Estimating U.S. metropolitan area export and import competition.
Testa, William ; Klier, Thomas ; Zelenev, Alexei 等
This article calculates estimates of the extent to which U.S.
cities' manufacturers face competition from foreign producers.
Foreign and U.S production can compete in the U.S. domestic market,
foreign markets, or both. Accordingly, this article examines measures of
metropolitan-area (MSA) level import competition, based on each
city's industrial composition and industry-level data on import
competition, as well as measures of metro-level export competition,
based on U.S. export data. With these measures, we evaluate whether the
growth experience of U.S. cities that face high competition from foreign
producers substantially differs from that of cities with low
competition. Measures of import and export competition at the MSA level
may be helpful to metropolitan area residents and policymakers in
evaluating their own actions in various arenas such as household
movements, investment, and local development.
The International Trade Administration (ITA) tracks exports from
U.S. metropolitan areas. However, there are no comparable statistics of
actual imports into particular metropolitan areas. Nor, even if they
existed, would such figures be particularly useful in measuring the
degree to which metropolitan area economies (and their local industries)
are impacted by import competition. To the extent that the manufacturing
sector of a metropolitan area sells much of its output to markets
located outside of its own metropolitan area, own-industry imports at
the metropolitan area level would not fully measure the degree of
competition to this metropolitan area's producers. As an
alternative to such a hypothetical measure of local imports, we
construct measures of metropolitan areas' exposure to national or
U.S. market import competition.
In examining trends in imports into the U.S. market over time, we
find robust growth in imports of manufactured goods during the 1990s. As
one measure, we allocate such imports--good by good--to each
metropolitan area based on its own size and mix of manufacturing
industries. In constructing these estimates, we find a wide variation
across U.S. metropolitan areas in import market share and in the growth
of such imports from 1989 to 1999. A rapidly growing share of imports,
however, does not necessarily accompany local production decline or
stagnation, because rising imports may also be associated with a rising
domestic demand for these products. For example, imagine the rapidly
rising U.S. imports for pharmaceuticals not necessarily displacing
domestic production, but simply serving a growing market (perhaps fueled
by an aging U.S. population).
A separate and different accounting of import behavior over time,
the degree of "import penetration," measures the extent to
which the domestic U.S. market for goods is served by foreign sources
rather than domestic producers. Here again, we find a wide regional
variation, both for the current period and across time. Such evidence of
market penetration does not, of course, measure changes in the economic
well-being of workers and firms. Imports of capital goods and technology
also assist domestic industry to improve and stay competitive in its
production and export activity. Indeed, imports are often not final
goods but intermediate products used in the production of other goods,
which are ultimately sold both domestically and abroad. (1) And
importantly, imports of consumer goods presumably improve well-being and
quality of life for U.S. individuals and households. Even on its
production side, displacement of manufacturing by imports may result in
reallocation of workers and capital to higher-valued production, for
example, in exports, non-traded goods, or in the service sector. In
these ways, enhanced imports can lift domestic production and income
rather than retard them.
On the export side, we analyze data gathered by the International
Trade Administration for large metropolitan areas. These data are
reported with several user cautions, the most important of which is that
the production locale of exported goods often remains unknown or is
misleading, with the reported geography perhaps attributed to the place
of final shipment of goods by an intermediary or perhaps to an affiliate
of the manufacturer, rather than to its origin of production. To offset
the possible slant of these data toward cities where exports are shipped
abroad or otherwise affiliated, we construct an alternative,
hypothetical measure of exports. This measure allocates U.S. exports by
location of similar production activity; in particular, it allocates
exports associated with an individual industry in proportion to each
MSA's employment share of that same industry in the U.S. Such a
measure, imperfect in its own way, is slanted toward production origin
of the good rather than toward the place of shipment. Both measures
indicate a wide range of openness across individual metropolitan areas.
In comparing the two measures of exports, we find significant and
systematic differences, suggesting that each measure may reflect a
different dimension of metropolitan area exports--both point of
production and point of shipment overseas. As evidence, we find that
metropolitan areas with large transportation sectors tend to have higher
rankings in the ITA's reported MSA export series. The presence of
large manufacturing company headquarters, however, does not appear to
slant reported ITA export figures in any systematic way.
Given that our import measures are constructs rather than observed
data, we would like to test whether these measures lend themselves to a
plausible interpretation. We examine the cross-sectional growth behavior
of metropolitan areas' net job creation in manufacturing from 1989
to 1999. Using a single-equation ordinary least square (OLS) regression,
we regress the growth rate of manufacturing jobs on the growth rates of
exports, import market growth, and export and import penetration
specific to each U.S. metropolitan area. In this exercise, we find
statistically significant regression coefficients that are plausible.
That is, trends toward import penetration of an area's local
industries are associated with short-term manufacturing job disruption
(declines) in a metropolitan area; export growth is associated with
manufacturing gain. Yet this simple modeling exercise does not allow
firm inferences about causality. For example, increased metro area imports could be a response to a negative technology shock affecting a
specific industry in the home country that faces import competition.
In the next section, we begin by looking at some previous studies
of imports into the U.S. and then describe our measures of import
sensitivity. In the following section, we focus on exports.
Imports
Previous attempts at attributing U.S. imports to regions have been
made at broad geographic levels. In their work on the potential impact
of the North American Trade Agreement (Nafta), Hayward and Erickson
(1995) allocate manufactured imports from Canada and Mexico by
individual industry in proportion to each state's share of domestic
shipments by that industry. They find much variation among states, and
highlight the fact that these trade flows are smaller than most people
believe. Hervey and Strauss (1998) allocate manufactured imports for an
industrial aggregation at the even-broader "durable" and
"nondurable" industry categories, though in the process, they
are able to identify imports as coming from 44 individual foreign
countries. They attribute high overall import shares to the
manufacturing East South Central and East North Central regions. These
high import shares are ambiguous in that they might represent either
imports into a region or that region's competition for markets
served in the remainder of the U.S.
In this section, we improve on these import allocations in two
respects. First, we use a much narrower industry breakdown to allocate
finely defined U.S. imported goods to particular metropolitan areas.
Using employment data for U.S. counties from the County Business
Patterns (CBP) data, we can identify four-digit Standard Industrial
Classification (SIC) based industry definitions for manufactured
products. (2) This use of narrow industry definition means, for example,
that automotive production (and attendant import competition) need no
longer be erroneously attributed to the state of Washington; domestic
aircraft production need not be erroneously attributed to Detroit.
A second refinement is that imports can be attributed to
metropolitan areas rather than to states and multi-state regions.
Metropolitan area economies are more cohesive than state or multi-state
economies, in that they share a common work force and transportation
infrastructure. In addition, metropolitan areas are not so arbitrarily
defined by jurisdictional boundaries, as are state economies, for
example. (3)
Import trends
Manufactured imports into the U.S. grew rapidly for most of the
1990s. This is not surprising, given that import growth is strongly
influenced by the overall growth of the home country's economy.
From 1991, the trough of the previous economic downturn, to 2000, the
peak of the expansion, total U.S. imports increased by $722 billion in
nominal dollars, and by $616 billion (or 109 percent) as deflated by the
general price index for U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) (figure 1).
