Measuring the equilibrium real interest rate.
Justiniano, Alejandro ; Primiceri, Giorgio E.
The equilibrium real interest rate represents the real rate of
return required to keep the economy's output equal to potential
output. This article discusses how to measure the equilibrium real
interest rate, using an empirical structural model of the economy.
Introduction and summary
In conducting monetary policy, policymakers find it useful to
monitor the performance of the economy relative to some benchmark. For
instance, the policy decision whether to raise or lower the short-term
nominal interest rate might be affected by the deviations of current
inflation from policymakers' comfort zone, of output from potential
output, and of the real interest rate (current nominal rate minus
expected future inflation) from its equilibrium value (the rate that
would be consistent with output at its potential level). Unfortunately,
these benchmark concepts are not directly observed in the data, but can
only be defined in the context of a specific theoretical framework.
Over the past decade, the new Keynesian model has become the
workhorse for the analysis of monetary policy. This model departs from
the neoclassical framework of the 1980s by assuming imperfect
competition in goods and labor markets and "sticky" (meaning
rigid or inflexible) prices and wages--neoclassical models assume prices
and wages are flexible and adjust quickly. These ingredients in the new
Keynesian model alter the transmission of fundamental shocks perturbing
the economy and allow monetary policy to have temporary real effects.
The equilibrium real interest rate is a crucial concept in the new
Keynesian class of models. This rate represents the real rate of return
required to keep the economy's output equal to potential output,
which, in turn, is the level of output consistent with flexible prices
and wages and constant markups in goods and labor markets (Woodford,
2003; and Gali, 2008). (1) Meanwhile, the difference between the ex ante
real interest rate--the nominal interest rate minus expected
inflation-and the equilibrium real interest rate is defined as the real
interest rate gap.
In the new Keynesian model, the real interest rate (RIR hereafter)
gap is central to the determination of output and inflation. Loosely
speaking, if this RIR gap is positive, output will decline relative to
potential. This is because people will be inclined to postpone spending
decisions today to take advantage of higher returns to savings. All else
being equal, a negative output gap will then put downward pressures on
prices and wages because of weaker aggregate demand. Conversely, a
negative RIR gap will typically be associated with a positive output
gap, setting in motion inflationary forces--higher demand leads to
higher prices.
The main policy implication of this observation is that
policymakers concerned with maintaining output close to its potential
level should set short-term nominal interest rates--the policy
instrument of most central banks--in order to minimize the RIR gap. In
the absence of a trade-off between stabilizing inflation and output,
this simple policy prescription would also completely stabilize
inflation. In practice, however, there may well be a trade-off between
the two objectives of output and inflation stabilization. (2)
Nonetheless, the equilibrium RIR constitutes a natural benchmark for the
conduct of monetary policy, and the RIR gap can be viewed as providing
some indication of the stance of monetary policy (Neiss and Nelson,
2003).
While the equilibrium RIR is theoretically appealing, its use in
guiding monetary policy decisions faces at least two major hurdles.
First and foremost, the equilibrium RIR is not directly observable in
the data, limiting its usefulness as a target for monetary policy in
practice. (3) Moreover, rather than being constant, the equilibrium RIR
fluctuates over time in response to a variety of shocks to preferences
and technology that perturb the economy.
Second, setting nominal interest rates to track the equilibrium RIR
may not be feasible at times because of the existence of the zero bound;
that is, nominal interest rates cannot be set lower than zero. Indeed,
the equilibrium RIR may fall enough to induce a positive RIR gap, even
with the nominal interest rate at zero. Output would then decline below
potential, engendering deflation. In this way, the gap helps us to gauge
the constraint imposed by the zero bound on monetary policy. With
short-term nominal interest rates now at historically low levels in the
United States and a number of other industrialized countries, this
scenario is receiving a lot of attention from both the academic
community and policymakers.
Given the importance that the equilibrium RIR plays for the design
of monetary policy in modern macroeconomic models, our purpose in this
article is to provide an estimate of this unobservable variable. We do
so by inferring it from an empirical new Keynesian model fitted to U.S.
quarterly data on a few key macroeconomic variables from 1962:Q1 through
2008:Q4. (4)
Specifically, our analysis accomplishes three objectives. First, we
describe the historical evolution of the equilibrium RIR. We find that
this rate has been negative at times, particularly in the late 1970s
and, most interestingly, during the latest recession.
Second, we estimate the short-term RIR gap as the difference
between the current (as opposed to future) ex ante RIR and the
equilibrium RIR. This provides some indication of the stance of
monetary policy. Consistent with the anecdotal view, the estimated
short-term RIR gap suggests that policy was loose during most of the
1970s. In contrast, policy would seem to have been tight at the end of
our sample. However, this mostly reflects the zero bound
problem--policymakers' inability to lower long-term nominal
interest rates below zero--and provides a rationale for the
nonconventional policy measures undertaken by the Federal Reserve during
the most recent recession, such as direct purchases of longer-term
securities and the creation of special facilities and programs (for
example, the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, or TALF)
intended to increase access to credit.
Finally, we compare the evolution of the short-term and long-term
RIR gaps, where the latter is defined as the sum of the current and
expected future long-term RIR gaps or, alternatively, the difference
between the ex ante long-term RIR and the equilibrium long-term RIR.
