What is the relationship between large deficits and inflation in industrialized countries?
Bassetto, Marco ; Butters, R. Andrew
Introduction and summary
In the aftermath of the recent financial crisis, the U.S.
government ran a deficit of 9.9 percent of gross domestic product (GDP)
in 2009--an unprecedented level during peacetime. Figure 1 shows the
United States' deficit experience since World War II. Because U.S.
history does not provide us with a guide for how fiscal balance will be
restored, we look at the experiences of other countries that have faced
similar budget shortfalls. In our investigation, we restrict our
attention to industrialized countries since 1970. We do this because of
the availability and quality of data published on these countries. Also,
the institutions and economic fabric of these countries are closest to
those of the United States, so their experiences are more likely to be
informative for our current situation.
In this article, we address the following questions: Is there
evidence of a relationship between high deficits and inflation? And how
was fiscal balance restored in industrialized countries that experienced
large deficits? Did governments do this primarily by restoring fiscal
discipline, by defaulting on debt, or by devaluing debt by means of high
inflation?
In the next two sections, we explain the intuition and then review
empirical evidence concerning the first question. Deficits and inflation
are mechanically linked because inflation causes higher nominal interest
payments and thus swells public spending. However, as we explain in box
l (p. 85), these large interest payments simply cover the depreciation
in the real value of debt and do not increase the real burden of debt.
After appropriately accounting for these interest payments, we find that
large deficits are not associated with higher inflation
contemporaneously, nor are they associated with the emergence of higher
inflation in subsequent years. This finding should not necessarily be
interpreted as implying that high deficits never cause inflation;
rather, it is likely that the countries that can afford large deficits
have built solid reputations and institutions that support a sound
monetary policy and the reversion to a stable fiscal regime.
Having shown that inflation does not appear to be the universal
outcome of large fiscal deficits in our main sample, we examine the
specific experiences of three countries that ran among the largest
public deficits on record while retaining low inflation: Finland and
Sweden in the early 1990s and Japan in the 1990s and 2000s. In the case
of Finland and Sweden, the fiscal imbalance was short-lived; after a
large but brief rise, the level of public debt returned to a sustainable
path, thanks to fiscal surpluses and healthy macroeconomic growth. In
Japan, public deficits were much more persistent, partly as a result of
economic stagnation. Consequently, public debt there has continued to
increase over the past 20 years, and a full resolution of fiscal
imbalances has yet to occur.
One commonality of the Finnish, Swedish, and Japanese experiences
is that each nation's large deficits were the consequence of a
banking crisis and the ensuing recession--this is analogous to the
current U.S. experience. Our analysis complements Reinhart and
Rogoff's (2008a, 2008b, 2009) broader and more systematic work,
which specifically looks at the onsets and aftermaths of financial
crises across the world. Reinhart and Rogoff pay particular attention to
macroeconomic performance and fiscal policy; our findings confirm
Reinhart and Rogoff's (2009) conclusion that banking
crises are associated with large jumps in public indebtedness. In
this article, our focus is on the consequences of these episodes for
inflation and monetary policy.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Theoretical background on deficits and inflation
To establish our framework for examining the link between large
deficits and higher inflation, we start by looking at a simple version
of the government budget constraint relating nominal government debt to
government surplus:
1) [B.sub.t] = (1 + [i.sub.t])[B.sub.t-1] + [P.sub.t]([G.sub.t] -
[T.sub.t])- [S.sub.t],
where [B.sub.t] is the nominal value of government debt in year t,
i is the nominal rate of return on government debt, [P.sub.t] is the
price index, [G.sub.t] is real government expenditure (including
transfers, but excluding interest payments on debt), [T.sub.t] is real
tax revenues, and [S.sub.t] is seigniorage (that is, central bank
profits remitted to the treasury). (1)
Since we will concentrate on the experience of low-inflation
countries, S will not play a significant role in our analysis.
Nonetheless, we include it explicitly because it has been emphasized by
much of the prior research on the connections between inflation and
budget deficits. King and Plosser (1985) discuss several different
measures of seigniorage and show their similarities and differences in
the case of the United States. The measure we adopt here starts from a
simple version of the central bank's balance sheet: On the
liability side is the monetary base, made up of cash and bank reserves;
(2) and on the asset side are bonds, paying the nominal interest rate
[i.sub.t]. If no interest is paid on bank reserves, the central
bank's profits are then given by [S.sub.t] = [i.sub.t] [M.sub.t],
where [M.sub.t], is the monetary base.
Equation 1 describes the evolution of public debt from one year to
the next in nominal terms. Growth in debt need not lead to fiscal
imbalances if it is purely driven by inflation or if it is matched by
growth in the real economy that supports debt repayments. We thus
rescale the equation by (nominal) GDP.
2) [B.sub.t]/[P.sub.t][Y.sub.t] = 1 + [i.sub.i]/(1 +
[[pi].sub.t])(1 + [g.sub.t) [B.sub.t-1]/[P.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t-1] +
[G.sub.t] - [T.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t] - [i.sub.t][M.sub.t]/[P.sub.t][Y.sub.t],
where [Y.sub.t] is real GDP, [[pi].sub.t], = [P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1] - 1
is inflation, and [g.sub.t] = [Y.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t-1] - 1 is the real
growth rate of the economy.
We make explicit the link between nominal interest rates and
inflation by writing
3) 1 + [i.sub.t] = (1 + [r.sup.e.sub.t])(1 + [[pi].sup.e.sub.t])
[??] [i.sub.t] [approximately equal to] [r.sup.e.sub.t] +
[[pi].sup.e.sub.t].
Equation 3 states that the nominal interest rate is approximately
the sum of the real rate of return that savers expect to obtain from
bonds ([r.sup.e.sub.t]) and their expectations about inflation. (3) We
substitute equation 3 into equation 2 and obtain
4) [B.sub.t]/[P.sub.t][Y.sub.t] = (1 + [r.sup.e.sub.t])(1 +
[[pi].sup.e.sub.t])/(1 + [[pi].sub.t])(1 + [g.sub.t])
[B.sub.t-1]/[P.sub.t-1][Y.sub.t-1] + [G.sub.t]-[T.sub.t]/[Y.sub.t] -
([r.sup.e.sub.t] + [[pi].sup.e.sub.t])[M.sub.t]/[P.sub.t][Y.sub.t].
