The acceleration in the U.S. total factor productivity after 1995: the role of information technology.
Fernald, John G. ; Ramnath, Shanthi
Introduction and summary
After the mid-1990s, labor and total factor productivity (TFP)
accelerated in the United States. A growing body of research has
explored the robustness of the U.S. acceleration, generally concluding
that it reflects an underlying technology acceleration. This research,
along with considerable anecdotal and microeconomic evidence, suggests a
substantial role for information and communications technology (ICT).
(1)
In this article, we briefly discuss the results of so-called growth
accounting at the aggregate level. We then look more closely at the
experience since the mid-1990s, when TFP accelerated. We look at data on
which industries account for the TFP acceleration: Were the 1990s a time
of rising total factor productivity growth outside of the production of
ICT? Our industry data strongly support the view that a majority of the
TFP acceleration reflects an acceleration outside of the production of
ICT goods and software. (2) Even when we focus on arguably "well-measured" sectors (Griliches 1994; Nordhaus 2002), we
find a substantial TFP acceleration outside of ICT production.
In particular, wholesale and retail trade show a substantial
acceleration in TFP after the mid-1990s. This observation leads us, in
the final part of the article, to discuss anecdotal evidence on the
kinds of changes that have taken place in trade industries that might
show up in measured TFP. Retailers implemented numerous organizational
innovations, many of which required substantial industry, firm, and
establishment reorganization; many of these innovations themselves
relied centrally on innovations in ICT. Thus, ICT appears to play a
nuanced role in the post-1995 pickup in productivity growth. In
particular, the benefits of ICT may be subtle, affecting measured TFP in
sectors that use ICT, as firms reorganize production in order to take
advantage of the new technologies.
Before discussing numbers, why do we care about TFP growth? First,
TFP growth allows us to increase the amount of output we produce--and,
hence, how much we have available to consume today or invest for the
future--without having to increase the resources (mainly capital and
labor) used. Equivalently, we can produce the same output with fewer
resources. This efficiency gain is clearly good for society. Second,
economists generally argue that in the long run, TFP growth is the only
means of getting sustained increases in standards of living, or output
per worker. The reason is that tangible capital is generally thought to
have a "diminishing marginal product." In other words, for a
given number of workers, suppose we increase the quantity of capital. It
is reasonable to expect that the marginal contribution of that capital
falls, since we have to spread the same workers over more machines and
structures. As a result, investment in equipment, software, and
structures alone probably cannot lead to sustained increases in
standards of living-as the marginal product of capital declines, the
extra capital leads to little or no extra output.
A complementary way to look at the benefits of TFP growth is that
one can show that TFP growth is identically equal to a weighted average
of real wages and real payments to capital. If TFP growth rises, either
real wages or real payments to capital rise. Thus, if we want to raise
real wages without reducing returns to capital, we need TFP growth.
Aggregate growth accounting results
If the economy's output increases, then someone must have
produced it. In our empirical work, we think of the economy as
comprising a large number of finns and industries. But to fix ideas, we
start by assuming that the economy has an aggregate production function
that relates its overall real output Y to inputs of capital K and labor
L. Output also depends on the level of technology, A. Output goes up if
the economy's capital or labor input increases or if technology
improves. We write this function as:
1) Y=A x F(K,L).
The relationship in equation 1 is relatively intuitive. For
example, the United States produces more output than India each year,
even though India has a much larger labor force (and many more employed
workers) than the United States. Equation 1 suggests that the United
States either has more capital than India or is more efficient at
converting inputs into output than India (that is, A is higher in the
United States), or (most likely) both.
More closely related to the focus of this article, U.S. nonfarm
business output increased more than sixfold between 1948 and 2000;
equation 1 says that this reflects increases in capital, labor, or
technology. According to Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) data, over
this same period, total labor input (adjusted for changes in the
composition of the labor force) increased two and a half times, while
capital input increased about eightfold.
But what was the role of technological innovations, represented by
A? With a few assumptions about the production function in equation 1,
we can be more precise about the role of technological innovations
versus input increases in explaining output growth. We discuss these
assumptions further and derive the formal equations in the appendix.
Loosely speaking, the key is that economic theory indicates how one can
account for the productive contribution of the inputs of capital and
labor. Any increase in output not accounted for by increases in inputs
is called total factor productivity (also known as the Solow residual,
after Solow, 1957, or multifactor productivity).
The BLS produces a widely cited measure of TFP growth, and the data
that underlie its calculation, for the U.S. economy. The BLS refers to
this measure as "multifactor productivity" or MFP; MFP, TFP,
and the Solow residual are three names for the same concept--that is,
output growth unexplained by growth in inputs and we use them
interchangeably. As of this writing, the data run through 2001. However,
we focus on the period through 2000, since 2001 was a recession year and
a large literature discusses the fact that the Solow residual is
procyclical (rising in booms and falling in recessions). (3) We wish to
abstract from that short-run focus here.
Several comments on the data are useful. In particular, there are,
of course, many different types of output and input. For real output,
the BLS uses national accounting data from the Bureau of Economic
Analysis (BEA); (the BEA output indexes combine the real value of the
many different types of goods and services produced). For labor, there
are also many different types of workers. These workers have different
levels of productivity, reflecting factors such as age, experience, and
education. The BLS attempts to control for these differences largely by
using relative wage rates: If a college-educated worker earns a higher
wage than a high-school dropout, then we expect the main reason for this
is that the college-educated worker is more productive. Similarly,
capital inputs combine a wide range of tangible goods, such as office
buildings, factories, machine presses, and computers. For productivity
calculations, one wants a measure of the relative service flow from
these different types of capital. The main issue is that a building may
last 50 or more years, so it needs a low annual service flow per dollar
of capital to cover its costs; a personal computer may last only three
or so years, and hence must have a high service flow per dollar of
capital since it needs to cover its costs in a very short period. The
BLS produces a capital input measure that takes into account the
composition of the capital stock across different types of capital. To
do so, the BLS estimates the service flow of different types of capital.
Table 1 shows BLS data for the private non-farm economy from 1948
to 2000. The first column shows TFP growth, which was at an annual rate
of about 1.2 percent between 1948 and 2000. This rate of increase,
compounded for 52 years, implies that the level of TFP approximately
doubled over this period.
The next three columns show the growth rates of output and input
quantities that underlie that TFP growth in the BLS data. Output growth
in the non-farm business sector averaged about 3.7 percent per year;
labor input grew somewhat more slowly, about 1.8 percent per year; while
capital input grew somewhat more quickly, nearly 4.1 percent per year.
The next column shows the average share of labor compensation in total
cost. Although it fluctuates somewhat from year to year, this share
averaged 0.69 over the full sample period.
The final two columns show that over time, labor has benefited
substantially from TFP growth, with real wages rising 1.9 percent per
year. Real rental rates, by comparison, have been relatively
flat--indeed, declining slightly over time. This finding--that
technological progress leads to an increase in real wages but not an
increase in real rental rates--is consistent with standard theories of
economic growth. When TFP increases, the marginal products of labor and
capital also increase; initially, this leads to higher payments to these
factors as finns compete to hire (or, in the case of capital, rent)
them. But in the case of capital, over time the increased marginal
product of capital leads to a substantial increase in investment and the
quantity of capital, thereby driving the marginal product of capital
back down. (The increase in the capital stock, of course, further raises
the marginal product of labor, driving the wage up further.) Hence, over
time, TFP increases raise the real wage as well as the real quantity of
capital.