Long-term rates reflect the path of current and expected future
long-term rates. Therefore, long-term gaps summarize private
expectations about future macroeconomic outcomes and monetary policy,
providing a more forward-looking measure of the policy stance. For
instance, according to this measure, policy was not loose in the 2002-06
period, which preceded the recent economic downturn. This
characterization of the policy stance contrasts with what is suggested
by the short-term RIR gap and, in particular, with the view of several
commentators (see, for instance, Taylor, 2007).
Several papers have tackled the estimation of the equilibrium RIR
before, most notably Laubach and Williams (2003) and Kozicki and Clark
(2005). In contrast to these earlier studies, our estimate of the
equilibrium RIR is based on a micro-founded model, which builds on the
optimizing behavior of households and finns seeking to maximize their
utility and profits. In this respect, this article is related to the
approach of Neiss and Nelson (2003), Amisano and Tristani (2008), and,
in particular, Edge, Kiley, and Laforte (2008). However, in contrast to
these earlier studies, we stress the importance of both current and
expected future RIR gaps for the determination of macroeconomic
outcomes.
As with all empirical work based on structural models, our results
may be sensitive to some aspects of the model specification. To
illustrate this point, we compare our results across two models that
differ in scale, shocks, and transmission mechanisms of these
disturbances.
The article is organized as follows. First, we provide a brief
description of our baseline model economy. Then, we describe the data
and the estimation approach. Next, we present the main results--that is,
we present our estimates of the equilibrium RIR and RIR gaps. We also
discuss the robustness of these estimates when inferred from a
larger-scale model. We conclude with a few comments and caveats to our
analysis, particularly with regard to the current economic situation.
More specifically, we note how the larger-scale model also suggests the
presence of positive long-term and long-term RIR gaps for the fourth
quarter of 2008. This provides a further rationale for the Federal
Reserve's response to the current crisis with nonconventional
measures to ease monetary policy. We do, however, emphasize the need to
enhance these models' ability to capture the interplay between the
financial sector and the real economy, particularly in light of recent
events.
The model
In this section, we sketch our baseline new Keynesian model and
analyze two of its key equilibrium relations--the aggregate demand and
supply equations. The presentation is mostly narrative, with most of the
technical details relegated to the appendix. Interested readers can
refer to Justiniano and Primiceri (2008) for greater details on the
model, or they can see the comprehensive treatment of new Keynesian
models in Woodford (2003) and Gall (2008), as well as the excellent
primer by Gall and Gertler (2007). For simplicity, relative to
Justiniano and Primiceri (2008), the model here abstracts from the roles
of habit formation, indexation, and endogenous capital accumulation. We
present the results based on a larger-scale model with these additional
features as a robustness check in a later section.
There are five types of agents in our model economy: 1) households,
2) employment agencies, 3) firms producing intermediate goods, 4) firms
producing final goods, and 5) the monetary authority. We now briefly
describe the behavior of each of them.
Households
We assume that we have a large number of households seeking to
maximize their stream of current and expected future utility, which
depends positively on their consumption of a single final good and
negatively on the number of hours they work for the production of
intermediate goods. Each household is the sole supplier of a specialized
type of labor that it sells to the employment agencies in exchange for
wages. Rather than taking wages as given--as under the neoclassical
assumption of perfect competition--each household has some market power
and can post its wage. This, in turn, determines the amount of their
specialized labor demanded by the employment agencies.
We introduce sticky wages in the labor market by assuming that at
each point in time only a random fraction of households can change their
posted wage. Hence, when setting its wage, each household takes into
consideration not only current but also future labor demand and costs of
working. For example, if future labor demand is expected to rise,
households will preemptively post higher wages, since they might not be
able to do so in the near future.
Finally, all households have access to savings through two types of
assets: one-period government bonds and state-contingent securities,
which pay only if a certain future state is realized. The former are
used to smooth consumption over time. State-contingent securities serve
instead to insure against the idiosyncratic risk arising from the
uncertainty about the length of time before households will be able to
reset their wages.
Employment agencies
Employment agencies mediate the demand and supply of labor between
households and firms producing intermediate goods. Their role is to
purchase all types of specialized labor supplied by households and
bundle them into a single homogenous labor input sold to intermediate
goods firms. Employment agencies operate in a perfectly competitive
market, taking the wage received for the labor bundle as given and
making zero profits.
Intermediate goods producers
A large number of intermediate goods producers combine technology
with labor inputs purchased from employment agencies to produce
differentiated intermediate goods, which are then sold to final goods
producers. Each of the intermediate goods producers has some market
power and can therefore post the price of its good. This, in turn,
determines the amount of its output demanded by the final goods
producers.
We introduce sticky prices in the goods market by assuming that at
each point in time only a random fraction of firms can change their
posted price. Hence, when setting its price, each firm takes into
consideration not only current but also future demand and marginal
costs, where the latter depend on wages. For example, if future demand
is expected to rise, producers will preemptively increase prices, since
they might not be able to adjust them in the near future.
Final goods producers
Final goods producers mediate between intermediate goods producers
and households. They produce the final good by bundling all intermediate
goods into a single final homogenous commodity purchased by households.
Final goods firms maximize profits as well, but in contrast to the
intermediate goods producers, they operate under perfect competition,
taking the price for the final good as given and making zero profits.
