Analyzing the relationship between health insurance, health costs, and health care utilization.
French, Eric ; Kamboj, Kirti
Introduction and summary
In this article, we provide an empirical analysis of the
determinants of whether an individual purchases health insurance
coverage. We describe the relationship between health insurance, health
costs, and health care utilization of the elderly, using data from the
Health and Retirement Survey and the Assets and Health Dynamics among
the Oldest Old. We show how health costs and health care utilization
depend upon access to health insurance for individuals aged 50 and
older.
Given the public interest in extending health insurance coverage to
those who are currently uninsured, it seems worthwhile to better
understand why some people do not purchase health insurance. For
example, 2000 Democratic presidential candidate Al Gore advocated that
individuals aged 55-64 be allowed to "buy in" to Medicare. The
idea was that eligible individuals would have to pay for Medicare
coverage, but would potentially pay less than the price of privately
available insurance. Medicare would potentially be cheaper because of
the cost advantages associated with the group coverage that Medicare
provides. By understanding the determinants of the health insurance
purchase decision, we can better understand how proposed reforms may
affect health insurance coverage.
First, we investigate the factors influencing a person's
decision to purchase health insurance. A General Accounting Office study
found that in 1998, private health insurance premiums for a family of
four ranged from $3,000 to $14,000 per year. Although health care
coverage can be expensive, very few households are unable to buy private
health insurance. Nevertheless, many households choose to be uninsured
rather than purchase private health insurance. (1) Therefore, we assume
that even low-income households are able to buy basic health insurance.
Given that almost all individuals in our data are able to purchase
health insurance, the most likely reason that they remain uninsured is
that they expect their health costs without insurance to be
significantly lower than their health costs with insurance. We test four
potential reasons why this might be the case: 1) adverse selection in
the insurance market--because insurers cannot distinguish between
high-cost and low-cost individuals in a group--leading to potentially
prohibitive costs of health insurance for healthy individuals; 2) moral
hazard--the idea that if the price of something is low, people use more
of it-leading to potentially prohibitive costs of general insurance; 3)
potentially prohibitive administrative costs of providing health
insurance for private individuals; and 4) many of the uninsured already
receive explicit insurance through Medicaid and implicit insurance
through hospitals that will treat indigent patients, which may obviate
the need for them to purchase additional health insuranc e.
Most studies of the health insurance purchase decision focus on the
importance of adverse selection and moral hazard as potential reasons
why individuals may not purchase insurance. Our results provide evidence
that neither adverse selection nor moral hazard is the key determinant of the health insurance purchase decision. We find no evidence that
adverse selection makes private insurance too expensive and only
moderate evidence that moral hazard may make private health insurance
prohibitively expensive. However, we find significant evidence that high
administrative costs drive up the price of private insurance. Moreover,
we find a large amount of evidence that the existence of Medicaid and
implicit insurance obviates the need for individuals to purchase
additional health insurance. This last result suggests that changes in
government-provided health insurance, such as allowing younger
individuals to "buy in" to the Medicare program, would likely
have a small effect on the health insurance coverage of older A
mericans. The data show that many of those currently
"uninsured" already have access to low- or no-cost health care
coverage from the government and hospitals.
Data: Health and Retirement Survey and Assets and Health Dynamics
among the Oldest Old
We use data from the Health and Retirement Survey (HRS) and Assets
and Health Dynamics among the Oldest Old (AHEAD). These two datasets are
collected by the same organization and have a similar sample design for
much of the sample period. Both contain detailed information on health
costs, health insurance, and demographics.
The HRS is a sample of non-institutionalized (2) individuals aged
51--61 in 1992. Spouses of these individuals were also interviewed,
regardless of the spouse's age. The HRS includes both a nationally
representative core sample and an additional sample of blacks,
Hispanics, and Florida residents. A total of 12,652 individuals in 7,608
households were interviewed in 1992 and re-interviewed in 1994, 1996,
1998, and 2000, creating up to five separate responses for each
individual.
The AHEAD is a nationally representative sample of
non-institutionalized individuals aged 70 and older in 1993. Like the
HRS, spouses of AHEAD respondents were also interviewed, regardless of
age. Also like the HRS, the AHEAD dataset includes both a nationally
representative core sample and additional samples of blacks, Hispanics,
and Florida residents. A total of 8,222 individuals in 6,047 households
were interviewed in 1993. These individuals were interviewed again in
1995, 1998, and 2000, creating up to four separate responses for each
individual. (3)
In order to assess the quality of the HRS/AHEAD data, we present
means of several key variables of individuals aged 50 and older and
compare them with aggregated statistics from other sources. (4)
Consider sources of insurance first. Table 1 shows that most
individuals receive employer-provided insurance, including insurance
from current employers, past employers, and unions, as well as from the
spouse's current employer, past employers, and unions. (5) Almost
all individuals over age 65, as well as those who draw disability
insurance, are eligible for Medicare. Individuals with low incomes and
asset levels are also eligible for Medicaid. Those not eligible for any
of the above forms of insurance are faced with either purchasing private
health insurance or having no insurance at all. Table 1 shows that many
individuals who do not have access to government- or employer-provided
health insurance choose not to purchase insurance on the private market.
Of our sample, 17 percent have private insurance, while 7 percent have
no insurance. Much of the remainder of this article is devoted to
understanding the health insurance purchase decision for people who are
neither covered by employers nor by the governmen t.
The central variable of interest in our study is the level of
health costs paid by the household. For single households, we compute this as the individual's health costs. For married households, it
is the sum of the husband's and wife's health costs. Health
costs are the sum of insurance premiums, drug costs, and costs for
hospital, nursing home care, doctor visits, dental visits, and
outpatient care. See the appendix for a more detailed description of
these variables. For our sample, mean household out-of-pocket health
costs are $2,527 per year and mean health costs for those aged 65 and
older are $2,716. The U.S. per capita average is $2,831 for
non-institutionalized households headed by an individual aged 65 or
older (Federal Interagency Forum, 2000). This means that health costs in
the HRS/AHEAD are likely significantly below the national average when
accounting for the institutionalized population.