Indeed, import expansion outpaced the more general and robust expansion
of the 1990s. As measured against the yardstick of (nominal) GDP,
(nominal) imports climbed from an 8.1 percent ratio to GDP in 1991 to
over 12 percent in 2000 (figure 2).
[FIGURES 1-2 OMITTED]
Import competition
How did the ran-up in imports play out across metropolitan areas?
In order to link national import growth to the industries of a
particular metropolitan area, we examine the industry-by-industry growth
of foreign imports in the U.S. market. Therefore, we allocate actual
U.S. imports by industry category to individual metropolitan areas
according to the metropolitan presence of that same industry. In
particular, we use employment data by industry at the county level of
geography to construct a local employment share of each national
industry for each of 269 metropolitan areas in the United States for
1989 and 1999. (4) Each MSA's employment share of the nation for a
particular industry then becomes the metro area's share of national
imports for that industry. For each metropolitan area, the sum total of
these imports across all industries is taken as the measure of its total
import competition.
Thus, import competition in MSA i = Sum over j [M.sup.ij.sub.US]
where [M.sup.ij.sub.US] = [L.sup.ij] and = MSA i's share of U.S.
employment for good j. [M.sup.j] = U.S. imports of good j.
In examining the 25 most populous metropolitan areas in 1999, the
allocated import pattern reveals an approximate but imperfect
correspondence with the size of metropolitan population in 1999 (table
1). (5) Places with heavy manufacturing concentrations and large
economies--such as Southern California--have an outsized measured share
of estimated imports attendant to the region's industrial
structure. However, there is much variation in these import allocations
owing to varying industry (import) composition. As a yardstick, we can
compare allocated imports against the size of each metropolitan economy.
In order to do this, we construct estimates of gross metropolitan
product (GMP) for each metropolitan area and report imports as a share
of GMP. (6) For 1999, we find an estimated average ratio of imports to
gross product of 9.48 percent for the 25 most populous metropolitan
areas. The Detroit--Ann Arbor area is a leader in this measure with 19
percent. Heavy U.S. imports of automotive products--many of them from
nearby Canada--coupled with Detroit's sharp concentration in
automotive industries, lie behind the reported import competition.
Manufacturing and technology-intensive San Francisco--Oakland--San Jose
and Portland--Salem follow behind at 14 percent and 17 percent,
respectively. At the other end of the spectrum, the
Baltimore-Washington, DC area registers only 2 percent on this metric.
Looking more widely at all metropolitan areas taken as a group, the
largest metropolitan areas average less direct import competition in
manufacturing than smaller areas (figure 3). (7) In 1999, metropolitan
areas greater in population than 610,000 approached 10 percent in import
competition versus almost 17 percent for metro areas ranging in size
from 275,000 to 610,000. The import competition for smaller metro areas
differed little from this.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
From 1989 to 1999, import intensity for all metro areas grew
significantly, along with the general expansion of imports into the
national economy. However, the average differences between large and
small metro areas widened significantly, with the third quartile of
metro area--with 275,000-610,000 in population--growing the most, from a
ratio of 12 percent imports to GMP in 1989 up to almost 17 percent by
1999.
Are large metropolitan areas, then, not "open" economies
compared with small metropolitan areas? Large metropolitan areas have
increasingly become service economies and less hospitable to many types
of manufacturing. Congested highways and high land costs in many large
urban areas are not conducive to today's production processes in
manufacturing. Nor have the tendencies toward global competition made it
any easier for manufacturers in higher cost urban locales. In response,
many domestic manufacturing facilities have sought out lower cost
locales in small cities and rural areas, often adjacent or with close
access to divided highways and the interstate highway system. There are
countervailing forces at play, however. A counter-tendency has been the
surge in technology and information intensity of the U.S. economy--both
manufacturing and services alike. In this regard, urban areas are
thought to have an advantage because key inputs to high-tech
production--namely information and technology--may be acquired more
easily in urban areas. At the same time, high-tech manufacturing
industries often feature young firms that require proximity to the wide
array of specialized business, legal, and financial services that are to
be found in large cities. (8)
The high service intensity that is attendant to manufacturing may
also mean that data based on manufacturing location alone may belie the
actual openness of the largest urban area economies. Embodied in the
value of manufactured goods is an increasing service component--be it
advertising, design, maintenance, management, marketing, or research and
development. The service economy of a large city in America is in this
way an unseen portion of international trade in goods. Such
considerations are caveats to the traded good measures that we
construct, and these caveats are inherent in almost all data on traded
goods and their location of value added. More generally, globalization also means that the geography of production is stretched and expanded
across wider and wider landscapes, making it more difficult to determine
any meaningful and specific location of value added of exports.
Import penetration
An alternative way to measure imports into the U.S. domestic market
more directly reflects "competition" to U.S. producers. Import
penetration measures the ratio of imports for a particular industry to
the sum of imports plus that portion of domestic production that is not
exported abroad. Varying between zero and one, this measure of import
penetration shows the share of domestic sales of a good that is imported
rather than domestically produced. We measure an MSA's import
penetration as a weighted average of national import penetration for
each industry. For each metropolitan area, the weights are its own
industry employment shares across all of manufacturing.
Import penetration in MSAi = Sum over all industries j M[P.sup.i],
where M[P.sup.i] = [L.sup.ij] x M[P.sup.j] and [L.sup.ij] = MSAi's
share of its own manufacturing employment employed in industry j.
M[P.sup.j] = U.S. import penetration of good. (9)
Import penetration at the national level is often used to indicate
the degree to which domestic sales in an industry have been penetrated
or accounted for by imports, (10) For a particular region, we assume
that an industry domiciled there tends to sell much of its output across
the national domestic market. This assumption is somewhat realistic for
U.S. metropolitan area economies because the U.S. market remains the
primary market for domestic production plants. Exports as a share of
U.S. gross domestic production remain below 8 percent overall.
Meanwhile, domestic manufacturing plants sold between 64 percent and 82
percent of production domestically in the year 2000. (11)
We report import penetration estimates for the 25 most populous
MSAs for 1999 (table 2). We see a wide range, from an import penetration
of 11.7 percent for the Kansas City MSA, to upwards of 24 percent for
San Diego. A pattern emerges that seems to suggest that high import
penetration alone may not be indicative of local area industrial
stagnation. For example, many MSAs known for a concentration in high
technology also have high import penetration. These include Boston, the
San Francisco Bay area, San Diego, Portland, and Phoenix. Translating
metro area import penetration rates to the more familiar state level, we
can map the geography of import competition for the entire country
(figure 4 on p. 19). (12) One can see that in 1999 most of the states
east of the Mississippi River (bold line on map) experienced import
competition on par or above the U.S. average (16 percent). Somewhat
surprisingly, eight states west of the Mississippi generally not
associated with manufacturing report above-average levels of import
competition as well.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Increases in import penetration over time may be more reflective of
industrial competition. Here, the variation in growth of import
penetration is again very wide (see table 2). Metro areas such as Miami
and Kansas City registered under 30 percent growth in penetration from
1989 to 1999; metro areas as diverse as Seattle and Pittsburgh more than
doubled their import penetration over the same period.
