Interest rates and the timing of new production.
Jovanovic, Boyan ; Rousseau, Peter L.
Introduction and summary
Policymakers are naturally interested in the effects of interest
rates on various economic activities. This article studies how interest
rates affect entrepreneurs' propensities to initiate new projects.
Since the implementation of new ideas and production techniques is an
important engine driving long-run economic growth, the effect of real
rates on this activity should be of particular interest. This article
illustrates that the effect of interest rates on the incentives to
implement is not monotonic. Starting at high interest rates, a fall in
the interest rate will spur entrepreneurs to implement projects more
rapidly. But lowering interest rates even further will only persuade
entrepreneurs to delay.
Ordinarily it would be difficult to measure the extent of delay,
since we cannot easily identify when an economic agent first received
the opportunity to bring a project to fruition. To get around this, we
look at initial public offerings (IPOs). Although the decision to issue
an IPO may reflect a host of considerations, Jain and Kini (1994) find
that IPOs appear to be related to growth in investment and sales. More
importantly, we can measure the amount of time that transpired between
when a firm was founded or incorporated and when its IPO was issued, so
we have a reasonable proxy for the delay time. Data on the time it takes
firms to go public show a non-monotonic correlation between interest
rates and the age at which the firm goes public. High rates of interest
induce a delay and discourage investment for the usual reason, namely
that when future income is discounted more heavily, it is not worthwhile
to sacrifice current resources. Very low rates of interest, however,
also discourage investment, because profits that are foregone during the
delay are not as costly in comparison with the gains to delaying.
Chetty (2001) has shown that irreversibility of investment can lead
to a non-monotonic relation between interest rates and investment. In
his two-period model, if investment is postponed to the second period,
the firm can better react to news about demand conditions. Aside from
offering a different model, we also provide evidence on the
non-monotonicity. In earlier work, Jovanovic and Rousseau (2001) show
that the incentive to delay implementing a project gets stronger as the
interest rate falls. In that paper, we also provide an
information-theoretic rationale for the gains to waiting, but do not
give any evidence.
The non-monotonicity of physical investment in the interest rate
stems, ultimately, from the fact that the firm is giving up profits
while it waits to implement its project. The decision to wait itself
delivers information, that is, human capital, hence what is really
happening is a substitution of one form of capital for another. We
comment on this again in the conclusion and the implications that it may
have for countries like Japan that are experiencing low investment, in
spite of enjoying very low interest rates.
In the next section, we explain the model, and in the following
section we describe its main implications for the data that we have.
Then, we test those implications and discuss some related literature.
The model
The following model is a simplified version of Jovanovic and
Rousseau (2001). Suppose the firm lives forever and has the property
rights to its project. When implemented, the project produces output
using knowledge and physical capital k. The firm starts to receive net
revenue cash only after it implements the project. Let T denote the
waiting time until implementation. Suppose that while it waits, the
firm's potential output is
y = f(T).
We assume that f increases with T but at a diminishing rate, as
drawn in figure 1. In this formulation the firm starts receiving y only
after implementing the project. At that point the project starts
yielding profits. Moreover there are no direct costs. In that case the
implementation decision is much like the decision of how long to remain
in school. This is like perfecting an idea before taking out a patent on
it.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Choosing the implementation date when there is no physical capital
If the firm lives forever and has the property rights to its
project, it must just decide when to implement it. There are no direct
costs. Only implicit "foregone-earnings" costs. The problem we
analyze is similar to the well-known tree-cutting problem in economics,
in which one wants to figure out the optimal time to cut down a tree.
The trade-off involved is that between selling a young tree for cash
today as opposed to selling a more mature tree for more cash tomorrow.
The rate of interest has an important influence on that trade-off.
Formally, the firm's problem is that of choosing the
implementation date T to maximize the present value of its future net
revenues
[e.sup.-rT] [1/r] f(T).
One can show that the optimal timing will satisfy the following
equation:
1) f(T) = [1/r] f'(T).
The left-hand side of equation 1 is the foregone-earnings costs of
waiting another period. In the problem as stated, this is the only cost.