The remainder of the table summarizes important changes over time
in the evolution of these series. Several facts are striking. First,
comparing the 1948-73 row with the 1973-95 row shows that TFP growth and
output growth slowed markedly after 1973. In terms of factor payments,
the slowdown in wage growth was particularly marked. By contrast, there
is little evidence that factor quantity growth changed in any
particularly striking way.
Second, after 1995, TFP growth and output growth surged. In the BLS
data, although TFP growth did not quite reach its pre-1973 levels,
output growth exceeded its earlier rates. Input growth rates rose--with
a particularly notable pace of capital growth (nearly 5.4 percent per
year). Real wage growth rose at a pace only slightly below its pre-1973
growth rate of nearly 2.8 percent; but real rental growth turned from a
slight negative to a sharp negative.
The post-1995 productivity acceleration is, of course, of more than
just historical interest, since many aspects of future U.S. economic
performance depend on whether this fast pace of growth continues. For
example, faster productivity growth means faster growth in income, which
not only raises people's standards of living but also means that
future tax receipts will be higher, improving the government's
budget balance. An important, and still unresolved, issue is the extent
to which this productivity acceleration reflects primarily information
technology--the most notable example of new technology in recent years.
Industry growth accounting results
The previous section looked at overall TFP growth for the economy.
A striking finding was the pickup in TFP growth after 1995. In this
section, we ask the interesting follow-up question: Where did the TFP
growth take place in the economy? In particular, was the pickup
primarily centered in ICT producing or ICT using industries?
When we disaggregate the data to an industry level, an important
conceptual question arises about how to treat intermediate inputs
(purchased goods and services such as raw materials, parts, consultants,
advertising, and so forth) and, as a result, how to measure output. For
example, suppose the economy produces bread. A farmer grows the wheat
and sells it to a miller; the miller produces flour and sells it to a
baker; and the baker bakes bread and sells it to a household. At an
economy-wide level, we do not want to measure total output by summing
the value of the wheat plus the value of the flour plus the value of the
bread. We just want to count the value of the final loaves of bread. An
alternative way to measure that final output is by summing the so-called
value added of the farmer, the miller, and the baker--that is, the value
of their sales minus the value of the intermediate inputs they
purchased. At an economy-wide level, the inputs used to produce the
bread comprise the capital and labor used by the farmer, the miller, and
the baker.
We focus, for simplicity, on the value-added approach, even at the
industry level. The advantage of this approach is that these estimates
are "scaled" to be comparable across industries. The potential
disadvantage, of course, is that the measure of output value added--is
rather less natural than the "gross output" of shoes, bread,
and so forth. In the words of Domar (1961), value added is "shoes
lacking leather, made without power." In our example, it is bread
lacking flour. Nevertheless, for standard measures of TFP, the
value-added measures are simply rescaled versions of gross-output TFP
(with a scaling factor that depends on the ratio of nominal gross output
to nominal value added), so no important information is lost. (4)
We use a 51-industry dataset discussed in Basu, Fernald, Oulton,
and Srinivasan (2003). These data update that used in Bosworth and
Triplett (2002) and Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro (2001). The industry
value-added measures (derived from industry gross output and
intermediate-input use) come from industry-level national accounts data
from the BEA. For capital input--including detailed ICT data--we use BLS
capital input data by disaggregated industry. For labor input, we use
unpublished BLS data on hours worked by two-digit Standard Industrial
Classification (SIC) industry. Real industry output data are not
available before 1977 and, for some industries, not before 1987. (5)
Table 2 overleaf provides standard estimates of TFP for various
aggregates, including the one-digit industry level. The first three
columns show TFP in value-added terms. The final column shows the
sector's nominal value-added share. (6)
The top line shows the sizable acceleration in TFP growth, from
about 0.6 percent per year to about 1.9 percent. (7) These calculations
incorporate a labor composition adjustment from Aaronson and Sullivan
(2001), shown in the second line. Labor quality growth increased more
slowly in the second half of the 1990s, when the booming economy drew
lower skilled workers into employment. Hence, adjusting for improvements
in labor "quality" heightens the magnitude of the TFP
acceleration calculated with raw hours (shown in the third line,
calculated as the appropriate weighted average of the industry TFP
growth rates shown in the table). (8)
The remainder of the table shows various sub-aggregates, including
the one-digit SIC level (none of which incorporate a labor quality
adjustment). It is clear that in our dataset, the acceleration was not
limited to the ICT-producing sectors. First, if we focus on the non-ICT
producing sectors (third line from bottom), we see an acceleration of
nearly 1 percentage point. In an accounting sense, these sectors
contribute about 0.9 percentage points of the 1.2 percentage point total
(non-quality adjusted) acceleration. Major non-ICT sectors contributing
to the acceleration include wholesale trade, retail trade, finance, and
insurance.
Second, Griliches (1994) and Nordhaus (2002) argue that real output
in many service industries is poorly measured--for example, it is often
difficult even conceptually to decide on the "real output" of
a bank or a lawyer. Nordhaus argues for focusing on what one hopes are
the "well-measured" (or at least, better measured) sectors of
the economy. The acceleration in TFP in well-measured industries is even
larger than the overall acceleration; the acceleration is sizable even
when we exclude ICT-producing sectors.
Looking more closely at the sectoral data, the trade sectors,
especially retail, emerge as a major contributor to the productivity
acceleration. U.S. retail value-added TFP growth rose by 4.5 percentage
points per year. Together, wholesale and retail trade
"account" for about three-quarters of the U.S. acceleration
(weighted by output shares). Nevertheless, they are not the entire
story. Even excluding these sectors, the U.S. data still show an
acceleration. (9)
That the U.S. productivity acceleration was broad-based is
consistent with a growing body of recent work. For example, the Council
of Economic Advisers (2003) reports that between 1973-95 and 1995-2002,
non-ICT TFP accelerated sharply, with its contribution to U.S. growth
rising from 0.18 percentage points per year to 1.25 percentage points,
roughly in line with the figures here. (10) Bosworth and Triplett (2002)
focus on the performance of service industries and find a widespread
acceleration. Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2002) also find that TFP
accelerated outside ICT production, although by a smaller amount. N
Case study: Anecdotal evidence on production and productivity in
retail trade
In the preceding sections of the article, we documented the
resurgence in TFP growth after 1995 in both aggregate and industry data.
We also documented that the majority of the acceleration occurred in
sectors that use, rather than produce, information technology. Within
these IT-using sectors, we reported that wholesale and retail trade
appeared particularly important in accounting for the TFP resurgence. We
now look more closely at these industries, seeking anecdotal evidence on
the kinds of changes that have taken place in trade industries that
might show up in measured TFP This anecdotal evidence may provide
insights into the underlying sources of TFP growth. (12)
The Bureau of Economic Analysis--the source for our data--defines
retail trade as a distribution service of goods to individuals. (13)
According to the BEA's gross domestic product-by-industry measure,
total output in retail trade is measured by retail sales, excluding the
value of the actual good sold and taxes collected by individual retail
stores. Thus, value added would be these distribution services minus the
contribution of the electricity, utilities, cleaning services, and other
intermediate inputs. (14)
A difficult issue that national accountants have to struggle with
is how to measure real, or inflation-adjusted, output. If there are no
changes in the quality of goods sold, then simply recording the value of
sales and the prices charged makes it relatively easy to measure real
output. However, when there are substantial changes in quality--for
example, retailers stock a wider variety of products so you are more
likely to find what you want; or the Internet makes it easy to buy goods
at home if, in fact, you hate fighting crowds at the mall--it becomes
much more difficult to properly measure real output. For example, some
people have argued that the substantial use of information technology in
retailing has made it increasingly difficult to measure real output
accurately.