Exports
The flip side of import penetration has been the rapid export
expansion of U.S. manufacturing. Both economic growth in overseas
markets and lower tariff barriers to trade have helped to expand U.S.
exports. Until the currency crises beginning in 1997, rapidly developing
countries in Asia such as Thailand, Malaysia, Korea, Singapore, and
Taiwan led the world in rates of economic growth. Though growth was
export-led there, imports of manufacturing goods from developed
countries--especially capital goods--grew as well, largely to meet the
development needs of manufacturing industries in these nations. The
manufacturing sectors of the industrial economies, including the U.S.,
grew rapidly to meet the demands of both the developing economies and a
general worldwide expansion.
The nominal value of manufactured exports attributed to U.S.
metropolitan areas was $567 billion for the last reported year, 1999, up
from $374 billion in the first reported year, 1993 (see figure 5).
Exports began to level off in 1997, coincident with the Asian economic
crisis. As measured against the gross domestic product of metropolitan
areas, exports declined from a peak of 8.8 percent in 1997 to 7.9
percent by 1999 (see figure 6).
[FIGURES 5-6 OMITTED]
For individual metropolitan areas, export data are telling but not
straightforward to interpret. The only publicly reported export figures
for MSAs are drawn from information of the U.S. Census Bureau, compiled
and reported by the International Trade Administration. In particular,
exports are reported by businesses in "export declarations,"
which identify location using five-digit zip codes. Yet the exporter of
record is not necessarily the entity that produced the merchandise, so
the data do not fully reflect the production origin of manufactured
goods. Instead, the exporter of record is the party "principally
responsible for effecting export from the United States." (13) This
means that if the exporter of record is a manufacturing company, the
location may either be the production plant or an administrative
establishment of the company, such as a corporate headquarters.
Similarly, exporters of record can be service companies, typically
wholesalers, but also other intermediaries, such as retailers. (14) This
means that the wholesaler, headquarters, or marketing arm of
manufacturing--to which the export may be attributed by the
data--actually tends to be responsible for some significant value added.
(15) Yet, the location of export production often tends to be
coincident, with wholesalers of a manufacturing product likely to locate
in the same region as the producer. The larger metropolitan areas are
likely to more accurately represent the location of value-added exports
because larger areas are more likely to contain all parties in the
transaction--all contributors to value added of the exported good.
Accordingly, we aggregate to the largest possible MSA geographic
definition, the so-called consolidated metropolitan statistical area or
CMSA. In this way, we minimize the errors inherent in geographical
assignment versus site of production. In addition, in reporting on
individual metropolitan areas, we focus on the largest MSAs. Wherever
possible, we exclude commodities, such as coal and minerals, from our
measures of manufacturing exports. Commodities are more likely to be
produced outside metropolitan areas, but to be shipped abroad from them.
(16)
Export levels tend to correlate with size of the metropolitan area.
As a result, a "mega-sized" NY-Long Island-Northern New Jersey
consolidated metropolitan area yields very large reported manufactured
exports, leading with $46.6 billion in 1999 (table 3). As we might
expect from their large size and manufacturing orientation, the greater
Chicago and Los Angeles areas round out the top three in value of
exports. However, the correspondence between size of economy and level
of exports is highly variable across the top 25 largest metropolitan
areas. The ratio of exports to gross metropolitan product averaged 8.7
percent in 1999, but the standard deviation was a sizable 5.2. At the
low end, service industry and domestically oriented regional areas such
as the Washington-Baltimore-Northern VA area reported a low 3.2 percent
of regional product. At the top of the spectrum, shipping-oriented and
aerospace-intensive Seattle reported a ratio of 25 percent. High-tech
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose (at 14.8 percent) aligns with our high
prior expectations for that economy. Auto-intensive Detroit-Ann
Arbor's ratio (at 17.2 percent) may be surprising to some, since
the automotive sector is not always known as a U.S. export industry.
However, the Detroit auto corridor to Ontario ranks among the most
integrated binational economic relationships in the world. (17)
Exports appear to have added to metro area growth in the 1990s,
assuming no displacement. For the 25 most populous regions reported in
table 4, estimated export growth added an average of 3.4 percent to the
size of metropolitan economies from 1993 to 1999. In comparison, import
growth (also measured against GMP) for the same period and sample
averaged 8.4 percent. The Asian crisis falloff post-1997 in U.S. exports
accounts for some of this difference; U.S. exports flattened out, even
while domestic demand (and import purchases) continued to grow robustly.
Export-led growth contributed more to large metropolitan area
economies than to smaller ones. Over the 1993-99 period, exports
contributed an average of over 3 percentage points to growth in
metropolitan areas with over 500,000 in population, versus just over 1
percent in the smallest population size category, 250,000 and less.
Can we generalize about export orientation by size of metro area
economy? Figure 7 confirms that larger metropolitan areas are more
export oriented. The top quartile, with population of 900,000 and above,
report a weighted average of over 8 percent exports in 1999. In
contrast, smaller metropolitan areas report smaller average export
intensities for 1999, with an average of 6.95 percent for the second
largest quartile, 6.36 for the third, and 6.74 for the fourth and
smallest quartile. Still, these data suggest that smaller metropolitan
areas do fully participate in export trade. In this regard, it is
noteworthy that export intensity increased across all MSA size classes
from 1993 to 1999.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
A different explanation for the high degree of export intensity in
the San Francisco Bay area is that reported exports may overstate actual
exports along some dimensions. In particular, seaports such as Portland
and San Francisco may have more exports attributed to them in the
reported data than they would under an alternative method that reflected
the origin of production. To explore the possible bias in the reported
export data further, we construct a second, hypothetical set of export
figures (see table 5). We allocate (impute) to metropolitan areas
national-level U.S. Department of Commerce, ITA data on exports. Export
data at the national level are available for detailed industry
classifications. We apportion these exports to particular metropolitan
areas according, again, to the area's national share of employment
in the corresponding industry. We then develop an overall measure of
exports from each metropolitan area by summing across all industries. In
this measure, since we are apportioning exports directly by the location
of production, the export total will tend to reflect "origin of
movement." Thus, this measure will have the opposite bias to the
reported exports, which may reflect point of shipment or arrangement to
ship. Note that there will be errors in assigning the exports in the new
measure due to the fact that not all industries in locales actually have
the same propensity to export. In addition, our measure assumes that
labor intensity is uniform geographically within each industry.
Looking individually at the most populous metropolitan areas, we
see a general tendency for the reported exports to exceed the estimated
and hypothetical measures, though this is not the case for nine of the
metro regions. More startling is the extent to which the reported metro
area figures exceed the production-oriented estimates that are imputed from ITA data in a number of metro areas with significant international
ports or trans-shipment industries: In New York, the reported data
exceed the imputed estimate by $22.2 billion (91 percent); in the San
Francisco Bay metro area by $18.7 billion (69 percent); in
Seattle-Tacoma by $18.5 billion (128 percent); in Miami by $11.6 billion
(207 percent); in Houston by $8.1 billion (72 percent); and in Detroit
by $15.8 billion (108 percent). On the other hand, interior cities such
as Denver, Dallas, and St. Louis display a hypothetical export base,
according to the production method of allocation, that is greater than
the reported export figures for these cities.