The right-hand side is the gain from waiting. Since this gain is
received in every subsequent (production) period, it is capitalized, and
hence the r in the denominator. It is more revealing to write the
condition as
2) g = r,
where
g [equivalent to] f'(T)/f(T)
is the rate of growth of potential output. Thus, the implementation
occurs when g equals the rate of interest.
Example
As an example, consider f(t)=At[alpha], where [alpha] < 1.
Here the condition reads [alpha]/T = r, so that
3) T = [alpha]/r.
In this simple version of the model, then, a rise in the rate of
interest hastens the implementation because it makes the
foregone-earnings cost of waiting more important relative to the future
gains from waiting. Interestingly, the productivity of the firm, A, does
not affect the firm's implementation date because it simply scales
both costs and revenues in the same proportion.
The parameter [alpha] will be important in what follows. It
measures the gain in productivity that the firm gets by delaying its
implementation. Delay lets the firm resolve technological uncertainties,
perfect its ideas, and choose the right inputs for its production
process.
Adding physical capital
To the extent that implementation entails spending on capital goods (as suggested by the evidence in Jain and Kini, 1994), this implies that
the effect of the real rate of interest on investment is unambiguously
positive! Lower rates discourage implementation by inducing firms to
wait longer so as to perfect their investments. The only cost is that of
the profits that are postponed--a foregone-earnings cost.
In reality, firms must incur direct costs of implementation.
However, these direct costs now introduce a new consideration: Higher
interest rates imply it is better to defer these costs into the future
since their present value is smaller. This suggests that lowering the
interest rate will mitigate the incentive to delay, and that ignoring
fixed costs of implementation (even if they do not correspond to
measured investment) may be misleading. Therefore, we now introduce
capital expenditure of I that is incurred at the implementation date.
This modifies the firm's problem to one of choosing T to maximize
the following present value:
[e.sup.-rT] {-I + [1/2] f(T)}.
One can now show that the optimal timing will satisfy the following
equation:
4) rI - f(T) + [1/2] f'(T) = 0,
so that instead of equation 2, the condition of optimality reads
5) g = r - (I/f(T)) [r.sup.2].
Now g is essentially a quadratic in r. When r is small, the effect
of r on g is positive as before, but when r gets large, the opposite is
true, and the effect of r on g is non-monotonic. Note, too, that the
coefficient on [r.sup.2] is the capital output ratio. As a result, the
effect on T is non-monotonic too, and with it the effect on
implementation investment.
The example again
To illustrate this, let us return to and augment the example f(t) =
A[t.sup.[alpha]] we outlined above. The firm's problem becomes one
of choosing T to maximize the following present value:
[e.sup.-rT] {-I + [1/r] A[T.sup.[alpha]]}.
Figure 2 plots the optimal implementation delay on the vertical
axis and the rate of interest on the horizontal axis. We see that for a
smaller r, the term 2/r dominates, driving T to infinity. For a larger
r, the term rI/A dominates, again driving T to infinity. We therefore
have a U-shaped relation between r on the horizontal axis and T on the
vertical, as illustrated in figure 2 for the case where I = 30A. We also
plot T for the case where I = 45A, and I = 60A. We note that 1) the
curves bottom out at levels of r ranging between 5 percent and 10
percent, and 2) higher investment outlays imply longer waiting at all
levels of the interest rate. For practical purposes, however, the size
of the outlay, I, starts to matter only when the interest rate is
relatively high, say above 4 percent.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Implications of the model
The model has time-series and cross-sectional implications. The
time-series implications concern low-frequency movements in T and the
market value of the firm at IPO, which we denote as
v = [e.sup.-rT] {-I + [1/r] A[T.sup.[alpha]]}. We are especially
interested
in the relation between interest rates and IPO investment. The
model assumes that r is fixed, and therefore we may, at best, take
figure 2 to predict the effects on T of low-frequency movements in r.
These movements will induce changes in total investment spending--the
total outlays on I--that we associate with implementation investment.
The above framework lets us derive the following results.
Relationship between time to go public and the real interest rate
At low frequencies, the relation between T and r is U-shaped, as
figure 2 shows. This means that the investment schedule is backward
bending. We note that the negative relationship that emerges at low
levels of the real rate is more pronounced than the positive relation at
higher rates and that such high rates are not often observed.