According to equation 4, the following five factors would shrink
the debt/GDP ratio (or increase it if reversed).
* High primary surplus relative to GDP? Like any other debtor in
the economy, the government can reduce its debt by spending less than
its revenues.
* Increased seigniorage: When expected and realized inflation
coincide ([[pi].sup.e.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.t), high inflation increases
seigniorage and reduces debt. This source of funds has been important
for many developing countries that have experienced high inflation. As
an example, Sargent, Williams, and Zha (2009) report that seigniorage
frequently raised revenues of more than 5 percent of GDP for Argentina
and Brazil during their high-inflation years, with occasional higher
spikes. In the case of low-inflation economies, however, this number is
always very small. In the case of the United States, seigniorage
revenues averaged 0.36 percent of GDP between 1959 and 2009, and were
never more than 0.8 percent, even in the 1970s, when inflation was
relatively high? Any link between deficits and inflation that concerns
us will thus come from a different channel.
* High unexpected inflation: When unexpected inflation comes, it
reduces the real value of previously issued debt. Unexpected inflation
acts thus as a hidden default on debtors' obligations. A government
dealing with larger deficits faces a greater incentive to lean on the
central bank and encourage higher inflation to alleviate its fiscal
imbalance. This is a well-known source of the time inconsistency of
monetary policy: (6) Once the private sector's expectations are
locked into the nominal interest rate, any movement in inflation becomes
"unexpected," and the temptation to "inflate debt
away" emerges. In our simple version of the budget constraint,
inflation expectations are locked in for a single year, since all debt
matures at the end of the year. However, in reality government debt has
a longer average maturity; for example, the current average maturity of
U.S. debt is 54 months. (7) This gives extra time for inflation to act,
and correspondingly increases the temptation for a government to inflate
its debt away. (8)
* A smaller real interest rate: The debt/GDP ratio decreases (or
increases more slowly) if lenders require a smaller real interest rate.
To the extent that government debt crowds out private investment, we
would expect higher debt/GDP ratios to put upward pressure on the real
interest rate. However, large deficits may be associated with other
circumstances that lower the real interest rate paid by the government.
For instance, the recent financial market turmoil has led to a
"flight to quality" that has greatly reduced yields on
government bonds while sharply increasing rates for less creditworthy
borrowers. The government may also be tempted to use capital taxes,
capital controls, or other direct measures to divert credit away from
private markets and toward its own needs. A prominent recent example was
the Argentinian government's takeover of private pension plans. (9)
For the United States after World War II, Berndt, Lustig, and Yeltekin
(2010) find that real interest rates decrease after a negative fiscal
shock, hedging 7.8 percent of the risk stemming from these shocks.
* High real economic growth: Growth spreads the burden of debt onto
a bigger productive base. In most economic models of a closed economy,
high growth is associated with high real interest rates, and no direct
fiscal benefit would ensue from such growth. However, empirically, the
link between growth and interest rates is not as strict, and this is
particularly true in an open economy, where interest rates are also
affected by the saving decisions of foreigners. (10)
BOX 1
Adjusting deficits to distinguish between nominal and real interest
payments
To understand the importance of adjusting the deficit measure, we
start with equation 1 (p. 84). In that equation, net lending
is--([B.sub.t]--[B.sub.t-1]). As the equation shows, nominal
interest payments by the government ([i.sub.t]--[B.sub.t-1])
contribute to the deficit, since the government's balance sheet
counts them as expenses. However, the balance sheet does not take
into account that in the presence of inflation, the real value of
nominal debt is reduced. In nominal terms, investors lent
[B.sub.t-1] to the government in period t--1 and receive (1 +
[i.sub.t])[B.sub.t-1] in period t. However, in real terms, the
resources lent by the investors are [B.sub.t-1]/[P.sub.t-1] and the
resources received are
B1) [B.sub.t-1](1 + [i.sub.t])/[P.sub.t] = [B.sub.t-1](1 +
[i.sub.t])/[P.sub.t-1 (1 + [[phi].sub.t]) [approximately equal to]
[B.sub.t-1]/[P.sub.t-1] (1 + [i.sub.t])/[[pi].sub.t],
where the last approximation is accurate when inflation is small.
Equation B1 suggests that the true interest cost to the government
is only approximately [i.sub.t]--[[pi].sub.t]. Accordingly, from
now on we correct the deficit according to the following
definition:
B2) Corrected [deficit.sub.t] = [B.sub.t]--(1 + [[pi].sub.t])
[B.sub.t-1].
Equation B2 would be the precise correction if all government
assets and liabilities were nominal and all debt lasted one period.
In practice, the precise correction should take into account the
following complications.
* Governments issue long-term, as well as short-term debt. The real
value of long-term debt fluctuates not just because of inflation,
but also because of changes in future interest rates. The future
rate may fluctuate both because expectations about future inflation
may change and because real interest rates may vary.
* Some governments issue debt indexed to inflation, or some issue
debt denominated in a foreign currency. In this case, the real
value of debt will be preserved even if interest payments do not
track domestic inflation, and a correction based on domestic
inflation would be inappropriate.
* An important distinction arises between gross and net government
liabilities. One particularly stark example is Norway, which issues
some government debt and thus has some nominal liabilities that are
subject to erosion; at the same time, its Government Pension Fund
uses oil revenues to purchase a very large amount of assets. When
government assets are stakes in real companies (or are invested
abroad), correcting for domestic inflation should be done only on
the liability side, since the real value of a company will not be
affected by inflation. However, in some cases, large nominal assets
may also be relevant. In Japan, a large fraction of government
liabilities are held by other government entities, such as public
financial institutions and social security funds.