To explain the variance between these data series, we ran an OLS
regression with the metropolitan export estimates reported by the ITA as
the dependent variable (see table 6 on p. 24). We used the sample of all
208 metropolitan areas for which data were reported for 1998 and 1999.
We included an independent variable for each observed metropolitan area,
"percent of its employment in transportation industries," to
test for the effect of shipment rather than production location on
manufacturing exports. Even after accounting for the estimated exports
based on the location of manufacturing, the transportation variable is
positive and significant at the 1 percent level.
Another source of bias in the reported metro export series is
suspected to arise from the separate location of a manufacturer's
corporate headquarters from its production plants. In particular,
exports may tend to be attributed to the location of the headquarters
rather than to the location of the production plant. Large companies in
particular have a very high propensity to export, and they also tend to
have separate headquarters locations. Accordingly, the presence of a
single or multiple large company headquarters in an MSA might tend to
inflate the reported export figures compared with our estimated
(imputed) export figure, the latter being based on the production
employment location of industries. When we account for large
headquarters in our regression equation, we find no apparent systematic
relationship between headquarters location and the levels of reported
exports. Of course, there may be significant individual instances in
which large-scale exports are attributed to company headquarters, and
thereby serve to inflate the reported exports of particular MSAs.
Examining trade and growth
Are the measures of trade--exports, export competition, import
growth, and import penetration--meaningful measures that affect the
growth and composition of metropolitan areas? One way to explore this
question is to examine the relationship between MSA economic growth and
these trade-related measurements over time. To do that, we can relate
the growth or decline in MSA total manufacturing employment to changes
in these variables using multiple regression. We use manufacturing
employment as the growth indicator--the dependent variable to be
explained--owing to general data availability of these figures at the
MSA level of geography over the 1989-99 period. In particular, because
MSAs vary in size, we use the percent change in total manufacturing
employment as the dependent variable for the 269 U.S. MSAs.
The general estimation strategy is to examine a cross-sectional
panel of the percentage change in manufacturing employment--a variable
of growth relative to the size of each particular MSA over a ten-year
period. The estimation is in "changes" or first difference
form. This functional form has the advantage of differencing out
variables which presumably remain constant for individual MSAs over the
period, but which vary significantly in level across MSAs--the so-called
omitted variable problem. A possible downside is that, in first
differencing, any measurement errors in the regression variables tend to
be magnified--leading to inefficient estimators or large standard errors
in the coefficients.
The explanatory variables are also measured in percent changes, so
that the coefficients can be read as elasticities. In this, there are
two exceptions. One is that the MSA's predominant broad geographic
region is entered as a fixed effect. This is intended to pick up the
broad inter-regional shifts of economic activity, which have been taking
place from Frost Belt regions to Sun Belt and from the Northeast-Midwest
to the South and West. Population in particular has been shifting in
these directions, which would be especially reflective of regional
shifts in nontraded manufactured goods. A second exception is the
"size of MSA economy" variable. This measure reflects the fact
that production activity in general has been tending to deconcentrate from large metropolitan areas. This trend has been ongoing for 50 years
or more as production technology has been shifting from multi-story,
railroad-dependent, labor-intensive modes to low-slung, truck-intensive,
capital-intensive operations. We measure each of the remaining variables
as percent change and define them identically to those discussed in the
preceding sections.
In estimating this simple OLS regression, we find statistically
significant results that are plausible (table 7). That is, both export
and import growth are associated with manufacturing gains. That is
consistent with imports having grown faster in industries with a strong
expansion in domestic demand. (18) In addition, we find that import
penetration is negatively related to manufacturing employment (column
3). Thus, an increase in the level of imports as a share of domestic
demand is associated with lower labor usage over time across metro
areas. Similarly, we find a negative relationship between a change in
export intensity and manufacturing employment. A possible interpretation
is that U.S. industries may need to become more efficient in order to
compete in and capture foreign markets. Yet, caution is urged as this
simple modeling exercise does not allow for confident inferences about
causality. For example, increased metro area imports could be a response
to a negative technology shock affecting a specific industry in the U.S.
that faces import competition.
Conclusion
The process of globalization has moved ahead over the past ten to
15 years, albeit in fits and starts. Some have speculated that
metropolitan economies are sure to undergo restructuring and upheaval
attendant to globalization. Their industry structure and performance,
along with local wages and prices, are thought to be under pressure as
global integration gives rise to greater trade opportunities and
challenges. Many such changes will take place, regardless of direct
outflows and inflows of tradable goods. Still, measures of exports and
import competition may be important indicators to policymakers and
others of the sources and direction of upheaval and change. Both exports
and imports of manufactured goods have generally expanded for U.S.
metropolitan areas over the past decade or more--imports more than
exports--with wide variation across metropolitan areas.
Heretofore, direct insights into trade-related restructuring for
U.S. MSAs were sparse, because there is little data reporting directly
on international trade at the metropolitan area level of geography. In
constructing new estimates, and exploring the properties of existing
data, we have suggested that there is a wide variation in the openness
to trade in manufactured goods among U.S. metropolitan areas, both in
direct exports from these areas and in measures of import competition
and penetration for their specific industrial sectors.
Large metropolitan areas do not appear to be experiencing as high a
level of import competition for manufactured goods as medium and smaller
metropolitan areas. However, this may reflect the more general tendency
of production activity to eschew large urban areas in favor of less
densely populated areas. In reality, the increasing service intensity of
large urban areas may belie their actual trade intensity in the global
trade of manufactured goods. Services, many of them originating in large
urban areas, are implicitly and increasingly embodied in manufactured
goods--imports, exports, and domestically produced goods alike.
When it comes to exports, large metropolitan areas tend to report
high export intensity for manufactured goods. Many large urban areas
tend to ship or facilitate shipment of exported goods, and they are
accordingly cited as the domicile of exports abroad. In one sense, this
is misleading in that the origin of production for many of these exports
is likely to be in smaller metro areas or rural areas. However, in
another sense, it is appropriate to attribute value added to large
metropolitan areas because, as mentioned above, services embedded in
manufactured goods often originate in these areas.
These first explorations of trade-related data at the metropolitan
level remain suggestive and rudimentary. There is much more that we
don't know. Trade remains a single but important element
contributing to shifting roles and structure of metropolitan areas.
