Stock margins and the conditional probability of price reversals.
Kofman, Paul ; Moser, James T.
Introduction and summary
The debate over the need for regulated stock margins is an old one.
The argument that "low margins make speculation cheap"
persuades some observers that low margin requirements lead to greater
stock price volatility. One rebuttal to this argument is that low
margins encourage greater stock market participation and that greater
diversity of expectations actually lessens volatility.
It would seem that a look at stock prices should quickly settle the
question. After all, one might argue, all that is needed is to look over
the history of stock margins and see whether market volatility was high
when margins were low and low when margins were high. This seemingly
simple solution is fraught with problems. For example, suppose stock
market volatility rises and falls cyclically but, absent any major news,
tends to adjust toward some natural level. Then a trend-following margin
authority will be lowering margin requirements as volatility declines
and raising them as volatility rises. The result will be data showing a
correlation between margin levels and stock price volatility. An
incautious interpretation of these data might conclude that low margin
levels lead to high stock price volatility, but by construction this
interpretation would be incorrect.
Advanced statistical methods can solve this sort of problem, but
the effectiveness of these methods relies on the data that are
available. The fact is that in the U.S., changes in margin levels have
been too infrequent for these methods to be conclusive. A good theory
for the cause of systematic price changes reduces the need for more
data, but our understanding of price volatility remains too primitive.
[1]
This article takes another tack in examining this question. Our
approach reframes the issue by focusing entirely on stock price
reversals. By studying the frequency with which stock price changes in
one direction are followed by changes in the opposite direction
(reversals), we obtain a measure of the frequency with which prices may
have overreacted to new information. Overreaction followed by price
correction is a pattern that is consistent with what is termed fad
trading. Fad trading is buying or selling based less on information
about the value of assets than on the fact that buying or selling is the
thing to do. The idea of fad-motivated trading is described as prices
being the result of traders "getting on the bandwagon," as
opposed to independently arrived at judgements about the true value of
these assets.
Specifically, we measure the relationship between the frequency of
reversals and the level of margins. Thus, our article does not address
whether stock margins control volatility. Instead, we ask whether stock
margins affect the overreactions associated with fad-motivated
transactions. The merit of this approach is to sidestep the problems
associated with directly studying volatility. We look instead for
evidence supporting the claim that low margins increase the diversity of
expectations, thereby lowering volatility. An absence of evidence for
low margins mitigating volatility is not the same as "proving"
low margins cause volatility, but disproving a reasonable linkage,
especially one with an opposing effect on volatility, does add
credibility to the remaining explanations.
The ideal data set for the tests we perform in this article would
be the numbers of stock market participants throughout the history of
margin levels for the period we study. In previous drafts of this work,
a number of researchers commented that we should look at trading volume data to get at this issue. However, we conclude that trade volume data
say very little about the extent of market participation. So, we again
find ourselves one step removed from the ideal and rely on evidence that
is consistent with variations in market participation.
We first examine whether margin levels affect trading activity. Lo
and MacKinlay (1990) show that a partial explanation for why a
stock's return might be correlated with its previously occurring
returns is the probability of nontrading during the return computation
period. High nontrading probabilities would be encountered were trading
activity concentrated in short time frames and, therefore, more likely
motivated by similar information. We find that autocorrelations of stock
index returns are positively related to levels of margin. This suggests
that higher margin levels increase the probability of nontrading, a
result that is consistent with the cost of transacting influencing the
decision to trade.
Next, we examine stock return reversals to determine their
responsiveness to changes in margin levels. We interpret evidence that
price reversals decrease at higher levels of margin as indicative of a
relative decrease in fad-based trading. We use three approaches to
investigate this question. The answers we obtain from these procedures
are consistent. First, frequency graphs of price reversals demonstrate
that the percentage of reversals is negatively related to margin levels.
Second, mean times between reversals are also negatively related to
margin levels. Third, our logit specifications concur that reversal
probabilities are negatively related to margin levels. We conclude that
the evidence consistently rejects the null of no association between
margin levels and stock price reversals. [2]
Below, we introduce the stock return data and estimate nontrading
probabilities for various levels of required margin. Then, we develop
our measure of price reversals and discuss our results in detail.
Linkage between trading costs and volatility
We begin with a brief review of the literature linking serial
dependence in stock returns to transactional considerations. Following
this literature review, we introduce a model in which prices are
determined by two investing clienteles: informed investors and
noise-trading investors.
