首页    期刊浏览 2025年07月18日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Forecasting inflation and the great recession.
  • 作者:Bassetto, Marco ; Messer, Todd ; Ostrowski, Christine
  • 期刊名称:Economic Perspectives
  • 印刷版ISSN:1048-115X
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:September
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
  • 摘要:In 2001, Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) presented a challenge for most statistical models of (U.S.) inflation, showing that for the period 1985-99, forecasting future inflation to remain at its most recently observed value (the "random-walk" hypothesis) would outperform more-sophisticated models that incorporated information from many other economic variables, such as unemployment. Brave and Fisher (2004) expanded and qualified this observation: They found that it did not necessarily hold true for periods other than 1985-99, but they also confirmed that it is difficult to find a model that would perform better than the simple random walk consistently across a variety of sample periods.
  • 关键词:Inflation (Economics);Inflation (Finance);Recessions;Social Studies/Economics/Unemployment and;Unemployment

Forecasting inflation and the great recession.


Bassetto, Marco ; Messer, Todd ; Ostrowski, Christine 等


Introduction and summary

In 2001, Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) presented a challenge for most statistical models of (U.S.) inflation, showing that for the period 1985-99, forecasting future inflation to remain at its most recently observed value (the "random-walk" hypothesis) would outperform more-sophisticated models that incorporated information from many other economic variables, such as unemployment. Brave and Fisher (2004) expanded and qualified this observation: They found that it did not necessarily hold true for periods other than 1985-99, but they also confirmed that it is difficult to find a model that would perform better than the simple random walk consistently across a variety of sample periods.

In more recent years, inflation has appeared to be more stable than in the past, and using a simple constant to forecast inflation has been an even more successful strategy than adopting the random-walk hypothesis, as shown by Stock and Watson (2007) and Diron and Mojon (2008). But, as noted by Stock and Watson, the quest for variables-other than inflation itself-that would consistently help predict inflation has yet to deliver satisfactory results. (1)

In this article, we reassess several of the models considered by Brave and Fisher (2004) in the wake of the Great Recession of2008-09 and its aftermath. This period is particularly interesting because many economic variables saw more extreme movements than they had ever experienced in the stable-inflation era since 1985.

As an example, figure 1 shows the behavior of the Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI). If measures of economic or labor market activity are ever useful in forecasting inflation, then this should become particularly clear in times of large movements. In figure 2, we show the behavior of inflation over the same period. The black line shows total inflation as measured by the Personal Consumption Expenditure Price Index (PCE), while the red line shows core inflation, excluding the volatile energy and food sectors. Inflation did drop in 2008, at the same time as the economy was contracting, but this drop could not be forecasted based on the benign economic data of 2007. More importantly, inflation recovered between 2009 and 2010.

We are not the first to point out that inflation remained remarkably stable in the face of serious economic weakness over the last five years: This is discussed by Hall (2011), Ball and Mazumder (2011), and Simon, Matheson, and Sandri (2013), among others. This observation is commonly cited as evidence that the "Phillips curve," which illustrates the relationship between inflation and unemployment, has flattened in recent years. Our goal in this article goes beyond this observation in two ways:

1) We show how the recovery of inflation in 2009-10 occurred precisely at the only time (since 1985) in which the statistical models considered here would predict sharp disinflation, that is, inflation went up at the time at which the models would most strongly predict that it should go down.

2) We quantify the effect of the resulting large forecast errors on the coefficient estimates of the model, offering a metric by which we can assess how much weaker the relationship between inflation and economic activity appears when the data from 2008-12 are taken into account.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Our work is also related to Del Negro, Giannoni, and Schorfheide (2013). In their paper, they consider a fully fledged new Keynesian model, and they show that inflation during the Great Recession behaved in ways that are broadly consistent with the implications of the model; in particular, their model anticipated some disinflation, but not enough to get to deflation. The path of inflation forecasts displayed by Del Negro, Giannoni, and Schorfheide is not out of line with the results of the purely statistical forecasting models that we consider. (2) Indeed, if we only look at our figure 12 (p. 94), the performance of the statistical models does not appear as bad during the Great Recession. However, when we look at the forecasts of changes in inflation, the failure of the models to account for the behavior of inflation over the last five years becomes apparent: It is this failure that leads to the conclusion that estimates based on data up to 2007 were not robust to the inclusion of data observed since then. It would be interesting to perform experiments similar to ours in a wider class of both statistical and economic models.

In the next section, we describe the statistical models that form the basis of our analysis. Then, we present the results from our estimation. We first document the magnitude and timing of the forecast errors from the models and then discuss how the past five years affect the coefficient estimates.

Brief description of data and models

We use monthly data for both inflation and the variables to be used in forecasting it. We consider two forecasting horizons: 12 months and 24 months. This represents a fairly standard choice, and our results would not change substantially if we considered other, similar forecasting horizons. We perform our analysis on core inflation in order to strip out highly volatile food and energy prices. We consider two measures of inflation, based on the price index for Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE) and the Consumer Price Index (CPI), respectively. (3) Most of our analysis is based on data from January 1985 to December 2012; (4) we exclude earlier years, in which monetary policy was conducted very differently and inflation was much less stable. As a robustness experiment, we also consider what happens if we include the high-inflation period of the 1970s and the disinflation period of the early 1980s.

Models in differences

It is common to assume that inflation itself is a unit-root process (or close to it), which suggests we should run forecasting regressions in differences. In this form, the forecasting regression is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

In equation 1, [[pi].sup.12.sub.t] is 12-month inflation in period t, that is, it is the logarithmic change in the price index between period t and t-12. Then h is the forecast horizon (12 or 24 months). [DELTA][[pi].sup.1.sub.t] is the one-month change in monthly inflation; x is the vector of variables used in the forecast (which varies by model); [p.sup.*], [q.sup.*], [alpha], [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] are parameters to be estimated; and [[epsilon].sub.t+h] is the forecast error, which (by construction) is uncorrelated with all the variables used in the regression up to period t. We study four models that share the common structure of equation 1, but differ in the variables used to predict changes in the inflation rate. These models follow research by Stock and Watson (1999, 2002, and 2003).

Specifically, all four models include a constant5 and lags of one-month changes in inflation, but they then differ as follows:

Activity index model

This model is based on the premise that inflation may increase in periods of brisk economic activity and decrease when the economy exhibits slack. Activity is measured by the three-month moving average of the Chicago Fed National Activity Index (CFNAI). (6) The CFNAI aggregates information (7) from 85 series capturing various aspects of economic activity and is calibrated so as to have a mean of zero and a variance of one, with positive or negative values, respectively, indicating periods of above-average or below-average economic activity. As shown in figure 1, the Great Recession of 2008 brought the CFNAI to values that were matched only by the most severe recession of the 1970s.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Natural rate model

This model looks more specifically at labor market conditions. To construct [x.sub.t], we start with the civilian unemployment rate, and we split it into two components. (8) The first component is a slow-moving trend, which captures demographic changes and other institutional factors that may affect unemployment without being associated with the business cycle. The second component (the "cyclical component"), which is the residual after the trend has been removed, is meant to be associated with business cycle movements in unemployment that may be predictive of inflationary pressures.