Table 1 Manufacturing imports as percent of GMP (1999)
Rank by % of
MSA (by 1999 population) imports Imports GMP GMP
($billions) ($billions)
New York-Northern New 2 43.3 5.4 797
Jersey-Long Island,
NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside- 1 51.8 11.2 464
Orange County, CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, 6 27.9 8.8 316
IL-IN-WI
Washington-Baltimore, 31 6.1 2.1 289
DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland- 3 43.1 14.0 308
San Jose, CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington- 9 16.6 8.6 193
Atlantic City, PA-NJ-
DE-MD
Boston-Worcester- 5 28.5 12.5 229
Lawrence, MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor- 4 33.7 19.0 177
Flint, MI
Dallas-Fort Worth, TX 8 17.0 9.1 186
Houston-Galveston- 7 18.1 11.0 164
Brazoria, TX
Atlanta, GA 17 8.4 5.8 145
Miami-Fort 40 4.7 5.0 93
Lauderdale, FL
Seattle-Tacoma- 11 10.3 7.8 132
Bremerton, WA
Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 16 8.9 10.2 87
Cleveland-Akron, OH 18 8.2 9.6 86
Minneapolis-St. Paul, 14 9.0 8.3 108
MN-WI
San Diego, CA 22 7.8 9.4 83
St. Louis, MO-IL 24 7.8 10.1 77
Denver-Boulder- 19 8.1 8.5 96
Greeley, CO
Pittsburgh, PA 23 7.8 11.7 67
Tampa-St. Petersburg- 46 3.5 6.0 59
Clearwater, FL
Portland-Salem, OR-WA 10 11.0 17.0 65
Cincinnati-Hamilton, 28 6.7 11.5 58
OH-KY-IN
Kansas City, MO-KS 34 5.6 9.9 57
Sacramento-Yolo, CA 64 2.2 4.4 51
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan
product.
Source: Author's calculations based on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration, Trade Development, Office
of Trade and Economic Analysis; Haver Analytics; and U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Table 2 Import penetration, 25 largest metro areas
Import penetration (percent)
% change
MSA (by population) 1989 1999 1989-99
New York-Northern New 10.4 17.8 70
Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside- 11.1 17.7 60
Orange County, CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, 9.6 15.5 62
IL-IN-WI
Washington-Baltimore, 8.2 12.4 51
DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland- 16.7 23.7 42
San Jose, CA
Philadelphia=-Wilmington- 9.3 16.5 77
Atlantic City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston- Worcester- 14.6 21.7 49
Lawrence, MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI 11.3 16.3 45
Dallas-Fort Worth, TX 10.4 16.1 55
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria, TX 8.8 13.9 58
Atlanta, GA 8.4 12.6 50
Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL 13.2 16.7 26
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton, WA 7.9 16.7 112
Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 14.7 19.3 32
Cleveland-Akron, OH 8.8 13.8 56
Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI 9.1 14.1 55
San Diego, CA 16.8 24.1 43
St. Louis, MO-IL 9.6 12.9 35
Denver-Boulder-Greeley, CO* 13.2 17.3 31
Pittsburgh, PA 8.7 17.8 104
Tampa-St. Petersburg- 9.5 16.2 70
Clearwater, FL
Portland-Salem, OR-WA 13.2 21.7 64
Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY-IN 10.0 16.9 68
Kansas City, MO-KS 9.2 11.7 28
Sacramento-Yolo, CA 7.9 12.8 62
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan
product.
Source: Author's calculation based on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration Trade Development, Office
of Trade and Economic Analysis; National Bureau of Economic Research;
and U.S. Department of Commerce Bureau of the Census, Center for
Economic Studies, Annual Survey of Manufactures.
Table 3 Metro area export intensify, 1999
% of
MSA (by population) Exports GMP GMP
($billions) ($billions)
1 New York-Northern New 46.6 5.8 797
Jersey-Long Island,NY-NJ-CT
2 Los Angeles-Riverside- 34.7 7.5 464
Orange County, CA
3 Chicago-Gary-Kenosha,IL-IN-WI 21.5 6.8 316
4 Washington-Baltimore, 9.4 3.2 289
DC-MD-VA-WV
5 San Francisco-Oakland- 45.6 14.8 308
San Jose, CA
6 Philadelphia-Wilmington- 14.2 7.4 193
Atlantic City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
7 Boston-Worcester- 15.5 6.8 229
Lawrence, MA-NH-ME-CT
8 Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI 30.5 17.2 177
9 Dallas-Fort Worth, TX 11.8 6.4 186
10 Houston-Galveston- 19.3 11.8 164
Brazoria, TX
11 Atlanta, GA 7.2 4.9 145
12 Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL 13.9 15.0 93
13 Seattle-Tacoma- 33.0 25.0 132
Bremerton, WA
14 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 7.3 8.5 87
15 Cleveland-Akron, OH 7.4 8.6 86
16 Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI 8.4 7.8 108
17 San Diego, CA 8.7 10.4 83
18 St. Louis, MO-IL 4.4 5.7 77
19 Denver-Boulder-Greeley, C03 2.6 2.7 96
20 Pittsburgh, PA 3.6 5.4 67
21 Tampa-St. Petersburg- 2.4 4.1 59
Clearwater, FL*
22 Portland-Salem, OR-WA 7.9 12.1 65
23 Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY-IN 6.6 11.4 58
24 Kansas City, MO-KS 1.6 2.9 57
25 Sacramento-Yolo, CA. 2.6 5.1 51
* Exports include nonmanufactured commodity shipments
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan
product.
Source:Author's calculations based on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the census,
Exporter Location Series; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of
Economic Analysis.
Table 4 Prospective export intensify
GMP Exports Exports
MSA (by population) 1993 1993 1999
($billions) ($billions) ($billions)
1 New York-Northern 561 43.5 41.8
New Jersey-Long
Island, NY-NJ-CT
2 Los Angeles- 343 25.6 31.1
Riverside-Orange
County, CA
3 Chicago-Gary- 221 13.8 19.3
Kenosha,
IL-IN-WI
4 Washington- 206 8.5 8.4
Baltimore,
DC-MD-VA-WV
5 San Francisco- 190 29.8 41.0
Oakland-
San Jose,CA
6 Philadelphia- 143 9.3 12.8
Wilmington-Atlantic
City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
7 Boston-Worcester- 152 10.0 14.0
Lawrence,
MA-NH-ME-CT
8 Detroit-Ann Arbor- 128 19.7 27.4
Flint, MI
9 Dallas-Fort 112 6.2 10.6
Worth, TX
10 Houston-Galveston- 104 12.8 17.3
Brazoria, TX
11 Atlanta, GA 86 3.6 6.5
12 Miami-Fort 67 9.0 12.5
Lauderdale, FL
13 Seattle-Tacoma- 82 24.0 29.7
Bremerton, WA
14 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 48 4.3 6.6
15 Cleveland-Akron, OH 65 4.7 6.6
16 Minneapolis-St. 72 6.2 7.5
Paul,MN-WI
17 San Diego, CA 56 4.3 7.8
18 St. Louis, MO-IL 57 3.0 3.9
19 Denver-Boulder 57 1.3 2.3
Greeley, CO
20 Pittsburgh, PA 51 2.6 3.2
21 Tampa-St. Petersburg- 38 1.3 2.2
Clearwater, FL
22 Portland-Salem, 42 3.6 7.1
OR-WA
23 Cincinnati-Hamilton, 40 3.8 6.0
OH-KY-IN
24 Kansas City, MO-KS 39 1.1 1.5
25 Sacramento-Yolo, CA 33 1.2 2.3
Table 4 Prospective export intensify
MSA (by population) Growth(b)
(GMP 1993)
1 New York-Northern -0.3
New Jersey-Long
Island, NY-NJ-CT
2 Los Angeles- 1.6
Riverside-Orange
County, CA
3 Chicago-Gary- 2.5
Kenosha,
IL-IN-WI
4 Washington- 0.0
Baltimore,
DC-MD-VA-WV
5 San Francisco- 5.9
Oakland-
San Jose,CA
6 Philadelphia- 2.4
Wilmington-Atlantic
City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
7 Boston-Worcester- 2.6
Lawrence,
MA-NH-ME-CT
8 Detroit-Ann Arbor- 6.0
Flint, MI
9 Dallas-Fort 4.0
Worth, TX
10 Houston-Galveston- 4.4
Brazoria, TX
11 Atlanta, GA 3.3
12 Miami-Fort 5.1
Lauderdale, FL
13 Seattle-Tacoma- 7.0
Bremerton, WA
14 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 4.8
15 Cleveland-Akron, OH 2.9
16 Minneapolis-St. 1.9
Paul,MN-WI
17 San Diego, CA 6.4
18 St. Louis, MO-IL 1.6
19 Denver-Boulder 1.7
Greeley, CO
20 Pittsburgh, PA 1.2
21 Tampa-St. Petersburg- 2.3
Clearwater, FL
22 Portland-Salem, 8.2
OR-WA
23 Cincinnati-Hamilton, 5.4
OH-KY-IN
24 Kansas City, MO-KS 0.9
25 Sacramento-Yolo, CA 3.3
(a) Real growth in 1993-99 exports as a percent of 1993 GMP.