In this article, we ignore the first two factors. For our main
sample, based on Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) countries, this does not constitute a large
problem, since most borrowing undertaken by these countries is
nominal. The larger sample from International Monetary Fund
statistics does include countries whose borrowing is primarily
indexed to prices or foreign exchange rates. As was the case for
Catao and Terrones (2005), a deficit correction is impossible in
the larger sample because we lack data on the stock of government
liabilities ([B.sub.t-1] in equations B1 and B2). Hall and Sargent
(1997, 2010) use detailed information about individual government
securities to compute the value of government debt at each point in
time in the United States since World War II. Their exercise
provides a much more accurate account of the factors that drove the
evolution of U.S. government debt. Unfortunately, a similar
exercise is not available for other countries. Over short horizons,
the Hall-Sargent measure of deficits is much more volatile than the
one adopted here, and is mainly driven by changes in interest
rates. At longer horizons, however, the two measures are more
similar.
We deal with the third factor by conservatively assuming that
government assets are nominal, and we thus compute the inflation
correction based on net government financial liabilities. Figures
based on correcting deficits based on gross liabilities would
strengthen our conclusion--that deficits are not associated with
higher inflation in our OECD sample; in fact, the opposite
relationship would emerge--that is. countries with higher deficits
(after the correction) would tend to have lower inflation.
Equation 4 does not explicitly allow for a reduction in debt
through default; this is not an important omission, since we are mainly
interested in the experience of countries that experienced high deficits
and low inflation (none of them having defaulted on their debt).
Nonetheless, an implicit default is allowed by equation 4, in the form
of a capital levy on holders of government debt that would be counted
among the tax revenues.
The empirical link between deficits and inflation
In the previous section, we noted that engineering higher inflation
is a temptation for governments facing fiscal imbalances, since it
devalues previously issued debt. In this section, we explore the
relationship between deficits and inflation in the data.
A very large literature on this topic already exists. Sargent
(1982, 1983) finds evidence of a strong link between deficits and
inflation in several European countries in the aftermath of World War I.
Furthermore, inflation was brought under control in these countries only
when fiscal reforms placed government finances on sound footing. While
there is widespread consensus that hyperinflations are caused by fiscal
imbalances, (11) at more-moderate inflations the evidence of a link is
murkier. The case of France in the 1920s analyzed by Sargent (1983) is
not as typical of the post-World War II experience.
Rather than looking at inflation, several researchers have studied
the link between money creation and deficits. For the United States
after World War II, Hamburger and Zwick (1981) find that monetary growth
is influenced by deficits, but only in specific episodes. Likewise, King
and Plosser 0985) show that whether deficits can predict monetary growth
depends on what other variables are used in the forecasting exercise;
they conclude that there is no evidence of a link between monetary
growth and deficits in the United States. King and Plosser also extend
the analysis to 11 other countries and again find no evidence of a link
between deficits and seigniorage.
Catao and Terrones (2005) expand the analysis of inflation and
deficits to a very large number of countries by relying on the
International Monetary Fund's (IMF) International Financial
Statistics. They also allow for a richer dynamic specification of the
inflation process and test whether there is a long-run relationship
between deficits and inflation. They do find such a link: Specifically,
when deficits are rescaled by GDP, a 1 percent increase in the
deficit/GDP measure is associated with about 5 percent extra inflation.
(12) However, even in their paper, no such evidence is found among
advanced economies with low inflation. Furthermore, data limitations do
not allow them to correct deficits to properly account for real interest
payments on debt.
In this article, we take the view that an economy with inflation is
like a person with a fever: The fever tells you something is wrong, but
it can have many causes. (13) The question we address is whether high
deficits are one of the conditions that is invariably associated with
inflation. To answer this question, we work mostly in reverse, looking
at low-inflation countries and checking whether their fiscal house is
always in order.
In figure 2, panel A, we look at the relationship between
government surplus as a fraction of GDP (more formally, net lending as a
fraction of GDP) and inflation, as measured by the consumer price index
(CPI), in our main sample. This sample consists of data for countries in
the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD),
excluding Mexico, Turkey, and some other ex-communist countries, over
the period 1970-2008 (for details, see the appendix). The marks in panel
A of figure 2 represent the inflation--surplus pairs for all the
countries in each year of available data. To gain a better understanding
of the pattern, we sort all observations by their inflation level and
divide them into ten bins. Within each bin, we then compute the median,
represented by the black line, and the 5th and 10th percentiles,
represented by the two red lines. (14) While the median shows little, if
any relationship between surpluses and inflation, the two red lines
suggest a negative relationship: It appears that, at high deficit levels
(very negative surpluses), further increases in deficits are associated
with higher inflation.
Figure 2, panel B shows a similar pattern for a broader set of
countries--52 countries from the IMF's International Financial
Statistics (15) (see the appendix for details). Panels A and B of figure
2 paint a misleading picture of the true economic relationship between
deficits and inflation. The nominal deficit measure adopted in these
panels shows the change in nominal debt. In the presence of inflation,
nominal interest payments may be high and swell the nominal deficit
measure, even though the real cost of servicing the debt is not
particularly high, as shown by equation 3. This generates a mechanical
link between inflation and deficits that is not related to the
underlying economic situation. A more accurate description of the fiscal
burden left to repay is the change in real debt. Therefore, we exclude
the part of the nominal interest payments that compensates investors for
the erosion of the real value of debt that comes from inflation.
From now on, we focus on our main sample, which uses data on OECD
countries. Figure 2, panel C shows how the relationship changes after
the surplus measure is corrected. Here, we observe no relationship
between surpluses and inflation. Table 1 presents the same evidence
through the lens of a parametric statistical model. Specifically, we
regress the surplus in country i and in year t (measured in percentage
points of GDP) on CPI inflation (measured in percentage points):
5) [surplus.sub.it] = [alpha] + [beta][inflation.sub.it] +
[[epsilon].sub.it], where [[epsilon].sub.it], is an error term that
captures all the reasons why inflation and surpluses are not perfectly
linked. As in figure 2, we are interested in capturing how the
relationship fits at different deficit levels, paying particular
attention to countries experiencing high deficits. We achieve this by
estimating equation 5 with three separate quantile regressions: The 5
percent and 10 percent quantiles show the relationship at very low
surplus levels (high deficits), and the median (the 50 percent quantile)
shows the relationship closer to more typical levels. (16) Each
regression suggests a very weak, statistically insignificant, and
positive relationship between inflation and surpluses, as shown by the
positive coefficients on inflation; these results confirm the picture
emerging from the figure 2, panel C.