Figure 3 plots the civilian unemployment rate and its slow-moving trend as estimated at the end of 2012. Because the most recent recession was so unusually protracted, a significant part of the increase in unemployment of the past five years is attributed to the trend (dotted red line). This formulation has the counterintuitive implication that during the recession of 2008, unemployment was actually lower than its long-run trend. For this reason, we choose to construct the residual in a period t that is used for estimation from the trend as it would be estimated on data only up to that period. (9) Using this one-sided estimate, the spike in unemployment in 2008 and 2009 is entirely perceived as a cyclical downturn, which should affect inflation. For the sake of robustness, we also repeated the experiment using the trend as currently estimated; our conclusions would be similar and, if anything, stronger in this case.

Diffusion model

This model closely resembles Stock and Watson (2002). As for the activity index model, we rely on a large number of series whose common information is summarized by means of principal components. The difference between the activity index model and the diffusion model is that we include here a much larger number of series (148), which capture not only economic activity, but also information on prices and financial market conditions. Here, [x.sub.t] represents the first four principal components of the 148 series.

Indicator model

While for the diffusion model we first summarize the information from many series into a few principal components and then use those to forecast inflation, here we proceed in reverse. First, we use 22 economic series (10) and run 22 separate regressions, each one containing a single series as a regressor [x.sub.t]. Then we summarize this information by taking the median forecast among the 22.

In addition to choosing the series to include in equation 1, we need a criterion to choose the number of lags of inflation and the regressors that appear on the right-hand side of equation 1. For the first three models, we rely on the Bayesian information criterion to make a selection. (11)

For the indicator model, the Bayesian information criterion may select different lag lengths depending on the variable that we use; we thus simply fix [p.sup.*] and [q.sup.*], which we choose to be 5.

Models in levels

There is evidence that inflation has been less persistent in recent years than in the past. (12) For this reason, we experiment with a different specification, where inflation is treated as a stationary process:

2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Compared with equation 1, equation 2 allows the effect of past inflation to decay over time and long-run inflation to revert to a constant.

Thus, we repeat our exercise for each model, replacing equation 1 with equation 2.

Results

Models in differences

To begin, we estimate the four models using data from January 1985 to December 2007, before the Great Recession. Using this output, we forecast the predicted change in year-over-year inflation at each point in our sample. Up to 2007, this is an in-sample prediction: The coefficients of the statistical model are estimated to fit the data as well as possible. From 2008 onward, this becomes an out-of-sample forecast, where we explore whether the coefficients that we estimated on previous data are helpful in accounting for inflation during and after the Great Recession.

Figure 4 shows results for PCE in the post-1984 sample at the 12-month horizon, where the blue line is the actual change in inflation and the red line is the predicted change. All four models predict a drop in inflation from late 2009 to early 2010. Measures of slack are greatest after the recession has taken its toll on economic activity and the labor market, and this is when the statistical relationship of equation 1 would imply the greatest downward pressure on inflation. However, inflation actually dropped contemporaneously with the deterioration in economic activity and labor market conditions. By 2010, inflation was instead recovering. In other words, the models were predicting the greatest decrease at precisely the time when inflation was increasing. Further, none of the models predicted an increase in inflation at all: Inflation was expected to decrease and continue to decrease throughout the early 2010s.

Next, we examine the forecast errors (the difference between the blue line and the red line in figure 4) to understand how this miss compares with past episodes. These errors are shown in figure 5. This figure shows that the forecast errors were large but not unprecedented by historical standards. The only exception is the diffusion model (panel D), which performed particularly poorly during the Great Recession. However, returning to figure 4, we see that a noticeable difference emerges in the source of these errors in the later period. Previously, forecast errors were due to movements in inflation that the models failed to predict. During the Great Recession, the models predicted a large change that never occurred.

We now reestimate the models by adding five more years of data, so that the sample covers the period from January 1985 to December 2012, and we recompute our forecasts based on the estimates obtained on this new sample. Figure 6 adds these new forecasts (represented by the black lines) to those that were already included in figure 4. In the activity and diffusion models (panels A and D, respectively), the forecasts become much flatter, indicating that the CFNAI and the diffusion factors appear to be less predictive of inflation changes in the wake of the Great Recession. The indicator model stayed roughly equal, but the aggregation of the indicators in this model was never particularly informative of inflation changes, resulting in a flat forecast line throughout. The change in coefficients is particularly stark in the case of the natural rate model: The inflation forecast almost becomes a constant. Estimating the models using the additional data shows a much more muted response of inflation.

Why do the forecasts become flatter when we add the more recent data? The forecasts are composed of a constant, current and lagged values of monthly changes in inflation, and current and lagged values of measures of economic activity (or labor/financial market conditions). In figure 7, we isolate the component of the forecast that is due to the measure of economic activity. As before, the red line refers to the coefficients estimated on data up to 2007, and the black line includes data up to 2012. This figure shows that the large drop in inflation the models predicted in late 2009 and 2010 that never occurred was indeed due to weakness in the measures of economic activity. It is this failed prediction that mutes the response of the forecasts when coefficients are estimated on the entire sample of data to December 2012. For the natural rate model, this revision is so large that unemployment almost completely loses its predictive power for inflation.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

We now explore the robustness of our findings along several dimensions. First, in figure 8, we repeat the experiment forecasting CPI inflation, rather than PCE inflation. Here, the mismatch between forecasts and outcomes is less jarring, in that inflation remained constant when the models predicted the largest drop (March 2010 in the activity and indicator models [panels A and C, respectively], November 2010 in the natural rate model [panel B], and March 2011 in the diffusion model [panel D] in the extended sample), rather than actually increasing as was the case for PCE; by the time actual CPI inflation recovered, the model forecasted changes were close to zero. Nonetheless, the discrepancy between the red and black lines shows that adding the years of the Great Recession reduces the magnitude of estimated changes in inflation. As was the case for PCE, the diffusion model (panel D) performed particularly poorly during the Great Recession; accordingly it saw the biggest revisions in its coefficients with the addition of the new data.

Figure 9 reverts to forecasting PCE inflation and extends the horizon of the forecast to 24 months. This longer window has the effect of smoothing the ups and downs that inflation experienced, and the forecast based on using the CFNAI now appears less out of line with the realized outcomes in the period 2008-12. As we saw at the 12-month horizon, the natural rate model (panel B) suggests that deviations of unemployment from its filtered path have hardly any predictive power for inflation changes when data up to 2012 are included in the estimation; and the diffusion model (panel D) remains the worst-performing model for the period, resulting in the largest revisions.