Relationship between investment and the real interest rate
The results on the effects of r on T can now be translated into
results for IPO investment. A rise in T means that investment is
postponed. Consider the stock of new projects that need implementing.
Into this stock there is an inflow of new projects as entrepreneurs get
new ideas and at the same time an outflow due to projects being
implemented. Investment will be proportional to the outflow of projects,
because any project that is implemented requires investment. An increase
in T will imply that the current cohort of projects will take a long
time to leave. But if the inflow of ideas is constant, in the new steady
state the outflow will be constant as well. Any effects of changes in T
will only affect the transitional path.
The size of this transient effect will depend on the difference
[T.sub.NEW] - [T.sub.OLD]. To see this more clearly, consider an economy
that has a constant inflow of ideas. If a change in r (perceived by
firms to be permanent) raises T, then strictly speaking we should see no
investment at all for [T.sub.NEW] - [T.sub.OLD] periods, followed
immediately by the same steady state investment rate as took place
before the change. Conversely, if a change in r lowers T, then there
would immediately be a burst of investment that implements all existing
ideas that are older than [T.sub.NEW]. The general point is that
interestrate variation at low frequencies will produce changes in
investment that are in the direction opposite to the change in T, and
this change is related to the level of [T.sub.NEW].
Roughly speaking, then, decade to decade, we may expect a negative
relation between T and implementation investment. Therefore, the
relation between investment on the vertical axis and the rate of
interest on the horizontal should have an inverted-U shape. We
illustrate this in figure 3. The vertical axis shows the ratio I/T
plotted against r by decade. The curves cross because T is increasing in
I, and the ratios are not ordered the same way at different levels of r.
But what is important here is the inverted-U shape in the graph and this
is what we are looking for in the data.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
IPO-issuing firms versus stock-market incumbents
Our model derives implementation lags from the improvement of
projects prior to their implementation. It is the upward slope in figure
1 that creates the incentive for a firm to delay implementation while
the project is improved and refined. The returns to waiting should, in
turn, depend on how uncertain the environment is for the firm and its
project. These uncertainties are likely to be greater for new products
and new markets, and it is in such products and markets that new firms
predominate. IPO-issuing firms tend to be new, or they at least tend to
be younger than most established corporations. Therefore, we expect to
see a difference between the investment behavior of entrants and
incumbents.
The parameter that the model isolates in this regard is [alpha].
The curvature of f is likely to be larger, and the returns to waiting
likely to be smaller, for established firms. This is most evident in
equation 3, where a low [alpha] reduces the incentive to delay and
therefore mitigates the forces that we have been describing here. In the
expanded version of the model where we allow for physical investment,
this simply means that the incentive to delay because of improving the
project is weaker relative to the standard considerations of comparing I
with discounted profits.
As a result, we expect to find a quantitative difference between
the estimated investment schedules of incumbents and IPO-issuing firms.
Even for incumbents, the incentives to delay should be there, but they
should be much smaller. We thus expect to see less of a backward bend,
if any, in the investment schedules of established firms.
Tests of the implications
Having listed the main implications of the model, we report on how
they fare with the data, taking them up in the same order as above. IPOs
provide a context for measuring a delay until investment--Jain and Kini
(1994) find that IPOs are associated with a rise in investment and
sales. Our use of IPO data in testing the theory is reasonable if:
1. Funds are a constraint for private companies;
2. IPOs can deliver the funds for a significant expansion; and
3. Upon the initial expansion, the firm is irrevocably defined and
its IPO investments cannot be reversed.