Nakamura discusses the difficulties in measuring output that
resulted from changes in the retail environment between 1978 and 1996.
Retailers with advanced technology offered lower prices and replaced
retailers with older technology whose goods sold for more. Nakamura
(1997) defines this "rapid automation of retail transactions
processing" as the "retail revolution." According to
Nakamura, the BLS methodology measures this decline in price as a
decline in output with a stable price, and misleadingly captures
efficiency as inefficiency. He suggests that retail output was
understated due to an increase in the quality of service provided to
consumers. Nakamura cites a report in the trade publication Progressive
Grocer that the average items per store grew from 7,800 in 1970 to
19,612 in 1994. He notes that "Americans no longer had to make do
with bright yellow mustard, canned peas, and gelatin desserts"
(Nakamura, 1997), highlighting increased American living standards reflecting a proliferation in goods provided by retailers.
Leaving this measurement issue aside, what do the BEA data show
about the growth rates of real output and real inputs of capital and
labor? Real value-added in retail trade averaged 5.4 percent from 1995
to 2000, almost doubling the average growth between 1978 and 1995 of 2.9
percent. From our original production function, we see that increases in
value added are explained by either increases in inputs (capital and
labor) or improvements in technology. According to BLS data, both
capital and labor inputs for retail trade grew more slowly, not more
quickly, in the latter half of the 1990s. Capital input grew at 4.7
percent between 1978 and 1995, but only 3.9 percent between 1995 and
2000. Labor hour growth slowed from 1.5 percent to 1.3 percent over
these periods.
Since the faster pace of output growth does not reflect faster
growth in inputs, TFP growth must have risen. To think about the sources
of TFP growth, it is useful to think a bit about how information
technology shows up in the retail sector. The direct effect of adding,
say, new high-tech scanners and computers is simply capital deepening:
Each worker can produce more output using the same level of effort. But
this new information technology as such represents more capital input,
not higher TFP. For example, many large retailers invested in barcode
technology with scanning capabilities for identifying goods. Prices then
entered into registers automatically, leaving less room for mistakes
and, consequently, speeding the entire checkout process. As a result,
output increased, given that the number of purchases increased along
with overall sales.
This capital-deepening raises labor productivity (output per hour),
even if it does not raise TFP. Studies conducted by the BLS find that
labor productivity accelerated between 1987 and 1999, partially
accounted for by information technology investment (Sieling, Friedman,
and Dumas, 2001). These BLS findings show capital deepening indeed
existed in retail trade and contributed to higher output.
So how could investments in information technology affect TFP? One
reason is that when retailers invested heavily in new information
technology, additional organizational changes followed that also
enhanced production. Small modifications of this nature often appear in
TFP measures, and therefore serve as a useful tool for examining TFP
growth. For example, adding coiled wire extensions to barcode scanners
made it unnecessary for employees to lift heavy objects in stores that
sold large items. This wire is a relatively cheap piece of capital; the
innovation is really the idea of adding it to the scanner, an idea that
may have been thought up and implemented by the retailer rather than the
scanner manufacturer. This innovation, in turn, helped speed the
checkout line; output increased, with a minimal investment.
In the remainder of this section, we investigate changes that took
place in retail trade prior to the late 1990s in the hope of gaining
further insight into the industry's exceptional TFP performance.
However, one challenge is that organizational changes are often coupled
with capital investments, making it difficult sometimes to disentangle
the role of the capital itself (an increase in capital per worker) from
the increase in TFP that came because the organizational innovation
allowed retailers to increase output more than they increased inputs. So
we do not try to separate or quantify the effects. Given that capital
input grew more slowly in the second half of the 1990s than the first,
while output grew more quickly, it is clear that the organizational
changes played a key role.
The organizational structure of individual retail firms altered
dramatically following the introduction of information technology to the
industry. Retailers partnered with manufacturers in place of using
wholesale trade as an intermediary. With electronic data interchange systems (EDI), retailers linked to suppliers, which allowed for instant
data exchanges. In addition, both retailers and suppliers agreed in
advance on how suppliers should react to the sales data gathered.
Together, these new practices helped reduce imperfect information.
According to the Economic Report of the President, "Even where
firms in the supply chain remain separate entities, the degree of
cooperation may come to resemble what might occur in a vertically
integrated firm" (Council of Economic Advisers, 2001). Holmes
(2000) illustrates this aspect of supply-chain management using the
partnership between retailer Wal-Mart and manufacturer Proctor &
Gamble (see also Kumar, 1996). According to Lou Prichett, vice president
at Proctor & Gamble, "P&G could monitor Wal-Mart's
sales and inventory data, and then use that information to make its own
production and shipping plans with a great deal more efficiency"
(Walton and Huey, 1992). The Harvard Business Review finds IT use in
retailing helped reduce both human error and shipment time, which then
allowed retailers to trim costs. Cutting costs grew in importance as
more discount stores entered the market. Changes also occurred in how
retailers organized inventory deliveries. Holmes (2000) finds evidence
that investment in IT complemented both increases in inventory
deliveries and increases to store size. Retailers benefited from
economies of scale by filling trucks to capacity with larger orders and,
thus, stores grew in size. Holmes also notes that "Wal-Mart and
Home Depot led other retailers in increasing the frequency of
deliveries," citing Vance and Scott (1994), who claim that
Wal-Mart's daily deliveries set them apart from rival Kmart, whose
deliveries came once every five days.
As modifications were taking place within individual firms, the
entire marketplace experienced a transformation as well. A new larger
design for stores emerged--the "big-box" format--whereby
retailers took advantage of their size and offered a wide spectrum of
goods at lower prices. Retail trade is typically dominated by small
businesses; thus, Foster, Haltiwanger, and Krizan's (2000) finding
that large retailers displaced
smaller, less efficient retailers implies that the entrance of large
chain stores significantly affected the industry. They find that this
displacement increased overall productivity in retail trade through
entry and exit of firms, with the entrance of efficient firms carrying a
larger weight in the productivity boost. Anecdotal evidence shows that
large retailers also displaced other large retailers. Kmart surpassed
Sears, Roebuck, and Co. to dominate market share of the retail industry,
but later fell to Wal-Mart, which currently dominates. (15)
Using new systems under supply-side management, retailers cut costs
and offered "everyday low prices," yet remained profitable
since sales increased with lower-priced goods. Organizational changes
tied to the infiltration of information technology increased efficiency
and improved the overall production process. These within-firm changes
affected the entire industry by displacing inefficient firms and
promoting the spread of effective production procedures. In fact,
studies by McKinsey Global Institute suggest retail giant, Wal-Mart, had
both an indirect and direct impact on general merchandizing through
"managerial innovation that increased competitive intensity and
drove the diffusion of best practice" (McKinsey, 2001). Below, we
discuss operations initiated by Wal-Mart to add a firm-level perspective
to the productivity acceleration in retail trade.
Wal-Mart: Examples of ideas put to work
"How did a peddler of cheap shirts and fishing rods become the
mightiest corporation in America?"--Fortune magazine posed this
question after Wal-Mart topped its Fortune 500 list in 2002, making it
the first service sector corporation to reach the top. From its small
town start in Arkansas, Wal-Mart has grown into an empire spanning the
globe. In fact, Wal-Mart accounted for 6 percent of total U.S. retail
sales in the fiscal year ending January 31, 2003. (16)
Wal-Mart differed from other retailers in many of its strategies.
