (2003, January 31). Shredder Ended Work Backlog, U.S.
Says. The New York Times, pp. A22.
Brudney, J.L., Hebert, F.T & Wright, D.S. (1999).
"Reinventing Government in the American States: Measuring and
Explaining Administrative Reform." Public Administration Review,
59(1), 19-30.
Brudney, J., Fernandez, S., Ryu, J.E., & Wright, D.S. (2005).
"Exploring and Explaining Contracting Out: Patterns among the
American States." Journal of Public Administration Research &
Theory, 75(3), 393-419.
Coggburn, J. (2006). "At-Will Employment in Government:
Insights From the State of Texas." Review of Public Personnel
Administration, 26(2), 158-177.
Condrey, S.E., &. Battaglio Jr., R.P. 2007. "A Return to
Spoils? Revisiting Radical Civil Service Reform in the United
States." Public Administration Review 67(3) 425-436.
deHaven-Smith, L. & Jenne, K.C. (2006). "Management by
Inquiry: A Discursive Accountability System for Large
Organizations." Public Administration Review, 66(1), 64-76.
Downs, G.W., & Larkey, P.D. (1986). The Search for Government
Efficiency. New York: Random House.
Dias, J.J & Maynard-Moody, S. (2007). "For-Profit Welfare:
Contracts, Conflicts, and the Performance Paradox." Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory, 77(2), 189-211.
Fording, R., Schram, S. & Soss, J. (2006). The Bottom-Line, the
Business Model and the Bogey: Performance Management, Sanctions and the
Brave New World of Welfare-to-Work in Florida. Paper delivered at the
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, August 31-September 3.
Franklin, A.L. (2000). "An Examination of Bureaucratic
Reactions to Institutional Controls." Public Performance and
Management Review, 24(1), 8-21.
Gruening, G. (2001). "Origin and Theoretical Basis of New
Public Management." International Public Management Journal, 4(1),
1-25.
Hays, S.W., & Sowa, J.E. (2006). "A Broader Look at the
"Accountability" Movement: Some Grim Realities in State Civil
Service Systems." Review of Public Personnel Administration, 26(2),
102-117.
Hood, C. & Jackson, M. (1991). Administrative Argument.
Aldershot, Hants: Dartmouth.
Heinrich, C.J. (1999). "Do Government Bureaucrats Make
Effective Use of Performance Management Information?" Journal of
Public Administration Research and Theory, 9(3), 363-393.
Heinrich, C.J. (2003). "Measuring Public Sector Performance
and Effectiveness." In B.G. Peters & J. Pierre (Eds.), The
Handbook of Public Administration (pp.25-37). Thousand Oaks: Sage
Publications.
Heinrich, C.J. & Choi, Y. (Forthcoming). Performance-based
Contracting in Social Welfare Programs. The American Review of Public
Administration
Heinrich, C.J. (2007). "False or Fitting Recognition? The Use
of High Performance Bonuses in Motivating Organizational
Achievements." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 26(2),
281-304.
Hood, C. (2006). "Gaming in Targetworld: The Targets Approach
to Managing British Public Services." Public Administration Review
66(4), 515-521.
Joyce, P.G., & Tompkins, S.S. (2002). "Using Performance
Information for Budgeting: Clarifying the Framework and Investigating
Recent State Experience." In K. Newcomer, C.B. Jennings & A.
Lomax (Eds.), Meeting the Challenges of Performance-oriented Government
(pp.61-96). Washington, DC: American Society for Public Administration.
Kellough, J. E., & Nigro, L. (2002). "Pay for Performance
in Georgia State Government: Employee Perspectives on GeorgiaGain after
Five Years." Review of Public Personnel Administration, 22(2):
146-166.
Kellough, J. E., & Nigro, L. (2006). "Dramatic Reform of
the Civil Service: At-Will Employment and the Creation of a New Public
Workforce." Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory,
76(3): 447-466.
Lipshitz, R., Popper, M., & Sasson, O. (1996). "Building
Learning Organizations: The Design and Implementation of Organizational
Learning Mechanisms." Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 32(3):
292-305.
