Improving the impact of federal aid to the states.
Mattoon, Richard H. ; Haleco-Meyer, Vanessa ; Foster, Taft 等
Introduction and summary
On February 17, 2009, President Barack Obama signed into law the
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA). (1) The legislation
represents the most recent attempt by the federal government to provide
countercyclical aid to states and localities suffering from fiscal
stress stemming from a broad-based economic recession. (2) The
legislation follows the pattern of previous federal aid programs in that
it provides a combination of direct program support (Medicaid,
unemployment insurance, and education aid) and infrastructure grants.
The intention is to provide two forms of relief. First, the program aid
will serve as a stabilizer for state and local governments by allowing
them to maintain (or at least minimize the reduction in) key expenditure
areas. Second, the infrastructure money is intended to serve as a
stimulus and potential job creator. The ARRA's emphasis on job
creation and economic growth objectives makes it a little different from
past federal aid programs; traditionally these have focused heavily on
fiscal stabilization. (3)
While states and localities often support such generosity from
Washington, there are several questions that remain regarding the
efficacy of countercyclical federal aid. In this article, we discuss the
rationale for federal assistance and examine different mechanisms for
its distribution. Of particular interest is whether the aid program is
calibrated to reflect changes in the business cycle. Since this is
countercyclical aid, it is intended only to ameliorate changes in
business cycle conditions that have a direct impact on state budgets and
not to facilitate poor budget policy by state and local governments.
Through empirical analysis, we model the effects of the use of different
economic triggers to start and stop aid over the business cycle and
examine how these triggers would have performed over previous business
cycles. The triggers we use are the unemployment rate, measured as the
excess rate above a specific unemployment threshold; the change in sales
tax revenues, relative to a four-quarter moving average decline in
revenues by more than 5 percent; and the change in a state-specific
business cycle indicator (the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia's state coincident indexes). Clearly, decisions about
the timing and targeting of aid are critical to structuring an
appropriate federal response to states' financial difficulties. We
find that the Philadelphia Fed's coincident indexes do a relatively
good job of timing aid to reflect both the local intensity of the
business cycle in individual states and the duration of the recession on
a national level. The use of such a trigger would improve the likelihood
that the aid would reduce the stress related to the business cycle, as
opposed to the stress caused by structural imbalances in a given
state's economy or fiscal system.
Purpose and structure of aid
The idea of federal support for state (and local) governments in a
downturn is hardly a new one. For example, in response to the recession
of 1973-75, (4) Congress enacted the Antirecession Fiscal Assistance
(ARFA) program, which was combined with general revenue sharing grants
and the Local Public Works (LPW) program to provide unrestricted grants
and infrastructure funding to the states. In addition, Congress passed
the Comprehensive Employment and Training Act (CETA) in 1973 and, in
conjunction with these other programs, this became an anti-recessionary
mechanism for delivering job training. More recently, in 2003, Congress
passed the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act, as states
dealt with a slow recovery from the 2001 recession.
The purpose of such funding is primarily to stabilize fiscal
behavior in the state government sector. This aid is intended to smooth
the budgetary actions states would be forced to take in the face of
declining revenues and increasing expenditure demands from programs such
as Medicaid and unemployment insurance. In practice, the composition of
state spending has become more countercyclical, given that health and
education programs now consume larger shares (relative to spending in
the past) of state budgets and tend to have rising program demands
during economic downturns. The federal government sometimes adds an
infrastructure element to its aid as a way of increasing demand in the
construction sector and stimulating the economy. However, economic
stimulus is clearly a secondary objective of this aid; if the federal
government's primary purpose were to provide an economic stimulus,
it would probably be better off simply spending the money directly
rather than funneling it through the states.
Federal response to the 1973-75 recession
The 1973-75 recession lasted 16 months and was strongly associated
with the rapid rise of oil prices and the U.S. moving off the gold
standard. The Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)
quadrupled prices in 1973 and this, combined with high inflation, led to
three quarters of negative growth and an unemployment rate that peaked
at 9 percent in 1975. This recession was also notable for the
government's creation of wage and price controls in an effort to
restrain inflation. (5) Inflation peaked at 12.6 percent in the fourth
quarter of 1974.
In response, the federal government passed three programs in 1976
designed to help states and localities. These were expanded in 1977. The
package had three components: public works, anti-recession general
assistance, and public employment and work force training. In all, $14.5
billion was allocated to the states from November 1975 to March 1978.
(6)
Aid from the three programs was divided as follows: $5.7 billion
for local public works, $2.5 billion for antirecession fiscal
assistance, and $6.3 billion for employment and training through the
Comprehensive Education and Training Act (CETA). All three programs used
measures of unemployment to trigger eligibility for aid. For the local
public works and CETA programs, a national unemployment rate in excess
of 6.5 percent was the baseline measure; for the anti-recessionary aid,
a 6 percent national unemployment rate triggered fund allocations to
states with local unemployment rates exceeding 4.5 percent.
Evaluating the effectiveness of the aid
Detailed evaluations of the aid programs were presented in reports
by the U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO, 1977) and the Congressional
Budget Office (CBO, 1978).
The GAO report specifically examined Title II of the Public Works
Employment Act of 1976. This was one component of the federal
government's response to the recession. The stated goal of the
program was "to offset destabilizing fiscal action of state and
local governments during recessions and, in particular, to maintain
basic services customarily provided with the emphasis placed on wages
and salaries of public employees." (7)
Specifically, Title II of the act authorized the distribution of
$1.25 billion over five quarters from July 1976 through September 1977.
The GAO report focused on five areas of inquiry:
* Was the provision of aid to state and local jurisdictions timely
so that it was an effective tool to counter economic recession?
* What was the magnitude of destabilizing fiscal action by state
and local governments during the economic downturn?
* Was the aid targeted effectively so that it was directed to those
state and local jurisdictions that suffered most from the impact of the
recession?
* Was the level of excess unemployment (which was defined in the
law as any rate above 4.5 percent) the best indicator of the impact of
the recession on states and localities?
* Was the effect of the recession a less serious problem for state
and local governments than long-term structural problems associated with
secular decline?
The report's findings suggested several flaws in the federal
assistance program. For example, the excess unemployment rate trigger
was not sensitive enough to reflect cyclical change in state economies.