Large retailers like Kmart and Sears, Roebuck, and Company targeted
urban populations, believing that rural areas were not profitable.
Wal-Mart, on the other hand, contended that a market existed in rural
America as well. Though the advantage of building in urban areas came
from proximity to distributors, Wal-Mart solved this problem by building
capacity to install an internal distribution system. Essentially,
Wal-Mart took on wholesaling in addition to the retail business
(McKinsey, 2001). As discussed earlier, retailers cut costs and saved
time by establishing direct contact with manufacturers. Wal-Mart
exploited this new practice by establishing direct contact with Proctor
& Gamble, and then warehoused merchandise in P&G's
distribution centers. By centrally placing large orders, Wal-Mart was
able to negotiate reduced prices on goods from manufacturers, helping it
later to under-price competitors (McKinsey, 2001; Raff and Temin, 1997).
Wal-Mart also benefited from shrewd managerial tactics, beginning
with company founder and CEO, Sam Walton. According to McKinsey Global
Institute, managerial innovations "gave Wal-Mart a 44 percent
productivity gap relative to the remainder of the market"
(McKinsey, 2001). In Walton's book, Made in America, he discusses
the importance of learning from those who were more successful, which at
the time was Kmart. Wal-Mart was not an overnight success--in fact, it
spent many years on the sidelines learning while retailers like Kmart
dominated the industry. Walton asserts that "During this whole
early period, Wal-Mart was too small and insignificant for any of the
big boys to notice .... That helped me get access to a lot of
information about how they were doing things" (Walton and Huey,
1992). While Wal-Mart remained small, Walton invested in intangible
capital by learning the most effective methods of operation. Flying all
over the country and noting different ways to run a business, Walton
accumulated a wide array of business models to develop his own, using
what he believed to be the most successful practices. Described by
Fortune magazine as "an admirer and student of Kmart," Walton
was later named one of Fortune's Top 10 CEOs of All Time. During
Wal-Mart's fledgling years, Walton spent time and money learning
the trade from his competition. That investment made in intangible
capital (knowledge) can be considered similar to an investment in
physical capital. With some lag, Walton's knowledge would
eventually pay off, adding to Wal-Mart's output production by way
of efficiency. This heightened efficiency would then contribute to TFP
growth.
Wal-Mart is often cited as a leader in using information
technology. Walton discusses how he chose to adopt computerization. He
discusses how Wal-Mart maintained inventory through lists that they
updated manually. At that time other retailers were moving toward
computerization. Walton says "I made up my mind I was going to
learn something about IBM computers. So I enrolled in a school for
retailers in Poughkeepsie, New York" (Walton and Huey, p. 107).
Significantly, Walton used this opportunity to recruit talented
individuals to work for Wal-Mart. Additionally, Walton recruited
Wal-Mart's team from other successful retailers. Though this would
seem to benefit Wal-Mart at the expense of other retailers, the overall
advantage came from the increased competition for the entire industry.
Outside human capital accumulated by scouting other companies for
talented individuals who knew the field and free riding off knowledge
learned elsewhere--this contribution of knowledge also appears in TFP
measures.
Insights from the case study
The preceding discussion of developments in the trade sector, along
with the quantitative evidence on the TFP acceleration, suggests some
admittedly speculative insights into the U.S. productivity acceleration.
In particular, as many people have noted, the acceleration coincided
with accelerated price declines for computers and semiconductors; but,
as we just saw, most of the TFP acceleration appears to have taken place
outside of ICT production, such as in retail trade. How are these two
observations related?
First, as the retail discussion suggested, innovation is a
challenge for the measurement of real output. Information technology
makes it possible for retailers to keep track of a much larger variety
of goods and to operate much larger stores. Consumers likely value the
greater variety of goods that they get access to; this variety thus
suggests that consumers get a higher quality shopping experience.
Correcting for this quality improvement suggests that we currently
overstate prices and understate real output, as Nakamura (1997, 1998)
argues. But as Kay (2003) suggests, some consumers may also be getting a
less pleasurable shopping experience--offsetting some of that higher
quality shopping experience.
It is worth mentioning, however, that innovation and the ensuing difficulties in disentangling price from quantity are not new. Although
most people suspect that information technology has made the measurement
problems worse, Triplett (1997) expresses skepticism, noting that these
difficulties existed in the past as well. De Long (1998) argues that
because of unmeasured improvements in the quality of goods and services,
real incomes per work hour plausibly rose thirtyfold over the preceding
century, compared with the sixfold increase one would find if one simply
looked at the Historical Statistics of the United States. DeLong's
discussion, in particular, highlights the vast range of new products
available late in the twentieth century that were unavailable at any
price in the late nineteenth century (and, as he suggests, makes it
difficult to capture changes in living standards in a single number).
For example, DeLong (2000) writes of the shortcomings of life in the
mid-nineteenth century as follows:
I would want, first, health insurance:
the ability to go to the doctor and be treated
with late-twentieth-century medicines.
Franklin Delano Roosevelt was crippled
by polio. Without antibiotic and adrenaline
shots I would now be dead of childhood
pneumonia. The second thing I would want
would be utility hookups--electricity and gas,
central heating, and consumer appliances.
The third thing I want to buy is access to
information--audio and video broadcasts,
recorded music, computing power, and
access to databases. None of these were
available at any price back in 1860.
I could substitute other purchases for
some. I could not buy a washing machine,
but I could (and would) hire a live-in laundress
to do the household's washing. I could
not buy airplane tickets; I could make sure
that when I did travel by long distance train
and boat I could do so first class, so that
even though travel churned up enormous
amounts of time it would be time spent relatively
pleasantly. But I could do nothing for
medical care. And I could do nothing for access
to information, communications, and
entertainment technology save to leave the
children home with the servants and go to
the opera and the theater every other week.
How much are the central heating, electric
lights, fluoridated toothpaste, electric toaster
ovens, clothes-washing machines, dishwashers,
synthetic fiber-blend clothes, radios,
intercontinental telephones, xerox machines,
notebook computers, automobiles, and
steel-framed skyscrapers that I have used so
far today worth--and it is only 10 A.M.?
Of the products DeLong lists, only notebook computers are clearly
associated with the late 1990s.
Second, in retailing, many innovations implemented by retailers
were accompanied by capital investment in computers or structures (for
example, the big box format). In essence, the innovation often required
reorganization at the level of the establishment, firm, or
industry--which requires tangible physical changes. This can make it
difficult to disentangle anecdotally the role of TFP from the role of
capital deepening. But conceptually, innovations in computers per se
should not show up as faster technology change in retailing: For a
retailer, a new computer represents capital deepening, and growth
accountants take account of that. (And, indeed, we found that in
retailing, there was a slower pace of capital deepening in the late
1990s than in the 1977-95 period.)
Computer innovations would show up as retailing TFP to the extent
that computers have an abnormally large return or to the extent that
investments in computers are correlated with other, unobserved
innovations by retailers. Indeed, many of the key innovations took place
in retailing per se, for example, organizational changes that were made
possible by information technology but nevertheless required substantial
investments of time and resources by retailers to implement.
A growing literature on ICT as a "general purpose
technology" (GPT) suggests important--but often indirect and hard
to foresee--potential ways for ICT to affect measured production and
productivity in sectors using ICT. (17) Conceptually, one can separate
these potential links into two categories: purposeful co-invention,
which we interpret as the accumulation of "complementary
capital," which leads to mismeasurement of true technology; and
externalities of one sort or another.