March, J.G., & Olsen, J.P. (1983). "Organizing Political
Life: What Administrative Reform Tells Us about Government."
American Political Science Review, 77(2): 281-296.
Melkers, J.E., & Willoughby, K.G. (2004). Staying the Course:
The Use of Performance Measurement in State Government. Washington DC:
IBM Center for the Business of Government.
Moynihan, Donald P. (Forthcoming). "The Normative Model in
Decline? Public Service Motivation in the Age of Governance." In
J.L. Perry & A. Hondeghem (Eds.), Public Service Motivation: State
of the Science and Art. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Moynihan, D.P. (2005a). "Why and How do State Governments
Adopt and Implement 'Managing for Results' Reforms."
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 75(2), 219-243.
Moynihan, D.P. (2005b). "Goal-based Learning and the Future of
Performance Management." Public Administration Review, 65(2),
203-216.
Moynihan, D.P. (2006). "Managing for Results in State
Government: Evaluating a Decade of Reform." Public Administration
Review, 66(1), 78-90.
Moynihan, D.P. & Ingraham, P.W. (2004). "Integrative
Leadership in the Public Sector: A Model of Performance Information
Use." Administration & Society, 36(4), 427-453.
Moynihan, D.P. & Ingraham, P.W. (2003). "Look for the
Silver Lining: Managing for Results in State Government." Journal
of Public Administration Research and Theory, 73(4), 469-490.
Osborne, D.E. & Gaebler, T. (1992). Reinventing Government: How
the Entrepreneurial Government is Transforming the Public Sector. New
York: Plume.
Perry, J.L. & Wise, L.R. (1990). "The Motivational Bases
of Public Service." Public Administration Review, 50(3), 367-373.
Piotrowski, S.J. & Rosenbloom, D.S. (2002).
"Nonmission-Based Values in Results-Oriented Public Management: The
Case of Freedom of Information." Public Administration Review,
62(6), 643-658.
Radin, B.A. (2006). Challenging the Performance Movement:
Accountability, Complexity and Democratic Values. Washington D.C.:
Georgetown University Press.
Schick, A. (2002) "Opportunity, Strategy, and Tactics in
Reforming Public Management." OECD Journal of Budgeting 2(3), 7-35.
Selden, S.C., Ingraham, P.W., & Jacobson, W.S. (2001).
"Human Resources Practices in State Government: Findings from a
National Survey." Public Administration Review 61(5): 598-607.
Seong, S.K. (2004). Adoption of Innovation: Event History Analysis
on State Legislation of Performance Budgeting in the 7990s. Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science
Association Hilton Chicago and the Palmer House Hilton, September 1-4,
2004.
Talbot, C. (2004). Executive Agencies: Have They Improved
Management in Government? Public Money and Management, 24(2), 104-112.
Weibel, A., Rost, K. & Osterloh, M. (2007). Crowding-out of
Intrinsic Motivation--Opening the Black Box. Retrieved, May 10 2007 from
the Social Science Research Network,
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=
957770#PaperDownload.
Wildavsky, A.A. Budgeting: A Comparative Theory of Budgeting
Processes. Boston: Little Brown and Company, 1975
DONALD P. MOYNIHAN
La Follette School of Public Affairs, University of
Wisconsin-Madison
Figure 1
How Managerial Authority and Focus on Results Create
Different Management Systems
Low focus on results High focus on results
High Box 1. Pre-bureaucratic Box 3: The Market Model
managerial systems
authority Managers have clear goals
Focus on goals other than and authority to achieve
performance or rule probity goals. The goal is program
(political spoils, personal effectiveness, higher
enrichment). technical efficiency and
results-based
accountability, but may
also lead to opportunism,
partisan values, crowding
out of intrinsic
motivation.
Low Box 2: Bureaucratic systems Box 4: Constrained
managerial performance system
authority High focus on inputs and
little incentive or Demand for results, but
authority to increase managers lack authority to
technical efficiency engineer change, limiting
performance improvement
and results-based
accountability