When these assumptions hold at least approximately, we may
interpret the firm's age at the IPO date as a proxy for the delay
time to investment. Some of the costs incurred at IPO are transaction
costs--Lee et al. (1996). We lump all costs into I and treat them as
"investment." (1)
Testing the relationship between time to go public and the real
interest rate
The first implication says that the relation between T and r should
be U-shaped. To measure T, we construct average waiting times from
founding and incorporation to stock-exchange listing since 1886, based
on individual company histories and our extension of the stock files
distributed by the University of Chicago's Center for Research in
Securities Prices (CRSP) from its 1925 starting date back through 1885
using newspaper sources. (2) Figure 4 shows these series after smoothing
with the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Table 1 shows the coverage of our
collection of IPO waiting times by decade. Waiting times by either
measure were longest in the 1950s and 1960s and shortest at both ends of
the twentieth century.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
To what extent do these waiting times reflect waiting to implement
projects? According to figure 4, the smoothed number of years between
founding and listing ranges from ten to 60 years. It is hard to believe
that a firm delays entirely for the purpose of perfecting and honing and
then finally initiating its project when it goes public. Moreover, many
profitable firms remain private. The time it takes to go public probably
depends on several factors that are absent from our model. What matters,
however, is time variation in the time to go public, which, barring any
technological changes, is probably driven partly by incentives that we
have modeled. While it may at first seem unlikely that the age at IPO
should have increased by 15 years or 20 years in the 1940s entirely in
response to interest rates, figure 2 shows that the model is able to
generate very sharp increases in waiting times as interest rates near
zero. Indeed, this is a robust implication. From equation 5 it follows
that as the interest rate tends toward zero, the waiting time goes to
infinity. No other parameter restrictions are required for this
conclusion to hold. It is also true, however, that the relation is much
steeper at low rates than it is at high rates. Thus, the greatest
potential of this model to explain waiting times is when interest rates
fluctuate around a low level.
Figure 5 shows the real interest rate on commercial paper with
30-90 days until maturity from 1885 to 2002, along with an HP-filtered
(Hodrick-Prescott) trend. (3) Real rates were lowest in the middle of
the twentieth century, and the series is roughly U-shaped. The long wait
times in the 1950s and the corresponding negative real interest rates
appear roughly consistent with our model. To examine the low-frequency
relationship between T and r more precisely, however, we average both
across ten-year periods and test for non-monotonicity with a quadratic
regression.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figure 6 shows a scatterplot of averages by decade of T on r, with
T measured by the number of years from founding to exchange listing.
Figure 7 instead uses years from incorporation as the measure of T. In
either case, a U-shaped pattern appears in the data. The regressions in
table 2 confirm this, with the coefficient on the real interest rate
negative and significant at the 5 percent level for the linear term and
positive (though not significant) for the quadratic term. We interpret
this as supporting evidence for the first implication of our model. We
note, however, that negative real interest rates are inconsistent with
the model and that instead of varying between 0 percent and 10 percent
(as the interest rate does in the theoretical plots of figures 1-3), the
decade averages vary from about -3 percent to 7 percent.
[FIGURES 6-7 OMITTED]
Testing the relation between investment and the real interest rate
The second implication deals with the relation between IPO
investment and the real rate of interest. In testing for this, we
provide a parallel analysis of the relation between aggregate investment
(which is dominated by investment of stock-market incumbents) and the
rate of interest. We do this to contrast the two relationships.
IPO-issuing firms probably face much greater uncertainty than
incumbent firms. IPO-issuing firms are in the process of defining
themselves, their products, and their technologies, and once they have
chosen these directions, there is no going back for most of them.
Choosing the wrong standard, for example, can condemn a new business to
an early demise. There is a real sense, then, in which their investments
are irreversible.
Incumbent firms, on the other hand, have chosen their domains of
operation and face uncertainty more in the scale of demand, input
prices, and so on. For these firms, there is less to be gained by
waiting because there is less uncertainty to be resolved by delaying
investment. Therefore, we would expect the investment of incumbents to
be negatively related to the rate of interest. So, while we do not offer
a model of incumbent investment, we note that the standard Q-theory
model of investment (for example, Hayashi, 1982) with convex adjustment
costs and no irreversibilities, predicts that a rise in the interest
rate reduces investment.
Our model implies that, unlike incumbent investment, the relation
between IPO investment and the rate of interest should be an inverted-U.
Figure 8 shows the two investment series that we consider. The yellow
line is private domestic investment as a percentage of the aggregate
capital stock. (4) The black line is the value of IPO-issuing firms at
the end of each year as a percentage of total stock market
capitalization. (5) While investment rates tended to rise until the
Great Depression and then stabilized after World War II, IPOs followed a
more erratic pattern, with the value of new equity largest around the
turn of the twentieth century, around 1915, in the late 1920s, at the
end of World War II, in the late 1960s, the mid-1980s, and the 1990s.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
To examine the low-frequency relationship between these measures of
investment and r more precisely, we again average across ten-year
periods.