For example, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2003) find that in a sample of
527 large U.S. firms from 1987 to 1994, the benefits of computers for
output and productivity rise over time. The full benefits do not appear
to be realized for at least five to seven years. They interpret their
results as suggesting the importance of combining computer investments
with "large and time-consuming investments in complementary inputs,
such as organizational capital."
Basu, Fernald, Oulton, and Srinivasan (2003) suggest that these
indirect effects that arise from general purpose technologies such as
ICT are akin to what Einstein, in the context of particle physics,
called "spooky action at a distance": Quantum physics predicts
that in some circumstances, actions performed on a particle in one
location instantaneously influence another particle that is arbitrarily
far away. In terms of the effects of ICT, an innovation in one sector,
ICT, often causes unexpected ripples of co-invention and co-investment
in other sectors, such as retail trade. Many of the GPT stories (for
example, Bresnahan and Trajtenberg, 1995, or Helpman and Trajtenberg,
1998) fall into this "spooky action" camp. (Of course,
Einstein's spooky action was instantaneous; the effects of GPTs are
not.)
Basu, Fernald, Oulton, and Srinivasan (2003) discuss the
difficulties in measuring the "intangible investment" that
firms accumulate in the form of organizational knowledge. The resulting
"organizational capital" is, to some extent, analogous to
physical capital in that companies accumulate it in a purposeful way.
Basu et al. interpret this complementary capital as an additional input
into a standard neoclassical production function; it differs from
ordinary capital and labor in that it is not directly observed but must,
somehow, be inferred. (18) When resources (for example, labor time and
effort) are diverted from production to investment in this stock of
unobserved complementary knowledge, measured output and TFP fall; over
time, the service flow from that unobserved stock of knowledge raises
measured output and TFP. This story is reasonably consistent with the
experience in retail trade, where inputs grew more quickly in the
pre-1995 period, while output grew more quickly in the post-1995 period.
In addition, the GPT literature suggests the likelihood of sizeable
externalities to ICT. For example, successful new managerial ideas--such
as those implemented in retail trade--seem likely to diffuse to other
firms. Imitation is often easier and less costly than the initial
co-invention of, say, a new organization change, because you learn by
watching and analyzing the experimentation, the successes and,
importantly, the mistakes made by others. (19)
Third, the complementary innovations by ICT users, and any
spillovers, take time to show up. Sam Walton, for example, benefited in
the 1980s and 1990s from knowledge he accumulated flying around the
country visiting competing discount stores and attending IBM conferences
in the 1960s and 1970s. More formally, Basu et al. (2003) find that
industries that had high growth rates of ICT capital in the 1980s or
early 1990s tended to have faster TFP growth rates in the late 1990s.
Importantly, benefiting from ICT requires substantial complementary
investments in learning, reorganization, and the like, so that the
payoff in terms of measured output may be long delayed.
Conclusion
In this article, we have argued that the acceleration in TFP was
relatively broad based, with much of it occurring in industries that
used, not merely in industries that produced, information and
communications technology. Thus, it appears that ICT users themselves
introduced a lot of innovations in the way they did business.
Nevertheless, as the experience of retail trade suggests, many of
these innovations took advantage of the opportunities opened up by
developments in ICT. We view the experience of retail trade as
consistent with stories of ICT as a general purpose technology. GPT
stories generally suggest a subtle, nuanced, but potentially
far-reaching role for ICT to affect the economy. In particular, ICT
induces innovations by ICT-users both in the methods or processes they
use to produce and in the products themselves, in ways that are often
hard to forecast.
APPENDIX
Framework for traditional growth accounting
If the economy's output increases, then someone must have
produced it. In our empirical work, we think of the economy as
comprising a large number of firms and industries. But to fix ideas, we
start by assuming that the economy has an aggregate production function
that relates its overall real output Y to inputs of capital K and labor
L. Output also depends on the level of technology, A. Output goes up if
the economy's capital or labor input increases or if technology
improves. We write this function as:
A1) Y = A x F(K,L).
The relationship in equation A1 is relatively intuitive. For
example, the United States produces more output than India each year,
even though India has a much larger labor force (and many more employed
workers) than the United States. Equation A1 suggests that either the
United States has more capital than India, or the United States is more
efficient at converting inputs into output (that is, A is higher in the
United States), or (most likely) both.
More closely related to the focus of this paper, U.S. nonfarm
business output increased more than sixfold between 1948 and 2000;
equation A1 says that this reflects increases in capital, labor, or
technology. According to BLS data, over this same time period, total
labor input (adjusted for changes in the composition of the labor force)
increased two and a half times, while capital input increased about
eightfold.
But what was the role of technological innovations? With a few
assumptions about the production function in equation A1, we can be more
precise about the role of technological innovations versus input
increases in explaining output growth. To begin, we assume that the
production function has constant returns to scale in inputs. This
assumption implies that if we change all inputs by a given factor, then
output changes by the same proportion; for example, if we increase
capital and labor inputs by 10 percent each, then output also rises by
10 percent.
In the U.S. example, of course, inputs did not increase
proportionately--capital input grew much faster. So how much should we
weight each factor? Suppose labor input, say, rises by a small amount
dL, while nothing else changes. The resulting increase in output, which
we denote dY, is approximately equal to the following:
dY = MPL x dL.
MPL is the marginal product of labor, that is, it tells us how much
extra output one gets from a little bit more labor input. (In calculus terms, MPL [equivalent to] [delta]Y/[delta]L.) By dividing through by Y
and rearranging, one finds:
dY/Y = [MPL x L/Y](dL/L).
The left-hand side, dY/Y, is the percent change in output--that is,
the actual change dY divided by the level E Similarly, dL/L is the
percent change in labor input. In words, if labor input rises by, say,
10 percent ((dL/L) = 10 percent), then output growth equals an
elasticity [MPL x L/Y] times 10 percent.
With some further assumptions about how firms behave, we can gain
further insight into this output elasticity. Suppose a firm operates in
a competitive market (so it takes its output price as given) and hires
one additional worker. The benefit is that the firm gets MPL more units
of output, which it sells at price P; the cost equals the wage, W. If
the firm seeks to maximize profits, it will hire workers as long as the
additional revenue it earns exceeds the wage it must pay. The firm stops
hiring when the benefits and costs are just equal at the margin:
P x MPL = W.
Rearranging, we find an equation for labor's output
elasticity:
MPL x L/Y = WL/PY [equivalent to] [s.sub.L].
Hence, the output elasticity is equal to labor's share in
output, [s.sub.L], which in turn equals payments to labor, WL, as a
share of the total value of output, PY.
Similarly, suppose R represents the rental cost of capital to a
firm; if the firm owns the capital, then this rental cost is the
implicit "user cost" or opportunity cost of the capital to the
firm. Following the same logic as with labor, the elasticity of output
with respect to capital is:
MPK x K/Y = RK/PY [equivalent to] [s.sub.K].
In practice, wages are generally easier to observe directly than is
this rental value, since firms often own the capital and do not make an
explicit, observable payment. But suppose we are willing to assume that
firms earn zero economic profits. Then, by definition, the value of
output equals the cost of production; the cost of production, in turn,
equals the value of payments to capital and labor. That is,
A2) PY = WL + RK.
If we take equation A2 as an accounting identity, then we can take
capital's share of output as a residual:
RK/PY = 1 - WL/PY
[right arrow] [s.sub.K] = 1 - [s.sub.L].