(b) Deflated to 1993.
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross
metropolitan product.
Source: Author's calculations based on data from U.S.
Department of Commerce, International trade Administration,
Office of Trade and Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series; and
U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis.
TABLE 5 Export sensitivity test: ITA export data versus estimates
1999 1999
MSA (by population) ITA exports estimates
($billions) ($billions)
1 New York-Northern New 46.6 24.4
Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-CT
2 Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange 34.7 32.4
County, CA
3 Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, 21.5 17.5
IL-IN-WI
4 Washington-Baltimore, 9.4 4.5
DC-MD-VA-WV
5 San Francisco-Oakland-San 45.6 27.0
Jose, CA
6 Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic 14.2 10.2
City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
7 Boston-Worcester-Lawrence, 15.5 18.5
MA-NH-ME-CT
8 Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI 30.5 14.7
9 Dallas-Fort Worth, TX 11.8 14.6
10 Houston-Galveston-Brazoria, TX 19.3 11.2
11 Atlanta, GA 7.2 5.6
12 Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL 13.9 2.3
13 Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton, WA 33.0 14.5
14 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ 7.3 7.9
15 Cleveland-Akron, OH 7.4 6.4
16 Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI 8.4 6.5
17 San Diego, CA 8.7 6.5
18 St. Louis, MO-IL 4.4 8.4
19 Denver-Boulder-Greeley, CO 2.6 3.5
20 Pittsburgh, PA 3.6 4.5
21 Tampa-St. 2.4 2.0
Petersburg-Clearwater, FL
22 Portland-Salem, OR-WA 7.9 7.5
23 Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY-IN 6.6 4.9
24 Kansas City, MO-KS 1.6 2.6
25 Sacramento-Yolo, CA 2.6 1.9
MSA (by population) [X.sub.ITA] - [X.sub.ITA]-
[X.sub.est.] [X.sub.est.]
(billions) (billions)
1 New York-Northern New 22.2 23.6
Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-CT
2 Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange 2.3 4.2
County, CA
3 Chicago-Gary-Kenosha, 4.0 2.2
IL-IN-WI
4 Washington-Baltimore, 4.9 5.2
DC-MD-VA-WV
5 San Francisco-Oakland-San 18.7 15.6
Jose, CA
6 Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic 4.0 1.7
City, PA-NJ-DE-MD
7 Boston-Worcester-Lawrence, -3.0 -0.9
MA-NH-ME-CT
8 Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint, MI 15.8 6.6
9 Dallas-Fort Worth, TX -2.8 -1.7
10 Houston-Galveston-Brazoria, TX 8.1 4.0
11 Atlanta, GA 1.6 -0.2
12 Miami-Fort Lauderdale, FL 11.6 7.3
13 Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton, WA 18.5 15.5
14 Phoenix-Mesa, AZ -0.6 0.4
15 Cleveland-Akron, OH 1.0 0.1
16 Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN-WI 1.9 1.4
17 San Diego, CA 2.2 0.0
18 St. Louis, MO-IL -4.1 -3.0
19 Denver-Boulder-Greeley, CO -0.9 -1.4
20 Pittsburgh, PA -0.9 -0.3
21 Tampa-St. 0.4 -0.1
Petersburg-Clearwater, FL
22 Portland-Salem, OR-WA 0.4 -0.3
23 Cincinnati-Hamilton, OH-KY-IN 1.8 0.7
24 Kansas City, MO-KS -1.0 -1.3
25 Sacramento-Yolo, CA 0.7 0.4
Notes: The two datasets overlap between 1993 and 1999. In the data
reported by the International Trade Administration (ITA), the
non-manufactured commodity shipments have been subtracted in 43
metropolitan statistical areas (MSA).
Source: Author's calculations base on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Cencus,
Exporter Location Series; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of
Economic Analysis.
TABLE 6 OLS regression: ITA annual manufacturing exports by metro area
(natural log)
1 2 3
Constant -6.36 ** -3.41 ** -4.72 **
(.04) (.35) (.46)
Year (1998=1, 0 otherwise) .075 .067 (.071)
(.072) (.07) (.069)
Estimated exports (log) .66 ** .46 **
(.05) (.071)
Gross metro product (log) 1.21 ** .49 ** .73 **
(.041) (.06) (.083)
Employment share, transportation 11.40 ** 14.0 ** 14.14 **
(log) (2.00) (2.00) (1.95)
Employment share, manufacturing 5.27 ** 2.64 **
(log) (.049) (.62)
Number of large manufacturing HQs -.002 .003 .001
(.005) (.005) (.005)
Adjusted R-squared .80 .81 .82
N=416 N=416 N=16
** Denotes statistical significance at the 1 percent level.
Standard error in parentheses.
Notes: OLS is ordinary least squares. HQs is headquarters. Regressions
were also estimated substituting "all manufacturing headquarters"
for "large" with different results. The signs on independent variables,
including transportation, remained the same. However, statistical
significance dropped. "Large headquarters" is defined as worldwide
employment of 2,000 or more. The calculations in this table are based
upon [Exports.sub.MSA] = [beta].sub.1]([estExports.sub.MSA]) +
+[beta].sub.2]([GMP.sub.MSA]) + [beta].sub.3]([ShTr.sub.MSA])
+ [beta].sub.4]([ShMfg.sub.MSA])
+ [beta].sub.5]([HQ.sub.MSA]) + [beta].sub.6(Year Dummy)
+ [epsilon].sub.MSA].
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census,
Exporter Location Series; U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis; and Compustat.