One important reason why average health costs in the HRS/AHEAD data
are below the national average is that individuals in the HRS/AHEAD
spend far fewer nights in a nursing home. Households headed by someone
aged 65 or older spend 7.2 nights in a nursing home per year in our
sample versus 15.8 nights in the aggregate statistics (National Center
for Health Statistics, 1999). (6) Selden et al. (2001) find that 9
percent of total aggregate health costs and 13 percent of costs paid out
of pocket arise from nursing home visits.
Why is there a market for health insurance?
In the next two sections of this article, we describe some of the
important determinants of the health insurance purchase decision. Then,
we provide empirical evidence on these issues.
The most obvious reason people purchase health insurance is to
limit uncertainty associated with catastrophic health costs. (7) The
idea behind health insurance is that uncertain health expenditures are
diversifiable risks. That is, health insurers provide health insurance
to many individuals. While there is a great amount of uncertainty about
how much insurers must pay out for any individual, there is very little
uncertainty about average medical expenses for a large pool of
individuals.
Therefore, even if the health insurer is risk averse, by pooling
health costs of many individuals together, the insurer faces very little
risk. As a result, the insurer cares only about expected medical
expenditures of the individual when setting the insurance premium.
Suppose that the firm's only cost of providing health
insurance is medical expenditures. In other words, we ignore
administrative costs to the insurer. Also, assume that there are a large
number of individuals in the market, and that all of these individuals
face the same distribution of health costs. If markets are perfectly
competitive, the firm's expected profit is zero. If the insurer
makes profits, new health insurance providers will enter the market and
bid down insurance premiums to the expected health costs of the
individual. Therefore, insurers will offer insurance to individuals at
"actuarially fair" prices, that is, prices equal to the
expected health costs that individuals face.
Assuming that individuals are risk averse, they would rather pay
their expected health costs than face the possibility of extremely high
health costs. Therefore, individuals will be better off purchasing
actuarially fair insurance. As we noted in table 1, however, many people
do not purchase insurance. The most common explanation why people do not
buy insurance is that it is impossible to buy actuarially fair
insurance. Next, we examine why this is so.
Why doesn't everyone purchase health insurance?
Above, we argued that people should purchase health insurance to
reduce uncertainty if their expectation is that they will pay the same
amount for health care whether or not they are insured. However, insured
individuals are, on average, likely to pay more than the uninsured.
Below, we highlight four reasons for this and cite existing evidence for
each of the reasons.
First, prices of health insurance may be potentially high because
of adverse selection. Adverse selection occurs when there are high
health cost individuals and low health cost individuals in a group, but
health insurers cannot distinguish between the two.
Recall that if markets are competitive and there are no
administrative costs, insurers will set the price of health insurance
equal to the average medical expenditure of individuals who purchase
health insurance. If individuals with low health costs are able to
reveal that, on average, they will have low health costs, health
insurers will charge those individuals low insurance premiums.
However, in practice it is very difficult for insurers to
distinguish between the two groups. Individuals may know whether they
are "high cost." However, this information is not available to
the insurer of a group plan. For example, Blue Cross/Blue Shield health
insurance merely requests home address, date of birth, sex, whether the
individual smokes, and whether the individual wants maternity coverage.
As a result of not being able to distinguish between high-cost and
low-cost individuals, insurers charge everyone (conditional on the
information listed immediately above) the same price for health
insurance. (8) If only high health cost individuals purchase health
insurance, and health insurers charge premiums equal to average health
costs of people who buy health insurance, then the cost will be
relatively high. Although low health cost individuals may value health
insurance at more than the cost to insurers of providing it to them,
since they are risk averse, they may value it at less than what insurers
charge to provide health insurance to high health cost people. In this
scenario, the low health cost individuals will not purchase health
insurance. (9)
If insurers could distinguish between high-cost and low-cost
individuals, they would provide insurance to low health cost individuals
at a price equal to their expected health costs. This would make
low-cost individuals better off. Insurers would still charge high-cost
individuals their expected health costs, making them no worse off.
Cutler and Zeckhauser (2000) survey the evidence on adverse
selection. They argue that empirical work has repeatedly documented its
importance when comparing insurers that offer multiple plans. For
example, individuals who opt for Medicare health maintenance
organizations (HMOs) (that offer less generous service than most
Medicare plans but cover some services, like drug costs, that most
Medicare plans do not cover) are more likely to have consumed few
medical services in the past than those who do not opt for Medicare
HMOs.
Many researchers also cite the high price of privately provided
health insurance as evidence that adverse selection does drive up the
price of health insurance. For example, Gruber and Madrian (1995)
document that Blue Cross/Blue Shield health insurance for a family of
four in New England costs $10,310 in 1998 dollars. (10)
However, it is not clear in the above example that individuals who
buy Blue Cross/Blue Shield are any less healthy than those who decide
not to purchase insurance. Moreover, many studies that consider the
health insurance purchase decision have found relatively little evidence
that adverse selection exists in the market for health insurance (see
Cardon and Hendel, 2001, for example).
The second reason insurance may be so expensive is the cost of
administering plans for large employers. Administrative costs account
for 10 percent to 15 percent of the costs of the health plans (Cutler
and Zeckhauser, 2000). However, these costs are potentially higher for
insurance plans administered to small groups of people. For example a
Congressional Budget Office (U.S. Congress, 1988) study found that large
firms (10,000+ workers) pay 35 percent less than small firms (one to
four workers). Gruber and Madrian (1995) argue that this price
difference reflects some combination of adverse selection and
administrative costs. Given that it is not obvious that adverse
selection is more serious for small employers than large employers, it
is likely that the cost difference is largely from the lower
administrative costs at large firms. Pauly (1986) finds that
administrative costs may account for 50 percent of the cost of
"Medigap" health insurance plans. (11)
Moral hazard is the third reason health insurance costs are high.