We can now return to the question of how output growth is related
to input growth and technological improvement. Following the same
argument we made earlier, we can again differentiate equation A1, this
time allowing all inputs as well as technology to change, we find:
A3) dY/Y = (1 - [s.sub.L])(dK/K) + [s.sub.L](dL/L)+(dA/A).
This equation shows that for output to grow, either inputs must
increase, or technology must improve. This equation also allows us to
"account" for growth, by attributing output growth to
increases in particular factors or else to technology. In practice, we
observe (or can estimate) output growth and growth in capital and labor;
we observe labor's share in output. Although we don't observe
technology directly, we can estimate it as a residual:
A4) (dA/A) = dY/Y - (1 - [s.sub.L])(dK/K) - [s.sub.L](dL/L).
Suppose inputs don't change. Then output only changes if this
so-called "total factor productivity" (TFP) residual, or Solow
residual, changes. (1) Although we think of it as a broad measure of the
economy's technological possibilities, it will capture all sorts of
things. These include pure technological innovations (for example,
faster computers); managerial innovations such as workplace
reorganization that allows the firm to produce more output from a given
quantity of inputs; "cost reductions" that allow a firm to
produce the same quantity of output using less input; and any spillovers
of knowledge from other firms, for example, on how best to benefit from
information technology.
Why do we care about TFP growth? First, TFP growth allows us to
increase the amount of output we produce--and hence, how much we have
available to consume today or invest for the future--without having to
increase the amount we use of any input. This is clearly good for
society. Second, economists generally argue that in the long run, TFP
growth is the only means of getting sustained increases in standards of
living, or output per worker. The reason is that capital is generally
thought to have a "diminishing marginal product." In other
words, for a given number of workers, suppose we increase the quantity
of capital. It is reasonable to expect that the marginal contribution of
that capital falls, since we have to spread the same workers over more
machines and structures. As a result, investment alone cannot lead to
sustained increases in standards of living--as the marginal product of
capital declines, the extra capital leads to little or no extra output.
A complementary way to look at this question on standards of living
is that one can show that TFP growth is identically equal to a weighted
average of real factor prices, W/P and R/P. Thus, if TFP growth rises,
either real wages or real payments to capital rise. Thus, if we want to
raise real wages without reducing returns to capital, we need TFP
growth. (2)
(1) This derivation follows Solow (1957). Hence, dA/A is often
referred to as the Solow residual. In addition to TFP or the Solow
residual, this measure is sometimes referred to as multifactor
productivity.
(2) To show this, consider the accounting identity in equation A2
again, but think of it as applying at an economy-wide level rather than
a firm-level; this is just the national accounts identity, which tells
us that total income equals total output. Taking the total
differential--allowing all prices and quantities to change--yields:
PdY + YdP = [WdL + LdW] + [RdK + KdR].
With considerable rearrangement, one finds that TFP growth equals a
weighted average of real factor prices:
dY/Y - (1 - [s.sub.L])(dK/K) - [s.sub.L](dL/L) = [s.sub.L][dW/W -
dP/P] + (1 - [s.sub.L][dR/R - dP/P].
TABLE 1
Output, inputs, factor prices, and TFP--Nonfarm business sector
(average annual percent change)
Labor Capital Average Real wage
TFP Output input input labor share growth
1 2 3 4 5 6
1948-2000 1.18 3.66 1.77 4.06 0.69 1.91
1948-1973 1.90 4.10 1.45 3.91 0.69 2.79
1973-1995 0.38 2.95 1.98 3.94 0.69 0.76
1995-2000 1.13 4.54 2.46 5.37 0.67 2.55
Real rental
growth
7
1948-2000 -0.45
1948-1973 -0.14
1973-1995 -0.50
1995-2000 -1.83
Note: Real labor compensation and rental rate of capital are deflated
using the output deflator.
Source: Data obtained from the U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of
Labor Statistics website on Multifactor Productivity, at
www.bls.gov/web/prod3.supp.toc.htm.
TABLE 2
Total factor productivity growth by industry in private non-farm
business, 1990-2000 (percent change, annual rate)
Productivity (value- Share of nominal
added terms) (b) value added
pre-1995 post-1995 Acceleration 2000
Private non-farm economy
(adjusted for labor
quality) (a) 0.59 1.92 1.32 100.0
Contribution of labor
quality 0.32 0.16
Private non-farm economy
(not adjusted for labor
quality) 0.91 2.08 1.17
Mining 3.08 -2.15 -5.23 1.6
Manufacturing 2.40 2.76 0.36 20.6
Nondurables 1.02 -1.20 -2.22 8.7
Durables 3.47 5.61 2.14 12.0
Construction 0.39 -0.98 -1.38 6.1
Transportation 1.69 1.53 -0.16 4.2
Communication 2.31 0.15 -2.16 3.7
Electric/gas/sanitary 0.42 0.17 -0.25 2.9
Wholesale trade 1.66 5.37 3.71 9.2
Retail trade 0.83 5.33 4.50 11.8
Finance & insurance 0.44 3.39 2.96 10.7
Finance 1.31 4.90 3.59 7.5
Insurance -1.49 -0.06 1.44 3.2
Business services & real
estate 1.12 0.40 -0.72 13.9
Business services 0.60 -1.40 -2.00 7.1
Real estate 1.55 2.34 0.79 6.8
Other services -1.89 0.08 1.97 15.2
ICT producing (c) 5.52 11.02 5.50 5.3
Non ICT producing 0.61 1.54 0.93 94.7
Well-measured industries
(d) 1.80 3.17 1.37 54.2
Well-measured
(excluding ICT
producing) 1.35 2.24 0.88 48.9
(a) For productivity purposes, our definition of private non-farm
business excludes holding and other investment offices along with
miscellaneous services, since consistent input and output data are
unavailable for these industries.
(b) Value-added TFP growth is defined as (gross output TFP growth)/(1
- share of intermediate inputs). Implicitly, this uses the Tornqvist
index of value added for a sector.
(c) ICT-producing includes industrial machinery and electronic and
other electrical equipment sectors.
(d) Well-measured industries include mining, manufacturing,
transportation, communication, electric/gas/sanitary, and wholesale and
retail trade.
Sources: Authors' calculations based upon data from Bosworth and
Triplett (2003), the Bureau of Economic Analysis, and the Bureau of
Labor Statistics.
NOTES
(1) See Jorgenson (2001) or Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2002) for
reviews of the empirical literature on the productivity acceleration and
the role of information technology. We discuss this literature in
greater detail later.
(2) In our view, more studies than not find a widespread
acceleration in technology, for example, Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro
(2001), Baily and Lawrence (2001), Bosworth and Triplett (2002), Council
of Economic Advisers (2003), Jorgenson, Stiroh, and Ho (2002), Nordhaus
(2002), Oliner and Sichel (2000), and Stiroh (2002a, 2002b). Gordon
(2003) remains a skeptic.
(3) See, for example, Basu and Fernald (2001).
(4) The productivity literature (for example, Jorgenson, Gollop,
and Fraumeni, 1987) tends to prefer to use gross-output residuals, with
explicit accounting for intermediate inputs. This literature then uses
"Domar weights" (the ratio of industry gross output to
aggregate value added) to get aggregate residuals. Apart from
approximation error, this is equivalent to estimating industry
value-added residuals and then using value-added weights. Thus, our
approach of focusing on value added is conceptually equivalent to the
standard gross-output approach. If the assumptions of constant returns
and perfect competition do not hold, however, then not only does TFP not
properly measure technology, but for econometric analysis the use of
value added versus gross output may make a difference; for a discussion
of this point, see Basu and Fernald (1995, 2001).