In figure 10 we take a broader perspective, estimating the models on a sample from January 1969 onward. When we include the high inflation of the 1970s and the 1980s disinflation, the models suggest that economic activity has more predictive power for changes in inflation: This finding is most likely due to the fact that, in those periods, inflation expectations were less well anchored and it was easier for real shocks to propagate to persistent inflation. As a consequence, the activity, natural rate, and diffusion models (panels A, B, and D, respectively) imply a bigger forecasted disinflation after the Great Recession and generally perform worse. The bigger forecast errors would lead to bigger revisions in coefficients, but this effect is tempered by the fact that five years of additional data have less of an effect when models are estimated on a 45-year sample than when they are estimated on a shorter, 28-year sample.

The figures provide consistent evidence of a qualitative change in the forecasting relationships, but they do not provide a quantitative answer as to how much flatter the relationship between inflation changes and economic activity has become. We now turn to this question.

When the estimated model does not include any lags on the measure of economic activity, the ratio of the (absolute value of) coefficients on the measure of economic activity is a straightforward measure of how much flatter the relationship has become. However, the structure of our models allows for the selection of any number of lags, and some models estimate different numbers of lags depending on the period used. To summarize the changes in the coefficients into a single measure, we take the time series of the predicted contributions to the forecast of the independent variable and calculate the maximum and the median of those values. Formally, for the case of the maximum, this means that we compute the following object:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

In equation 3, t varies over the sample period (1985-2012 for the post-1984 sample, 1969-2012 for PCE over the full sample, and December 1979-2012 for CPI over the full sample), [[beta].sup.2012.sub.j] represents the estimates of the coefficients of equation 1 based on data up to 2012, and [[beta].sup.2007.sub.j] represents the estimates of the same coefficients based on data up to 2007.

The results are presented in table 1 (p. 92). The table confirms the visual impression from the figures. With the exception of the indicator models, where the relationship between economic indicators and inflation was already estimated to be weak as of 2007, all other ratios are considerably less than 1, indicating a flatter relationship in the wake of the Great Recession.

In most cases, the ratios imply a flattening out of at least 20-30 percent--a large change considering that the additional five years of data represent just 18 percent of the post-1984 sample, and 11 percent and 14 percent of the full sample for PCE and CPI, respectively. To better understand the source of the large changes ob- served in this table, we observe that there are two ways in which including new observations can have large effects in estimating a linear relationship in equation 1. First, observations for [DELTA][[phi].sup.1.sub.t-j] and [x.sub.t-j] could be very far from their mean in the new period. In this case, their effect could be uncovered much more clearly, because it would be more difficult for the error [[epsilon].sub.t+h] to mask it. Thus, large changes would simply reflect the fact that the new period was very informative about the statistical relationship, increasing confidence in the estimates. Alternatively, large changes could follow if the data exhibited a very different statistical relationship in the recent period than in past observations; in this case, the relationship could be unstable. As we observed earlier, the first explanation is certainly a possibility for 2008-12, since all measures of economic activity were far away from their usual ranges during the Great Recession. In the experiment of figure 11, we show some evidence against the second explanation. Specifically, we estimate the activity index model at the 12-month horizon on a rolling sample of five years and plot the coefficient on the activity index. (13) The figure shows that the coefficient estimated over the last five years (the last point of the line) is not very different from estimates from previous five-year windows. Thus, we do not see obvious signs that the statistical relationship changed; the lack of predictive power that measures of economic activity exhibit against inflation changes in the latest period holds true throughout the sample and simply becomes more apparent at times of large swings in activity.

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]

Models in levels

In this section, we consider whether a stationary model of inflation, whereby inflation is expected to always revert to a constant long-run mean, is better able to account for the inflation experience of the Great Recession. For the sake of brevity, we only consider our baseline case, which aims to forecast core PCE inflation 12 months ahead, using data from 1985 onward.

Our estimate of the autoregressive coefficient [omega] varies between 0.82 and 0.86 across the four models when we estimate them up to 2007: These estimates suggest a substantial amount of mean reversion. However, as shown in figure 12, estimating the model in levels rather than differences has only very subtle effects on the forecasts of inflation 12 months ahead. (14) In figure 13, we again compare the performance of the models estimated in levels and differences, but we look at the forecast of the change in inflation rather than the forecast of inflation itself. These pictures are more comparable to those that we introduced earlier; they also make it easier to notice the difference between the two estimation strategies. Not surprisingly, the models in levels predict lower inflation in the early part of our sample and higher inflation in the later part. This happens because inflation was higher in the first part of the sample than in the second part of the sample: Models based on differences in inflation start from a baseline assumption that inflation will stay at its current value, while models in levels predict that inflation will revert to the mean and thus trend lower when it is above its sample mean and higher in the opposite case. The predicted mean reversion contributes to moderating the forecast errors since the Great Recession, but it does not qualitatively alter our conclusion that the models predicted the most disinflation at a time in which inflation was instead increasing.

[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]

In figure 14 (p. 96), we repeat the exercise of figure 7 for the models estimated in inflation levels. Specifically, we look at the contribution that the economic activity measures make at each point in time to the inflation forecast. (15) As was the case in the previous section, we see that the economic activity measures aggregated using the indicator model have almost no predictive power; for this reason, it does not matter whether the model is estimated with data up to 2007 (the red line) or 2012 (the black line). The conclusions for the natural rate and diffusion models (panels B and D, respectively) are also similar to those of the previous section: Even when we estimate inflation in levels, unemployment and the four factors of the diffusion index lose a notable fraction of their forecasting power when we include data from 2008 to 2012 in the estimation. Only the activity index model seems to perform better--while the black line is still flatter than the red line, the difference is now minor.

[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]

Figure 15 shows the contribution to the forecasted inflation change coming from the current position of inflation, that is, the value of -(1 - [omega])([[pi].sup.12.sub.t] - [bar.[pi]]) in equation 2, where [bar.[phi]] is the sample mean of inflation, to which inflation is expected to revert in the long run. When inflation reached a low of 1.2 percent in July 2009, this contribution was positive and pointed the models toward a recovery in inflation; this force, which was not present by construction when we estimated the models in differences, gave the estimates based on equation 2 a slight edge over those based on equation 1. Nonetheless, the magnitude of the contribution in figure 15 is much smaller than that in figure 14. With the exception of the indicator model (panel C), economic weakness remained the dominant force driving forecasts of inflation changes, with further disinflation predicted throughout the period to 2012.

To complete our analysis of estimates based on mean-reverting models of inflation, we perform the analogous computation from table 1 in table 2. Here, we look at the contributions that economic indicators make to forecasted inflation changes based on data up to 2012 versus data up to 2007. The shrinkage in the estimated importance of activity measures is less pronounced than in table 1, confirming that our models perform better when we allow for mean reversion in inflation. Nonetheless, the ratios in table 2 remain largely well below 1; so even accounting for mean reversion, in the last five years inflation responded less to economic weakness than the models would have predicted. The natural rate model, based on unemployment, is subject to the most dramatic revision. The indicator model stands out as an exception; as noted earlier, even with data up to 2007, its indicator variables as a group had no predictive power for inflation.