In addition, it was not clear that the recession by itself was
sufficient to cause destabilizing state and local fiscal actions. In the
case of this recession, inflation played a significant role. Further,
the use of the excess unemployment rate to allocate aid also failed, as
it was unclear that excess unemployment directly reflected the impact of
the recession on the state or local budget. Finally, the report found
that the program appeared to provide aid that was most closely related
to patterns of secular/structural decline. Areas of the country that
experienced relatively low growth rates prior to the recession received
disproportionate shares of aid. This was not the intent of the
legislation.
The report identified a basic tension in the legislation between
simply supporting the state and local government sector and anticipating
that aid to state and local governments would stimulate the economy. The
report had no direct findings on the degree to which the aid stimulated
the economy, but suggested that this should be considered in crafting
any future anti-recessionary response. (8)
In the CBO report, a key finding was that the intent of the federal
action needed to be explicit. There can be conflicting pressures when
programs are designed for both economic and fiscal stabilization. If the
goal is economic stabilization (and the federal government wants to use
states and localities as agents for distributing funds), the CBO
suggested that targeted grants would be the best form of aid, since
these can be earmarked for specific programs and populations that are in
need of economic stabilization due to a recession. A further advantage
is that targeted grants are less likely to serve as substitutes for
state and local revenues and cannot be used to rebuild state or local
surpluses. If the purpose is fiscal stabilization, unrestricted aid or
broad block grants are more effective, since they allow states to
maintain their aggregate spending level without (or with minimal) fiscal
adjustment. (9)
Federal response to the double-dip recession, 1980 and 1981-83
The 1980 recession lasted only six months and was marked by record
high interest rates and a spike in energy prices. This was followed by a
deeper, 16-month recession beginning in July of 1981, during which the
continued impact of high interest rates (peaking at 21.5 percent in June
1982) and high energy prices caused a spike in unemployment; the
national unemployment rate reached 10.8 percent in November and December
1982.
The federal response was along two dimensions. First, the Surface
Transportation Assistance Act was passed in 1983. This was forecasted to
create 320,000 jobs. The act also authorized up to six weeks of extended
unemployment insurance benefits. Second, the Emergency Jobs Act of 1983
was passed. This provided $9 billion for 77 different federal programs
designed to stimulate economic growth and job creation (U.S. General
Accounting Office, 1986).
Evaluating the effectiveness of the aid The GAO evaluated the
Emergency Jobs Act in December 1986. Their evaluation focused on: 1)
when funds were spent; 2) when and how many people were employed; 3) how
many unemployed persons were provided with jobs; 4) what efforts were
made to provide employment to the unemployed; and 5) what benefits,
other than employment, were provided.
The GAO found that the program was enacted faster than previous
countercyclical federal programs. The bill became law 21 months after
the beginning of the 1981 recession. The previous average for
congressional action was 27 months after the onset of a recession.
However, the GAO also found that funds from the act were spent slowly
and unevenly and relatively few jobs could be attributed to the program.
In all, the GAO estimated that by June of 1984 only 35,000 jobs could be
attributed directly to the act. Specifically the report states,
"... from its review of projects and available data, GAO found that
1) unemployed persons received a relatively small portion of the jobs
provided, and 2) project officials' efforts to provide employment
opportunities to the unemployed ranged from no effort being made to
working closely with state unemployment agencies to locate unemployed
persons" (U.S. General Accounting Office, 1986).
In conclusion, the GAO report suggested that future job creation
programs should emphasize channeling money to programs that are able to
spend money quickly and have projects available that can be implemented
immediately. Further, it recommended that agencies should be obligated
to spend funds within a specific period.
Federal response to the 1990-91 recession
The 1990-91 recession followed the savings and loan crisis of the
1980s. In addition, the first Gulf War and a spike in energy prices were
drags on the economy during this period. This recession was relatively
brief(eight months) and mild; GDP fell 1.3 percentage points from peak
to trough. The impact of this recession was felt mostly on the East and
West Coasts of the United States and, given its limited nature, no
significant anti-recessionary aid was offered beyond the usual programs
such as extensions in unemployment insurance. Congress also passed the
$151 billion Intermodal Surface Transportation Efficiency Act, which
helped serve as a stimulus for state and local transportation
infrastructure, but this was not a direct response to the recession. For
the most part, states drew on budget reserves and adjusted spending and
tax policies to fill gaps. State revenue growth slowed during this
period, but remained positive at 3.3 percent in fiscal year (FY) 1991
(U.S. Census Bureau, 1993).
Federal response to the 2001 recession
The 2001 recession reflected the bursting of the tech bubble and
the September 11 terrorist attacks. Like the 1990-91 recession, the 2001
downturn was relatively short and mild. The economy contracted by -0.5
percent in the first quarter and -1.4 percent in the third quarter.
Unemployment peaked at 6 percent after the recession ended in June 2003.
However, unlike the 1990-91 recession, this time state tax revenues
collapsed. In particular, states with high dependence on the income tax
found that collections turned highly volatile as the underlying tax base
became less predictable (see Mattoon and McGranahan, 2008). States
quickly exhausted any reserve funds and were reluctant to raise major
taxes. In addition, the labor market was slow to recover. States also
complained about increased spending that was required to meet new
security standards in the wake of the terrorist attacks. Given these
circumstances, states pressed for federal assistance. The federal
government responded with the Jobs and Growth Relief and Reconciliation
Act of 2003.
Evaluating the effectiveness of the aid
The GAO (2004) evaluated the effect of $10 billion in fiscal relief
that was provided to the states on a largely unrestricted basis in the
aftermath of the 2001-02 recession. The aid was provided in even $5
billion allotments for FY2003 and FY2004. The act was in response to a
slow labor market recovery from the recession and the unanticipated
sharp decline in state revenues that had left states with large
cumulative deficits (the National Conference of State Legislatures
estimated deficits at nearly $26 billion). The act authorized federal
funds to be used for "providing essential government services"
and to "cover the costs of complying with federal intergovernmental
mandate."
The GAO review looked at two areas:
* What is known about the potential impacts of unrestricted fiscal
relief on state fiscal behavior?