So far, we have concentrated on the contemporaneous correlation
between inflation and deficits. There are several reasons, however, why
this relationship may show up with a delay. First, Sargent and Wallace
(1981) show that the timing of an inflationary response to deficits may
depend on the details of monetary policy. Second, if engineering higher
inflation is a response to the temptation to devalue nominal debt, this
temptation will gradually grow as deficits swell the size of debt. In
figure 3 (p. 90), we look for evidence that large deficits are
precursors to higher inflation in subsequent years. Specifically, panel
A of figure 3 shows the connection between (corrected) surpluses and the
average of inflation two to four years ahead, and panel B of figure 3
repeats the exercise for the average of inflation five to seven years
ahead. Again, these panels in figure 3 show no clear connection; if
anything, very high deficits seem more prevalent in countries that
experience low inflation in the subsequent years. As a final check, in
figure 4 we look at the relationship between the stock of government net
assets (as a fraction of GDP) and inflation. Once again, this figure
shows no evidence of a negative relationship: Heavily indebted countries
seem to have lower inflation. (17)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Government deficits are the outcome of a supply of bonds by the
government that is met by a demand from willing lenders. (18)
Accordingly, our results are consistent with two possible explanations
that emphasize the supply and the demand, respectively:
* Governments do not give in to the temptation to inflate away
debt, even in times of fiscal straits that lead them to large deficits.
* Lenders are aware that different governments have different
reactions to the temptation to inflate debt away or to outright default
on their obligations through other means; each government's
reaction largely depends on the institutional framework of the country
or the political inclination of the dominant parties in that country. As
a consequence, lenders are only willing to lend to (and thus permit
large deficits in) countries during periods in which the government can
be trusted to raise appropriate revenues to repay debt. In this case,
the lack of a relationship between higher inflation and large deficits
reflects the fact that only the "most virtuous" countries
(those that repay their debts on time) ever experience large deficits.
We will not attempt to distinguish which is the correct
interpretation. However, previous literature has provided indirect
evidence in favor of the second hypothesis. Many researchers have
emphasized the link between low inflation and central bank independence
from the executive branch of government; (19) it is likely that this
institutional arrangement played an important role for many countries
that had low inflation, though they were running (or had previously run)
high deficits. (20) Furthermore, Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano (2003)
identify thresholds of "external debt intolerance" that differ
across countries. A country more intolerant of debt faces macroeconomic
instability and market expectations of a default at levels that do not
cause concern for a less intolerant country.
In figure 2, panel C (p. 88), we established that there are several
instances of countries that ran very large deficits and pursued low
inflation at the same time. Figure 5 magnifies the bottom left corner of
figure 2, panel C, and identifies these instances. Of the points
identified here, three are due to large one-off accounting adjustments
that do not reflect the true deficit: This is the case of Germany and
the Netherlands in 1995 and Japan in 1998 (although Japan's deficit
in 1998 remains substantial even after adjusting for one-off measures).
(21) Two countries appear repeatedly in the picture: Sweden in the early
1990s and Japan in the late 1990s and at the beginning of this century.
Furthermore, while Finland appears only once, its macroeconomic and
fiscal performance in the early 1990s was similar to that of Sweden. In
the next two sections, we discuss these particular deficit experiences
in Finland, Sweden, and Japan in further detail.
Finland and Sweden
In both Finland and Sweden, the 1980s were a decade of financial
deregulation. (22) The improved ability to access foreign capital
markets led to a boom in asset prices. Figure 6, panel A (p. 92) shows
the performance of major stock market indexes in the two countries; for
Sweden, the stock market appreciation of the late 1980s is even faster
than the high-flying dot-com era of the late 1990s. Both countries
adopted a fixed-exchange-rate regime in this period: Both the Finnish
markka and the Swedish krona were pegged to a basket of foreign
currencies. (23) The interest rate differential with respect to Germany
and other countries with a stronger tradition of price stability induced
domestic borrowers to take loans denominated in foreign currencies;
while this saved interest costs during the pegged-exchange-rate regime,
it magnified the balance sheet difficulties when central banks were
forced to devalue their currencies and let them float in the wake of the
crisis.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
By 1990, the combination of a rise in interest rates throughout
Europe (following the German reunification) and the increasing risk of a
devaluation of the Finnish markka and the Swedish krona led to a surge
in interest rates, first stopping and later dramatically reversing the
asset price appreciation. This led to large losses in the banking
sector, and eventually forced the governments of both Finland and Sweden
to step in, guarantee the banks' creditors, and take over some of
the most troubled institutions. The financial crisis was accompanied by
a severe recession, as highlighted in figure 6, panel B, which measures
real GDP. Figure 6, panel C plots government surpluses as a fraction of
GDP (that is, net lending as a fraction of GDP) in Finland and Sweden.
(24) As seen in this panel, the large deficits documented in figure 5
were a (slightly delayed) consequence of the recession. They were mostly
caused by the need to recapitalize the banks and by the so-called
automatic fiscal stabilizers, that is, the natural tendency of tax
revenues to drop and unemployment and other welfare payments to increase
during recessions. There was no intentional "fiscal stimulus;"
rather, discretionary fiscal policy actually started tightening by 1993,
with tax rate increases and the containment of public expenditure, as
discussed by Honkapohja et al. (2009) and Jonung, Schuknecht, and Tujula
(2005). Figure 6, panel D displays government gross financial
liabilities. (25) The financial crisis and the recession saddled Finland
and Sweden with substantial liabilities. Nonetheless, the ratio of debt
to GDP in both countries started to decline shortly after the end of the
recession. This decline was entirely driven by solid growth rates in GDP
and fiscal surpluses--and not by inflation, to which we turn next, in
figure 6, panel E. As seen in that panel, Finland and Sweden did
experience moderate degrees of inflation, but this preceded the crisis,
rather than followed it. Inflation was one of the causes of the crisis:
In combination with a fixed exchange rate, it led to a loss in
competitiveness, which was only restored after the currency pegs were
abandoned in 1992. However, neither country attempted to rely on a
monetary policy accommodating high inflation during or after the deficit
years to erode the large stock of accumulated financial liabilities.