TABLE 7 OLS regression: Dependent variable as percent change in
manufacturing employment by MSA, 1989-99
1 2 3 4
Constant -0.0562 -0.0504 -0.0003 -0.0154
0.030) (0.033) (0.030) (0.029)
% Change exports 0.0873 0.0881 0.1311 0.1131
(0.0144) * (0.0145) * (0.014) * (0.01382) *
% Change imports 0.0202 0.0212 0.0492
(0.00948) * (0.00950) * (0.0097) *
% Change import -0.1208 -0.1773
penetration (0.0241) * (0.0256) *
% Change export
penetration
% Change -0.0287
productivity,
1987-97 (0.0130) *
Size of MSA -0.0009 -0.0007 -0.0009 -0.0009
by GMP, 1989 (0.0003) * (0.0003) * (0.0003) * (0.0003) *
Regional Yes Yes Yes Yes
fixed effect
Sample size 269 269 269 269
R-bar squared 0.350 0.367 0.397 0.451
5 6 7 8-
Constant -0.019 -0.014 -0.017 -0.062
(0.027) (0.027) (0.029) (0.017) *
% Change exports 0.186 0.178 0.179 0.196
0.017) * (0.018) * (0.018) * 0.018) *
% Change imports 0.021 0.027 0.028 0.035
(0.008) * (0.01) * (0.010) * 0.010) *
% Change import -0.039 -0.038 -0.036
penetration (0.034) (0.035) 0.035)
% Change export -0.250 -0.218 -0.217 -0.266
penetration (0.027) * (0.039) * (0.040) * 0.039) *
% Change -0.015 0.011
productivity,
1987-97 (0.011) -0.012)
Size of MSA -0.0006 -0.0006 -0.0006 0.0007
by GMP, 1989 (0.0003) * (0.0002) * (0.00002) * (0.00002) *
Regional Yes Yes Yes No
fixed effect
Sample size 269 269 269 269
R-bar squared 0.510 0.510 0.517 0.473
* T-stat significant at 5 percent level.
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. OLS is ordinary least squares.
MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product.
The calculations in this table are based upon [PchMfgEmp.sub.msa] =
[beta].sub.1] ([pChExports.sub.msa]) + [beta].sub2]([pChImports.sub.msa]
+ [beta].sub.3] ([pChImPenetration.sub.msa]) + [beta].sub.4]
(pChExportPenetration.sub.msa) + [beta].sub.5](pChProductivity) +
[beta].sub.6(regional dummies) + [upsilon].sub.MSA].
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from U.S. Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census,
Exporter Location Series, Center for Economic Studies, and Annual Survey
of Manufactures; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; National Bureau of Economic Research.
NOTES
(1) See Campa and Goldberg (1997), who identify changes in the use
of imported inputs for a set of manufacturing industries from the U.S.,
Canada, the UK, and Japan. They find manufacturing industries in the
U.S. to have experienced a very strong increase in the use of imported
inputs. The role of trade in imported inputs in the context of our
article will be left for future research. See also Hummels et al.
(2001), who show that the internationalization of the supply chain, a
phenomenon they refer to as vertical specialization, has accounted for a
large and increasing share of international trade over the last several
decades. They find that this increase in vertical specialization
accounts for a sizable piece of the growth in world trade.
(2) County Business Patterns is published by the U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of the Census, and contains information on employment,
payroll, and number of establishments by industry for every county in
the U.S. For 1998 and 1999, the North American Industrial Classification
System (NAICS) replaced the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
system. This new classification maps fairly well into the former SIC
system for manufacturing industries. One exception is the auxiliary
establishment employment of manufacturing companies (for example,
corporate headquarters), which has been shifted to a separate NAICS
category in "services."
(3) For example, the Chicago Consolidated Metropolitan Statistical
area encompasses the primary metropolitan statistical areas of Chicago,
IL, Gary, IN, Kankakee, IL, and Kenosha, WI. Yet, it is possible that
the use of subregional entities, such as metropolitan areas, does not
sufficiently account for regional economic linkages. Multi-state regions
are often highly integrated in their trade between and among industries
(see Hewings et al., 1998).
(4) The CBP industry data are available at a four-digit level based
on SIC for 1977-97 and a six-digit industry level based on NAICS for
1998 and 1999. Undisclosed or "suppressed" CPB data were
estimated by the Center for Public Policy at Northern Illinois
University (see Gardocki and Baj, 1985).
The data on U.S. exports and imports by industry contain
information on the value of physical goods that have cleared through
customs. These were provided to us by the International Trade
Administration of the U.S. Department of Commerce. Exports are limited
to domestic exports and are valued "free alongside ship,"
while imports are restricted to goods imported for consumption (not for
re-export) and are on a customs value basis.
The ITA data, which we use in our analysis, are classified
according to four-digit SIC and six-digit NAICS codes, yet, in their
original form, they do not strictly conform to the SIC and NAICS
industry definitions. The trade and economic analysts at the ITA mapped
original trade data categories from the Bureau of the Census'
Foreign Trade (exports and imports) into industry classification codes
(NAICS and SIC). They did so based on their knowledge of and familiarity
with industry products in international trade into and out of the U.S.
Between 2 percent and 3 percent of imports could not be reliably
assigned, or were assigned to miscellaneous categories. These are
dropped from our analysis.
(5) We construct these measures for 269 metropolitan areas of the
U.S. The employment data at the fine level of industry detail are
thought to be much more accurate for large metropolitan areas. In such
places, the county-level employment by industry is likely to be less
subject to errors of imputation. There, employment data will be reported
directly rather than imputed due to "disclosure" problems of a
thin presence in the number of establishments in any particular
industry.
(6) We construct our own estimates of gross regional product. To do
so, we allocate nonagricultural gross product for the U.S. to each
metropolitan area in proportion to its share of nonfarm personal income.
(7) Metropolitan area figures here are constructed as if the
regions were a single region, rather than taking an arithmetic mean with
each metropolitan area as an observation. (Either way, the results
differ little.)
(8) See Ono (2001).
(9) Import penetration is defined for an industry by the ratio of
imports to domestic market sales.
(10) Yet this is not a wholly accurate accounting of the local
impact of overseas activity. An unmeasured change in competition or
displacement may take place in foreign markets that are now contested
between U.S.-domiciled production plants and overseas producers.
(11) The estimated range is derived by taking the value of exports
of manufactured goods to total production in the manufactured sector.
The larger estimate measures production by "value added in
manufacturing." The lower figure uses "value of
shipments" in manufacturing as the base. Since "export"
value includes value added from nonmanufacturing industries, value of
shipments may be an appropriate basis of comparison. However, shipments
also include re-shipments, some of which may be exported. Hence, there
may be a double counting in the U.S. of shipments data, making value
added another, perhaps preferable candidate.
(12) A state's value on the map represents the average of its
MSAs' import penetration rates. The MSAs encompassing multiple
states and component primary MSAs (PMSAs) are allocated to the state
that includes the PMSA.
(13) See U.S. Department of Commerce (1999).
(14) As with other data, there are also flaws in reporting. In this
case, the principle problems are that approximately 7 percent of exports
do not report a location; and another 3 percent ace not allocable to
particular metropolitan areas using a zip code basis (the
"crossover" or overlap problem). The data are f.a.s. (free
alongside ship) basis and include re-exports.
(15) See Dow Jones and Company (2003), which reports that, of the
17 million manufacturing jobs in the U.S., 52 percent are production
workers versus 68 percent ten years earlier. For regional perspectives,
see Testa (1989). These articles document that the value of
manufacturing shipments, exports or domestic shipments, is increasingly
composed of both services produced by manufacturing companies and
services purchased by manufacturing companies and "embedded"
into the value of the final manufacturing shipment.