Conclusion

We have shown that measures of economic activity and labor market conditions have not been helpful in predicting the evolution of inflation since 2008. This phenomenon is usually interpreted as a "flattening" of the Phillips curve, the relationship between unemployment (or other measures of economic activity) and inflation. A flattening of this curve would imply that unemployment would have to change more than in the past to have a detectable impact on inflation. Our analysis was based on purely statistical models, which cannot be used to analyze the consequences of alternative monetary and fiscal policies. However, when a flat Phillips curve is embedded in a full general equilibrium model, such as that of Smets and Wouters (2003), it implies that monetary policy can be most effective at stabilizing output, with minimal consequences for inflation, at least as long as interest rates do not drop to the zero lower bound. The converse of this observation is that a flat Phillips curve presents a difficult challenge for monetary policy should inflation drift up from the central bank target, because it would then take an extreme downturn to rein inflation in.

However, our results offer an alternative explanation. Specifically, the degree by which the statistical relationship between economic activity and output has become flatter--as well as the fact that models would often predict not only the wrong magnitude of the response of inflation, but also the wrong direction--may offer support to the idea of a vertical Phillips curve, where the determinants of (forecastable) inflation changes are unrelated to economic activity, such as in the model of Lucas (1972). This model would have diametrically opposed implications for policy, suggesting that (the systematic component of) monetary policy can be most effective at controlling inflation, while having little or no direct impact on measures of economic activity. The policy implications of a situation in which a central bank misperceives the policy-relevant trade-off between inflation and unemployment have been studied by Sargent (1999) and Cogley and Sargent (2005).

The two competing explanations for the behavior of inflation in recent years also offer different assessments of how monetary policy has fared in its quest to achieve maximum employment and stable prices. Under the first explanation, inflation was bound to remain more or less stable with little effort on the part of monetary authorities. In normal circumstances, monetary policy could have done more to stimulate aggregate demand and overcome weakness in economic activity, but recently it was hamstrung by the zero bound on nominal interest rates, which forced the use of alternative, less effective policy measures. If instead the second interpretation of the data is correct, stable inflation in the wake of economic turbulence was not a given, but rather a successful outcome of monetary policy that maintained control of the price level even in the face of severe adverse shocks. This stands in contrast with the experience of the 1970s, when severe economic disturbances were accompanied by increasing bouts of inflation; by avoiding a repeat of that experience, monetary policy might have contributed to mitigating uncertainty and lessening the impact of other shocks that exacted their unavoidable toll on economic activity.

[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]

APPENDIX 1: ALTERNATIVE UNEMPLOYMENT GAP

In their quest to find a robust relationship between unemployment and expected inflation changes, Stock and Watson (2010) have suggested a new unemployment-gap metric: the maximum between zero and the difference between the current unemployment level and the lowest unemployment has been over the previous 11 quarters. Inspired by their suggestion, we changed the natural rate model to see whether this alternative measure of cyclical unemployment, active only during downturns, would help to recover a role for unemployment in predicting inflation. Since our model is based on monthly data, we change 11 quarters to 35 months. Figure A1 presents our results. (1) Stock and Watson used data up to the second quarter of 2010. Up to this point, their measure of unemployment is far from a perfect predictor of inflation, but it forecasts dips that are correctly associated with disinflation most of the time. Unfortunately, the period right after their model was designed yields very large forecast errors: As of late 2010 and early 2011, unemployment was substantially above its level of three years earlier, forecasting further disinflation, whereas inflation in fact accelerated in late 2011 and in 2012. When estimated on data from 1985 to 2012, even this new measure of cyclical unemployment loses its predictive power for inflation.

(1) It is worth nothing that our model is simpler than Stock and Watson's in which inflation is the sum of transitory and permanent components; nonetheless, we expect that the observations included here would also apply to their richer environment.

[FIGURE 1A OMITTED]

APPENDIX 2: MONTHLY DATA, JANUARY 1969-DECEMBER 2012
Model                   Mnemonic

Activity                le
Activity                lrm25
Activity                a0m005
Activity, diffusion     cbhm
Activity, diffusion     cdbhm
Activity, diffusion     cnbhm
Activity, diffusion     csbhm
Activity, diffusion     ypdhm
Activity, diffusion     hsm
Activity, diffusion     hst
Activity, diffusion     hstmw
Activity, diffusion     hstne
Activity, diffusion     hsts
Activity, diffusion     hstw
Activity, diffusion     ip
Activity, diffusion     ip51
Activity, diffusion     ip511
Activity, diffusion     ip512
Activity, diffusion     ip521
Activity, diffusion     ip53
Activity, diffusion     ip531
Activity, diffusion     ip532
Activity, diffusion     ip54
Activity, diffusion     ipbO
Activity, diffusion     ipfp
Activity, diffusion     ipmdg
Activity, diffusion     ipmfg
Activity, diffusion     ipmnd
Activity, diffusion     iptp
Activity, diffusion     iputl
Activity, diffusion     laconsa
Activity, diffusion     ladurga
Activity, diffusion     lafirea
Activity, diffusion     lagooda
Activity, diffusion     lagovta
Activity, diffusion     lamanua
Activity, diffusion     laminga
Activity, diffusion     lanagra
Activity, diffusion     landura
Activity, diffusion     lapriva
Activity, diffusion     lawtrda + lartrda
Activity, diffusion     laserpa
Activity, diffusion     lainfoa + lapbsva + laeduha +
                          laleiha + lasrvoa
Activity, diffusion     lattula - lawtrda - lartrda
Activity, diffusion     lena
Activity, diffusion     lhelpr
Activity, diffusion     lomanua
Activity, diffusion     lrmanua
Activity, diffusion     napmc
Activity, diffusion     napmei
Activity, diffusion     napmii
Activity, diffusion     napmni
Activity, diffusion     napmoi
Activity, diffusion     rsdh
Activity, diffusion     rsh, rsh2
Activity, diffusion     rsnh
Activity, diffusion     timdh, timdh2
Activity, diffusion     timh, timh2
Activity, diffusion     timnh, thnnh2
Activity, diffusion     tirti, tirh2
Activity, diffusion     tith, tith2
Activity, diffusion     tiwh, tiwh2
Activity, diffusion     trmh, trmh2
Activity, diffusion     trrti, trrh2
Activity, diffusion     trth, trth2
Activity, diffusion     trwmh, trwmh2
Activity, diffusion     tsmdh, tsmdh2
Activity, diffusion     tsmh, tsmh2
Activity, diffusion     tsmnh, tsmnh2
Activity, diffusion     tsth, tsth2
Activity, diffusion     tswmdh
Activity, diffusion     tswmh, tswmh2
Activity, diffusion     tswmnh, tswmnh2
Activity, diffusion     ypltpmh
Activity, diffusion     cdvhm, cdvh
Activity, diffusion     a0m007
Activity, diffusion     a0m008
Activity, diffusion     a0m027
Activity, diffusion,    hpt
  indicators
Activity, diffusion,    cumtg
  indicators
Activity, diffusion     lhelp
Activity, diffusion     lr
Activity, indicators    napmvdi
Diffusion               cexp
Diffusion               luO
Diffusion               lu15
Diffusion               lu5
Diffusion               luad
Diffusion               lut15
Diffusion               lut27
Diffusion               faram
Diffusion               farat
Diffusion               farmsr
Diffusion               fm1
Diffusion               fm2c
Diffusion               fm3
Diffusion               fxtwb
Diffusion               fxuk
Diffusion               faaa
Diffusion               fbaa
Diffusion               faaa--ffed
Diffusion               fbaa--ffed
Diffusion               sdy5comm
Diffusion               sp500
Diffusion               spe5comm
Diffusion               spny
Diffusion               spspi
Diffusion               ftbs3
Diffusion               ftbs6
Diffusion               ftbs3--ffed
Diffusion               ftbs6--ffed
Diffusion               fcm1
Diffusion               fcm5
Diffusion               fcm1--ffed
Diffusion               fcm5--ffed
Diffusion               fcm 10--ffed
Diffusion               sp1000
Diffusion               sp3100
Diffusion               pcua
Diffusion               pcucc
Diffusion               pcuccd
Diffusion               pcucs
Diffusion               pcum
Diffusion               pcu
Diffusion               pcuslf
Diffusion               pcuslm
Diffusion               pcusls
Diffusion               pcut
Diffusion               jcdm
Diffusion               jcm
Diffusion               jcnm
Diffusion               jcsm
Diffusion               leconsa
Diffusion               lemanua
Diffusion               a0m101
Diffusion               mom
Diffusion               mum
Diffusion               modgu
Diffusion               mudg
Diffusion               mong
Diffusion               fxjap
Diffusion               fxcan
Diffusion               fxsw
Diffusion               fxger
Activity, diffusion     jfns, cpv, cpvr
Activity, diffusion     gfnis, gfnisq, gsis, gsisq, cpg
Diffusion, indicators   fm2
Diffusion, indicators   fcm10
Diffusion               ffed
Diffusion, indicators   sp2000
Diffusion, indicators   sp3000
Diffusion, indicators   napmpi
Indicators              zlead
Indicators              jfns, cpv, cpvr, gfnis, gfnisq,
                          gsis, gsisq, cpg
Indicators              hnlus
Indicators              chm
Indicators              fcm3--fcm1
Indicators              fxtwm
Indicators              pzgld
Indicators              pzsil
Indicators              pzad
Indicators              spwpc
Indicators              pfaH
Indicators              p101
Indicators              ueg
Indicators              ffed--ffed{1)
Natural rate            ra16
Prices                  jcxfem
Prices                  pculfer
COMEX                   http://www.wrenresearch.com.au/
                          downloads/index.htni
FSC                     http://www.webspace4me.net/~blhin2/
                          data/commodities
BCRB                    http://economic-charts.com/em-cgi/
                          data.exe/crb/crb01
FAME                    Federal Reserve Bank of San
                          Francisco website