* How were the relief payments distributed among the states
relative to their fiscal circumstances?
According to state budget officials, how were the funds used? The
GAO study noted that while the funds were authorized 19 months after the
end of the recession, the slow recovery in labor markets and continuing
fiscal stress in the states made the timing of the aid a secondary
concern. From the outset, the funds did not appear to be particularly
targeted to reflect the relative fiscal or economic stress each state
was experiencing. The funding formula did not take into account the
impact of the recession, fiscal capacity, or the cost of expenditure
responsibilities in any individual state. Funds were allocated on a per
capita basis with an adjustment that provided a minimum payment for
smaller states.
The report found that by April 2004, the cumulative budget gap for
the states had fallen to $720 million from $21.5 billion the previous
year. States had closed the gap through a combination of using their own
reserve funds and the federal fiscal relief funds. The study also found
that it was hard to identify specifically where the federal dollars went
once they were commingled with state resources. The major criticism of
the program was that, with unrestricted funds, issues of timing and
targeting were all the more important. Since the unrestricted funds were
provided to all states, the potential existed for states with little
need to substitute the federal funds for their own revenues to lower
taxes, increase spending, or place funds into state reserves. None of
these actions would effectively stabilize state budgets. Of particular
concern was the potential for states to use the federal funds to avoid
prudent financial planning, such as building budget reserves in
anticipation of an economic downturn.
When examining the specific pattern of relief provided, the GAO
focused on the relationship between the per capita federal aid provided
and changes in each state's nonfarm employment and gross state
product (GSP). On the one hand, Wyoming, which had fared relatively well
in the recession--with a gain of more than 1 percent in nonfarm
employment and above the national average gross state product per
capita--received a much larger fiscal relief payment per capita than the
national average. On the other hand, Indiana, Michigan, and
Tennessee--with below national average GSP per capita and employment
losses ranging from 1.5 percent to nearly 2 percent--received slightly
less than the national average per capita fiscal relief. (10)
In conclusion, the GAO made two observations regarding the
effectiveness of the program:
* Fiscal relief payments arrived when the economy was already in
recovery (as measured by GDP growth). As such, the economic stimulus
value of the payments was doubtful.
* However, given that employment growth lagged the recovery, states
continued to see pressure on income and sales tax receipts, making the
aid important in helping to improve the fiscal stability of state
governments. However, the formula used to distribute funds was
relatively insensitive to the degree of economic stress individual
states were experiencing, which calls into question the targeting of the
funds.
A final caution issued by the GAO concerned the potential moral
hazard of federal intervention. If states believe that the federal
government will always intercede to provide countercyclical relief, they
will have little incentive to develop their own budgetary strategies to
address recessions. In particular, savings programs such as rainy day
funds may be severely undercapitalized.
Federal response to the 2007-09 recession
The most recent recession has been termed the worst since the Great
Depression of the 1930s. Both the depth and duration of the recession
have been notable, although GDP turned positive by the third quarter of
2009, possibly signaling the end of the cycle. For states and
localities, tax revenues have suffered broad declines. Total state tax
revenues turned negative in the fourth quarter of 2008 and remained
negative through the fourth quarter of 2009. For local governments,
property tax revenues have been falling as communities face a
combination of falling real estate prices and foreclosures. In
particular, localities that favored real estate transaction and
construction fees have found these revenue sources drying up in the
current cycle.
In response, the federal government passed the American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act of 2009. The package targets three areas. The first
is economic stimulus through $288 billion in tax cuts for individuals
and businesses. The second is fiscal stabilization through targeted
state programs of $224 billion for education, health care, and
unemployment insurance. The third component is infrastructure spending
targeted to job creation and investment in the form of $275 billion of
federal contracts, grants, and loans. The fiscal stabilization portion
of the aid package requires states to demonstrate a maintenance of
effort in health care and education programs to be eligible for the aid;
and the infrastructure funding is geared to "shovel ready"
projects that are past the planning stage and ready for construction.
Is there a better way?
In reviewing the recent history of countercyclical federal aid, it
is clear that the programs must balance many competing interests.
Regardless of the relative severity of the recession in a given state,
there is a desire to provide aid to all states rather than targeting aid
to those suffering the most. This is most likely a political necessity
needed to gain passage of an aid program. There is also a tension
between simply stabilizing the performance of the state and local sector
and providing stimulus to the national economy through infrastructure
and capital projects. Should the federal government attach strings to
the aid in an effort to redirect state fiscal policy? The intent of
countercyclical aid is often muddled and this makes evaluating its
effectiveness difficult.
Finally, the timing of the aid is almost always problematic. The
nature of the legislative process almost guarantees that the aid arrives
well after the recession's effects are being felt in a state. A key
question is whether providing aid earlier in the cycle might enable
states to adapt to recessions with less dislocation.
Defining criteria for distributing federal aid
If an aid program is primarily designed to counter downturns in the
business cycle, the ideal program might be one that is almost mechanical
in responding to business cycle movements. This would take the politics
out of constructing aid packages and also would help eliminate the
inevitable delay that occurs before Congress can act to authorize an aid
program. As the business cycle dips, a trigger could be switched on once
the decline reaches a designated point. Similarly, the trigger could be
switched off once recovery is under way. In other words, the trigger
would be timed to reflect the business cycle expansion and contraction.
Furthermore, aid should reflect the severity of the downturn in
each state. It would seem obvious that states bearing the brunt of the
recession should receive a larger share of aid than states that are less
severely affected. However, a complicating factor is that the aid needs
to be calibrated to only offset the cyclical stress of the recession. If
a state enters a recession with a structural deficit caused by inept
fiscal management, the federal aid should not act to make the state
whole. Given that moral hazard is a real concern with federal aid, then
ideally, federal aid should come with strings attached to encourage
states to plan better for future business cycle declines through their
own countercyclical measures (such as maintaining a rainy day fund).
Timing of aid
For federal countercyclical aid to be effective, it must be timed
to counter the economic effects associated with a decline in the
business cycle. This is easier said than done. Ideally, the aid should
start arriving to the states shortly after the peak in the cycle and be
discontinued either once a recovery has begun or when a recovery is
firmly established. In addition, there is the issue of whether the
amount of aid should be scaled to reflect the severity of the downturn.