(16) In particular, for many of the largest MSAs, the reported data
break out "commodity" exports, such as agriculture and mining,
for metropolitan areas. In our tables listing exports by metropolitan
area, we have extracted commodity exports whenever possible.
(17) See Klier and Testa (2002).
(18) See Hine and Wright (1997), who also point out that import and
export growth rates tend to be strongly positively correlated.
REFERENCES
Campa, Jose, and Linda S. Goldberg, 1997, "The evolving
external orientation of manufacturing industries: Evidence from four
countries" Economic Policy Review, Vol. 3, July, pp. 53-81.
Dow Jones and Company, 2003, "Manufacturers find themselves
increasingly in the service sector," Wall Street Journal, February
10, p. A2.
Gardocki, Jr., Bernard C., and John Baj, 1985, "Methodology
for estimating nondisclosure in county business patterns," Northern
Illinois University, Center for Governmental Studies, April, mimeo.
Hayward D. J., and R. A. Erickson, 1995, "The North American
trade of U.S. states: A comparative analysis of industrial shipments,
1983-91" International Regional Science Review, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp.
1-31.
Hervey, Jack L., 1999, "A regional approach to measures of
import activity" Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, No. 147, November.
Hervey, J. L., and W. A. Strauss, 1998, "Foreign growth, the
dollar, and regional economies 1970-97," Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Fourth Quarter, pp. 35-55.
Hewings, Geoffrey J. D., Graham R. Schindler, and Philip R.
Israilevich, 1998, "Interstate trade among Midwest economies,"
Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 129, May.
Hine, Robert C., and Peter Wright, 1997, "Trade and
manufacturing employment in the United Kingdom," in International
Trade and Labour Markets, Jitendralal Borkakoti and Chris Milner (eds.),
New York: St. Martin's Press, pp. 118-139.
Hummels, David, Jun Ishii, and Kei-Mu Yi, 2001, "The nature
and growth of vertical specialization in world trade," Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 54, pp. 75-96.
Katics, Michelle M., and Bruce C. Petersen, 1994, "The effect
of rising import competition on market power: A panel data study of U.S.
manufacturing," Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 42,
September, pp. 277-286.
Klier, Thomas, and William Testa, 2002, "The Great Lakes border and economy," Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, No. 179a, July.
Ono, Yukako, 2001, "Outsourcing business services and the role
of central administrative offices," Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, working paper, No. 2002-01.
Testa, William, 1989, "Manufacturing's changeover to
services in the Great Lakes economy," Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Regional Economic Issues, working paper, No. WP 21.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1999, County
Business Patterns, 1989-99, Washington, DC.
U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration,
Trade Development, Office of Trade and Economic Analysis, 2003, U.S.
Exports and Imports, Washington, DC, January.
CALL FOR PAPERS
May 5-7, 2004
40th ANNUAL CONFERENCE ON BANK STRUCTURE AND COMPETITION FEDERAL
RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO
The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago invites the submission of
research and policy-oriented papers for the 40th annual Conference on
Bank Structure and Competition to be held May 5-7, 2004, at the Fairmont
Hotel in Chicago. Since its inception, the conference has fostered an
ongoing dialogue on current public policy issues affecting the financial
services industry. In addition to papers related to the conference
theme, we are interested in any high-quality research addressing public
policy issues affecting financial services and will have a number of
sessions on topics unrelated to the conference theme. We welcome
submissions on all topics related to financial services and regulation.
The theme of the 2004 conference will address issues related to how
banks compete. Over the past two decades, commercial banks have
aggressively repositioned themselves to compete under new economic,
technological, and regulatory conditions. No longer protected by
regulatory entry barriers, and confronted with sea change advances in
telecommunications and computer technology, banks are no longer able to
rely on traditional banking models. Instead, banks and other financial
institutions have invested huge amounts of resources in the search for
new competitive strategies. While many of these attempts have been dead
ends, the most successful strategic innovations have set new standards
for the industry and have changed the way that banks compete. The manner
in which commercial banks currently underwrite their loans, finance
their activities, grow their franchises, distribute their services, and
market their images would be barely recognizable to a banker from the
1970s.
Banks still do not compete in a completely unregulated environment,
however, and regulations continue to shape banking strategies. For
example, federally insured deposits are a cornerstone of the community
bank business strategy. Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) loans are a
requirement for any bank that wishes to grow by acquisition, Investment
decisions--at least at the margin--are influenced by capital
regulations. Our system of multiple regulators and bank chartering
agencies can affect the organizational form that banking companies
choose. Terrorist threats and governance scandals have led regulators to
make increased informational demands on banks. As banking markets grow
more concentrated, anti-trust laws may increasingly limit the scale and
scope of bank mergers. At a minimum, regulation is simply a fixed cost
that must be borne by banks but does not influence bank behavior. At the
other extreme, and perhaps more realistically, regulation can
significantly affect banks' strategic choices and influence
competition in financial markets. Innovations introduced in the
marketplace are often driven by--and in some cases succeed exclusively
because of--the existing regulatory environment.
Similarly, commercial banks' competitive strategies are shaped
not only by new technologies, but also by the limitations of technology.
Retail banking franchises have traditionally been built around
paper-based payments, but information and communications technologies
have created new strategic possibilities for retail banking. Electronic
delivery of financial services can reduce banks' overhead costs,
but abandoning bank branch offices can also give rise to disastrous
strategic costs. New financial technologies have transformed
risk-management at commercial banks, but application of leading-edge
techniques may create unforeseen new risks. After generations of
technological stasis in the banking industry, the rapid pace of
technological change has made "strategic innovation" a viable
competitive strategy for some banking companies. In this environment,
must all banks become strategic innovators in order to survive, or can
some banks remain competitive as strategic followers?
The 2004 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago's Conference on Bank
Structure and Competition will explore these issues. Additional
financial topics that we are interested in evaluating include:
* The regulation and riskiness of government sponsored enterprises
(GSEs),
* The Basel II Capital Accord,
* Financial industry consolidation,
* Payments innovations,
* Credit access: fair lending, CRA, and predatory lending issues,
* Deposit insurance and safety-net reform,
* Measuring, monitoring, and managing bank risk,
* The viability and future role of community banks, and
* Restructuring of financial regulatory agencies.
If you would like to present a paper at the conference, please
submit four copies of the completed paper or a detailed abstract (the
more complete the paper, the better) with your name, address,
affiliation, telephone number, and e-mail address, and those of any
co-authors, by December 22, 2003. Correspondence should be addressed to:
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 230 South LaSalle Street Chicago,
Illinois 60604-1413
For additional information contact:
Douglas Evanoff at 312-322-5814 (devanoff@frbchi.org), Robert
DeYoung at 312-322-5396 (robert.deyoung@frbchi.org), or Regina Langston
at 312-322-5641 (rlangston@frbchi.org).
William A. Testa is a vice president and the director of regional
programs, Thomas Klier is a senior economist, and Alexei Zelenev is an
associate economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors
would like to thank Jeff Campbell and seminar participants at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and express their appreciation to the
late senior economist Jack L. Hervey for inspiration and friendship.