Moral hazard is a consequence of downward sloping demand curves: If the
price of a good becomes cheaper, people buy more of that good. People
purchase health insurance to reduce the costs of medical procedures. For
example, many "indemnity" plans like Blue Cross/Blue Shield
allow people to obtain whatever health care they wish, but the insurer
pays most of the price. If individuals have a 20 percent co-payment,
then the price of medical services is only 20 percent of what it would
be without insurance. This potentially leads people to use medical
services that are of very little value to them. Recall that if markets
are competitive, then the price of health insurance is equal to expected
medical expenses of purchasers of health insurance plus administrative
costs. The high level of medical services consumed by insured
individuals will be reflected in the price of health insurance.
Evidence from the RAND Health Insurance Experiment (Manning et al.,
1987) suggests that a 1 percent rise in the price of health care
services results in a .2 percent reduction in the quantity of health
care services consumed, or a price elasticity of.2. Given that the price
of health care services differs greatly between those with and without
insurance, moral hazard potentially leads insured individuals to consume
far more medical services than is ideal, leading to expensive medical
insurance.
A final reason many people may find private medical insurance
expensive is that they already receive insurance from the government or
through hospitals. Medicaid provides insurance to individuals with low
income and assets. Moreover, hospitals that receive federal funding
cannot turn away indigent patients. Therefore, individuals with low
income and assets do not need to purchase insurance. They already have
it provided explicitly by Medicaid or implicitly by hospitals. This
explanation has received less attention than the other explanations (see
Cutler and Gruber, 1996, for an exception). However, as shown in the
empirical work below, this may be an important oversight.
With these explanations in mind, table 2 describes the problems
associated with universal government insurance relative to
employer-provided health insurance and private insurance. The main
advantage of nationalizing health insurance, such as expanding Medicare
to all individuals aged 55 and older, is to overcome adverse selection
problems. (12) Because the government would expand coverage to everyone,
both the healthy and unhealthy would be covered. Indeed, Akerlof (1970)
points out that most individuals aged 65+ were uninsured before Medicare
was passed into law and argues that adverse selection was one reason for
the low insurance rates of these people. However, nationalizing health
care would do little if anything to overcome high administrative costs
or moral hazard. Administrative costs would potentially be the same for
insurance plans administered by large private industries and the
government. And moral hazard is inherent in the very nature of insurance
contracts and is not specific to the insurance p rovider. Therefore,
arguments in favor of nationalizing health insurance must rest on the
assumption that adverse selection exists in the marketplace for health
insurance coverage and partly on the assumption that, because of risk
aversion, health insurance makes people better off.
Health insurance coverage, health costs, and health care
utilization
In this section we provide some new empirical evidence on the four
potential reasons individuals do not purchase health insurance We find
no evidence of adverse selection and limited evidence in favor of moral
hazard and high administrative costs. Instead, we believe the main
reason some individuals do not purchase insurance is that they are
already receiving insurance, either through the government or implicitly
through hospitals.
In order to assess the importance of administrative costs, we
compare individuals with private insurance with individuals with
employer-provided insurance. Recall that Cutler and Zeckhauser (2000)
find that administration accounts for 10 percent to 15 percent of the
total cost of health insurance at large firms. Our goal is to find out
whether individuals who purchase private insurance face significantly
higher administrative costs than those who receive health insurance
through their employer.
Table 3 shows household health costs by age group and health
insurance type. For households headed by someone aged 50-64, health
insurance premiums are $1,154 per year for those with employer-provided
plans. The Employee Benefit Research Institute (1999) reports that
employers contribute an average of $3,288 to their employees'
health insurance. Therefore, the total cost of employer-provided
insurance premiums is the sum of the employee contribution plus the
employer contribution, or $4,442. Compare this amount with insurance
premiums for households headed by individuals aged 50-64 with private
insurance. These households spend $4,067, on average.
This would imply that the total cost of a private plan is slightly
less than the cost of an employer-provided plan. (13) However, not only
do households with private insurance spend more on insurance premiums
than households with employer-provided insurance, they also have higher
out-of-pocket expenses. This may reflect the higher deductibles and
co-pays of private health insurance policies. When we sum up the
insurance premiums paid by the individual and the firm plus what the
individual pays out of pocket, the total health cost for households with
employer-provided insurance is $5,489 (a $3,288 employer contribution
plus total household expenses of $2,201) and the total cost for private
insurance is $5,871, a difference of 7 percent. Given that
administrative costs constitute about 13 percent of insurance costs for
employer-provided plans, these costs make up 20 percent of private
insurance costs.
Moreover, table 3 shows that households with private insurance
receive fewer medical procedures than households with employer-provided
health insurance. This may reflect the fact that private insurance does
not usually cover pre-existing conditions. Given that those with private
health insurance consume fewer medical services than those with
employer-provided insurance, the cost (net of administrative cost) of
private health insurance is likely lower than the cost (net of
administrative cost) of employer-provided insurance. Therefore, the
calculation of administrative costs above likely understates the
administrative cost of private health insurance.