Figure 9 shows a scatterplot of decade averages of r on IPO value,
along with the fitted values from a quadratic regression. Figure 10
shows the scatterplot and quadratic regression line for incumbents'
investments.
We report the details of the quadratic regressions and their linear
counterparts in table 3. For IPO investment, the linear term is positive
and statistically significant at the 5 percent level, while the
coefficient on the quadratic term is negative and approaching
statistical significance. We interpret this as evidence for the inverted U-shape that the model predicts. With incumbent investment, we also find
an inverted U-shape, but the coefficient on the linear term is much
smaller and not statistically significant.
[FIGURES 9-10 OMITTED]
Summary of the empirical results
To the extent that we may proxy implementation delays by the ages
of firms at their IPOs, our results, on the whole, confirm the
implications of the model. This is especially true for the
backward-bending IPO-investment schedule. We did not find such evidence
for the investment of established firms.
Our focus has been on the individual firm's decision and not
the aggregate equilibrium aspects surrounding IPOs. Had we analyzed
these, we would have needed to mention economies of scale in IPO
activity and start-up activity (for example, due to concentration of
venture capital focus) and to discuss the models of Diamond (1982) and
Veldcamp (2003) that could perhaps explain some IPO waves.
We have assumed that, at IPO, the public pays exactly what the firm
is worth. In a more expansive paper, one could entertain a hypothesis of
"irrational exuberance," or times when the public is willing
to pay more than the firm is worth. Along the lines of Shleifer and
Vishny's (2003) paper on mergers, one could argue that perhaps
IPO-issuing firms wait in the wings in order to take advantage of such
exuberance. If so, the beneficiaries are neither the IPO-issuing firms
nor the participating venture capitalists themselves. Data from Ritter (2003a, b) show that, despite being times of high IPO volume, high-Q
periods are, in fact, times of more severe underpricing of firms going
public. In other words, models in which a naive shareholder buys
overpriced firms will not explain the time-series correlation between
the volume of IPOs and Tobin's Q. Perhaps it is only the investment
bankers who benefit from such exuberance.
Conclusion
We have presented and tested a neoclassical model with liquidity
constraints. In this model, delay to implementation occurs because the
firm is trying to improve its idea to the point where it becomes optimal
to incur the fixed cost of implementing a project.
The broader implication of our work here is that lowering interest
rates may impede new ideas rather than foster them. But this does not
mean that low interest rates are bad for firms, even when they lead
firms to postpone their investment. Regardless of how investment reacts,
the value of projects rises as the interest rate falls.
Nor do our results say that low interest rates discourage all
investment broadly defined. Our finding that at low rates
physical-capital investment rises with the interest rate is really about
the composition of capital. A delay is a switch of one kind of
investment profile for another. When the reason for delaying is the
gathering of information, total investment (including information
investment) may still be monotone-decreasing in the interest rate. Firms
postpone physical investment, but they gather information, and this is
human capital. Before implementing its project, the value of that
project is monotone-decreasing in the interest rate, and that
value--that is, the value of the physical and human capital combined--is
being maximized by the firm's policy. Thus, when physical
investment rises with the interest rate, this simply means that the
firm's human capital investment is falling, and perhaps its total
capital properly measured. Therefore, for example, the Japanese economy
may be in better shape than it seems today because the very individuals
that are not investing may be accumulating a different kind of capital
that is not measured as such.
REFERENCES
Berry, T. S., 1988, Production and population since 1789: Revised
GNP series in constant dollars, Richmond, VA: The Bostwick Press,
Bostwick Paper, No. 6.
Bradstreet Co., 1885-1925, Bradstreet's, New York: Bradstreet
Co., various issues.
Buera, Francisco, 2003, "A dynamic model of entrepreneurship
with borrowing constraints," University of Chicago, manuscript,
November.
Chetty, Raj, 2001, "Interest rates, learning, and business
investment under uncertainty," University of California, Berkeley,
manuscript, December.
Choe, Hyuk, Ronald Masulis, and Vikram Nanda, 1993, "Common
stock offerings across the business cycle," Journal of Empirical
Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 3-31.