Model                   Haver description                     Haver
                                                              database

Activity                Civilian employment: Sixteen years    usecon
                          & over 16 yr + (SA, 000s)
Activity                Civilian unemployment rate: Men,      usecon
                          25-54 years (SA, %)
Activity                Average weekly initial claims         bci
                          unemployment insurance (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Personal consumption expenditures     usecon
                          (SAAR, chained 2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     Personal consumption expenditures:    usecon
                          Durable goods (SAAR, chained
                          2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     Personal consumption expenditures:    usecon
                          Nondurable goods (SAAR, chained
                          2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     Personal consumption expenditures:    usecon
                          Services (SAAR, chained
                          2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real disposable personal income       usecon
                          (SAAR, chained 2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     Manufacturers' shipments of mobile    usecon
                          homes (SAAR, units in 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Housing starts (SAAR, units in        usecon
                          000s)
Activity, diffusion     Housing starts: Midwest (SAAR,        usecon
                          units in 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Housing starts: Northeast (SAAR,      usecon
                          units in 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Housing starts: South (SAAR, units    usecon
                          in 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Housing starts: West (SAAR, units     usecon
                          in 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production Index (SA,      usecon
                          1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Consumer       usecon
                          goods (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Durable        usecon
                          consumer goods (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Nondurable     usecon
                          consumer goods (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Business       usecon
                          equipment (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Materials      usecon
                          (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Durable        usecon
                          goods materials (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Nondurable     usecon
                          goods materials (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production:                usecon
                          Nonindustrial supplies (SA,
                          1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Mining (SA,    usecon
                          1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Final          usecon
                          products (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Durable        usecon
                          goods [NAICS] (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production:                usecon
                          Manufacturing [SIC] (SA,
                          1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Nondurable     usecon
                          manufacturing (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Final          usecon
                          products and nonindustrial
                          supplies (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     Industrial Production: Electric and   usecon
                          gas utilities (SA, 1997=100)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Construction (SA,      usecon
                          000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Durable goods          usecon
                          manufacturing (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Financial activities   usecon
                          (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Goods-producing        usecon
                          industries (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Government (SA,        usecon
                          000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Manufacturing (SA,     usecon
                          000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Mining (SA, 000s)      usecon
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Total nonfarm (SA,     usecon
                          000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Nondurable goods       usecon
                          manufacturing (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Total private          usecon
                          industries (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Wholesale and Retail   usecon
                          trade (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Service-providing      usecon
                          industries (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Aggregate of           usecon
                          categories
Activity, diffusion     All employees: Aggregate of           usecon
                          categories
Activity, diffusion     Civilian employment:                  usecon
                          Nonagricultural Industries: 16yr+
                          (SA, 000s)
Activity, diffusion     Ratio: Help-wanted advertising in     usecon
                          newspapers/Number unemployed (SA)
Activity, diffusion     Average weekly hours: Overtime:       usecon
                          Manufacturing (SA, Hrs)
Activity, diffusion     Average weekly hours: Manufacturing   usecon
                          (SA, Hrs)
Activity, diffusion     ISM Mfg: PMI Composite Index (SA,     usecon
                          50+ = Econ Expand)
Activity, diffusion     ISM Mfg: Employment Index (SA,        usecon
                          50+ = Econ Expand)
Activity, diffusion     ISM Mfg: Inventories Index (SA,       usecon
                          50+ = Econ Expand)
Activity, diffusion     ISM Mfg: New Orders Index (SA,        usecon
                          50+ = Econ Expand)
Activity, diffusion     ISM Mfg: Production Index (SA,        usecon
                          50+ = Econ Expand)
Activity, diffusion     Real retail sales: Durable goods      usecon
                          (SA, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Retail sales: Retail trade (SA,       usecon
                          Spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real retail sales: Nondurable goods   usecon
                          (SA, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real inventories: Mfg: Durable        usecon
                          goods industries (SA, EOP,
                          spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real manufacturing & trade            usecon
                          inventories: Mfg industries (SA,
                          EOP, spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real mfg inventories: Nondurable      usecon
                          goods industries (SA, EOP,
                          spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real inventories: Retail trade        usecon
                          industries (SA, EOP, spliced,
                          chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real manufacturing & trade            usecon
                          inventories: Industries (SA, EOP,
                          spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real inventories: Merchant            usecon
                          wholesale trade industries (SA,
                          EOP, spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real inventories/sales ratio:         usecon
                          Manufacturing industries (SA,
                          spliced, chained 2000$)
Activity, diffusion     Inventories/sates ratio: Retail       usna
                          trade industries (SA, spliced,
                          chained 2000$)
Activity, diffusion     Real manufacturing & trade:           usna
                          Inventories/sales ratio (SA,
                          spliced, chained 2000$)
Activity, diffusion     Inventories/sales ratio: Merchant     usna
                          wholesale trade industries(SA,
                          spliced, chained 2000$)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: Mfg: Durable goods        usna
                          industries(SA, spliced, chained
                          2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: Manufacturing             usna
                          industries (SA, spliced, chained
                          2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: Mfg: Nondurable goods     usna
                          industries (SA, spliced, chained
                          2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real manufacturing & trade sales:     usna
                          All industries (SA, spliced,
                          chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: Merchant wholesalers:     usna
                          Durable goods inds. (SA, spliced,
                          chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: Merchant wholesale        usna
                          trade industries (SA, spliced,
                          chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real sales: merchant wholesale:       usna
                          Nondurable goods inds. (SA,
                          spliced, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Real personal income less transfer    usecon
                          payments (SAAR, chained
                          2000$bil.)
Activity, diffusion     PCE: Durable goods: Motor vehicles    usna
                          and parts (SAAR, spliced and
                          interpolated, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Manufacturers' new orders: Durable    bci
                          goods (SA, chained 2000$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Manufacturers' new orders: Consumer   bci
                          goods & materials (SA, 1982$mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Manufacturers' new orders:            bci