Monetary authority
The central bank determines monetary policy by setting the
short-term nominal interest rate in response to price inflation and
output growth. This interest rate rule is a variant of the instrument
rule proposed by Taylor (1993), the Taylor rule, which approximates the
historical behavior of the U.S. federal funds rate. According to this
rule, nominal interest rates rise more than one-to-one with inflation
and fall in response to output contractions.
Demand, supply, and the equilibrium RIR
Before presenting our estimation results, we highlight the main
insights of the two crucial equilibrium relations in the model. This
helps explain the roles of the equilibrium RIR and RIR gaps in the
determination of output and inflation.
Aggregate demand
In the model, aggregate spending is determined by the behavior of
the representative household, which seeks to smooth consumption over
time by investing its savings in one-period government bonds. This
optimizing behavior results in the following (log-linearized) aggregate
demand equation, which is also known as the IS equation:
1) [[??].sub.t] = [E.sub.t] + [[??].sub.t+1] - [[??].sub.t],
where y, and r, are output and the RIR, respectively, and the hat
symbol (^) denotes deviations from the equilibrium level. Hence, y,
denotes the output gap, and [[??].sub.i] stands for the short-term RIR
gap. Intuitively, according to the aggregate demand equation,
fluctuations in the short-term RIR gap induce deviations of the output
gap from its expected future value, [E.sub.t] [[??].sub.t+1], where the
operator [E.sub.t] denotes households' expectation of future values
conditional on the information available today.
Equation 1 can be iterated forward to express the output gap today
only as a function of the current and expected future short-term RIR
gaps. This procedure yields the expression
2) [[??].sub.t] = +[infinity].summation over (j=0)
[E.sub.t][[??].sub.t+j]
by which the output gap is negatively associated with the long-term
RIR gap. The latter corresponds to the sum of current and expected
future short-term RIR gaps. (5) Notice, therefore, that if the long-run
RIR gap is negative, the output gap will be positive, and vice versa.
Aggregate supply
In terms of the supply side, intermediate goods firms set prices
according to the current and expected future evolution of marginal costs
and demand conditions. Profit-maximizing behavior results in the
following (log-linearized) aggregate supply or Phillips curve equation:
3) [[pi].sub.t] = [beta][E.sub.t][[pi].sub.t=1] + [kappa][s.sub.t]
+ [[lambda].sub.[pi],t],
where [[pi].sub.t] and [s.sub.t] stand for price inflation and real
marginal costs, respectively, and [[lambda].sub.[pi],t] is a markup
shock that represents exogenous variation to the level of markup desired
by intermediate goods producers. Finally, [beta] is a constant very
close to one that represents the temporal discount factor, and [kappa]
is a positive constant that is inversely related to the degree of price
stickiness. Intuitively, inflation exceeds its expected future level
either if real marginal costs increase or if intermediate goods firms
change their desired markup of prices over marginal costs for other
reasons exogenous to the model.
To highlight the importance of the RIR gap for inflation
determination, we briefly analyze a special case of our model obtained
by assuming perfectly flexible wages. Under this assumption, real
marginal costs are proportional to the output gap. Hence, all else being
equal, a positive output gap will cause inflation to rise relative to
its expected future level. Moreover, if the output gap is projected to
remain positive in the future, expected future inflation will also
increase, further fueling the rise in current inflation. That is,
current and expected future RIR gaps engender pressures on prices
through their effects on aggregate demand. This crucial insight also
holds in our general model with wage rigidities, although with sticky
wages the link between the output gap and real marginal costs is more
complex.
RIR gaps and monetary policy
Equations 1 and 3 highlight the importance of RIR gaps for output
and inflation determination. Current and future expected deviations of
ex ante RIRs from their corresponding equilibrium values affect the
output gap, which, in turn, influences the inflation rate. Since the ex
ante RIRs depend on the nominal interest rates set by the monetary
authority, the conduct of monetary policy is central to the behavior of
the RIR gaps and, hence, output and inflation.
Consider, for instance, a central bank that seeks to stabilize
price inflation and the output gap. Absent any markup shocks
([[lambda].sub.[pi],t]), the central bank can achieve full stabilization
of both output and inflation by committing to set nominal interest rates
according to an appropriate instrument rule that delivers a zero RIR gap
at every point in time.
However, as we mentioned in the introduction, tracking the
equilibrium RIR may not be feasible when the zero bound on nominal
interest rates becomes binding. Put another way, sometimes the
equilibrium RIR may fall enough that, even with the short-term nominal
interest rate at zero, positive RIR gaps would emerge. In this case,
according to the model, output would decline relative to potential and
inflation would fall.
Even abstracting from the zero bound, in practice optimal monetary
policy is more involved than the simple prescription of tracking the
equilibrium RIR. This is due to the fact that markup shocks bring about
a trade-off between stabilizing the output gap and inflation. (6)
Nonetheless, despite these considerations, the equilibrium RIR remains
an important reference point for the conduct of monetary policy,
assuming that it can be accurately estimated and forecasted. This is the
task we undertake next.
Model solution and estimation
In this section, we provide a brief overview of the approach that
we adopt to estimate the model's parameters and to infer the
evolution of the latent (unobservable) variables. The discussion is
somewhat technical, although we do not aim to provide a comprehensive
overview of the techniques we used. For more details on these
techniques, interested readers should refer to An and Schorfheide
(2007).