The relevance of transactional considerations for markets
Niederhoffer and Osborne (1966) report that stock price reversals
occur two or three times more often than price continuations. Fama
(1970) suggests reversals are induced by the presence of orders to buy
or sell that are conditioned on the price of the stock. More recently,
researchers have been considering the possibility that the presence of
these reversals is indicative of noise trading, that is, trading by
investors who tend to participate in trading fads and whose trading
activity is not information based. Summers (1986) suggests that the
presence of a fad component in the determination of stock prices implies
that stock prices will reverse as fads dissipate. Some have suggested
introducing trading frictions as a means of mitigating the influence
fads may have on stock price volatility. The transactions-tax proposal
of Summers and Summers (1989) is a straightforward example of this
rationale. Transactions taxes raise trading costs, thereby reducing the
benefits derived from participating in fads. It has also been suggested
that stock margins can serve a similar function inasmuch as they also
introduce frictions through their effect on trading costs for levered
strategies. In general, as trading-cost levels increase, the extent of
fad-motivated trading activity can be expected to decline, thereby
diminishing any effects from these trades.
Contradicting this view is the recognition that the introduction of
frictions can have other consequences. Especially important,
trading-cost levels affect the benefit that can be derived from any
trading activity, not only those that are fad induced. This view
suggests that higher trading costs lessen liquidity, increasing price
volatility. Thus, the social usefulness of introducing trading frictions
depends on the net effects from affecting both fad trading and
liquidity.
The argument that underlies a linkage between price volatility and
transaction costs is that the relative size of positions taken by
noise-trading investors is influenced by the costs they incur when
entering into stock positions. For the same reason that demand curves
are downward sloping, the motivation to enter into stock positions
declines as the cost of entering rises. All investors can be expected to
invest less as their per-transaction fees rise. For a variety of
reasons, the incidence of these costs may have different effects on
investment decisions. The question we are framing here is whether these
effects can be ascribed to whether the investor is trading on
information or on noise.
The number of noise traders taking positions and the total number
of investors taking positions determine the impact of noise trading
activity. The proponents of a linkage between margin levels and stock
price volatility appear to have in mind a difference in the elasticity
of investment with respect to margin levels. Specifically, their
prediction stems from a response to margin changes at low levels by
noise-trading investors that is greater than the response of informed
investors. This may be the case, but if so, it is an expression of the
preferences of the two groups rather than an inherent property linking
transactions costs to price volatility.
Suppose every dollar invested by a noise-trading investor generates
a constant amount of noise. From the perspective of informed investors,
this noise can be a profit opportunity. Lower margins enable investment
of more dollars by noise traders--we do not know why they trade, but if
their trading costs decline, all else the same, it is reasonable to
predict they will trade more, so ceteris paribus lower margins increase
noise.
With respect to informed investors, we have a somewhat better
understanding of their decisions to trade--they can observe mispricing
and buy or sell accordingly so as to earn profits. From the perspective
of informed investors, mispricing induced by the noise-trading activity
can be a profit opportunity. It is a profit opportunity if the amount of
mispricing due to noise trading can be corrected by trades made by
informed investors (we will assume it can), and if the revenue from
trades by informed investors exceeds the cost of making the trade. As in
the case of noise-trading investors, a lower margin requirement implies
a lower cost of trading for informed investors. Thus, it is entirely
plausible to expect that any noise created will be offset by the trading
activity of informed traders. It is also plausible that informed
investing is not sufficient to eliminate the noise.
The point of the above is that analytic determination of the
linkage between stock price volatility and margin levels requires
greater specificity about the characteristics of informed and
noise-trading investors than is given here. These are not questions that
are readily amenable to analysis, but we might gain some insight into
these questions by examining data.
Margin levels and the probability of nontrading
Next, we introduce our data sample and report on some preliminary
tests to determine if margin levels affect trading activity. We find
evidence of greater nontrading during periods of high margin.
Our sample of daily returns is for a broad stock index over the
period January 1, 1902, through December 31, 1987. [3] The data,
described in Schwert (1990), combine the returns of several stock
indexes to obtain a continuously reported index of stock returns dating
from 1886. Schwert's study of the statistical attributes of the
spliced data series concludes they are homogenous; that is, seasonal
patterns appear similar across various sample periods.
Guiding our sample-period choice is the need to include all changes
in required margin by U.S. regulators (see figure 1)--the first being in
1935, the last in 1975. In addition, we include observations for the
pre-regulatory period to differentiate from any regulatory effects.
Observations after 1982 include those effects stemming from trading in
stock index futures contracts. Finally, we chose the sample end date to
include 1987, a year of unprecedented volatility.