(5) We thank Jack Triplett for sending us their industry dataset
that merged the BEA and BLS data. Basu, Fernald, Oulton, and Srinivasan
(2003) updated the BEA data to incorporate November 2002 NIPA industry
revisions and also to remove owner-occupied housing. The BEA labor
compensation data do not include proprietors or the self-employed, so we
follow Bosworth and Triplett in using BLS data that correct for this. We
thank Larry Rosenblum at the BLS for sending us unpublished industry
hours data, which make adjustments for estimated hours worked by
non-production and supervisory employees as well as the self-employed.
We updated the BLS capital data from www.bls.gov/web/prod3.supp.toc.htm
(downloaded December 2002). We follow Bosworth and Triplett and exclude
several service sectors where consistent input or output data are
unavailable: holding and other investment offices, social services,
membership organizations, and other services. The dataset, along with
further details on its construction, is available on request.
(6) With Tornqvist aggregation, aggregate TFP growth is a weighted
average of industry gross-output TFP growth, where the so-called Domar
weights equal nominal industry gross output divided by aggregate value
added; the weights thus sum to more than one. In continuous time, this
is equivalent to first converting gross-output residuals to value-added
terms by dividing by one minus the intermediate share and then using
shares in nominal value added. (In discrete time, using average shares
from adjacent periods, they are approximately equivalent.) Basu and
Fernald (2001) discuss this aggregation and its extension to the case of
imperfect competition; see also Oulton (2001).
(7) As noted earlier, the acceleration exceeds that in product-side
BLS data shown in table 1.
(8) The BEA industry data come from the income-side of the national
accounts, which, as is well known, accelerated faster than the
expenditure side in the late 1990s. See Bosworth and Triplett (2002) for
an extensive discussion of the difference between TFP growth calculated
with industry data and with the aggregate BLS data.
(9) We would note that Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2002), who use
output data from the BLS Office of Employment Projections, do not find
as important a contribution from the trade sectors.
(10) The CEA methodology is very similar to that of Oliner and
Sichel (2002), who report no TFP acceleration outside of ICT production.
But Oliner and Sichel discount their finding on this score, since their
method takes non-ICT TFP as a residual. Since the Oliner-Sichel
end-point is a recession year, 2001, they point out that any cyclical effects on productivity are forced to show up in non-ICT TFP. In
addition, the CEA measure of labor productivity is a geometric average
of income- and product-side measures of output per hour.
(11) Some recent research has looked at whether the results cited
here are robust to deviations from the usual growth-accounting
assumptions that all industries have constant returns to scale and
operate under perfect competition; that firms can quickly and costlessly
adjust their levels of inputs; and that we observe all variations in
input use--that is, there is no unobserved utilization margin. In terms
of variable utilization, Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro (2001), Council of
Economic Advisers (various years), and Baily and Lawrence (2001) all
argue that variations in utilization, that is, cyclical mismeasurement
of inputs, play little if any role in the U.S. acceleration of the late
1990s. Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro also find little role in the
productivity acceleration for deviations from constant returns and
perfect competition. Basu, Fernald, and Shapiro do find a noticeable
role for traditional adjustment costs associated with investment.
Because investment rose sharply in the late 1990s, firms were,
presumably, diverting an increasing amount of worker time to installing
the new capital rather than producing marketable output. In other words,
if there are costs of adjusting the capital stock and faster growth
leads to higher costs, then true technological progress was faster than
measured. These considerations strengthen the conclusion that the
technology acceleration was broad-based, since service and trade
industries invested heavily in the late 1990s and, hence, paid a lot of
investment adjustment
(12) McKinsey (2001) provides anecdotal as well as quantitative
evidence on the transformation of wholesale and retail trade; Foster,
Haltiwanger, and Krizan (2002) link the retail industry data to
firm-level developments.
(13) BEA definition can be found in Industry Input-Output
Methodologies at www.bea.gov/bea/mp.htm.
(14) Sieling, Friedman, and Dumas (2001) and Foster, Haltiwanger,
and Krizan (2000) focus on detailed establishment-level data using
Census Bureau data on retail sales as their measure of (gross) output.
Hence, one needs to keep in mind that some studies use a different
definition of output. Nevertheless, although the Census Bureau and BEA
measures differ, they nevertheless share identical definitions of
value-added output.
(15) Robert Gordon (2003) discusses the importance of the "big
box" format that retailers like Wal-Mart follow. He argues Europe
has yet to reap the benefits of scale economies in retailing due to
strict regulations against large stores, which may help to explain the
productivity gap between Europe and the U.S. On the other hand, John Kay (2003) cautions that it is difficult to control for changes in
quality--many small markets in Europe, while they may not stock as many
products as Wal-Mart, are in many cases a tourist attraction because of
the charm and pleasure associated with visiting them.
(16) Wal-Mart's market share was calculated as Wal-Mart's
reported total net sales for 2002 over total U.S. retail sales in that
year.
(17) See, for example, Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000) and Bresnahan
(2001) for a discussion of the kinds of complementary investments and
co-invention that firms undertake in order to benefit from ICT, given
its "general purpose" attributes. David and Wright (1999)
provide a nice historical reflection on general purpose technologies.
(18) Much of Brynjolfsson's work tries to quantify the role of
unobserved complementary capital. Macroeconomic studies of the effects
of organizational capital include Greenwood and Yorokoglu (1997),
Hornstein and Krusell (1996), Hall (2001), and Laitner and Stolyarov
(2003).
(19) Bresnahan (2001) provides a nice discussion of the channels
for externalities to operate. Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1995) highlight
both "vertical" externalities (between general purpose
technology producers and each application sector) and
"horizontal" externalities (across application sectors).
REFERENCES
Aaronson, D., and D. Sullivan, 2001, "Growth in worker
quality," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Vol. 25, No. 4, pp. 53-74.
Baily, M. N., and R. Lawrence, 2001, "Do we have a new
e-conomy?," American Economic Review, Vol. 91, pp. 308-312.
Basu, S., and J. G. Fernald, 2001, "Why is productivity
procyclical? Why do we care?," in New Developments in Productivity
Analysis, C. Hulten, E. Dean, and M. Harper (eds.), Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
--, 1995, "Aggregate productivity and the productivity of
aggregates," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 532.
Basu, Susanto, John G. Fernald, Nicholas Oulton, and Sylaja
Srinivasan, 2003, "The case of the missing productivity growth: Or,
does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the
United States but not the United Kingdom?," Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, working paper.
Basu, S., J. G. Fernald, and Matthew D. Shapiro, 2001,
"Productivity growth in the 1990s: Technology, utilization, or
adjustment?," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public
Policy, Vol. 55, pp. 117-165.
Bell, David, and Ann Leamon, 1998, "Note on the retailing
industry," Harvard Business School Case, May 13, at
http://harvardbusinessonline.hbsp.harvard.edu/.
Bosworth, B. P., and J. E. Triplett, 2002,"
'Baumol's Disease' has been cured: IT and multifactor
productivity in U.S. services industries," Brookings Institution,
manuscript.
Bresnahan, T. F., 2001, "The mechanisms of information
technology's contribution to economic growth," paper prepared
for presentation at the Saint-Gobain Centre for Economic Research.