Ideally, the level of aid would be recalibrated during each quarter to
reflect the cyclical stress being felt by the states; this is preferable
to the aid being distributed as a lump sum based on a one-time reading
of the states' economic condition.
Another issue with timing is recognizing the lags in distributing
the aid. Unless there is an automatic mechanism for triggering aid, the
first lag is often the time it takes to secure passage of an aid bill by
Congress. Consider the current circumstances: The National Bureau of
Economic Research (NBER) dates the current recession as having begun in
December 2007, and the aid package was enacted in February 2009. So,
nearly five quarters had passed before aid became available to the
states. The second lag is the time it takes for the federal government
to distribute the aid money to the states. Further, the states often
have to set up mechanisms for channeling the funds into the necessary
programs. All of this slows the process of spending the money during the
recession. In the GAO's assessment of the aid programs enacted in
response to the 1973-75 recession, it found that only 50 percent of the
federal money appropriated had actually been spent by the states even
after the recession ended. (11) The balance went either to build
surpluses or reduce the states' deficits. In the case of the Jobs
and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003, the first federal
funds were distributed 19 months after the end of the recession. (12)
An experiment based on three triggers
In this article, we use three different triggers for turning aid on
and off over the business cycle. Our goal in selecting the three
possible triggers was to find indicators that are both state specific
and reported on a timely basis. We selected the excess unemployment
rate, state sales tax revenues, and the Philadelphia Fed's state
coincident indexes. As our analysis shows, each trigger performs quite
differently over the business cycle.
Trigger 1: Excess unemployment rate
The excess unemployment rate has been used in the past and offers
several advantages. First, it is available on a reasonably timely basis
and can be reported at different geographic levels. The transparency of
the measure makes it easier to assess the relative stress that different
regions are facing and also allows for more precise targeting, since (in
theory) intra-state variation can be considered, allowing for specific
metropolitan aid strategies. A clear limitation of the unemployment rate
is that it can reflect structural change in the economy and, therefore,
tend to be higher in some regions and lower in others. As such it is not
necessarily a cyclical indicator. Also, unemployment is a lagging
indicator, meaning it follows the business cycle's direction with
some delay in both upturns and downturns. As a result, it is likely to
continue to trigger aid even when recovery is well under way. For this
article, the unemployment trigger that initiates the distribution of
funds will be an increase in the national unemployment rate from its
most recent trough of more than 1 percentage point. Aid will be turned
off when the national unemployment rate falls by at least 1 percentage
point. To ensure that funding reflects cyclicality, once the
unemployment trigger has begun the distribution of funds, the monthly
level of funds allocated to each state will depend on that state's
net increase in unemployment relative to its most recent trough.
Trigger 2: State sales tax revenues
The general sales tax is the first or second largest source of
general fund revenues in most states and is heavily relied upon for
funding expenditures. Therefore, a decline in sales tax revenues is
usually a harbinger of fiscal stress. Arguably, movements in sales tax
revenues are best able to track macroeconomic cycles and do not suffer
from the high volatility demonstrated in income tax revenues, where
factors such as capital gains and bonus income can distort the tax base.
In particular, since the sales tax reflects households' big ticket
expenditures, a downturn in the economy (particularly in housing or auto
sales) will be reflected in sales tax receipts. Finally, sales tax data
are available on a timely basis.
The disadvantage to sales tax receipts as an indicator is that
policy changes enacted by states can impact the sales tax base or rate.
For example, many states have gradually added services as taxable
activities. This has expanded the sales tax base, but the treatment of
services is hardly uniform from state to state. Similarly, states have
varying sales tax rates and often allow for local optional tax add-ons.
The fact that neither the rate nor base is static makes assessing how
much is raised in a given year somewhat harder. Ideally, you would want
to measure the natural rate of growth in a fixed sales tax base. In our
experiment, the sales tax trigger will turn on when the four-quarter
moving average of national sales tax revenues falls by 5 percent and
turn off when it returns to previous levels. Finally, there is also the
difficulty that some states do not have a general sales tax. Therefore,
the behavior of what for these states would be a hypothetical revenue
stream would have to be imputed. (We exclude the states without a sales
tax from our experiment.)
Trigger 3: Philadelphia Fed's state coincident indexes
The biggest advantage to the state coincident indexes is that they
provide a state-specific index reading for how each state responds to
the business cycle. As such, they allow for a measurement of variation
in state response that permits a better understanding of which states
are seeing the largest effects from the recession. In addition, the
indexes are available monthly, allowing for reasonably current analysis.
Also, since they are published for all 50 states, they allow for
transparency and offer a clear methodology that can be easily
understood. Specifically, the coincident indexes consist of four
state-level variables: nonfarm payroll employment, average hours worked
in manufacturing, the unemployment rate, and wage and salary
disbursements deflated by the consumer price index (U.S. city average).
The trend for each state's index is set to the trend of its gross
state product, so long-term growth in the state's index matches
long-term growth in its GSP. For this trigger in our experiment, a drop
of 0.1 percentage points in the month-over-month difference in the log
measure of the national index (which is a summary measure of all the
state indexes) will turn aid on and the return of the monthly change in
the national log measure to 0 will turn aid off.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Defining the experiment
The first stage of this experiment is to examine how the three
potential triggers behave over the business cycle. Specifically, how
long does it take for aid to be triggered after a recession is under
way, and when does the aid turn off when recovery is detected? The
second stage of the experiment concerns targeting of the aid. Using a
set of rules for how the aid is distributed based on state-specific
criteria, we distribute a hypothetical aid package. Then we evaluate the
level of aid received by each state. Figures 1, 2, and 3 demonstrate the
pattern of aid that each trigger would have produced from 1979 through
2009. In each figure, a period in which aid would have been dispersed is
indicated by a plateau in the "aid" line (the specific values
attained on the respective vertical axes by the aid lines are
meaningless). The vertical axis in each figure corresponds to the values
of its respective trigger. In the case of figure 3, the left axis
corresponds to the coincident index, and the right axis corresponds to
the differenced log coincident index.