The second potential reason people do not purchase health insurance
is adverse selection, which implies that only the most unhealthy
purchase private insurance, which makes premiums prohibitively expensive
for healthy people. However, the evidence presented in table 3 refutes
this explanation. Fully 81 percent of people aged 50-64 with private
insurance report that they are in good health. However, only 65 percent
of the uninsured do likewise. Therefore, the uninsured are more likely
to be unhealthy than those who purchase private insurance. Comparing
those older than 65 who purchase private Medigap health insurance with
those who only have Medicare or who have no health insurance at all,
again we see that those who purchase private insurance are healthier
than those with no insurance other than Medicare. (14)
The third potential reason individuals may not purchase health
insurance is the moral hazard problem. Those who are insured face a low
price of health care services, so they tend to consume more, which
drives up the price of premiums. Therefore, controlling for health
status, those who have private health insurance should consume more
health care services than those who have no insurance. Table 3 shows
that for households headed by someone aged 50-64, those with private
health insurance are the least likely to spend a night in a nursing home
or a hospital. Those 50-64 with private insurance spend .01 nights in a
nursing home and .8 nights in a hospital per year, on average. Those
without insurance spend .6 nights in a nursing home and .9 nights in a
hospital per year, on average.
These findings are not consistent with the moral hazard
explanation. However, those with private insurance on average have more
doctor visits, are more likely to have outpatient surgery, are more
likely to see a dentist, and are less likely to not take prescribed drugs than those without insurance. These findings are consistent with
moral hazard. These patterns hold when comparing those older than 65
with private insurance with those older than 65 who have either Medicare
insurance or no insurance. The privately insured older than 65 are less
likely to spend time in a nursing home or in a hospital, but have more
doctor visits, are more likely to have outpatient surgery, are more
likely to see a dentist, and are less likely to not take prescribed
drugs than those without insurance or those who only have Medicare.
One possible reason those with private insurance are less likely to
spend the night in a nursing home or a hospital than those who are
uninsured is that the privately insured are healthier. For two people
with equal health, the person with private insurance is potentially more
likely to spend time in a nursing home or a hospital than the person
without insurance. We return to this issue when conducting our
multivariate analysis in the next section. Another possible reason that
complements the previous explanation is that hospitals may have a
difficult time turning away those without insurance who are very ill.
However, it is easy for dentists and doctors offering elective surgery to turn away the uninsured.
The final explanation why people do not purchase health insurance
is that they receive implicit insurance through the government and
hospitals. One testable implication of this hypothesis is that those
without insurance pay less for a unit of health care services than those
with insurance. As discussed previously, table 3 provides evidence that
those without health insurance consume only slightly fewer health care
services than those with private insurance. Note, however, that those
aged 50-64 with no insurance spend only $1,277 per year on health care,
versus $5,871 per year for those with private insurance. This difference
in costs is not completely an artifact of differences in insurance
premiums either. Those who have no insurance spend less on out-of-pocket
expenses such as drugs and co-pays than those with private insurance.
We also note that households with no insurance are more likely to
have low assets and low income than those with private insurance. This
is important for two reasons. First, if an individual is indigent,
public and non-profit hospitals must treat them. Therefore, low-asset
individuals have implicit insurance through hospitals. Second,
individuals with low assets are potentially eligible for Medicaid.
Individuals receiving Medicaid insurance consume more medical
services and spend less on health care than any other group. That
expenditures by Medicaid beneficiaries, who have low income and assets,
are low is not surprising. After all, the government spent $10,243 per
Medicaid beneficiary aged 65 or older and $9,097 per blind or disabled
individual in 1998 (U.S. House of Representatives, 2000).
One way to test whether Medicaid is a significant source of
insurance for the uninsured is to estimate the probability that a
household that is uninsured becomes covered by Medicaid health insurance
two years later. For uninsured households headed by someone aged 50-64,
there is a 9.2 percent probability that they will be covered by Medicaid
two years later. For households that purchase private insurance, there
is only a 2.6 percent probability that they will be covered by Medicaid
two years later. This shows that individuals with "no"
insurance are more likely to be covered in the near future. This may
mean that individuals who believe that they will be eligible for
Medicaid in the event of a household emergency feel less compelled to
purchase private health insurance than those who do not believe that
they will be eligible for Medicaid.
Multivariate analysis of determinants of health costs
As noted above, we find that the total cost of employer-provided
insurance plans (that is, the sum of costs paid by both employees and
employers) is similar to that of private plans for households headed by
individuals younger than 65. We also find that those with no insurance
pay much less for medical care than those with private insurance.
However, these comparisons are difficult to interpret because there may
be important differences in the quality of care provided across health
care plans. Even though having private insurance leads to higher health
costs than having no insurance, having private insurance may also lead
to a significantly higher quality of care. In this section, we use
multivariate regressions to control for the quality of health care
received. Although we cannot control for all aspects of health care
quality, we can control for many of the determinants of health costs,
such as nights in a hospital or nursing home. In this analysis, we aim
to explain differences in costs of different types of health insurance,
controlling for health care utilization.
Table 4 presents estimates of some of the determinants of health
costs for the three age groups. Each age group has two columns, the
first one with the health care utilization and health status measures
and the second one without. By controlling for health care utilization
in the regressions, we can assess whether differences in health care
utilization explain differences in health costs among households with
different types of insurance.
First, we need to infer administrative costs. Recall that although
the total cost of employer-provided insurance is similar to that of
private plans for households headed by an individual younger than 65,
households with employer-provided insurance consume more health care
services than households with private insurance. Here, we assess whether
controlling for the quantity of health care services consumed affects
the estimated cost differences for the two groups. We are interested in
whether the total cost of private insurance is greater than the total
cost of employer-provided insurance, holding utilization constant.
Column 2 in each category of table 4 provides evidence on this.
Controlling for the health utilization variables those with
employer-provided insurance pay $324 more than those with no insurance.
(15) Those with private health insurance plans pay $4,132 more than
those who are uninsured and ($4,132 - $324 =) $3,808 more than those
with employer-provided health insurance. Recall that firms contribute
about $3,288 toward employees' health insurance plans. Therefore,
the total cost of obtaining private health insurance is only $520
greater than the cost of obtaining private health insurance. This
estimate is not much different from the difference in mean health costs
described in the previous section. Therefore, our estimate of
administrative costs of private health insurance above is little changed
by the multivariate analysis.