Model solution and state-space representation
The model we described in the preceding section has a solution of
the form
4) [[??].sub.t] = G([theta])[[??].sub.t-1] +
M([theta])[[epsilon].sub.t],
where the state vector [[??].sub.t] collects all variables except
for the shocks. The elements of [[??].sub.t] are expressed in (log)
deviations from the model's nonstochastic steady state, which
corresponds to the constant values of all variables that the economy
would converge to in the absence of shocks. The shocks inducing
temporary deviations from the steady state are stacked in the vector
[[??].sub.t]. Meanwhile, G ([theta]) and M ([theta]) are matrices whose
elements are functions of the vector of model structural parameters,
denoted by [theta]. Our goal is to estimate these parameters and to
uncover the historical behavior of the unobserved variables in the state
vector.
In fact, while some elements of the state vector are directly
observed in the data (for instance, inflation and output), others are
not (such as the equilibrium RIR and expected inflation). Therefore, in
order to estimate the model, equation 4 must be combined with an
additional set of equations specifying which elements of the state
vector are observed in the data.
The general form of this additional set of equations is
5) [x.sub.t] = Z ([[??].sub.t] + C([theta])),
where Z is a matrix mapping the elements of [??] into [x.sub.t]
(the vector of observable data) and where C is a vector of constant
terms (which may depend on [theta]) representing the steady state of the
observable elements of [??]. Equations 4 and 5 constitute the transition
and measurement equations of a linear state-space model.
Data
We estimate the model, using five series of U.S. quarterly data: 1)
real per capita gross domestic product (GDP), 2) per capita hours
worked, 3) real per capita wages, 4) quarterly inflation, and 5) the
short-term nominal interest rate. We construct real GDP by dividing
nominal GDP by the population aged 22-65 and the GDP deflator. (7) For
hours, we use a measure of hours in all sectors of the economy following
Francis and Ramey (2008). This is also our source for the population
series. Real wages correspond to nominal compensation of employees from
the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis's national income and product
accounts (NIPAs), divided by hours and the GDP deflator; for the nominal
interest rates, we use the effective federal funds rate. The sample
period spans 1962:Q1 through 2008:Q4. (8) We do not de-mean or de-trend
any series.
Bayesian inference
The state-space representation of the model allows us to use a very
powerful algorithm known as the Kalman filter to estimate the parameters
[theta] and retrieve the most likely path of the unobservable elements
of [[??].sub.t]. We discuss each in turn.
A natural way to estimate the model is to find the value of the
parameters [theta] that maximizes the likelihood function. The
likelihood function summarizes all information about [theta] contained
in a sample of data and plays a pivotal role in econometrics and
statistics. The likelihood function of our state-space model can be
evaluated using the Kalman filter.
In practice, however, the likelihood function associated with most
modern macroeconomic models is typically a complicated nonlinear
function of the model parameters. This makes finding a unique value that
maximizes the likelihood a rather arduous task. For this reason, most of
the recent literature estimating macro models has turned to Bayesian
methods, which discipline the set of plausible values for [theta]
through the use of prior information.
Bayesian inference then seeks to characterize the distribution of
[theta] that results from combining the likelihood function with the
prior information. This is known as the posterior distribution, from
which we can compute the location of a parameter (mean or median) and a
measure of uncertainty. For instance, the uncertainty surrounding
[theta] can be conveyed by reporting posterior probability bands that
contain the range of values that parameters are likely to take with,
say, 99 percent probability.
Prior beliefs about the elements of [theta] may be informed by
theory or simply reflect and summarize information not contained in the
estimation sample. In practice, this prior information is formulated by
specifying a certain distribution for each element of the parameter
vector, centered at a particular value (mean) and with an associated
measure of uncertainty (standard deviation).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Once we have estimated the model's parameters, we can employ
the Kalman filter to sequentially and systematically update our guess
for the unobserved elements of the state vector. More precisely, at each
point in time, our guess for (,, based on data available in the previous
quarter, is updated after we observe the data for the current period.
This filtered (or one-sided) estimate for the state vector forms the
basis for our guess on the value of the state vector next period, which
we also update once we have data for the next quarter, and so on.
Having followed this procedure for all periods, we can go back and
revise the filtered estimate of [[??].sub.t], conditional not only on
information up to time t but also on the whole sample of data. We call
the state vector emerging from this procedure the smoothed (or
two-sided) estimate. We analyze these estimates in the next section.
Equilibrium RIR and RIR gaps in the estimated model
We do not report the estimated parameters in this article. They are
similar to those of Justiniano and Primiceri (2008), who use a longer
sample. Here, we focus on our estimates of the equilibrium RIR and the
RIR gaps.
The equilibrium RIR
Figure l plots the smoothed estimate of the equilibrium RIR (solid
blue line). It is also important to characterize the uncertainty
surrounding the estimated equilibrium RIR, particularly since this is
cited as a possible concern regarding its usefulness for monetary policy
analysis. Therefore, we also report uncertainty bands (dashed black
lines), which represent the values this variable is likely to have taken
with 99 percent probability. We first highlight a few properties of the
smoothed estimate and later discuss these probability bands.
The first thing to notice is that the inferred equilibrium RIR has
fluctuated substantially over our sample, with a standard deviation of
1.94 percent around a mean of 2.6 percent (annualized). (9) A second
interesting feature of figure 1 is that the equilibrium RIR has turned
negative in a few instances. This occurred around 1975 and the end of
2008--two recession dates, as determined by the National Bureau of
Economic Research--and during the 2003-04 period. These episodes were
characterized by a substantial decline in the federal funds rate in
response to weak economic conditions. However, the 2008 episode is the
only one in our sample for which the uncertainty bands are completely
below zero.