As the figures demonstrate, both the unemployment rate trigger and
the sales tax trigger perform unpredictably. The unemployment rate
trigger appears to "turn on" in a relatively timely fashion
but given the significant lag in employment growth relative to overall
economic growth in the past several recessions, aid would have continued
flowing to the states well after these recessions were technically over.
While it would be possible to simply change the sensitivity of the
trigger so that it turns off with only a modest improvement in
unemployment, this might be difficult for political reasons because it
would mean ending aid to the states when high unemployment is still
present (and state safety net programs are under stress). Similarly, the
sales tax indicator shows idiosyncratic behavior. In the double-dip
recession of the early 1980s, aid would have turned on too early and
would have stayed on well past the turn in the cycle. In 1990, it turns
on and turns off after the recession ends; and in 2001, it turns on late
and then persists well into the recovery. In the current cycle, it turns
on a little early.
In terms of matching the business cycle, it is not surprising that
a business cycle indicator would do the best job of switching aid on and
off. From a purely technical view, a rule based on changes to the
Philadelphia Fed's state coincident indexes would switch aid on and
off based on cyclical movements in the economy. It would appear then
that this would be our winning candidate. States might argue that if
this trigger were used, they could be exposed to continuing fiscal
stress after the aid stopped due to lags in their expenditure cycles.
The argument for the use of such a trigger is that the goal of the aid
is only to maintain state spending during the contraction of the
business cycle.
Rules for distributing the aid
Once the trigger has been activated in our experiment, aid will be
distributed to reflect the severity of the downturn in the indicator for
each state. Specifically, states will be divided into quintiles each
period (either month or quarter, depending on the availability of data)
according to the change in their indicator relative to its most recent
peak or trough. Aid will then be allocated according to a set of rules
that rely on these quintile rankings. And if a state does not have a
change in its individual indicator to match that of the national
trigger, it will receive no aid.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The specific rules that govern the distribution of aid are designed
to satisfy three guidelines that we refer to as "equity
principles." Each of these equity principles is intended to prevent
allocations that would likely be regarded as unfair or unjust from the
perspective of the states. They are as follows: 1) during a given month,
all states in a given quintile should receive equal aid per capita; 2)
during a given month, states in higher quintiles should receive more aid
per capita than states in lower quintiles; and 3) within a given
quintile, aid per capita during earlier quarters of a recession should
meet or exceed aid per capita during later quarters.
One type of distribution plan that conforms to these equity
principles requires policymakers to first select a parameter, z, which
governs the size of the aid program. When the trigger deems necessary,
each state then receives aid per capita equal to the product of z and
two other constants. More specifically, let [x.sub.q] be the fraction of
$z in aid per capita allocated to states in quintile q = 1, 2, 3, 4, or
5 during an entire recession; and let [y.sub.r], be the fraction of this
aid allocated per capita to states during the rth quarter of aid
distribution. In other words, the [x.sub.q values determine the
distribution of aid per capita across quintiles, and the [y.sub.r]
values determine the distribution of aid across quarters. The only
restrictions on these variables are 0 [less than or equal to] =
[X.sub.q] < [X.sub.q+1] for all q and 0 [less than or equal to] =
[y.sub.r+1] < [y.sub.r] for all r, which must hold in order for the
distribution plan to satisfy the equity principles. Using this notation,
a state in quintile q during the rth quarter of aid distribution will
receive $[x.sub.q][y.sub.r]z of aid per capita, as long as it meets the
initial aid criteria; otherwise, it will not receive aid. In the
analysis that follows, the values we use for these variables are z =
$130, [x.sub.1] = 10%, [x.sub.2] = 15%, [x.sub.3] = 20%, [x.sub.4] =
25%, [x.sub.5] = 30%, [y.sub.1] = 30%, [y.sub.2] = 25%, [y.sub.3] = 20%,
[y.sub.4] = 15%, [y.sub.5] = 10%, and [y.sub.n] = 0 for all n > 5.
At this point, we must emphasize that this is a purely illustrative
distribution plan. Although it was designed to satisfy certain
constraints, its parameters are somewhat arbitrary, and there is surely
room for improvement. For example, it might well be the case that to
have the largest macro effect, the distribution of aid should be further
frontloaded to ensure that as much as possible is spent in the first two
quarters of a recession. Another important question (that we do not deal
with here) is what should be the size of the federal aid package? While
this proposal has the advantage of not distributing money to states that
do not need the money (making it possible for the aid package to
distribute less than what is originally appropriated), it does not offer
guidance on the size of the original appropriation. It is possible that
the package could be calibrated to some projection of aggregate state
deficits, but these numbers are notoriously volatile and often in
dispute. If the states are going to receive federal aid, then there is
little incentive for them to understate the size of a deficit. Ideally,
the size of the federal aid should only reflect the cyclically related
portion of state deficits and not structural imbalances that are
unrelated to a decline in the business cycle.
Attaching strings to the aid
Another possible modification to countercyclical aid is to limit
how much of the federal money is available in outright grants. We would
propose that some of the aid be reserved as loans that states would have
to repay once revenues are restored. This would help limit the moral
hazard problem of simply bailing out the states; and, like any loan
program, the terms could be constructed to reflect the specific
conditions of the borrower.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Aid projections based on triggers and formula allocation
Tables A1, A2, and A3 in the appendix show the quintile rankings
for all states across four different recessions based on our three
triggers--excess unemployment (table Al), sales tax revenues (table A2),
and the state coincident indexes (table A3). Unlike the other two
triggers, the state coincident indexes trigger treats the 1980-82
recession as two separate recessions, 1980 and 1982 (see figures 1-3).
The quintile assignment is based on the average quintile rank over the
cycle and, therefore, is simply an illustration of where the stationary
rank would fall if the entire recession were treated as one period. In
practice, what we propose is a system where the quintile ranks would be
recalibrated upon the release of new data, so that states could move up
and down rankings as conditions either improved or worsened. As such, a
state showing significant improvement might move down from the fifth
quintile (most in need of aid based on the indicator) to the first
quintile (least in need). Such a move would significantly reduce the
level of aid the state receives. What these tables illustrate is that
the group of states that would receive the largest share of aid
(quintile 5) would differ from recession to recession. For example, the
1980 and 1982 recessions had a more significant impact on manufacturing
states, while the 1991 recession had an East Coast/New England bias.