                          Nondefense capital goods (SA,
                          1982$mil.)
Activity, diffusion,    New private housing units             usecon
  indicators              authorized by building permit
                          (SAAR, units in 000s)
Activity, diffusion,    Capacity utilization: Manufacturing   usecon
  indicators              [SIC] (SA, % of capacity)
Activity, diffusion     Index of help-wanted advertising in   usecon
                          newspapers (SA, 1987=100)
Activity, diffusion     Civilian unemployment rate: 16yr +    usecon
                          (SA, %)
Activity, indicators    ISM: Mfg: Vendor Deliveries Index     usecon
                          (SA, 50+ = Econ Expand)
Diffusion               University of Michigan: Consumer      usecon
                          expectations (NSA, 66Q1=100)
Diffusion               Civilians unemployed for less than    usecon
                          5 weeks (SA, 000s)
Diffusion               Civilians unemployed for 15-26        usecon
                          weeks (SA, 000s)
Diffusion               Civilians unemployed for 5-14 weeks   usecon
                          (SA, 000s)
Diffusion               Average (Mean) duration of            usecon
                          unemployment (SA, weeks)
Diffusion               Civilians unemployed for 15 weeks     usecon
                          and over (SA, 000s)
Diffusion               Civilians unemployed for 27 weeks     usecon
                          and over (SA, 000s)
Diffusion               Adjusted monetary base (SA, $mil.)    usecon
Diffusion               Adjusted reserves of depository       usecon
                          institutions (SA, $mil.)
Diffusion               Adj. monetary base including          usecon
                          deposits to satisfy clearing
                          balance contracts (SA, $bil.)
Diffusion               Money stock: M1 (SA, $bil.)           usecon
Diffusion               Real money stock: M2 (SA, chained     usecon
                          2000$bil.)
Diffusion               Money stock: M3 (SA, Sbil.)           usecon
Diffusion               Nominal broad trade-weighted          usecon
                          exchange value of US$ (JAN
                          97=100)
Diffusion               Foreign exchange rate: United         usecon
                          Kingdom (US$/Pound)
Diffusion               Moody's seasoned Aaa corporate bond   usecon
                          yield (% p.a.)
Diffusion               Moody's seasoned Baa corporate bond   usecon
                          yield (% p.a.)
Diffusion               Moody's seasoned Aaa corporate bond   usecon
                          yield--fed funds rate(% p.a.)
Diffusion               Moody's seasoned Baa corporate bond   usecon
                          yield--fed funds rate (% p.a.)
Diffusion               S&P: Composite 500, dividend yield    usecon
                          (%)
Diffusion               Stock Price Index: Standard &         usecon
                          Poor's 500 Composite (1941-43=10)
Diffusion               S&P: 500 Composite, P/E ratio,        usecon
                          4-qtr trailing earnings
Diffusion               Stock Price Index: NYSE Composite     usecon
                          (Avg, Dec. 31, 2002=5000)
Diffusion               Stock Price Index: Standard &         usecon
                          Poor's 400 Industrials
                          (1941-43=10)
Diffusion               3-month Treasury bills, secondary     usecon
                          market (% p.a.)
Diffusion               6-month Treasury bills, secondary     usecon
                          market (% p.a.)
Diffusion               3-month Treasury bills--fed funds     usecon
                          rate, (% p.a.)
Diffusion               6-month Treasury bills--fed funds     usecon
                          rate (% p.a.)
Diffusion               1-year Treasury bill yield at         usecon
                          constant maturity (% p.a.)
Diffusion               5-year Treasury note yield at         usecon
                          constant maturity (% p.a.)
Diffusion               1-year Treasury bill yield at         usecon
                          constant maturity--fed funds rate
                          (% p.a.)
Diffusion               5-year Treasury note yield at         usecon
                          constant maturity--fed funds rate
                          (% p.a.)
Diffusion               10-year Treasury note yield at        usecon
                          constant maturity--fed funds rate
                          (% p.a.)
Diffusion               PPI: Crude materials for further      usecon
                          processing (SA, 1982=100)
Diffusion               PPI: Finished consumer goods (SA,     usecon
                          1982=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: Apparel (SA, 1982-84=100)      usecon
Diffusion               CPI-U: Commodities (SA,               usecon
                          1982-84=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: Durables (SA, 1982-84=100)     usecon
Diffusion               CPI-U: Services (SA, 1982-84=100)     usecon
Diffusion               CPI-U: Medical care (SA,              usecon
                          1982-84=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: All Items (SA, 1982-84=100)    usecon
Diffusion               CPI-U: All items less food (SA,       usecon
                          1982-84=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: All items less medical care    usecon
                          (SA, 1982-84=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: All items less shelter (SA,    usecon
                          1982-84=100)
Diffusion               CPI-U: Transportation (SA,            usecon
                          1982-84=100)
Diffusion               PCE: Durable goods: Chain Price       usna
                          Index (SA, 2000=100)
Diffusion               PCE: Personal consumption             usna
                          expenditures: Chain Price Index
                          (SA, 2000=100)
Diffusion               PCE: Nondurable goods: Chain Price    usna
                          Index (SA, 2000=100)
Diffusion               PCE: Services: Chain Price Index      usna
                          (SA, 2000=100)
Diffusion               Avg hourly earnings: Construction     usecon
                          (SA, $/Hr)
Diffusion               Avg hourly earnings: Manufacturing    usecon
                          (SA, $/Hr)
Diffusion               Commercial & industrial loans         bci
                          outstanding (EOP, SA, chained
                          2000$mil.)
Diffusion               Manufacturers' New Orders (SA, Mil.   usecon
                          $)
Diffusion               Manufacturers' Unfilled Orders        usecon
                          (EOP, SA, Mil. $)
Diffusion               Mfrs' New Orders: Durable Goods       usecon
                          Industries With Unfilled Orders
                          (SA, Mil. $)
Diffusion               Mfrs' Unfilled Orders: Durable        usecon
                          Goods Industries (EOP, SA, Mil.
                          $)
Diffusion               Mfrs' New Orders: Nondurable Goods    usecon
                          Industries (SA, Mil. $)
Diffusion               Foreign exchange rate: Japan          usecon
                          (Yen/US$)
Diffusion               Foreign exchange rate: Canada         usecon
                          (C$/US$)
Diffusion               Foreign exchange rate: Switzerland    usecon
                          (Franc/US$)
Diffusion               Foreign exchange rate: Germany (D.    usecon
                          Mark/USS)
Activity, diffusion     Value of private construction put     usna
                          in place (SAAR, chained $mil.)
Activity, diffusion     Value of public construction put in   usecon
                          place (SAAR, chained $mil.)
Diffusion, indicators   Money stock: M2 (SA, $bil.)           usecon
Diffusion, indicators   10-year Treasury note yield at        usecon
                          constant maturity (% p.a.)
Diffusion               Federal funds [effective] rate        usecon
                          (% p.a.)
Diffusion, indicators   PPI: Intermediate materials,          usecon
                          supplies, and components (SA,
                          1982=100)
Diffusion, indicators   PPI: Finished goods (SA, 1982=100)    usecon
Diffusion, indicators   ISM: Mfg: Prices Index (NSA, 50+ =    usecon
                          Econ Expand)
Indicators              Composite Index of 10 Leading         bci
                          Indicators (1996=100)
Indicators              New construction put in place         usecon,
                          (SAAR, 2000$mil.)                     usna
Indicators              New single-family houses sold:        usecon
                          United States (SAAR, 000s)
Indicators              Personal consumption expenditures     usna
                          (SAAR, chained 2000$mil.)
                          (spliced from usna96 before 1990)
Indicators              3-year/1-year T-bill spread           usecon
Indicators              Nominal trade-weighted exch value     usecon
                          of US$/major currencies (MAR
                          73=100)
Indicators              Cash prices: gold, Handy & Harman     weekly
                          Base Price (avg, spliced, S/Troy
                          oz)
Indicators              Cash price: silver, troy oz, Handy    weekly
                          & Harman Base Price (avg, $/troy
                          oz)
Indicators              KR-CRB Spot Commodity Price Index:    usecon
                          All commodities
Indicators              SPOT COMMODITY PRICE--PLYWOOD,
                          CROWS (PUIWMWPC_N.WT)
Indicators              KR-CRB Futures: AH commodities        weekly
                          (avg, 1967=100)
Indicators              PPI: Iron and steel (NSA, 1982=100)   usecon
Indicators              CPI-U: Energy (SA, 1982-84=100)       cpidata
Indicators              Change in federal funds [effective]   usecon
                          rate (% p.a.)
Natural rate            Unemployment gap constructed from     empl
                          16+ unemployment rate (SA)
Prices                  PCE less food and energy: Price       usna
                          Index (SA) (2005=100)
Prices                  CPI less food and energy: Price       usecon
                          Index (SA) (Dec 1977 = 100)