Indeed, the third interesting observation is that the equilibrium
RIR has plummeted in the latest part of the sample. In particular,
during the latest recession, the equilibrium RIR seems to have recorded
by far its largest decline, with an estimate for 2008:Q4 of roughly
-2.15 percent.
The tightness of the posterior probability bands deserves some
comment. In particular, the precision with which the equilibrium RIR is
estimated perhaps seems implausible, especially considering that these
bands account for the uncertainty surrounding both the unobserved states
and the model parameters. It is important to keep in mind, however, that
these probability bands abstract from model uncertainty. That is,
alternative specifications of the model (for example, a different
historical characterization of U.S. monetary policy or a model with
additional propagation mechanisms and/or shocks) might deliver different
estimates of the equilibrium RIR. We return to this issue in the section
explaining the larger-scale model.
This being said, the cross-sectional dispersion at different points
in time is larger than perhaps suggested visually by figure 1. For
example, figure 2 plots the posterior distribution of the equilibrium
RIR for the last point in the sample, 2008:Q4. Values of the equilibrium
RIR are on the horizontal axis, with the vertical line drawn at the
median of-2.15 percent, which coincides with the estimate reported in
the previous figure. Notice that this distribution has a range from
roughly -4 percent to -0.5 percent, with hardly any weight assigned to
values close to zero. Therefore, our model-based estimates suggest that
it is quite likely that the equilibrium RIR became negative in 2008. To
what extent did this induce positive RIR gaps? We address this key issue
next.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The short-term RIR gap
The ex ante RIR is given by the difference between the nominal
interest rate and the inflation rate expected for next quarter. While
the former is directly observable in our data, the latter is part of the
unobservable state vector and must be backed out using the Kalman
filter.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 3 shows the smoothed estimate of the ex ante RIR (blue line)
together with the equilibrium RIR (black line). The mean of the ex ante
RIR is 2.37 percent (annualized) with a standard deviation of 2.45
percent. These statistics are similar to those corresponding to the
equilibrium RIR. The overall contours of these two series coincide,
although they have differed at times.
In order to highlight the discrepancies between the ex ante RIR and
the equilibrium RIR, figure 4 plots their difference together with its
99 percent probability bands. We refer to this difference as the
short-term RIR gap, in order to distinguish it from the long-term gap
that we analyze next. Note that the short-term gap has also fluctuated
considerably over time, with an average of-0.33 percent and a standard
deviation of 1.28 percent.
As we noted earlier, the short-term RIR gap is commonly taken as a
measure of the monetary policy stance. And indeed, at least for some
episodes, the evolution of the RIR gap aligns well with the anecdotal
characterization of monetary policy that we see in the literature. For
instance, according to our estimates, the equilibrium RIR exceeded the
ex ante real interest rate during most of the 1970s, exactly when U.S.
inflation was at historically high levels. This is consistent with the
view that monetary policy during this period was characterized by an
insufficient response to the rise in inflation (Clarida, Gali, and
Gertler, 2000). Similarly, the significant increase in the short-term
RIR gap in the early 1980s accords well with the conventional view that
the disinflation in the U.S. economy was engineered by a substantial
policy tightening under then-Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The long-term RIR gap
While the behavior of the short-term RIR gap presented in figure 4
squares quite well with the conventional view, there are a few caveats
that call for caution in interpreting this gap as a good proxy for the
stance of monetary policy. In particular, as we explained earlier, it is
important to recognize that the whole path of expected future short-term
RIR gaps--rather than just its contemporaneous value---matters for the
determination of output and inflation in the new Keynesian model (see
equation 2, p. 17). From this perspective, we might judge the monetary
policy stance better by looking at the long-term RIR gap, which
summarizes the information contained in the current and expected future
values of the federal funds rate, inflation, and the equilibrium RIR.
To this end, figure 5 compares the short-term RIR gap (blue line)
with the evolution of the long-term one (black line). Although the two
series often move together--the correlation coefficient is equal to
0.56--the message about the stance of monetary policy implied by the two
lines differs during some historical episodes.
The 2002-46 period provides an interesting example. In 2002:Q3 the
federal funds rate stood at 1.75 percent, but it had declined to 1
percent by 2003:Q3, and remained there for the next three quarters. The
federal funds rate then rose gradually, reaching 5.25 percent in
2006:Q3. Some have argued that monetary policy was too accommodative
during this period (for example, Taylor, 2007). Although the negative
value of the short-term RIR gap seems to accord with this claim (blue
line), the positive value of the long-term RIR gap (black line) does not
support the view that policy was too expansionary. In particular, it
suggests that the private sector expected a decline of the equilibrium
RIR or a monetary tightening.
The difference between short-term and long-term gaps toward the end
of the sample is also informative. For instance, our estimate of the
short-term RIR gap in 2008:Q4 is roughly 1.5 percent. This suggests
that, according to the model, the federal funds rate of 0.5 percent was
probably above the equilibrium RIR. Furthermore, it suggests that the
zero bound on nominal interest rates would have been binding before
additional interest rate cuts could have closed the short-term RIR gap.