Diamond, Peter, 1982, "Aggregate demand management in search
equilibrium," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, No. 5,
October, pp. 881-894.
Dun and Bradstreet, Inc., 2003, D&B Million Dollar Directory,
Bethlehem, PA: Dun and Bradstreet Inc. Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis, 2003, "Federal Reserve economic data (FRED)," database.
Hayashi, Fumio, 1982, "Tobin's marginal q and average q:
A neoclassical interpretation," Econometrica, Vol. 50, No. 1,
January, pp. pp. 213-224.
Homer, Sidney, and Richard Sylla, 1991, A History of Interest
Rates, third edition, New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.
Jain, Bharat A., and Omesh Kini, 1994, "The post-issue
operating performance of IPO firms," Journal of Finance, Vol. 49,
December, pp. 1699-1726.
Jovanovic, Boyan, and Peter L. Rousseau, 2001, "Why wait? A
century of life before IPO," American Economic Review, Papers and
Proceedings, Vol. 91, No. 2, May, pp. 336-341.
Kelley, E. M., 1954, The Business Founding Date Directory,
Scarsdale, NY: Morgan and Morgan.
Kuznets, Simon S., 1961a, Capital in the American Economy: Its
Formation and Financing, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
--, 1961b, "Annual estimates, 1869-1955," Johns Hopkins
University, Baltimore, MD, manuscript. Lee, Inmoo, Scott Lockhead, Jay
Ritter, and Quanshui Zhao, 1996, "The costs of raising
capital," Journal of Financial Research, Vol. 19, No. 1, Spring,
pp. 59-74.
Lowry, Michelle, 2002, "Why does IPO volume fluctuate so
much?," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 67, No. 1, pp. 3-40.
Moody's Investors Service, 1920, 1929, 1931, 1941, 1951, 1956,
1961, Moody's Industrial Manual, New York: Moody's Investors
Service.
Moskowitz, Tobias J., and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen, 2002,
"The returns to entrepreneurial investment: A private equity
premium puzzle?," American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 4,
September, pp. 745-778.
National News Service, 1885-1925, The Commercial and Financial
Chronicle, New York, various issues. New York Times Co., The, 1897-1928,
The New York Times, New York, various issues.
--, 1913-1925, The Annalist: A Magazine of Finance, Commerce, and
Economics, New York, various issues.
Ritter, Jay, 2003a, "Long-run returns on IPOs from
1970-2002," University of Florida, manuscript.
--, 2003b, "Some factoids about the 2002 IPO market,"
University of Florida, manuscript, January.
Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny, 2003, "Stock market driven
acquisitions," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 70, No. 3,
December, pp. 295-311.
Standard and Poor's Corporation, 1981, 1988, 2000, 2002, Stock
Market Encyclopedia, New York.
--, various years, Stock Reports, New York: Standard and
Poor's Corporation.
United States Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2003, Survey of Current
Business, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.
University of Chicago, Center for Research on Securities Prices,
2002, CRSP Database, Chicago. Veldcamp, Laura, 2003, "Media
frenzies in markets for financial innovation," New York University,
manuscript, June.
NOTES
(1) Other evidence shows that increasing funds for investment is
indeed one of the motives behind an IPO. Jain and Kini (1994, table 2),
for example, find that by the fourth year after its IPO, the firm will
experience a rise in sales of 80 percent compared with its industry
counterparts and 143 percent compared with its own sales in the year
just before the IPO (also see Choe, Masulis, and Nanda, 1993; Lowry,
2002; and Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen, 2002). We find that the
1955-2001 correlation between funds that firms take in at IPO and their
real investment is 0.33 and highly significant.
Our assumption that the firm's investment occurs at the time
of IPO brings us closer to the literature on liquidity constraints. When
an entrepreneur has a high return activity that he cannot fund in the
capital market, he has a greater incentive to save, because those
savings can fund an investment that is more profitable than the average
market investment. Buera (2003) analyzes optimal saving behavior by
liquidity-constrained entrepreneurs.
(2) Listing years after 1925 are those for which firms enter CRSP.