We examine the relationship of autocorrelations in the return
series with levels of required margin to make inferences about the
effect of margin on nontrading of stocks within our sample portfolio. Lo
and MacKinlay (1990) demonstrate that nontrading of stocks within sample
portfolios induces positive autocorrelation in the time series of
returns for stock portfolios. [4] If investors condition their trading
activity on trading costs, then nontrading is likely to increase when
required-margin levels increase. Suppose, for example, that traders
restrict their trading activity to stocks whose returns are expected to
exceed their cost of trading. Under these circumstances, any changes in
trading costs implied by changes in margin levels would lead to changes
in the number of stocks traded. Thus, margin levels are a plausible
determinant of the nontrading probabilities: Nontrading probabilities
increase as the costs of maintaining margin deposits rise.
A further result of Lo and MacKinlay (1990) permits interpretation
of the first-order autocorrelation coefficient as an estimate of the
probability of nontrading of stocks within an index. Thus, we can
investigate the nontrading effect by estimating autocorrelation
coefficients conditional on their contemporaneous levels of required
margin. We employ the following specification:
1) [R.sub.t] = [[delta].sub.0] +
[[[sigma].sup.14].sub.i=1][[delta].sub.i][[D.sup.t-1].sub.i][R.sub.t- 1]
+ [[epsilon].sub.t],
where [R.sub.t] are stock returns at time t and [[D.sup.t-1].sub.i]
are indicator variables, one for each of the 14 levels of required
margin during the sample period ordered from lowest to highest. Each of
these indicator variables is set to one when the required margin at t -
1 is at level i; otherwise, they are set to zero.
The estimates are reported in table 1. The second column of the
table lists the margin level associated with each coefficient.
Generally, the coefficients on margin levels interacted with lagged
returns are larger at higher levels of required margin. For example, the
sum of the coefficients at the highest seven levels of margin (the last
seven coefficients listed) is 1.40973, while the sum of coefficients for
the lowest seven levels of margin (the first seven coefficients listed)
is 0.16889. This difference implies that the autocorrelation coefficient
is positively related to levels of margin and indicates that the
probability of nontrading increases with margin levels. We analyze the
significance of this difference in summed coefficients with an F test
for their equality. [5] The F statistic is 36.4, easily rejecting the
equality of these coefficient sums. The result, therefore, implies an
increase in nontrading probabilities at higher levels of margin,
suggesting that margin levels do affect trading activi ty. In the
following two sections, we examine price reversals to see if these
changes in trading activity are more pronounced among noise traders.
Preliminary examination of stock-price reversals
As noted above, we find a positive relationship between margin
levels and the likelihood of nontrading. If the incidence of nontrading
by noise traders increased more than that of informed traders, this
would lend support to the case that margin levels can affect mispricing.
Here, we report on price reversal patterns that suggest that the cost of
margined positions discourages noise-trading activity.
Consider a class of traders with a propensity to participate in
trading fads. Their trades are not information-based in the sense of
Black (1986), so we refer to them as noise traders. The presence of
these noise traders increases the chance that trading overreactions will
affect prices and that price changes will deviate from fundamental
values. [6] These deviations increase the value of informed trading,
motivating trades by information-based traders. Informed trades bring
prices back toward their fundamental values, so that subsequent price
changes can be expected to reverse the changes induced by noise trading.
Black (1971) refers to the speed of price adjustment following
noise-induced shocks as price resilience. This characterization of
markets implies that prices can be expected to reverse following price
shocks stemming from noise-trading activity. The frequency of
noise-trading shocks and, consequently, the frequency of reversals will
be related to the extent of trader participation in fads. Specifi cally,
price reversals can be expected to occur more frequently when
participants in fads make up a relatively large proportion of the
market.
Some suggest that the cost of placing margin deposits has a role in
determining the relative importance of these two categories of traders.
Such costs play a role similar to the transactions taxes suggested by
Summers and Summers (1989). If low margins encourage a relative increase
in the number of noise traders, then prices reverse more often.
Conversely, if high margins cause a relative decrease in the number of
noise traders, prices reverse less often. Thus, an association between
margin levels and reversals implies a relation between the level of
margin and the proportion of trading by noise traders. A negative
association suggests that margins raise trading costs and that these
higher costs deter participation in fads. We compute reversals, denoted
[r.sub.t], for the stock return sample, as follows:
2) [r.sub.t] = {1 if [[epsilon].sub.t] X [[epsilon].sub.t-1] [less
than] 0, 0 otherwise
where [[epsilon].sub.t] = [R.sub.t] - E([R.sub.t]/[[phi].sub.t]).