(26)
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Japan
As with Finland and Sweden, Japan also experienced a dramatic rise
in asset prices during the 1980s. In late 1991, the value of the land
underneath the Emperor's Palace in Tokyo was estimated to be worth
about the same as the value of the land in the entire state of
California. (27) Panel A of figure 7 shows the performance of
Japan's stock market, which peaked a little earlier than those of
Finland and Sweden, in 1989. The causes of the Japanese boom and bust
are more complex than those of Finland and Sweden; a more complete
discussion can be found in Kuttner and Posen (2001), Posen (1998),
Hayashi and Prescott (2002), and Hoshi and Kashyap (2004). An important
difference is that Japanese assets never recovered from the crisis, and
still remain well below their peaks registered 20 years ago.
Panel B of figure 7 displays Japan's real GDP, whose path is
similar to that of Japan's stock market. While Finland and Sweden
experienced a quick recovery after the recession, Japan entered into a
prolonged period of stagnation. The extent to which Japan resorted to
expansionary fiscal policy to overcome its weak macroeconomic
performance is debated. Kuttner and Posen (2001) and Posen (1998) argue
that Japan's fiscal deficits were largely a natural consequence of
weak growth, with only small discretionary fiscal expansion; fiscal
policy even turned contractionary in 1997, as discussed in some detail
by Braun and Diaz-Gimenez (2009). Whether it was a consequence of
automatic stabilizers or a conscious choice to use fiscal policy to
stimulate growth, panel C of figure 7 shows that Japan has run large
public deficits since the early 1990s, particularly in the early 2000s.
(28) As a consequence of these deficits, Japan has accumulated a large
debt position. In figure 7, panel D, we plot the gross financial
liabilities of the Japanese government. Panel D of figure 7 exaggerates
the Japanese indebtedness, since a significant fraction of these
liabilities are held by government agencies, as emphasized by Broda and
Weinstein (2004). Government net financial liabilities, as shown in
figure 7, panel E, provide a clearer picture of the Japanese fiscal
situation. Even by this measure, Japan has been accumulating a large
stock of debt. Since our debt metric is the ratio of debt to GDP, the
lack of growth in GDP is an important cause of this accumulation: Had
Japan grown as much as Sweden between 1992 and 2008, its ratio of debt
to GDP would have been about 20 percent smaller than it is, even with no
change in deficits. (29) Unlike for Finland and Sweden, a full fiscal
adjustment to restore stability in the debt/GDP ratio has not yet
materialized in Japan, so it is still possible in principle that the
large debt accumulation will be eventually eroded away through higher
inflation. Nonetheless, the experience of the past 20 years shows no
evidence that Japan has given in to this temptation; in fact, as is well
known, Japan often experienced deflation in this period, as shown in
figure 7, panel F. Market interest rates on Japanese government bonds
remain low, suggesting that lenders do not yet perceive a significant
risk of default or inflation in the future. (30) This is yet another
difference from the Finnish and Swedish experience in the 1990s: In
Finland and Sweden, interest rates spiked during their financial crisis,
providing strong incentives for fiscal adjustment that Japan never
faced. (31)
Conclusion
The evidence presented in this article shows that large fiscal
deficits in industrialized countries did not coincide with higher
inflation, nor did large deficits precede higher inflation. Facing
sizable fiscal imbalances, central banks in these countries were
nonetheless able to maintain an orderly monetary policy. (32) A tempting
interpretation is that these central banks stood fast because their
independence allowed them to do so and they wanted to preserve their
solid reputations; at the same time, central bank independence shielded
governments from the temptation to force the monetization of debt, and
led fiscal authorities to revert quickly to a sustainable debt path.
However, a full account of the institutions that supported price
stability in the face of large fiscal shocks is beyond the scope of this
article.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
APPENDIX: DATA
Two separate samples were created for our analysis. We present
further details on our primary sample comprising data from most
countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
and our larger sample composed of data on 52 countries in the
International Monetary Fund's International Financial Statistics.
OECD sample
The primary sample for our article was compiled using the OECD
Economic Outlook Database on SourceOECD (www.sourceoecd.org). While this
sample does not include all OECD countries, for exposition purposes it
will be labeled as such. We gathered annual statistics of general
government net lending, net and gross general government financial
liabilities, and the inflation as measured by the CPI for 23 countries
over the period 1970-2008. The Czech Republic, Hungary, Luxembourg,
Mexico, the Slovak Republic, and Turkey were not included because of
data availability issues with the particular series of interest. For an
exhaustive list of the data availability of the net lending statistic,
as well as the countries used, see table A1. In the OECD Economic
Outlook Database, the general government sector consolidates accounts of
the central, state, and local governments, plus social security.
Additionally, net lending, net financial liabilities, and gross
financial liabilities are all scaled as a percentage of GDP.
In the OECD Economic Outlook Database, government net lending is
defined as general government current tax and nontax receipts less
general government total outlays. (1) Tax receipts of the government
sector include the sum of direct taxes on household and business
sectors, indirect taxes, and social security contributions. Nontax
receipts pertain to operating surpluses, property income, user charges
and fees, and other current account and capital transfers received by
the general government. Total outlays consist of current outlays plus
capital outlays. Current outlays are the sum of current consumption,
transfer payments, subsidies, and property income paid (including
interest payments). (2)
Gross financial liabilities refer to all the debt and other
liabilities (short- and long-term) of all the institutions in the
general government sector. Subsequently, net financial liabilities
measure these gross financial liabilities of the government sector less
the financial assets. Such assets may be cash, bank deposits, loans to
the private sector, participation in private sector companies, holdings
in public corporations, or foreign exchange reserves, depending on the
institutional structure of the country concerned and data availability.