In addition, the estimated long-term RIR gap exceeds 3 percent. Taken at
face value, this would suggest that at the end of 2008, positive
short-term gaps were expected to persist and the zero bound was expected
to bind beyond a single quarter.
Before we interpret this result as indicative of contractionary
monetary policy, we must acknowledge that these gaps can only reflect
the stance of conventional monetary policy. By this we mean the Federal
Reserve's management of the short-term nominal interest rate.
During the current economic crisis, the Federal Reserve has also
employed a variety of nonconventional policy measures; and these
measures have been reflected in the changing size and composition of the
Federal Reserve's balance sheet. Our simple analysis suggests that
these measures have been appropriate, insofar as both the short-term RIR
and long-term RIR exceeded the equilibrium RIR. However, these
extraordinary measures are not reflected in our analysis of the
short-term and long-term RIR gaps.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
A larger-scale model
The baseline model can be summarized in a few simple equations
that, as discussed, clearly highlight the role of the equilibrium RIR
for the dynamics of output and inflation. This simplicity, however,
comes at the expense of abstracting from other features that impart more
realism to the model. In particular, additional shocks can be included
and other mechanisms added (such as endogenous capital accumulation)
through which disturbances influence the evolution of the economy. For
this reason, we test the robustness of our main conclusions by using a
larger-scale model estimated on a richer data set. This extended model
is discussed in Justiniano and Primiceri (2008) and is based on the
well-known studies of Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (2005) and Smets
and Wouters (2007).
Relative to our baseline model, the larger-scale model includes the
additional propagation mechanisms provided by endogenous capital
accumulation, investment adjustment costs, a choice of capital
utilization, habit formation in consumption, and indexation in both
prices and wages. These features are essentially meant to increase the
length of time for which a given shock will affect the evolution of the
economy. There are three additional disturbances perturbing the model
economy, specifically, shocks to the marginal efficiency of investment,
to the disutility of labor, and to government spending. Finally, we
estimate the model over the same sample, 1962:Q1 through 2008:Q4, but we
incorporate additional data on consumption and investment.
Figure 6 reports the smoothed estimates of the equilibrium RIR and
the ex ante RIR, as well as the short-term and long-term RIR gaps. In
each panel, the black line reproduces the estimates from the baseline
model and the blue line corresponds to estimates from the extended
model.
Panel A highlights the fact that the cyclical pattern of the
equilibrium RIR is very similar across models, although the equilibrium
RIR is substantially more volatile in the larger-scale model. (10) One
implication of this finding is that, according to the extended model,
the equilibrium RIR has declined below zero more frequently than what is
predicted by our baseline framework. Furthermore, the decline in the
current downturn, while substantial, is not as dramatic by historical
standards as suggested by the baseline model.
Since the inferred ex ante RIR (panel B) is almost identical across
models, it is not surprising that the short-term RIR gap (panel C) and
long-term RIR gap (panel D) are more volatile in the larger-scale model
as well. Notice also that the estimates from our baseline model and
larger-scale model co-move more closely in the case of the long-term
gap, for which the two lines essentially overlap during the latest part
of the sample.
Regarding the 2002-06 period, the discrepancy between the
short-term and long-term RIR gaps is far less evident in the
larger-scale model than in our baseline model. However, both measures in
the larger-scale model remain positive or very close to zero. This
confirms our earlier observation that policy may not have been as
accommodative during this period as has been suggested (for example,
Taylor, 2007).
Consistent with the baseline model, the larger-scale framework also
predicts large positive short-term and long-term RIR gaps for the fourth
quarter of 2008. However, the same caveats we raised earlier about
interpreting these endpoint estimates as reflecting the policy stance
apply to the larger-scale model as well.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Overall, despite some obvious discrepancies, we view these results
as an important assessment of robustness of our main findings.
Furthermore, they suggest-in line with our earlier hypothesis--that
model uncertainty is likely to be a crucial factor surrounding the
measurement of the unobservable equilibrium RIR and related components.
This source of uncertainty is sometimes ignored in studies presenting
model-based estimates of the RIR, although our findings suggest that
this should be a major issue for further empirical work in this area.
Conclusion
In this article, we study the evolution of the equilibrium RIR and
RIR gaps, using both a prototypical new Keynesian model and a
larger-scale model similar to those in Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans
(2005) and Smets and Wouters (2007). Our estimates point to a
substantial degree of time variation in the equilibrium RIR. Moreover,
we find that this rate has sometimes become negative in the post-war
period. In particular, our analysis suggests that the equilibrium RIR
fell sharply below zero toward the end of 2008 (although the magnitude
of this decline relative to historical standards is model dependent),
resulting in positive short-term and long-term expected RIR gaps. This
provides some support for the Federal Reserve's response to the
current crisis with nonconventional measures to ease monetary policy.
We conclude by noting that the models we use here, even the
larger-scale one, are to some extent very stylized and have some
shortcomings. One of these shortcomings is the absence of an explicit
theoretical framework of the financial sector and financial frictions.
It would be useful to analyze how the introduction of these additional
features would affect our results (as, for instance, in Christiano,
Motto, and Rostagno, 2007). These features seem particularly relevant
for the analysis of current economic events.
APPENDIX: MODEL EQUATIONS
We present the main equations of the model for each of the five
classes of agents described in the main text.