Another finding in the previous section is that those who are
uninsured pay much less for health care than those who purchase private
insurance. However, those who purchase private insurance are also more
likely to consume certain medical services, such as dentist visits.
Controlling for assets, income, education, race, marital status, age,
and health care utilization does not affect the difference in health
costs between those who are insured and those who are uninsured. The gap
between health costs for households that are privately insured and
uninsured is $4,132, almost the same as the difference in mean health
costs shown in table 3. Therefore, our central finding, that the
uninsured are implicitly insured by hospitals and the government, is not
overturned by the multivariate regression analysis.
As further evidence on the hypothesis that "implicit"
insurance is important, it appears that greater household resources lead
to greater health costs, even after controlling for health care
utilization and health insurance. This is true when the proxy for
household resources is assets, income, or education. In other words,
poor people seem to pay less than rich people for the same medical
services. One caveat to this last finding is that more affluent
households may be paying more for medical care because they are
purchasing better care. For example, they are potentially spending
nights in better hospitals and seeing better doctors.
Conclusion
This article provides an empirical analysis of the determinants of
whether an individual purchases health insurance coverage. Using data
from the Health and Retirement Survey and the Assets and Health Dynamics
among the Oldest Old, we document the distribution of health costs and
health care utilization of individuals aged 50 and older. We show how
health costs and health care utilization depend upon access to health
insurance.
Of our sample, 6.5 percent are uninsured. We consider four
potential reasons for this. We show that adverse selection is unlikely
to be an important factor in driving health insurance costs. There is
some evidence that administrative costs and overconsumption due to moral
hazard raise the cost of health insurance. However, we find a large
amount of evidence that the existence of Medicaid and implicit insurance
obviates the need for individuals to purchase additional health
insurance. Given that many of the "uninsured" already have
access to low- or no-cost health care coverage from the government and
hospitals, we argue that Medicare buy-in proposals (that is, proposals
to allow younger individuals to pay a premium to join Medicare) would
most likely have a small effect on the health insurance coverage of
older Americans.
APPENDIX: CODING TWO HEALTH COST VARIABLES
This appendix describes the coding of the two main health cost
variables used in our analysis: medical costs paid by the individual and
total costs of medical treatment. Medical costs paid by the individual
are equal to the sum of drug costs, out-of-pocket expenses on items
other than drugs, and insurance costs. The total cost of medical
treatment is the total cost of medical services (whether or not the
individual pays for those services) plus drug costs.
During waves one and two, members of the HRS and AHEAD samples were
asked different sets of questions. Wave three includes only HRS
respondents. During waves four and five, HRS and AHEAD respondents were
asked the same questions.
Health cost information for wave one of the HRA is limited to
insurance premiums. The insurance premium question only refers to
insurance purchased directly from an insurance company or through a
membership organization, such as the American Association of Retired
Persons (AARP). It does not include employee contributions to
employer-provided insurance plans. Given that the information is
incomplete, we do not include wave one information. From wave two onward of the HRS, however, we are able to compute the total cost of medical
treatment, the out of pocket expenses, the drug costs, the cost of the
insurance, and the total medical costs the individual pays.
In wave two, the insurance premium question includes employee
contributions to employer-provided insurance plans and insurance
directly purchased or through a membership organization.
In wave two, respondents were asked whether they had any hospital
stays, nursing home stays, or visits to a doctor. If they answered yes
to any of these questions, they were then asked both the total cost and
out of pocket cost for the visit or stay.
Also in wave two, respondents were asked whether they purchased
medicines prescribed by a doctor. If they did, they were asked how much
these medicines cost per year. It is not clear whether the cost measure
refers to the cost paid by the individual or what the pharmacy charges
the individual and the insurer. Nevertheless, we use this variable to
determine the drug costs variable, which is also added into the total
costs variable.
For wave three onward, total health costs and out of pocket costs
are clarified to include the amount paid for doctors, hospitals, nursing
homes, outpatient surgery, dental expenses, in-home medical care, and
special facilities and services. Note that the costs (both out-of-pocket
and total) of outpatient surgery, dental expenses, in-home care, and
special facilities and services are not included in wave two.
The procedure for determining the insurance costs also changes for
HRS waves three through five. The insurance premium variable is now the
sum of premiums of all employer-provided insurance, Medicare through HMO plans, supplemental plans, private/AARP/professional coverage, and
long-term care plans. Note that in wave two, Medicare insurance costs
are missing.
For wave one of the AHEAD dataset, we can determine the
out-of-pocket and total costs. The out-of-pocket costs include the costs
of nursing home stays as well as "any part of hospital and doctor
bills and any other medical or dental expenses in the last 12
months." We infer that drug costs are included in this measure,
although respondents were not asked directly about drug costs. AHEAD
wave one also asked what policies besides Medicare respondents have,
including long-term care policies, and how much they paid yearly for
such policies. From this, we determine the insurance costs of the
respondent. We do not use wave one in our analysis in this article,
however, because the source of health insurance is incomplete.
For wave two of the AHEAD dataset, imputation procedures for total
costs, and out of pocket costs, insurance costs, drug costs, and medical
costs are the same as in waves three through five of the HRS.