For 1885-1924, they are years in which prices first appear in the New
York Stock Exchange (NYSE) listings of The Annalist, Bradstreet's,
The Commercial and Financial Chronicle, or The New York Times. The 6,632
incorporation dates used to construct figure 4 are from Moody's
Industrial Manual (1920, 1928, 1955, 1980), Standard and Poor's
Stock Market Encyclopedia (1981, 1988, 2000), various editions of
Standard and Poor's Stock Reports, and Mergent Online. The 4,221
foundings are from Dun and Bradstreet's Million Dollar Directory
(2000), Moody's, Etna M. Kelley (1954), and individual company
websites. We linearly interpolate the series between missing points
before applying the HP-filter to create the time series in the figure.
(3) Commercial paper rates are annual averages of 30-day terms from
the FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data) database for 1934-2002 and
60-90 day terms from Homer and Sylla (1991) for earlier years. We
compute the ex post return by subtracting inflation as computed by the
growth of the implicit price deflator for gross domestic product (GDP)
from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (2003) for 1929-2002 and
Berry (1988) for earlier years.
(4) To build the investment rate series, we start with gross
private domestic investment in current dollars from the U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis (2003, table 1, pp. 123-124) for 1929-2001 and then
ratiosplice the gross capital formation series in current dollars,
excluding military expenditures, from Kuznets (1961b, tables T-8 and
T-8a) for 1870-1929. We construct the net capital stock using the
private fixed assets tables of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (2003)
for 1925-2002. Then, using the estimates of the net stock of
non-military capital from Kuznets (1961a, table 3, pp. 64-65) in 1869,
1879, 1889, 1909, 1919, and 1929 as benchmarks, we use the percent
changes in a synthetic series for the capital stock formed by starting
with the 1869 Kuznets (1961a) estimate of $27 billion and adding net
capital formation in each year through 1929 from Kuznets (1961b) to
create an annual series that runs through the benchmark points. Finally,
we ratio-splice the resulting series for 1870-1925 to the later BEA
series. The investment rate that appears in figure 8 is the ratio of our
final investment to the capital stock series, expressed as a percentage.
(5) The stock market data are from the CRSP files and our backward
extension of them to 1885. NYSE firms are available in CRSP
continuously, AMEX firms after 1961, and NASDAQ firms after 1971. New
listings are given by the total year-end market value of firms that
entered our database in each year, excluding American depository receipts (ADRs).
Boyan Jovanovic is a professor of economics at the University of
Chicago and New York University, a research associate of the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), and a consultant to the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. Peter L. Rousseau is associate professor of
economics at Vanderbilt University and a research associate of the NBER.
The authors thank the National Science Foundation for financial help.
TABLE 1
Firms in the waiting-time sample
Number of
new CRSP Number of Number of
Decade listings incorporations foundings
1890-99 112 52 41
1900-09 112 78 44
1910-19 214 190 97
1920-29 545 492 273
1930-39 231 197 78
1940-49 271 246 97
1950-59 254 241 78
1960-69 2,008 964 198
1970-79 4,517 1,405 262
1980-89 6,322 904 790
1990-99 7,850 1,539 1,939
2000-02 1,311 324 324
Total 23,747 6,632 4,221
TABLE 2
Regressions of waiting times (T) on the real
commercial paper rate (r) by decade, 1886-2002
Dependent variable
T from founding T from incorporation
-3.47 -5.58 -1.71 -2.96
[r.sub.t]
(-2.23) (-2.46) (-1.77) (-2.07)
[r.sup.2.sub.t] 0.63 0.37
-1.25 -1.17
constant 41.68 39.46 21.11 19.81
(8.37) (7.65) (6.80) (6.10)
[R.sup.2] .33 .43 .24 .34
N 12 12 12 12
Note: T-statistics are in parentheses.
TABLE 3
Regressions of IPOs and the investment rate
on the commercial paper rate (r) by decade, 1886-2002
Dependent variable
IPOs / Stock
market I/K
0.20 0.56 -0.16 0.21
[r.sub.t]
(0.86) (1.71) (-0.66) (0.61)
[r.sup.2.sub.t] -0.11 -0.11
t
(-1.48) (-1.45)
constant 3.13 3.51 6.37 6.76
(4.23) (4.71) (8.08) (8.49)
[R.sup.2] .07 .25 .04 .22
N 12 12 12 12
Note: T-statistics are in parentheses.