Households
The expected discounted stream of utility that each household j
maximizes is given by
A1) [E.sub.t] [infinity.summation over (s=0)]
[[beta].sup.s][b.sub.t+s] [log [C.sub.t+s]] - [phi]
[L.sub.t+s][(j).sup.1+v]/1+v],
where [C.sub.t] denotes consumption, and the second argument of the
utility function represents the marginal disutility of each
household's specific labor, L(j), that depends on the parameter v,
known as the inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply. Future utility
is discounted at the rate [beta], and [b.sub.t] is a "discount
factor" shock affecting both the marginal utility of consumption
and the marginal disutility of labor. The logarithm of [b.sub.t] is
modeled as a Gaussian autoregressive process of order 1, denoted as
AR(I) for short.
At every point in time t, each household's sources and uses of
income must be equal, as summarized by the budget constraint
[P.sub.t][C.sub.t] + [T.sub.t] + [B.sub.t] [less than or equal to]
[R.sub.t-1][B.sub.t-1] + [Q.sub.t-1](j) + [[PI].sub.t] +
[W.sub.t](j)[L.sub.t](j),
where [T.sub.t] is lump-sum taxes and transfers, [B.sub.t] denotes
holdings of government bonds, [R.sub.t] is the gross nominal interest
rate, [Q.sub.t](j) is the net cash flow from participating in
state-contingent securities that insure against idiosyncratic risk, and
[[PI].sub.t] is the per capita profit that households get from owning
the intermediate goods firms.
Following Erceg, Henderson, and Levin (2000), we permit in every
period only a fraction 1 - [[xi].sub.w]. of households to reset their
wages to minimize the expected discounted stream of labor disutility for
the periods in which the posted wage is anticipated to remain in place,
[E.sub.t] [infinity.summation over (s=0)]
[[xi].sup.s.sub.w][[beta].sup.s][b.sub.t+s]] {[phi]
[L.sub.t+s][(j).sup.1+v]/1+v]}.
This is subject to the labor demand function of employment agencies
specified next. Wages for the remaining [[xi].sub.w] fraction of
households are indexed to steady-state inflation and productivity.
Employment agencies
Competitive employment agencies operate in competitive markets and
bundle each household's specialized labor [L.sub.t] (j) into a
homogenous labor input according to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Homogeneous labor is sold to intermediate goods firms. Profit
maximization and the zero profit condition imply a specialized labor
demand function,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [W.sub.t] (j) is the wage paid by the employment agencies to
the household supplying labor of type j, and [W.sub.t] is the hourly
wage paid by intermediate goods firms for their homogenous labor input.
The demand schedule for labor j is decreasing in the relative wage and
depends on the elasticity of substitution among varieties of labor given
by [[LAMBDA].sub.w,t]. Notice that this elasticity is time varying, and
we assume that log (1+ [[LAMBDA].sub.w,t]) is a Gaussian independent and
identically distributed (i.i.d.) process In the literature this is
referred to as the wage markup shock, and it is analyzed in detail in
Justiniano and Primiceri (2008).
Intermediate goods producers
A monopolistically competitive firm produces the intermediate good
[Y.sub.t] (i) with the production function
[Y.sub.t] (i) = [A.sub.t] [L.sub.t][(i).sup.a],
where [L.sub.t] (i) denotes the bundled labor input purchased from
employment agencies for the production of good i, and [A.sub.t]
represents a productivity shock. We model [A.sub.t] as nonstationary,
with its growth rate following a Gaussian AR(I) process.
As in Calvo (19837, at each point in time a fraction [[xi].sub.p]
of firms cannot reoptimize their prices and index them to steady-state
inflation. The remaining fraction 1 - [[xi].sub.p] of firms post a new
price [[??].sub.t] (i) to maximize the expected discounted stream of
profits for the periods in which the new price is anticipated to remain
in place,
[E.sub.t] [infinity.summation over (s=0)]
[[xi].sup.s.sub.p][[beta].sup.s][[LAMBDA].sub.t+s]]
{[[??].sub.t](i)[[pi].sup.s][Y.sub.t+s](i) - [W.sub.t+s]
[L.sub.t+s](i)}.
where [[LAMBDA].sub.t+s]] is the marginal utility of consumption
used to value future income, subject to the goods demand function
specified in the next section.
Final goods producers
Perfectly competitive firms produce the final good [Y.sub.t] by
bundling all intermediate goods according to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Profit maximization and zero profit condition for the final goods
producers imply the following demand function for the intermediate good
i:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [P.sub.t] corresponds to the aggregate price level. The
demand schedule for intermediate good i is decreasing in its relative
price, and depends on the elasticity of substitution [[LAMBDA].sub.p+s]]
among varieties of intermediate goods. This elasticity is time varying,
and we assume that log (1 + [[LAMBDA].sub.p,t]) is a Gaussian i.i.d,
process. This disturbance is known as the price markup shock.
Monetary authority
The Taylor type rule for the short-term nominal interest rate, R,
is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
with R being the steady state for the gross nominal interest rate
and [[epsilon].sub.R,t] being a Gaussian i.i.d, monetary policy shock.
The parameters [[phi].sub.[pi]] and [[phi].sub.Y] capture how
aggressively the monetary authority responds to variations in inflation
and output growth over the current and previous three quarters. There is
a time-varying inflation target [[pi].sup.*.sub.t], which evolves
exogenously according to a Gaussian AR(l) process. Finally, notice that
short-term nominal interest rates are adjusted gradually, as given by
[[rho].sub.R] , referred to as the smoothing coefficient.