Table 1
Descriptive statistics
Standard
Variable Mean deviation Observations
Fraction with insurance plan
Employer-provided 0.50 0.50 46,991
Private 0.17 0.37 46,991
None 0.07 0.25 46,991
Medicaid 0.10 0.29 46,991
Medicare 0.17 0.38 46,991
Medical costs (1998 dollars)
Out of pocket costs 744 2,516 41,876
Drug costs 753 2,523 41,807
Insurance premiums 1,085 3,197 34,251
Total household expenses 2,527 5,057 33,005
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 4.09 34.65 42,638
Nights in hospital 1.69 6.13 42,418
Doctor visits 6.95 9.99 41,757
Had outpatient surgery 0.13 0.24 42,663
Saw a dentist 0.65 0.48 36,315
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.09 0.28 36,316
Demographics
Fraction married 0.54 0.50 46,953
Good health 0.69 0.46 41,606
Economic resources
Assets <$50,000 0.32 0.47 45,627
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.34 0.47 45,627
Assets >$200,000 0.34 0.48 45,627
Income <$5,000 0.05 0.22 45,874
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.49 0.50 45,874
Income >$30,000 0.46 0.50 45,874
Working 0.38 0.48 46,442
Sources: HRS/AHEAD data and authors' calculations.
TABLE 2
Problems with health insurance, by payment system
Employer-
Nationalized provided Private
Administrative costs yes yes yes
Moral hazard yes yes yes
Adverse selection no some yes
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics by age group
Employer-
provided Private None Medicaid
A. Age 50-64
Fraction with insurance plan 0.67 0.09 0.12 0.07
Medical costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 659 1,049 599 224
Drug costs 513 709 585 465
Insurance premiums 1,154 4,067 110 53
Total household expenses 2,201 5,871 1,277 712
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 0.241 0.008 0.0627 5.350
Nights in hospital 1.067 0.809 0.932 3.146
Doctor visits 6.415 5.702 4.532 10.492
Had outpatient surgery 0.133 0.115 0.055 0.094
Saw a dentist 0.806 0.769 0.487 0.385
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.061 0.084 0.209 0.205
Demographics
Fraction married 0.683 0.583 0.451 0.201
Good health 0.822 0.809 0.646 0.235
Economic resource (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.229 0.197 0.572 0.857
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.392 0.252 0.285 0.122
Assets >$200,000 0.379 0.550 0.143 0.019
Income <$5,000 0.020 0.058 0.189 0.275
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.266 0.320 0.552 0.692
Income >$30,000 0.714 0.622 0.257 0.031
Working 0.729 0.653 0.554 0.071
B. Ages 65-79
Fraction with insurance plan 0.37 0.22 0.01 0.10
Medical Costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 732 651 605 333
Drug costs 669 1,394 880 585
Insurance premiums 1,255 2,408 211 149
Total household expenses 2,601 4,329 1,657 1,032
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 1.135 0.798 0.693 10.005
Nights in hospital 1.845 1.835 2.133 3.394
Doctor visits 7.776 7.260 6.336 9.305
Had outpatient surgery 0.174 0.159 0.077 0.102
Saw a dentist 0.762 0.701 0.463 0.384
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.040 0.095 0.136 0.139
Demographics
Fraction married 0.662 0.581 0.492 0.273
Good health 0.735 0.723 0.583 0.396
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.153 0.156 0.468 0.760
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.357 0.343 0.321 0.186
Assets >$200,000 0.489 0.501 0.205 0.049
Income <$5,000 0.010 0.012 0.174 0.122
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.429 0.528 0.626 0.831
Income >$30,000 0.561 0.460 0.200 0.047
Working 0.201 0.221 0.176 0.059
C. Ages 80 and older
Fraction with insurance plan 0.23 0.28 0.01 0.16
Medical costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 1,773 1,241 477 646
Drug costs 765 1,230 1,086 391
Insurance premiums 832 2,033 73 165
Total household expenses 3,198 4,431 1,141 1,123
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 16.168 12.622 25.198 44.476
Nights in hospital 2.638 2.366 1.984 3.275
Doctor visits 7.446 7.094 6.055 8.442
Had outpatient surgery 0.151 0.132 0.102 0.080
Saw a dentist 0.631 0.558 0.422 0.274
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.019 0.055 0.094 0.060
Demographics
Fraction married 0.369 0.309 0.294 0.140
Good health 0.560 0.592 0.564 0.359
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.214 0.241 0.433 0.804
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.375 0.376 0.328 0.154
Assets >$200,000 0.410 0.382 0.239 0.039
Income <$5,000 0.010 0.024 0.209 0.123
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.640 0.719 0.657 0.867
Income >$30,000 0.350 0.257 0.134 0.010
working 0.018 0.044 0.029 0.008
Medicare
A. Age 50-64
Fraction with insurance plan 0.04
Medical costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 994
Drug costs 1,354
Insurance premiums 366
Total household expenses 2,792
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 1.527
Nights in hospital 2.791
Doctor visits 9.608
Had outpatient surgery 0.118
Saw a dentist 0.469
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.311
Demographics
Fraction married 0.454
Good health 0.332
Economic resource (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.631
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.265
Assets >$200,000 0.102
Income <$5,000 0.148
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.706
Income >$30,000 0.146
Working 0.072
B. Ages 65-79
Fraction with insurance plan 0.30
Medical Costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 647
Drug costs 1,055
Insurance premiums 433
Total household expenses 2,088
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 1.921
Nights in hospital 1.690
Doctor visits 6.650
Had outpatient surgery 0.120
Saw a dentist 0.594
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.110
Demographics
Fraction married 0.509
Good health 0.650
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.323
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.369
Assets >$200,000 0.306
Income <$5,000 0.031
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.661
Income >$30,000 0.308
Working 0.170
C. Ages 80 and older
Fraction with insurance plan 0.32
Medical costs (1998 dollars)
Non-drug out-of-pocket costs 1,018
Drug costs 944
Insurance premiums 345
Total household expenses 2,281
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 12.279
Nights in hospital 1.975
Doctor visits 6.146
Had outpatient surgery 0.099
Saw a dentist 0.454
Did not take prescribed drugs 0.066
Demographics
Fraction married 0.266
Good health 0.586
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets <$50,000 0.391
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 0.341
Assets >$200,000 0.265
Income <$5,000 0.056
Income >$5,000<$30,000 0.789
Income >$30,000 0.155
working 0.040
Sources: HRS/AHEAD data and authors' calculations.