Due to the poor timing of the sales tax trigger (as shown in figure
2), we will focus this part of our experiment on the coincident index
and unemployment triggers. One way to compare the quintiles that these
two indicators generate is with scatter plots like those in figure 4.
The vertical axis in each chart corresponds to the average coincident
index quintile, and the horizontal axis gives the average unemployment
quintile. So each data point reveals the values of these two variables
for a given state during a given recession. The two charts depicted here
are of the 2001 (panel A) and 2008 (panel B) recessions. For the 2001
recession, the average quintiles for the two indicators have a
correlation coefficient of 0.6716; and for the 2008 recession, their
correlation coefficient is 0.6994. In other words, the quintile rankings
generated by the coincident index and unemployment indicators are
similar but not identical.
Since the quintile rankings of the various indicators often differ,
it is possible that one indicator may favor certain states over another,
which could have political repercussions. For example, if the
unemployment quintiles of a given state have been historically higher
than its coincident index quintiles, then we might expect the
state's legislators to push for the use of the unemployment
trigger. Table A4 lists the states in ascending order according to the
average ratio of their coincident index quintiles to their unemployment
quintiles. A value of less than one for this ratio indicates that the
state's unemployment quintiles were higher, on average, than its
coincident index quintiles; and a value of greater than one indicates
the reverse. So we might expect states with ratios significantly lower
than one to prefer the unemployment quintile because it would result in
more federal aid, and vice versa for states with ratios significantly
greater than one.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Distributing the aid
The results of a hypothetical implementation of our aid plan, with
z = $130, are displayed in figure 5. These charts contrast the amounts
of per capita aid that each state would have received under the
unemployment and coincident index triggers for the 2001 (panel A) and
2008 (panel B) recessions. The diagonal line in each chart is a 45
degree line, so states that fall below this line would have received
more aid per capita with the unemployment trigger than with the
coincident index trigger. This feature is most visible in the 2001
recession, reflecting the fact that the unemployment trigger was active
for a longer period than the coincident index trigger.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Conclusion
This article examines the use of three automatic triggers for
starting and stopping countercyclical aid to state governments during a
recession. While none of the triggers is perfect, it appears that the
Philadelphia Fed's state coincident indexes would do a better job
of timing aid to reflect both the local intensity of the business cycle
in individual states and the duration of the recession on a national
level. The use of such a trigger would ensure that the aid is designed
to reduce the stress related to the business cycle and not the stress
caused by structural imbalances in a state's economy or fiscal
system.
What this article does not address is whether there should be a
standing federal policy of providing recessionary aid to the states. The
use of any automatic stabilizing policy assumes that maintaining state
government programs should be a primary concern of federal policy. While
the current structure allows for an arbitrary decision as to when the
federal government does intervene, creating a federal insurance policy
for state fiscal behavior clearly would raise some concerns. Some might
argue that periodic budget crises may be necessary to force states to
re-examine their spending priorities and bring them in line with what
taxpayers are willing to pay. It may be possible to address the possible
moral hazard concerns by creating additional mechanisms that would
prevent states from undertaking risky budget behavior or punish them for
doing so. For example, more robust rainy day funds might be required or
a "stress test" for each state's budget under different
economic scenarios. Similarly, it might be wise to require states to pay
into a national rainy day fund, thereby creating their own insurance
system so they could self-fund countercyclical aid without relying on
federal assistance (see Mattoon, 2003).
A related issue is a closer examination of the efficiency with
which states might spend recessionary aid. States will always prefer
unrestricted aid that permits them to substitute new federal dollars for
state dollars, but should federal aid come with strings attached?
Further, is the state the proper recipient of the money? State funding
formulas are often criticized for distributing aid to less populated
areas, whereas money directed to large metropolitan areas might have a
greater impact. Should the federal government take a larger role in
targeting the aid to promote the efficiency of aid spending?
Finally, further research is needed to examine whether the state
fiscal cycle is significantly different from the business cycle. If it
is likely that there are lags in which states experience fiscal pressure
both entering and exiting a business cycle downturn, the timing of aid
might need to be adjusted to reflect this. This might favor a trigger
that starts aid several quarters after a national recession begins and
extends aid past the end of the recession.
APPENDIX: STATE RANKINGS BASED ON OUR THREE TRIGGERS
TABLE A1
Ranking of states' need for aid based on unemployment
rate trigger
Quintile 1
(lowest need) Quintile 2 Quintile 3
1981-83 recession
Delaware Rhode Island Idaho
Hawaii Connecticut Louisiana
New York New Mexico Kansas
Florida Maryland Vermont
New Jersey Maine South Dakota
Massachusetts Oklahoma Nebraska
Virginia Montana New Hampshire
California Pennsylvania Colorado
Texas Georgia Arizona
Alaska North Dakota Tennessee
1991 recession
South Dakota North Dakota Illinois
Montana Alabama Missouri
Utah New Mexico Washington
Georgia Arkansas Ohio
Iowa Idaho Tennessee
Nebraska Texas Oregon
Colorado Oklahoma Wisconsin
Wyoming Arizona Nevada
Hawaii Minnesota Alaska
Kansas Indiana Kentucky
2001 recession
Idaho South Dakota Tennessee
Montana Arkansas Kansas
New Mexico Georgia Nevada
West Virginia Iowa Alabama
North Dakota Maryland Mississippi
Rhode Island Maine Vermont
Delaware Louisiana Kentucky
Wyoming Nebraska Florida
Alaska Pennsylvania New Hampshire
Hawaii Ohio Texas
2008 recession
North Dakota Oklahoma Maine
South Dakota Texas Pennsylvania
Arkansas Kansas Washington
Nebraska Utah Mississippi
New Hampshire New Mexico New Jersey
Wisconsin Massachusetts Oregon
Iowa Maryland Delaware
Wyoming Montana Kentucky
West Virginia NewYork Virginia
Alaska Louisiana Missouri
Quintile 5
Quintile 4 (highest need)
1981-83 recession
Washington Utah
Iowa Kentucky
Minnesota Mississippi
Arkansas Illinois
Nevada Ohio
North Carolina Indiana
Wyoming Michigan
Alabama Missouri
Oregon Wisconsin
South Carolina West Virginia
1991 recession
Louisiana Maryland
Mississippi Delaware
South Carolina Connecticut
Virginia Massachusetts
Florida Maine
Pennsylvania New Hampshire
North Carolina New Jersey
Michigan New York
California Rhode Island
West Virginia Vermont
2001 recession
Connecticut Wisconsin
NewYork Oregon
California Utah
Minnesota Indiana
Oklahoma Colorado
Arizona Michigan
Virginia Missouri
New Jersey North Carolina
Illinois South Carolina
Massachusetts Washington
2008 recession
Ohio Minnesota
South Carolina Georgia
Colorado North Carolina
Vermont Tennessee
Alabama Illinois
Arizona Michigan
Indiana California
Idaho Florida
Connecticut Nevada
Hawaii Rhode Island
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from
the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics provided by
Haver Analytics.