                        Indicator model groups:

COMEX                   1: Economic activity
FSC                     2: Slackness measures
BCRB                    3: Housing and building activity
FAME                    4: Industrial prices
                        5: Financial markets

Source: Haver Analytics, FAME database.


(1) It is worth noting that our model is simpler than Stock and Watson's, in which inflation is the sum of transitory and permanent components; nonetheless, we expect that the observations included here would also apply to their richer environment.

NOTES

(1) More recently, Stock and Watson (2010) have suggested a new unemployment-gap metric that could be useful in forecasting inflation--this measure is the maximum between zero and the difference between the current unemployment level and the lowest unemployment observed over the previous 11 quarters. As figure A1 (p. 101) in appendix 1 shows, the relationship between this metric and changes in inflation has broken down in the past few years since Stock and Watson's paper was published.

(2) The difference between a full economic model and a purely statistical model is that the former should yield correct predictions even when policymakers adopt new rules of behavior, while the latter only yields appropriate forecasts if policymakers react to new developments following the same rules of conduct that they used in the past.

(3) The PCE Price Index is published by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, whereas the CPI is published by the US. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

(4) We rely on data published as of June 13, 2013.

(5) With the model in differences, a constant translates into a trend in inflation. This trend is relevant to account for the evolution of inflation since 1984. However, it is unlikely that this (negative) trend would persist into the future, with current inflation hovering between 1 percent and 2 percent. We thus experimented with removing the effect of the trend in evaluating the model forecasts for the Great Recession. This change does not have a material effect on the conclusions that we draw.

(6) For more information on the Chicago Fed National Activity Index, see www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/cfhai/index.cfm.

(7) The aggregation is done by taking the principal component of the series.

(8) Formally, this split is achieved by means of a band-pass filter, where we retain for forecasting purposes frequencies between two months and 12 years.

(9) As an example, unemployment in December 2008 was 7.3 percent. If we construct the trend including all the data up to 2012, we would estimate the trend to be 7.3 percent, and we would thus conclude that December 2008 was not a period of high cyclical unemployment. This is due to the fact that unemployment rose much higher in 2009 and stayed high for a protracted period of time. In contrast, if we only use data up to December 2008, the trend measure is estimated at 6.4 percent, and cyclical unemployment appears elevated. Finally, the unemployment series that we decompose into a trend and a cyclical component is itself subject to revisions over time.

(10) See appendix 2 for the list of series.

(11) The number of selected lags is as follows:
                                          PCE
Sample period
                  [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]
                    12-mo         24-mo         12-mo         24-mo

                 '07    '12    '07    '12    '07    '12    '07    '12

Act  Post-1984    0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0
Act  Full         0      7      0      0      11     9      10     3
Nat  Post-1984    0      0      0      0      0      0      1      0
Nat  Full         0      0      0      0      3      2      4      4
Diff Post-1984    0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0
Diff Full         0      0      0      0      0      0      1      0

                                          CPI
Sample period
                  [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]     [p.sup.*]
                    12-mo         24-mo         12-mo         24-mo

                 '07    '12    '07    '12    '07    '12    '07    '12

Act  Post-1984    0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0
Act  Full         0      0      0      0      0      0      4      0
Nat  Post-1984    0      0      0      0      3      3      3      3
Nat  Full         0      0      0      0      2      3      3      3
Diff Post-1984    0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0
Diff Full         0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0


(12) See, e.g., Stock and Watson (2007).