REFERENCES
Amisano, G., and O. Tristani, 2008, "Perceived productivity
and the natural rate of interest," European Central Bank, mimeo.
An, S., and F. Schorfheide, 2007, "Bayesian analysis of DSGE
models," Econometric Reviews, Vol. 26, Nos. 2-4, March, pp.
113-172.
Calvo, G., 1983, "Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing
framework," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, No. 3,
September, pp. 383-398.
Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbanm, and C. L. Evans, 2005,
"Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary
policy," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, No. 1, February,
pp. 1-45.
Christiano, L. J., R. Motto, and M. Rostagno, 2007, "Financial
factors in business cycles," Northwestern University, mimeo.
Clarida, R., J. Gall, and M. Gertler, 2000, "Monetary policy
rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, No. 1, February, pp. 147-180.
--, 1999, "The science of monetary policy: A new Keynesian
perspective," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 37, No. 4,
December, pp. 1661-1707.
Edge, R. M., M. T. Kiley, and J.-P. Laforte, 2008, "Natural
rate measures in an estimated DSGE model of the U.S. economy,"
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 32, No. 8, August, pp.
2512-2535.
Erceg, C. J., D. W. Henderson, and A. T. Levin, 2000, "Optimal
monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts," Journal
of Monetary Economics, Vol. 46, No. 2, October, pp. 281-313.
Ferguson, R., 2004, "Equilibrium real interest rate: Theory
and application," speech to the University of Connecticut School of
Business Graduate Learning Center and the SS&C Technologies
Financial Accelerator, Hartford, CT, October 29, available at
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20041029/default.htm.
Francis, N. R., and V. A. Ramey, 2008, "Measures of hours per
capita and their implications for the technology-hours debate,"
University of California, San Diego, mimeo.
Gali, J., 2008, Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle.
An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework, Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Gali, J., and M. Gertler, 2007, "Macroeconomic modeling for
monetary policy evaluation," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol.
21, No. 4, Fall, pp. 25-46.
Justiniano, A., and G. E. Primiceri, 2008, "Potential and
natural output," Northwestern University, mimeo.
Kozicki, S., and T. Clark, 2005, "Estimating equilibrium real
interest rates in real time," North American Journal of Economics
and Finance, Vol. 16, No. 3, December, pp. 395-413.
Laubach, T., and J. C. Williams, 2003, "Measuring the natural
rate of interest," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No.
4, November, pp. 1063-1070.
Neiss, K. S., and E. Nelson, 2003, "The real interest rate gap
as an inflation indicator," Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 7, No. 2,
April, pp. 239-262.
Orphanides, A., 2001, "Monetary policy rules based on
real-time data," American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 4,
September, pp. 964-985.
Smets, F., and R. Wouters, 2007, "Shocks and frictions in U.S.
business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach," American Economic
Review, Vol. 97, No. 3, June, pp. 586-606.
Taylor, J. B., 2007, "Housing and monetary policy," in
Housing, Housing Finance, and Monetary Policy, Jackson Hole Economic
Symposium Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 463-476.
--,1993, "Discretion versus policy rules in practice,"
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39, No. 1,
December, pp. 195-214.
Woodford, M., 2003, Interest and Prices. Foundations of a Theory of
Monetary Policy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
NOTES
(1) Hence, we could alternatively refer to the equilibrium real
interest rate as the real interest rate at potential. We prefer the
former terminology because it is more popular in the literature and
policy discussions, as exemplified by the discussion in Ferguson (2004).
Meanwhile, potential output is proportional, but lower than the
efficient level of output. The efficient level of output is the level of
output under perfect competition and, therefore, with zero markups. In
the goods market, the markup is defined as the amount by which prices
exceed the marginal cost of production. In the labor market, the markup
is defined as the excess of wages over the marginal cost of supplying
labor.
(2) Exogenous variations in desired markups, usually referred to as
markup shocks, introduce such a trade-off(see, for example, Clarida,
Gall, and Gertler, 1999)
(3) Potential output is not directly observable either, and the
policy implications of its measurement have received substantial
attention following the work of Orphanides (2001). See also Justiniano
and Primiceri (2008)
(4) We also estimate the model's unknown parameters and
subsequently extract all unobserved model-based variables, such as
expected inflation next period.
(5) While seemingly daunting to compute, the long-run rates can be
backed out from the Lagrange multiplier of the household's budget
constraint.
(6) If wages are rigid, optimal monetary policy must attribute some
weight to wage inflation stabilization as well.
(7) All data except for hours are from Haver Analytics. We are very
grateful to Shawn Sprague, of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, for
providing us the series of hours in all sectors of the economy.
(8) We use the eight years prior to the sample period to initialize
the Kalman filter.
(9) This result is consistent with the large degree of time
variation reported by Laubach and Williams (2003) and Edge, Kiley, and
Laforte (2008), but stands in contrast to the analysis of Neiss and
Nelson (2003), who argue that the equilibrium real interest rate
exhibits very little volatility.
(10) The main reason the equilibrium RIR in the larger-scale model
is more volatile is that this model includes habit formation.
Alejandro Justiniano is a senior economist in the Economic Research
Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Giorgio E. Primiceri
is an assistant professor in the Department of Economics at Northwestern
University The authors are grateful to Anna Pulson, Richard Porter,
Spence Krane, and seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago for helpful comments.