TABLE A2
Ranking of states' need for aid based on sales tax rate trigger
Quintile 1
(lowest need) Quintile 2 Quintile 3
1981-83 recession
Texas North Dakota Hawaii
Oklahoma New Mexico Iowa
Maine Arizona Nevada
Connecticut Louisiana South Carolina
Idaho Mississippi Virginia
South Dakota Nebraska New Jersey
Utah Rhode Island Florida
Vermont Arkansas Kansas
Minnesota Georgia North Carolina
1991 recession
Kentucky Iowa Texas
Arkansas Idaho Vermont
North Carolina Kansas Hawaii
Virginia Maine Illinois
Washington Minnesota Oklahoma
New Mexico Nebraska Pennsylvania
Arizona New Jersey South Dakota
Alabama Nevada North Dakota
California Tennessee Utah
2001 recession
Rhode Island Wyoming Pennsylvania
Arkansas Kansas Wisconsin
Arizona North Carolina Colorado
Idaho Mississippi Virginia
New Jersey North Dakota Alabama
Nebraska Oklahoma Illinois
South Dakota Hawaii Maine
Vermont Iowa Maryland
West Virginia Louisiana Michigan
2008 recession
North Dakota Utah Mississippi
Oklahoma Alabama North Carolina
South Dakota Indiana Virginia
Wyoming Maine Colorado
Idaho Kansas Nebraska
Vermont West Virginia Tennessee
Rhode Island Arkansas Louisiana
Texas Washington New Jersey
Hawaii Maryland Nevada
Quintile 5
Quintile 4 (highest need)
1981-83 recession
Wyoming Missouri
West Virginia Maryland
California Washington
Ohio New York
Tennessee Kentucky
Alabama Pennsylvania
Colorado Massachusetts
Michigan Illinois
Wisconsin Indiana
1991 recession
Wyoming Colorado
Florida Georgia
Indiana Ohio
Louisiana Maryland
Michigan New York
Missouri South Carolina
Mississippi Connecticut
Rhode Island Massachusetts
Wisconsin West Virginia
2001 recession
Nevada New Mexico
Massachusetts Ohio
Missouri Connecticut
Tennessee Washington
Texas Kentucky
New York Florida
South Carolina Utah
Georgia California
Indiana Minnesota
2008 recession
Iowa Massachusetts
New Mexico Michigan
South Carolina Connecticut
Arizona Pennsylvania
Kentucky California
Missouri Florida
Wisconsin Minnesota
Georgia New York
Illinois Ohio
Note: States that do not have a sales tax were excluded from the
analysis. As a result, each quintile in this table lists nine
states instead of ten.
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau
of the Census provided by Haver Analytics.
TABLE A3
Ranking of states' need for aid based on Philadelphia
Fed state coincident indexes trigger
Quintile 1
(lowest need) Quintile 2 Quintile 3
1980 recession
Colorado Connecticut North Carolina
Florida Arizona Maryland
Hawaii Delaware Maine
Louisiana Georgia Mississippi
New Hampshire Massachusetts North Dakota
Oklahoma New Jersey Rhode Island
Texas Nevada South Carolina
Virginia New York Tennessee
Wyoming Utah Vermont
California New Mexico Alaska
1982 recession
Alaska New Mexico Louisiana
Connecticut New York Maine
Florida Delaware Hawaii
New Hampshire Massachusetts Rhode Island
Utah California Tennessee
Georgia Arizona Wyoming
Colorado North Dakota South Carolina
New Jersey Oklahoma Wisconsin
Virginia Vermont Maryland
Texas North Carolina Mississippi
1991 recession
Arkansas New Mexico Nevada
Arizona Oklahoma California
Colorado South Dakota Alabama
Hawaii Tennessee Delaware
Iowa Texas Florida
Idaho Utah Georgia
Louisiana Wisconsin Illinois
Montana Kansas Indiana
North Dakota Mississippi Kentucky
Nebraska Minnesota Virginia
2001 recession
Alaska Maine Connecticut
Montana Nebraska Virginia
North Dakota Florida California
New Mexico Arizona Arkansas
Rhode Island Idaho Hawaii
South Dakota Louisiana Iowa
Wyoming Utah New Hampshire
Maryland Vermont Oklahoma
New Jersey Delaware Texas
West Virginia Kansas Wisconsin
2008 recession
Alaska Utah Arkansas
Louisiana Virginia Connecticut
North Dakota Wisconsin New York
Nebraska Iowa California
Oklahoma Kansas Indiana
Texas New Hampshire Missouri
Wyoming South Dakota New Jersey
New Mexico Massachusetts Tennessee
West Virginia Mississippi Hawaii
Colorado Montana Illinois
Quintile 5
Quintile 4 (highest need)
1980 recession
Alabama Idaho
Arkansas Indiana
Iowa Kentucky
Illinois Michigan
Kansas Missouri
Minnesota Montana
Nebraska Ohio
South Dakota Oregon
Wisconsin Pennsylvania
Washington West Virginia
1982 recession
Nebraska Idaho
Nevada Indiana
Kansas Pennsylvania
Arkansas Iowa
South Dakota Michigan
Alabama Montana
Kentucky Ohio
Minnesota Oregon
Missouri Washington
Illinois West Virginia
1991 recession
Missouri Michigan
North Carolina Pennsylvania
New Jersey Alaska
Ohio Connecticut
Oregon Massachusetts
South Carolina Maryland
Washington Maine
West Virginia New Hampshire
New York Rhode Island
Wyoming Vermont
2001 recession
Georgia Massachusetts
Illinois North Carolina
Kentucky Nevada
Minnesota Alabama
Mississippi Indiana
Ohio Michigan
Tennessee New York
Pennsylvania Oregon
Colorado South Carolina
Missouri Washington
2008 recession
North Carolina Rhode Island
Vermont Arizona
Minnesota Delaware
Alabama Florida
Georgia Idaho
Kentucky Michigan
Maryland Nevada
Maine Oregon
Pennsylvania South Carolina
Ohio Washington
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia provided by Haver Analytics.