(3) The status and treatment of government liabilities with respect to
their employee pension plans in the national accounts vary across
countries, making international comparability of government debts
difficult. The current interpretation of the 1993 System of National
Accounts distinguishing between "autonomous" funded pension
plans and "nonautonomous" pension plans is maintained for this
sample. (4)
IMF sample
The second sample was created by collecting the government deficit,
the inflation as measured by the CPI, and the GDP of each country from
the country pages of the International Monetary Fund's
International Financial Statistics Yearbooks. (5) This sample will be
referred to as the IMF sample. Annual figures were recorded over the
period 1970-2008 for 52 countries. For some countries the only reported
government budget was that of the central government; however, the
general government budget was used for every country in which it was
available over the entire history. For an exhaustive list of the data
availability of the deficit statistic, as well as the countries used,
see table A1. The deficit calculated by the IMF in its International
Financial Statistics is the difference between revenue, including grants
received, and the sum of expenditures and lending minus repayments. (6)
Subsequently, this deficit calculation is also equal, with the opposite
sign, to the sum of the net borrowing by the government plus the net
decrease in government cash, deposits, and securities held for liquidity
purposes, and parallels the OECD net lending statistic accordingly.
Table A1 summarizes the two samples by listing the particular
countries used in each; the data availability of the particular
deficit/surplus statistic; and the particular aggregation of the
government budget reported in the IMF sample.
(1) Sources and Methods of the OECD Economic Outlook, annex table
27, available at www.oecd.org/document/14/0,3343,en_2649_34573_
1847822_1_1_1_1,00.html (with general information available at
www.oecd.org/eco/sources-and-methods).
(2) Ibid, annex tables 25 and 36
(3) Ibid, annex table 33.
(4) Ibid.
(5) To construct the full time series for each country, we used
International Monetary Fund, Statistics Department (1990, 1995, 2000,
2009).
(6) See International Monetary Fund, Statistics Department (2009),
p. xxvi.
TABLE A1
Countries included in the analysis
Government
Country OECD IMF unit
Argentina 1970-2004 Central
Australia 1970-2008 1970-2002,2004-08 Central
Austria 1970-2008 1970-97, 2006-08 General
Belgium 1970-2008 1970-2008 Central
Brazil 1970-94,1997-98,2006-08 Central
Burkina Faso 1973-2005 Central
Cameroon 1975-83,1989-95,1998-99 Central
Canada 1970-2008 1970-2007 Central
Chile 1970-2008 Central
Colombia 1970-2006 Central
Costa Rica 1970-2006 Central
Cyprus 1970-2003 Central
Denmark 1971-2008 1970-2000,2006-08 General
Egypt 1975-79,1981-2004,2006-07 General
Finland 1970-2008 1970-2008 Central
France 1978-2008 1970-97, 1999-2007 General
Germany 1970-2008 1970-2008 General
Ghana 1970-97 Central
Greece 1970-2008 1970-2007 General
Iceland 1980-2008 1972-2008 General
India 1970-2008 Central
Indonesia 1970-2008 Central
Iran 1972-2007 Central
Ireland 1970-2008 1970-2002,2006-08 General
Israel 1970-2001,2006-08 Central
Italy 1970-2008 1970-2008 Central
Japan 1970-2008 1970-93,2001-06 General
Kenya 1970-2006 Central
Malaysia 1970-99 Central
Mexico 1972-2008 Central
Morocco 197G-2005,2007-08 Central
Netherlands 1970-2008 1970-2007 Central
New Zealand 1986-2008 1970-88,1990-2005 Central
Nigeria 1970-74,1976-94,1997-2007 Central
Norway 1970-2008 1970-2007 General
Pakistan 1970-2007 Central
Paraguay 1970-2007 Central
Peru 1970-2007 Central
Philippines 1970-2005,2008 Central
Portugal 1977-2008 1970-98,2006-08 General
South Africa 1970-2008 Central
South Korea 1975-2008 1970-99,2001-07 Central
Spain 1970-2008 1970-2007 Central
Sweden 1970-2008 1970-2000,2002-07 Central
Switzerland 1990-2008 1970-2007 Central
Tanzania 1970-2005 Central
Thailand 1970-2003 Central
Tunisia 1972-2007 Central
Turkey 1970-81,1983-84,1987-96 Central
United Kingdom 1970-2008 1970-2008 General
United States 1970-2008 1970-2008 Central
Uruguay 1970-2007 Central
Notes: The years in the second and third columns indicate the
periods for which data are available. The second column indicates
the data availability of countries in the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) sample, and the third
column indicates the data availability of countries in the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) sample. Government unit, in the
fourth column, refers only to the particular aggregation of
government budget reported in the IMF sample (all data in the
OECD sample are reported for the general government).
Sources: International Monetary Fund, Statistics Department
(1990, 1995, 2000, 2009); and Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development, SourceOECD and the Sources and
Methods of the OECD Economic Outlook, available at
www.oecd.org/eco/sources-and-methods.
REFERENCES
Alesina, Alberto, and Lawrence H. Summers, 1993, "Central bank
independence and macroeconomic performance: Some comparative
evidence," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 25, No. 2,
May, pp. 151-162.
Barro, Robert J., and David B. Gordon, 1983, "A positive
theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model," Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 4, August, pp. 589-610.
Bernanke, Ben S., 2010, "Central bank independence,
transparency, and accountability," speech at the Institute for
Monetary and Economic Studies International Conference, Bank of Japan,
Tokyo, Japan, May 25, available at
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bemanke20100525a.htm.
--, 2005, "The global saving glut and the U.S. current account
deficit," Homer Jones Memorial Lecture at the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, St. Louis, MO, April 14, available at
www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2005/20050414/default.htm.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Mark Gertler, 1999, "Monetary policy and
asset price volatility," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City, Fourth Quarter, pp. 17-51.
Berndt, Antje, Hanno N. Lustig, and Sevin Yeltekin, 2010, "How
does the U.S. government finance fiscal shocks?," Carnegie Mellon
University, Tepper School of Business; University of California, Los
Angeles, Anderson School of Management; and National Bureau of Economic
Research, working paper, April 23, available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1354699.
Braun, R. Anton, and Javier Diaz-Gimenez, 2009, "Spain, Japan,
and the dangers of early fiscal tightening," University of Tokyo;
and University of Navarra, IESE Business School, mimeo, October 20.
Broda, Christian, and David E. Weinstein, 2004, "Happy news
from the dismal science: Reassessing the Japanese fiscal policy and
sustainability," National Bureau of Economic Research, working
paper, No. 10988, December.