TABLE 4
Determinants of medical costs
Ages 50-64
1 2
Insurance type
Employer-provided 430 (99) 324 (122)
Private 4,057 (135) 4,132 (160)
Medicaid -172 (140) -550 (165)
Medicare 1,237 (168) 927 (197)
Demographics
High school graduate 225 (80) 161 (98)
College graduate 528 (105) 361 (130)
Age 58 (9) 48 (11)
Black -34 (83) 7 (100)
Married 1,751 (72) 1,623 (90)
Good health 159 (83) 316 (101)
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 531 (97) 736 (120)
Assets >$200,000 32 (126) 26 (152)
Income >$5,000<$30,000 55 (144) 11 (175)
Income >$30,000 -260 (77) 12 (95)
Working -2,937 (555) -2 (2)
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 66 (8)
Nights in hospital 28 (4)
Doctor visits 860 (176)
Had outpatient surgery 185 (92)
Saw a dentist 830 (126)
Did not take prescribed drugs -2,784 (684)
Constant
[R.sup.2] 0.148 0.180
Ages 65-79
1 2
Insurance type
Employer-provided 240 (418) 161 (435)
Private 2,037 (421) 1,892 (437)
Medicaid -241 (426) -653 (442)
Medicare 110 (416) -26 (431)
Demographics
High school graduate 241 (107) 228 (111)
College graduate 521 (153) 490 (159)
Age 46 (10) 31 (11)
Black -130 (132) -89 (137)
Married 1,848 (100) 1,499 (108)
Good health -32 (120) 70 (125)
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 344 (142) 484 (149)
Assets >$200,000 30 (247) -67 (255)
Income >$5,000<$30,000 376 (272) 247 (281)
Income >$30,000 -38 (122) 45 (126)
Working -2,455 (874) 19 (2)
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 23 (7)
Nights in hospital 41 (4)
Doctor visits 662 (196)
Had outpatient surgery 421 (107)
Saw a dentist 1,216 (162)
Did not take prescribed drugs -1,931 (904)
Constant
[R.sup.2] 0.091 0.121
Ages 80+
1 2
Insurance type
Employer-provided 1,423 (911) 1,121 (937)
Private 2,681 (905) 2,524 (932)
Medicaid 47 (912) -681 (940)
Medicare 929 (901) 787 (927)
Demographics
High school graduate 580 (196) 400 (196)
College graduate 461 (332) 380 (329)
Age 114 (20) 78 (20)
Black -794 (251) -783 (250)
Married 1,987 (231) 1,358 (243)
Good health -353 (216) -37 (215)
Economic resources (1998 dollars)
Assets >$50,000<$200,000 -516 (268) -231 (267)
Assets >$200,000 580 (387) 550 (387)
Income >$5,000<$30,000 2,038 (477) 1,854 (474)
Income >$30,000 -1,065 (499) -680 (485)
Working -9,237(1,935) 17 (1)
Health care utilization
Nights in nursing home 44 (14)
Nights in hospital 77 (11)
Doctor visits 259 (389)
Had outpatient surgery 211 (185)
Saw a dentist 1,531 (377)
Did not take prescribed drugs -6,989(1,961)
Constant
[R.sup.2] 0.065 0.117
Notes: For each age category, column 1 shows results with no health
utilization controls, while column 2 shows results with controls.
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
Sources: HRS/AHEAD data and authors' calculations.
NOTES
(1.) Blue Cross/Blue Shield is willing to cover most people,
although its plans often do not cover pre-existing conditions.
(2.) Institutionalized individuals include individuals in nursing
homes.
(3.) In 1998 and 2000, individuals in the HRS and AHEAD (as well as
an additional sample of older individuals) were asked the same
questions. In the HRS and AHEAD waves before 1998, many of the questions
asked were the same across the two datasets, allowing us to merge the
datasets. Because the health insurance and health cost data are
incomplete in wave one of both datasets, we use waves two through five
in our analysis here.
(4.) Health costs and health care utilization in the survey
instrument are for the past two years or since the individual was last
interviewed. We divide health costs and health care utilization measures
by the number of years since the individual was last interviewed, or by
two if the individual was never previously interviewed. We dropped
individuals with missing information on their health insurance coverage.
This reduced the original sample from 49,843 person-year observations to
46,991 person-year observations. However, we kept individuals with
missing information on other variables. There are 33,005 observations
with health cost information.
(5.) Employer-provided insurance includes individuals with
federally provided health insurance plans through the Veterans
Administration and the Post Office. It does not include Medicare or
Medicaid. Individuals with federally provided health insurance also have
rather similar characteristics to people with employer-provided
insurance. The main difference is that households with federal insurance
tend to spend less on insurance premiums.
(6.) Because the HRS/AHEAD sample was drawn from the
non-institutionalized population--which excludes individuals in nursing
homes--it is not surprising that the number of nights in a nursing home
is lower in the HRS/AHEAD sample than the national average.
Nevertheless, many HRS/AHEAD household members do enter a nursing home
after they are initially interviewed.
(7.) There are other explanations for why people purchase health
insurance. One is that people who purchase health insurance through
their employer pay for it with pre-tax dollars. If individuals face a 30
percent tax rate, they will be indifferent between spending $1,000 on
medical expenses pre-tax and $700 post-tax. Unless they have very large
medical expenses, making them eligible to deduct medical expenses on
taxes, they will pay for any medical procedures not covered by
employer-provided health insurance on a post-tax basis. Therefore, there
are important tax advantages to employer-provided insurance. Another
reason is that health maintenance organizations potentially have market
power in the market for medical services and thus can bargain with
hospitals for lower prices.
(8.) Note, however, that pre-existing conditions, such as cancer,
are usually not covered by private health insurance plans.