TABLE A4
Average ratio of state coincident index to unemployment
State Quintile State Quintile
ratio ratio
Louisiana 0.60 Kentucky 1.07
Virginia 0.74 Nebraska 1.08
Oklahoma 0.80 New Hampshire 1.08
California 0.81 North Dakota 1.09
Wisconsin 0.82 Maine 1.09
North Carolina 0.82 West Virginia 1.12
Mississippi 0.83 Maryland 1.13
Texas 0.84 Oregon 1.17
Florida 0.86 Alaska 1.19
New Mexico 0.87 Massachusetts 1.21
Vermont 0.87 Alabama 1.27
Colorado 0.88 New York 1.30
Utah 0.90 South Dakota 1.30
Connecticut 0.90 Rhode Island 1.31
Indiana 0.92 Hawaii 1.35
Arizona 0.93 Ohio 1.37
New Jersey 0.94 Washington 1.37
Minnesota 0.94 Wyoming 1.42
Illinois 0.95 Georgia 1.43
Missouri 0.97 Montana 1.48
Tennessee 0.99 Idaho 1.54
South Carolina 1.01 Arkansas 1.57
Nevada 1.02 Delaware 1.62
Michigan 1.03 Iowa 1.63
Kansas 1.04 Pennsylvania 1.67
Note: A value less than 1.0 indicates that the state's
unemployment quintiles were higher, on average, than its
coincident index quintiles; a value greater than 1.0 indicates
the reverse.
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia provided by Haver Analytics.
REFERENCES
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, 1978,
"Countercyclical aid and economic stabilization," report,
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, No. A-69, December,
available at www.library.unt.edu/gpo/acir/Reports/policy/A-69.pdf.
Amadeo, Kimberly, 2010, "The history of recessions in the
United States," About.com: US Economy, January 23, available at
http://useconomy.about.com/od/
grossdomesticproduct/a/recession_histo.htm.
American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, available at
www.recovery.gov/About/Pages/ The_Act.aspx.
Congressional Budget Office, 1978, "Countercyclical uses of
federal grant programs," background paper, Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office, November, available at
www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/92xx/ doc9257/78-cbo-046.pdf.
Gill, Kathy, "Recessions and politics: Federal government
action in economic crisis," About.com: US Politics, available at
http://uspolitics.about.com/od/economy/ tp/recessions_and_politics.htm.
Mattoon, Richard H., 2003, "Creating a national rainy day
fund: A modest proposal to improve future state fiscal
performance," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No.
WP-2003-20, November, available at
www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/ working_papers/2003/wp_20.cfm.
Mattoon, Richard H. and Leslie McGranahan, 2008, "Revenue
bubbles and structural deficits: What's a state to do?,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No. WP-2008-15, July,
available at www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/
working_papers/2008/wp_l5.cfm.
U.S. Census Bureau, 1993, "Recessions matter for state tax
collections," statistical brief, No. SB/93-11, July, available at
www.census.gov/apsd/www/statbrief/sb93_11.pdf.
U.S. General Accounting Office, 2004, "Federal assistance:
Temporary state fiscal relief," report, No. GAO-04-736R,
Washington, DC, May 7, pp. 2-7, available at
www.gao.gov/products/GAO-04-736R.
--, 1986, "Emergency Jobs Act of 1983: Funds spent slowly, few
jobs created," report, No. HRD-87-1, Washington, DC, December,
available at http://archive.gao.gov/f0102/132063.pdf.
--, 1977, "Antirecession assistance: An evaluation,"
report, No. PAD-78-20, Washington, DC, November 29, pp. 6-7, available
at www.gao. gov/products/PAD-78-20.
NOTES
(1) The breakdown for expenditures related tn the American Recovery
and Reinvestment Act of 2009 is: $288 billion in tax cuts for
individuals and businesses; $224 billion for education, health care, and
unemployment insurance; and $275 billion for federal contracts, grants,
and loans. See www.recovery.gov/About/Pages/The_Act.aspx.
(2) The business cycle refers to the periodic but irregular
up-and-down movements in economic activity, measured by fluctuations in
real gross domestic product and other macroeconomic variables.
Countercyclical aid, provided by the federal government, is intended to
smooth revenue contractions and expenditure increases that are
associated with business cycle declines
(3) The ARRA differs from previous aid programs in that its stated
goals emphasize economic stimulus and job creation, even though most of
the money going to the states will go toward stabilizing Medicaid,
education, and unemployment insurance. Specifically, the act's
three immediate goals are to: 1) create new jobs and save existing ones;
2) spur economic activity and invest in long-term economic growth; and
3) foster unprecedented levels of accountability and transparency in
government spending. See www, recovery.gov/About/Pages/ The_Act.aspx
(4) Throughout this article, we refer to official periods of
recession as identified by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
(5) Amadeo (2010).
(6) Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (1978).
(7) US. General Accounting Office (1977), p. i
(8) Ibid, p. 19.
(9) Congressional Budget Office (1978), p. 60
(10) U.S General Accounting Office (2004), p. 7
(11) U S. Government Accounting Office (1977), pp. 6-7.
(12) U.S. Government Accounting Office (2004), p. 2.
Richard H. Mattoon is a senior economist and economic advisor,
Vanessa Haleco-Meyer was a senior associate economist and is currently a
technology applications and programming analyst, and Taft Foster is an
associate economist in the Economic Research Department of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank Leslie McGranahan and Lisa
Barrow for their helpful comments on previous drafts.