Calvo, Guillermo A., and Pablo E. Guidotti, 1990, "Indexation
and maturity of government bonds: An exploratory model," in Public
Debt Management: Theory and History, Rudiger Dornbusch and Mario Draghi
(eds.), Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 52-82.
Catao, Luis A. V., and Marco E. Terrones, 2005, "Fiscal
deficits and inflation," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 52,
No. 3, April, pp. 529-554.
Cukierman, Alex, 1992, Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and
Independence: Theory and Evidence, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Economist Newspaper Limited, 2008, "Argentina: Harvesting
pensions," Economist, Vol. 389, No. 8608, November 29-December 5,
p. 44.
Englund, Peter, 1999, "The Swedish banking crisis: Roots and
consequences," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 15, No. 3,
pp. 80-97.
Grilli, Vittorio, Donato Masciandaro, and Guido Tabellini, 1991,
"Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies
in the industrial countries," Economic Policy, Vol. 6, No. 13,
October, pp. 342-392.
Hall, George J., and Thomas J. Sargent, 2010, "Interest rate
risk and other determinants of post-WWII U.S. government debt/GDP
dynamics," National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper, No.
15702, January.
--,1997, "Accounting for the federal government's cost of
funds," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Vol. 21, No. 4, July/August, pp. 18-28.
Hamburger, Michael J., and Burton Zwick, 1981, "Deficits,
money, and inflation," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 7, No.
1, January, pp. 141-150.
Hayashi, Fumio, and Edward C. Prescott, 2002, "The 1990s in
Japan: A lost decade," Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 5, No. 1,
January, pp. 206-235.
Holden, Steinar, and Birger Vikoren, 1996, "The credibility of
a fixed exchange rate: How reputation is gained or lost,"
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 98, No. 4, pp. 485-502.
Honkapohja, Seppo, Erkki A. Koskela, Willi Leibfritz, and Roope
Uusitalo, 2009, Economic Prosperity Recaptured: The Finnish Path from
Crisis to Rapid Growth, CESifo Book Series, Cambridge, MA, and London:
MIT Press.
Hoshi, Takeo, and Anil K Kashyap, 2004, "Japan's
financial crisis and economic stagnation," Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 18, No. 1, Winter, pp. 3-26.
International Monetary Fund, Statistics Department, 2009,
International Financial Statistics Yearbook, Vol. 62, Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
--,2000, International Financial Statistics Yearbook, Vol. 53,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
--, 1995, International Financial Statistics Yearbook, Vol. 48,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
--, 1990, International Financial Statistics Yearbook, Vol. 43,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Ireland, Peter N., 2000, "Interest rates, inflation, and
Federal Reserve policy since 1980," Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, Vol. 32, No. 3, August, 417-434.
Jonung, Lars, Ludger Schuknecht, and Mika Tujula, 2005, "The
boom--bust cycle in Finland and Sweden 1984-1995 in an international
perspective," European Economy--Economic Papers, European
Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, No.
237, December 13.
Joumard, Isabelle, Makoto Minegishi, Christophe Andre, Chantal
Nicq, and Robert Price, 2008, "Accounting for one-off operations
when assessing underlying fiscal positions," Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development, Economics Department, working
paper, No. 642, December 1.
King, Robert G., and Charles I. Plosser, 1985, "Money,
deficits, and inflation," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, Vol. 22, No. 1, January, pp. 147-195.
Kuttner, Kenneth N., and Adam S. Posen, 2001, "The Great
Recession: Lessons for macroeconomic policy from Japan," Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 32, No. 2, pp. 93-160.
Missale, Alessandro, and Olivier Jean Blanchard, 1994, "The
debt burden and debt maturity," American Economic" Review,
Vol. 84, No. 1, March, pp. 309-319.
Posen, Adam S., 1998, Restoring Japan's Economic Growth,
Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2009, "The
aftermath of financial crises," American Economic Review, Vol. 99,
No. 2, May, pp. 466-472.
--, 2008a, "Banking crises: An equal opportunity menace,"
National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper, No. 14587,
December.
--, 2008b, "This time is different: A panoramic view of eight
centuries of financial crises," National Bureau of Economic
Research, working paper, No. 13882, March.
Reinhart, Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano,
2003, "Debt intolerance," Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 1-74.
Sargent, Thomas J., 1983, "Stopping moderate inflations: The
methods of Poincare and Thatcher," in Inflation, Debt, and
Indexation, Rudiger Dornbusch and Mario Henrique Simonsen (eds.),
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 54-98.
--, 1982, "The ends of four big inflations," in
Inflation: Causes and Effects, Robert E. Hall (ed.), Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, pp. 41-97.
Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace, 1981, "Some unpleasant
monetarist arithmetic," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, Vol. 5, No. 3, Fall, pp. 1-17.
Sargent, Thomas J., Noah Williams, and Tao Zha, 2009, "The
conquest of South American inflation," Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 117, No. 2, pp. 211-256.
Stone, Douglas, and William T. Ziemba, 1993, "Land and stock
prices in Japan," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7, No. 3,
Summer, pp. 149-165.
U.S. Department of the Treasury, Financial Management Service,
2010, Treasury Bulletin, June, available at
www.fms.treas.gov/bulletin/index.html.
NOTES
(1) One simplification is that equation 1 treats government debt as
if it had a one-year maturity. In practice, a large fraction of
government debt has longer maturity. The deficit implications of
correctly valuing long-term debt are studied by Hall and Sargent (1997,
2010). This equation also treats the government as a single entity. In
practice, even at the U.S. federal level, the Social Security and
Medicare trust funds keep separate accounts from the rest of the federal
government Moreover, states and numerous local governments have their
own budgets. Throughout this article, we consolidate all of these
budgets into one (whenever possible). A further simplification is that
we lump purchases of capital together with other forms of spending in
[G.sub.t] and that we lump sales of capital together with other revenues
in [T.sub.t]. In the case of the United States, spectrum auctions
(auctions to sell the rights to transmit signals over specific
electromagnetic wavelengths) are the only major source of revenues from
privatization of public capital.
(2) The liability side also contains the bank's capital;
however, this is a relatively small entry, so we abstract from it here.
(3) The approximation is accurate as long as inflation and interest
rates are small.