(9.) Note that if everyone purchased health insurance, average
medical expenses would fall. Therefore, if low-cost individuals value
health insurance at more than the cost of providing insurance to them,
two equilibriums potentially exist: one in which health insurance is
purchased only by high-cost individuals (resulting in high health
insurance premiums), the other in which health insurance is purchased by
everyone and the price of health insurance premiums lies between the
costs of high- and low-cost individuals.
(10.) Gruber and Madrian (1995) document that Blue Cross/Blue
Shield was $8,640 in 1993. We adjusted this number to 1998 dollars using
the medical care component of the Consumer Price Index.
(11.) Medigap plans are private health insurance plans that cover
health costs that Medicare does not cover, such as co-pays. Note that
Medigap plans likely have high administrative costs because Medigap only
pays for the smaller expenses that Medicare does not cover.
(12.) However, Gore's "buy in" proposal still might
have had problems, given that the buy in would be voluntary. Healthy
individuals would potentially not buy into Medicare.
(13.) Nevertheless, $4,067 is surprisingly small given that Gruber
and Madrian (1995) found that Blue Cross/Blue Shield charged over
$10,000 in 1998 dollars for private health insurance for a family of
four in New England.
(14.) Note that differences in health costs amongst the different
health insurance groups fall greatly after age 65. Private health
insurance premiums fall from $4,067 for those aged 50-64 to $2,408 for
those aged 65-79. This is not surprising given that after age 65,
Medicare becomes the primary source of health insurance. Private
insurance pays many of the costs that Medicare does not pay. This is why
these health insurance plans are also often referred to as
"Medigap" plans.
(15.) The omitted category in these regressions is an uninsured,
low-asset, low-income, white individual, who dropped out of high school.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G., 1970, "The market for 'lemons': Quality
uncertainty and the market mechanism," Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3, pp. 488-500.
Arrow, K., 1963, "Uncertainty and the welfare economics of
medical care," American Economic Review, Vol. 53, No. 5, pp.
941-973.
Cardon, J., and I. Hendel, 2001, "Asymmetric information in
health insurance: Evidence from the National Medical Expenditure
Survey," RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 32, No. 3, pp. 408-427.
Cutler, D., and J. Gruber, 1996, "Does public insurance crowd
out private insurance?," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 111,
No. 2, pp. 391-430.
Cutler, D., and R. Zeckhauser, 2000, "The anatomy of health
insurance," in Handbook of Health Economics, A. Culyer and J.
Newhouse (eds.), New York: John Wiley and Sons, pp. 563-643.
Employee Benefit Research Institute, 1999, EBRI Health Benefits
Databook, Washington, DC.
Federal Interagency Forum on Aging-Related Statistics, 2000,
"Older Americans 2000: Key indicators of well-being,"
Hyattsville, MD, report.
Feenberg, D., and J. Skinner, 1994, "The risk and duration of
catastrophic health care expenditures," Review of Economics and
Statistics, Vol. 76, No. 4, pp. 633-647.
French, E., and J. Jones, 2002a, "The effects of health
insurance and self-insurance on retirement behavior," Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, mimeo.
_____, 2002b, "On the distribution and dynamics of health
costs," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, mimeo.
Gruber, J., and B. Madrian, 1996, "Health insurance and early
retirement: Evidence from the availability of continuation
coverage," in Advances in the Economics of Aging, D. A. Wise (ed.),
Chicago, University of Chicago Press, pp. 115-143.
_____, 1995, "Health Insurance availability and the retirement
decision," American Economic Review, pp. 938-948.
Gustman, A., and T. Steinmeier, 1999, "Effects of pensions on
savings: Analysis with data from the health and retirement study,"
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, pp. 271-324.
Hubbard, R., J. Skinner, and S. Zeldes, 1995, "Precautionary
saving and social insurance," Journal of Political Economy, Vol.
103, pp. 360-399.
_____, 1994, "The importance of pre-cautionary motives in
explaining individual and aggregate saving," Carnegie-Rochester
Series on Public Policy, pp. 59-125.
Manning, Willard G., Joseph P. Newhouse, Naihua Duan, Emmett B.
Keeler, Arleen Leibowitz, 1987, "Health insurance and the demand
for medical care: Evidence from a randomized experiment," American
Economic Review, Vol. 77, No. 3, June, pp. 251-277.
National Center for Health Statistics, 1999, "Health, United
States, 1999," Washington, DC, report.
Palumbo, M., 1999, "Uncertain medical expenses and
precautionary saving near the end of the life cycle," Review of
Economic Studies, Vol. 65, No. 2.
Pauly, Mark, 1986, "Taxation, health insurance, and market
failure," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp.
629-675.
Rust, J., and C. Phelan, 1997, "How Social Security and
Medicare affect retirement behavior in a world of incomplete
markets," Econometrica, Vol. 65, pp. 781-831.
Selden, T., L. Levit, J. Cohen, S. Zuvekas, J. Moeller, D.,
McKusik, and R. Arnett, 2001, "Reconciling medical expenditure
estimates from the MEPS and NHA, 1996," Health Care Financing
Review, Vol. 23, No. 1.
Smith, J., 1999, "Healthy bodies and thick wallets: The dual
relationship between health and economic status," Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 145-166.
U.S. Congress, Congressional Budget Office, 1988, Costs and Effects
of Extending Health Insurance Coverage, Washington, DC.
U.S. Congress, General Accounting Office, 2000, Private Health
Insurance: Potential Tax Benefit of a Health Insurance Deduction Proposed in H.R. 2990, No. GAO/HEHS-00-104R, April 21.
U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Ways and Means, 2000,
The 2000 Green Book: Background Material and Data on Programs within the
Jurisdiction of the Committee on Ways and Means, Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, No. WMCP 106-14.
Eric French is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Kirti Kambo] is a graduate student at the University of Chicago.