(13) We choose this model because it has few coefficients to estimate; in particular, we impose p* = q* = 0, as chosen by the information criterion for the full sample. With rolling five-year windows, estimates of models that feature more coefficients will become more and more unreliable.

(l4) Of course, the differences would become more pronounced for forecasts of inflation over a longer time horizon.

(15) Note that the contribution to the inflation forecast is the same as the contribution to the inflation forecast change, since the current level of inflation from which the change occurs is known.

REFERENCES

Atkeson, Andrew, and Lee E. Ohanian, 2001, "Are Phillips curves useful for forecasting inflation?," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Vol. 25, No. 1, Winter, pp. 2-11.

Ball, Laurence, and Sandeep Mazumder, 2011, "Inflation dynamics and the Great Recession," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 337-381.

Brave, Scott, and Jonas D. M. Fisher, 2004, "In search of a robust inflation forecast," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 28, Fourth Quarter, pp. 12-31, available at www.chicagofed.org/ digital_assets/publications/economic_perspectives/ 2004/ep_4qtr2004_part2_Brave_Fisher.pdf.

Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent, 2005, "The conquest of U.S. inflation: Learning and robustness to model uncertainty," Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 528-563.

Del Negro, Marco, Marc P. Giannoni, and Frank Schorfheide, 2013, "Inflation in the Great Recession and new Keynesian models," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, staff report, No. 618, May.

Diron, Marie, and Benoit Mojon, 2008, "Are inflation targets good inflation forecasts?," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 32, Second Quarter, pp. 33-45, available at www.chicagofed.org/ digital_assets/publications/economic_perspectives/2008/ ep_2qtr2008_part3_diron_mojon.pdf.

Hall, Robert E., 2011, "The long slump," American Economic Review, Vol. 101, No. 2, April, pp. 431-469.

Lucas, Robert E., Jr., 1972, "Expectations and the neutrality of money," Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 4, No. 2, April, pp. 103-124.

Sargent, Thomas J., 1999, The Conquest of American Inflation, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Simon, John, Troy Matheson, and Damiano Sandri, 2013, "The dog that didn't bark: Has inflation been muzzled or was it just sleeping?" in World Economic Outlook: Hopes, Realities, Risks, International Monetary Fund, April, pp. 79-95, available at www.imf.org/ extemal/pubs/ft/weo/2013/01/.

Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters, 2003, "An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area," Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1, No. 5, September, pp. 1123-1175.

Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson, 2010, "Modeling inflation after the crisis," in Macroeconomic Challenges: The Decade Ahead, proceedings of the Economic Symposium Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 173-220.

--, 2007, "Why has U.S. inflation become harder to forecast?," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 39, No. s1, February, pp. 3-33.

--, 2003, "Forecasting output and inflation:

The role of asset prices," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 41, No. 3, September, pp. 788-829.

--, 2002, "Macroeconomic forecasting using diffusion indexes," Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 147-162.

--, 1999, "Forecasting inflation," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 44, No. 2, October, pp. 293-335.

Marco Bassetto is a professor of macroeconomics at University College London, a senior economist and research advisor in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and a member of the Centre for Macroeconomics. Todd Messer is an associate economist and Christine Ostrowski is a senior associate economist in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors are indebted to Gadi Barlevy, Mariacristina De Nardi, Hesna Genay, and Ezra Obeifieldfor valuable suggestions.

[c] 2013 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Economic Perspectives is published by the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System

Charles L. Evans, President; Daniel G. Sullivan, Executive Vice President and Director of Research, Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic Advisor, David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial markets group', Daniel Aaronson, Vice President, microeconomic policy research, Jonas D. M. Fisher, Vice President, macroeconomic policy research, Richard Heckinger, Vice President, markets team', Anna L. Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A. Testa, Vice President, regional programs; Richard D. Porter, Vice President and Economics Editor, Helen Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors; Sheila A. Mangier, Editorial Assistant.

Economic Perspectives articles may be reproduced in whole or in part, provided the articles are not reproduced or distributed for commercial gain and provided the source is appropriately credited. Prior written permission must be obtained for any other reproduction, distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Economic Perspectives articles. To request permission, please contact Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org.

ISSN 0164-0682
TABLE 1
Contribution of economic activity to forecasts of 12-month and
24-month inflation changes (coefficients estimated on the period
to 2012 vs. the period to 2007)

                           Post-1984

                           CPI12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.66       0.71       0.68        0.51
Median      0.66       0.57       0.66        0.57

                          Post-1984

                           CPI24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.72       0.50       1.16        0.46
Median      0.72       0.46       0.93        0.59

                            Post-1984

                           PCE12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.61       0.02       1.51        0.43
Median      0.61       0.02       1.12        0.43

                           Post-1984

                           PCE24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.88       0.05       1.59        0.31
Median      0.88       0.05       1.17        0.25

                             All

                           CPI12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.76       0.80       0.66        0.41
Median      0.76       0.59       0.80        0.45

                             All

                           CPI24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.60       0.65       0.87        0.40
Median      0.51       0.50       0.81        0.45

                             All

                           PCE12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.69       0.70       0.65        0.49
Median      0.57       0.70       0.62        0.54

                             All

                           PCE24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.72       0.77       0.82        0.95
Median      0.59       0.72       0.69        0.99

Notes: Post-1984 refers to the sample from 1985 onwards. All refers to
a sample that starts in 1969 for PCE (Personal Consumption
Expenditures Price Index) and 1979 for CPI (Consumer Price Index).
Numbers smaller than one imply that the contribution shrank.

TABLE 2
Contribution of economic activity to forecasts of 12-month and
24-month inflation changes (coefficients estimated on the period
to 2012 vs. the period to 2007, model in levels)

                         Post-1984

Horizon                    CP112
Model
          Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.86       0.80       0.74        0.59
Median      0.86       0.53       1.23        0.60

                         Post-1984

Horizon                    CPI24
Model
          Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.89       0.56       1.98        0.56
Median      0.89       0.54       1.21        0.57

                         Post-1984

                           PCE12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.87       0.24       1.62        0.53
Median      0.87       0.24       1.17        0.48

                         Post-1984

                           PCE24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         1.03       0.58       1.53        0.47
Median      1.03       0.30       1.56        0.43

                             All

                           CPI12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.85       0.78       0.62        0.51
Median      0.85       0.63       1.05        0.57

                             All

                           CPI24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.97       0.69       0.72        0.49
Median      0.97       0.44       0.93        0.51

                             All

                           PCE12
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.70       0.69       0.77        0.59
Median      0.58       0.69       0.72        0.61

                             All

                           PCE24
Horizon
Model     Activity   Natural    Indicator   Diffusion

Max         0.75       0.87       0.86        0.61
Median      0.63       0.69       0.78        0.60

Notes: Post-1984 refers to the sample from 1985 onwards. All refers to
a sample that starts in 1969 for PCE (Personal Consumption
Expenditures Price Index) and 1979 for CPI (Consumer Price Index).
Numbers smaller than one imply that the contribution shrank.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有