(4) The primary surplus is the difference between government
revenues and expenditures, excluding interest payments, and is captured
by the second term on the right-hand side of equation 4.
(5) For this computation, we used interest rates on one-year
Treasury constant maturities and the monetary base from Federal Reserve
Statistical Releases H. 15 (www federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/
data.htm) and H.3 (wwwfederalreservegov/releases/h3/hist/), respectively
(6) For early treatments, see, for example, Calvo and Guidotti
(1990).
(7) See U.S. Department of the Treasury, Financial Management
Service (2010), table FD-5
(8) Missale and Blanchard (1994) analyze the relationship between
the size of debt and its maturity structure in the case of Belgium,
Ireland, and Italy, and show that the maturity structure varies
inversely with the size of the debt/GDP ratio They interpret this as
evidence that a shorter maturity is needed to contain the temptation to
inflate debt away when debt is larger.
(9) See Economist Newspaper Limited (2008).
(10) For example, the low interest rates of the last decade have
sometimes been attributed to a "'global saving glut;" see
Bernanke (2005).
(11) It should be noted that hyperinflations exacerbate underlying
fiscal imbalances; when inflation is so high that it impacts the real
value of money on a day-to-day basis, even minor delays in the
collection of taxes have a large effect on the real value of tax
revenues.
(12) More precisely, Catao and Terrones (2005) use a logarithmic
specification for one plus the inflation rate, and they find that a 1
percent increase in the deficit/GDP ratio is associated with 0.044 log
points for their logarithmic measure. At low levels of inflation, this
translates to 5 percent extra inflation, but this effect becomes bigger
at higher inflation rates.
(13) To mention but one example, Barro and Gordon (1983) stress the
time inconsistency problem that arises when the central bank wishes to
push employment beyond its equilibrium level. Ireland (2000) views this
as a cause for the inflation experienced by the United States in the
1970s.
(14) The 5th (10th) percentile is defined so that 5 percent (10
percent) of the points in the bin lie at or below it.
(15) International Monetary Fund, Statistics Department (1990,
1995, 2000, 2009)
(16) It may seem more natural to treat inflation as the dependent
variable and the surplus as the independent variable. However, ours is a
purely statistical exercise, trying to establish correlation patterns
among two variables with no pretense of establishing causation tn this
form, the regression allows us to concentrate on the low-surplus
quantiles that we are most interested in. We have run similar
regressions inverting the dependent and independent variables, and our
results are similar.
(17) The figure for gross financial liabilities would be even more
striking, mainly because of the recent Japanese experience, where very
large gross financial liabilities coexisted with stable or declining
prices.
(18) Sometimes governments resort to forced lending; in this case,
a proper economic accounting would require us to disentangle how much
lenders would willingly offer the government from the hidden tax that is
imposed by the mandatory government scheme. Fortunately, this is not an
issue for the OECD countries in the period we consider.
(19) See, for example, Grilli, Masciandaro, and Tabellini (1991);
Cukierman (1992); and Alesina and Summers (1993).
(20) In the case of Japan, the central bank only gained operational
independence in 1997, well after the crisis had started, but still well
before government debt grew to alarming levels. See, for example,
Bernanke (2010).
(21) See Joumard et al (2008).
(22) For more detailed accounts of the financial crisis in Finland
and Sweden, see, for example, Honkapohja et al. (2009); Jonung,
Schuknecht, and Tujula (2005); and Englund (1999).
(23) See Holden and Vikoren (1996). tn later years, the basket
corresponded to the accounting unit of the European Community--the ECU.
(24) Unlike in figure 5, the actual occurrence of deficits without
the correction for inflation is plotted in figure 6, panel C The pattern
is very similar even with the correction.
(25) Plotting net liabilities would show a similar pattern.
However, both the Finnish and Swedish governments own substantial
interests in private companies, whose market values fluctuated in the
late 1990s and early 2000s. These movements confound the underlying
evolution of the debt/GDP ratio driven by growth and stable fiscal
finances.
(26) It is interesting to note that the macroeconomic and fiscal
policy evolution continued to be very similar in both Finland and
Sweden, even though their respective institutional environments became
very different from the mid-1990s onward. Finland opted to join the
Economic and Monetary Union of the European Union (EU), relinquishing
its ability to run an independent monetary policy and accepting the
fiscal constraints implied by the EU's Stability and Growth Pact.
Sweden remained outside of the eurozone, but pursued similar fiscal and
monetary policies to those of Finland, even though it was not bound by
external constraints.
(27) See Stone and Ziemba (1993).
(28) As we already mentioned, the large outlier in 1998 is due to
one-off debt assumptions. The actual occurrence of deficits without the
correction for inflation is plotted in figure 7, panel C. The pattern is
very similar even with the correction.
(29) Additional growth would also have helped tax revenues, and
would thus most likely have reduced the deficits. At the same time, the
Japanese government paid very low real interest rates on its debt; had
the economy grown faster, higher rates might have prevailed, increasing
the burden of debt.
(30) Of course, the recent experience in Greece shows that market
expectations can change abruptly.
(31) We are indebted to R. Anton Braun for suggesting this
observation.
(32) In fact, many economists have complained that the Bank of
Japan was too restrictive given the economic conditions; see, for
example, Bernanke and Gertler (1999).
Marco Bassetto is a senior economist and economic advisor and R.
Andrew Butters is an associate economist in the Economic Research
Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank
Lisa Barrow, R Anton Braun, Martin Floden, Simon Gilchrist, Paul Klein,
Thomas J. Sargent, Juha Seppala, and Harald Uhlig for useful
suggestions.
TABLE 1
Quantile regressions of government surplus
on inflation
Fifth Tenth Median
Inflation 0.059 0.061 0.063
(0.091) (0.072) (0.039)
Constant -7.140 -5.617 -1.496
(0.554) (0.461) (0.238)
Notes: Inflation is measured by the consumer price index (CPI).
Each column corresponds to a different quantile regression. The
standard errors, which appear in parentheses, are not corrected
for clustering, so the precision of the estimates are overstated.
The cluster correction would lead them to be even less statistically
significant. For more details, see the text.
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from the Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development, SourceOECD.