Bresnahan, T. F., and M. Trajtenberg, 1995, "General purpose
technologies: 'Engines of growth?'," Journal of
Econometrics, Vol. 65, January, special issue, pp. 83-108.
Brookings Institution, 2002, "Summary of the workshop,"
Workshop on Economic Measurement Service Industry Productivity: New
estimates and new problems," May 17, available at
www.brook.edu/es/research/projects/productivity
/workshops/20020517_summary.pdf, downloaded March 16, 2003.
Brynjolfsson, E., and L. M. Hitt, 2003, "Computing
productivity: Firm-level evidence," Massachusetts Institute of
Technology, eBusiness@MIT, working paper, No. 139, June.
--, 2002, "Computing productivity: Firm-level evidence,"
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Sloan School, working paper, No.
4210-01, revised November 2002.
--, 2000, "Beyond computation: Information technology,
organizational transformation and business performance," Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 23-48.
Brynjolfsson, E., and S. Yang, 2001, "Intangible assets and
growth accounting: Evidence from computer investments,"
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, manuscript.
Council of Economic Advisers, 2003, "Annual report of the
Council of Economic Advisers," Economic Report of the President,
February.
--, 2001, "Annual report of the Council of Economic
Advisers," Economic Report of the President, January.
David, P. A., and G. Wright, 1999, "General purpose
technologies and surges in productivity: Historical reflections on the
future of the ICT revolution," Stanford University, manuscript.
De Long, J. B., 2000, "The U.S. economy 'back on
top'?: Economic growth and the rhetoric of national power," in
The U.S. at the Turn of the Millennium, Robert Brenner, (ed.).
--, 1998, "How fast is modern economic growth?," Weekly
Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, October 16.
Domar, Evsey, 1961, "On the measurement of technological
change," Economic Journal, Vol. 71, No. 284, December, pp. 709-729.
Feldstein, M., 2001, "Comments and analysis," The
Financial Times, June 28.
Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger, and C. J. Krizan, 2002, "The link
between aggregate and microproductivity growth: Evidence from retail
trade," National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper, No.
9120.
Gordon, R., 2003, "High tech innovation and productivity
growth: Does supply create its own demand?," National Bureau of
Economic Research, working paper, No. w9437.
Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell, 1997, "Long run
implications of investment-specific technological change," American
Economic Review, Vol. 87, pp. 342-362.
Greenwood, J., and M. Yorokoglu, 1997, "1974,"
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 46, pp.
49-95.
Griliches, Z., 1994, "Productivity, R&D, and the data
constraint," American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 1, pp. 1-23.
Hall, R. E., 2001, "The stock market and capital
accumulation," American Economic Review, Vol. 91, December, pp.
1185-1202.
Helpman, E. (ed.), 1998, General Purpose Technologies and Economic
Growth, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Helpman, E., and M. Trajtenberg, 1998, "Diffusion of general
purpose technologies," in General Purpose Technologies and Economic
Growth, E. Helpman (ed.), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Hobijn, B., and B. Jovanovic, 2001, "The
information-technology revolution and the stock market: evidence,"
American Economic Review, Vol. 91, December, pp. 1203-1220.
Holmes, T. J., 1999, "Bar codes lead to frequent deliveries
and superstores," Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Staff
Report, No. 261.
Hornstein, A., and P. Krusell, 1996, "Can technology
improvements cause productivity slowdowns?," in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, B. Bernanke and J. Rotemberg (eds.), Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Howitt, P., 1998, "Measurement, obsolescence, and general
purpose technologies," in General Purpose Technologies and Economic
Growth, E. Helpman (ed.), Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT Press.
Jorgenson, D. W., 2001, "Information technology and the U.S.
economy," American Economic Review, Vol. 91, March, pp. 1-32.
Jorgenson, Dale W., Frank M. Gollop, and Barbara M. Fraumeni, 1987,
Productivity and U. S. Economic Growth, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Jorgenson, D. W., M. S. Ho, and K. J. Stiroh, 2002, "Growth of
U.S. industries and investments in information technology and higher
education," Harvard University, manuscript, October 7.
Jorgenson, D. W., and K. J. Stiroh, 2000, "Raising the speed
limit: U.S. economic growth in the information age," Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1, pp. 125-211.
Jovanovic, B., and P. L. Rousseau, 2003, "Mergers as
reallocation," New York University, unpublished, February.
Kay, John, 2003, "A walk on Menton's marche municipal
reveals how the conclusions regarding differences in productivity among
countries, can be both obvious and meaningless," Financial Times,
August 28, at www.johnkay.com/print/297.html.
Krusell, P., L. Ohanian, J. Rios-Rull, and Gianluca Violante, 2000,
"Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic
analysis," Econometrica, Vol. 68, September, pp. 1029-1054.
Kumar, Nirmalya, 1996, "The power of trust in
manufacturer-retailer relationships," Harvard Business Review, Vol.
74, No. 6, pp. 92-106.
Laitner, J., and D. Stolyarov, 2003, "Technological change and
the stock market," American Economic Review.
Lynch, L., and S. Nickell, 2001, "Rising productivity and
falling unemployment: Can the U.S. experience be sustained and
replicated?," in The Roaring Nineties, A. Krueger and R. Solow
(eds.), New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
McKinsey Global Institute, 2001, "U.S. productivity growth
1995-2000: Understanding the contribution of information technology
relative to other factors," Washington, DC, October.
Nakamura, Leonard, 1998, "The retail revolution and food-price
mismeasurement," Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, May/June.
--, 1997, "Is the U.S. economy really growing too slowly?
Maybe we're measuring growth wrong," Business Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, March/April.
Nordhaus, W. D., 2002, "Productivity growth and the new
economy," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2.
Oliner, S. D., and D. E. Sichel, 2002, "Information technology
and productivity: Where are we now and where are we going?,"
Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Vol. 87, No. 3, pp.
15-44.
--, 2000, "The resurgence of growth in the late 1990s: Is
information technology the story?," Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 14, Fall, pp. 3-22.
Oulton, N., 2001, "Must the growth rate decline? Baumol's
unbalanced growth revisited," Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 53, pp.
605-627.
Raff, D., and Peter Temin, 1997, "Sears Roebuck in the
twentieth century: Competition, complementarities, and the problem of
wasting assets," National Bureau of Economic Research, historical
working paper, No. 102.
Shapiro, M., 1986, "The dynamic demand for capital and
labor," Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Sieling, Mark, Brian Friedman, and Mark Dumas, 2001, "Labor
productivity in the retail trade industry, 1987-99," Monthly Labor
Review, December, PDF (74K), pp. 3-14.
Solow, Robert M., 1957, "Technical change and the aggregate
production function," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39,
No. 3, pp. 312-320.
Stiroh, K. J., 2002a, "Are ICT spillovers driving the New
Economy?," Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 48, No. 1, pp. 33-58.
--, 2002b, "Information technology and the U.S. productivity
revival: What do the industry data say?," American Economic Review,
Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 1559-1576.
Triplett, J. E., 1997, "Measuring consumption: The post-1973
slowdown and the research issues," Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, July 2.
Vance, Sandra A., and Roy V. Scott, 1994, Wal-Mart: A History of
Sam Walton's Retail Phenomenon, New York: Twayne.
Walton, Sam, and John Huey, 1992, Sam Walton: Made In America, New
York: Bantam Books.
John G. Fernald is a senior economist and economic advisor and
Shanthi Ramnath is an associate economist in the Economic Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors thank
Susanto Basu, Jeff Campbell, Craig Furfine, and Spencer Krane for
helpful comments.