Equation 2 specifies an indicator variable assigned a value of one
on sample dates when the unanticipated portion of the return at time t
has the opposite sign as that of the unanticipated return at t - 1; on
other dates, the indicator variable is set to zero. Unanticipated
returns, denoted [[epsilon].sub.t], are defined as deviations of actual
returns from expectations. Expected returns are generated according to three characterizations of the market. The first assumes that stock
prices can be described by a martingale; that is, the price observed
today is an unbiased predictor of the price that can be expected to be
observed tomorrow. Hence, the expected return on stock purchased today
is zero or [E.sub.t-1]([R.sub.t]) = 0. The second assumes that stock
prices are a submartingale with constant expected returns; that is,
E([R.sub.t]) = [alpha]. The third assumes that stock prices are a
submartingale with time-varying expected returns; that is, E([R.sub.t])
= [alpha][[sigma].sub.t]. The third approach estima tes [[sigma].sub.t]
using the iterative method suggested by Schwert (1989) and extended in
Bessembinder and Seguin (1993).
This iterative method first regresses the time series of stock
returns on a constant. We use the absolute values of the residuals from
this regression as risk estimates at each date in the sample. We then
regress the returns on ten lags of these risk estimates. This generates
risk-adjusted expected returns. Inclusion of the residuals from this
second regression of returns on lagged-risk estimates incorporates
temporal variation of risk into the expected-return metric.
We then classify these reversals according to their corresponding
levels of required margin and study the relative frequencies within
these classifications. Stating the frequency of reversals as a fraction
of the number of observations provides a means of estimating the
probability of a reversal possibly conditional on category i; that is,
3) [P.sub.i] = [r.sub.i]/[n.sub.i],
where [r.sub.i] is the number of reversals in margin category i;
and [n.sub.i] is the number of observations in margin category i.
Figure 2 illustrates this approach. We compute reversals according
to the martingale assumption, then classify them by their year of
occurrence and their relative frequencies calculated based on equation
3. The figure graphs these relative frequencies. Bar heights illustrate
the relative frequency of stock reversals for each year of the sample.
The graph suggests a modest but permanent decline in reversal
probabilities occurring in the mid-1930s. Comparing pre-and post-1934
reversals, reversal occurrences averaged 48.4 percent of trading dates
prior to 1934. After 1934, average reversal occurrences declined to 43.3
percent of trading dates. [7]
Figure 1 (on page 4) gives margin requirements over this sample
period. Initial margin requirements prior to October 15, 1934, were set
by the industry. These were obtained from press accounts. After October
1934, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System set margin
requirements. We obtained these requirements and their effective dates
from Hardouvelis (1990). The higher margin requirements subsequent to
their determination by regulatory authority do correspond to the lower
reversal probabilities illustrated in figure 2. However, the decline
also corresponds to the increased regulation of the stock market through
the provisions of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).
Alternatively, one might conclude that innovations such as those in
trading or communications technology led to a change in the occurrence
of reversals. We examine these possibilities more rigorously in the next
section.
Table 2 reports the standard deviation of returns and percentages
of reversal occurrence at each level of required margin. [8] The table
does suggest a relationship between the conditional probability of a
reversal and margin requirements. The last row of the table gives the
unconditional probability of a reversal for each of the expected-return
models. Comparing these unconditional probabilities with the conditional
probabilities in the corresponding columns, the conditional
probabilities exceed the unconditional probability at each of the five
lowest margin categories. For the remaining nine categories, the
unconditional probability is exceeded at the 55 percent margin level and
at the 100 percent level for the martingale series. This result suggests
that, with few exceptions, margin levels are negatively related to the
odds of observing stock-price reversals.
The standard deviations of stock returns reported in table 2 are
generally higher at low margin levels; correspondingly, they are higher
when price reversals are more likely. The evidence suggests that low
margin levels are associated with a higher likelihood of price reversals
and increased levels of stock price volatility.
An alternative measure of reversal frequency is the time between
stock price reversals. Let [T.sub.t]([r.sub.t] = 1) be the date of a
reversal that occurs at time t, then [[tau].sub.t] = [T.sub.t]([r.sub.t]
= 1) - [T.sub.t-k]([r.sub.t-k] = 1) gives the number of days since a
reversal that occurred k periods previously. These intervals can be
measured in calendar units or in trading-day units. Measured in calendar
time, the average time between reversals prior to October 15, 1934, was
2.49 days. [9] After this date, the average time between reversals
increased to 3.11 days. This calendar time measure is dependent on the
length of any intervening nontrading intervals and the presumption that
reversals are uncorrelated with trading frequency. To avoid dependence
on nontrading intervals, we also use a trading time measure: the number
of trading days between reversals. [10] The mean number of trading days
between reversals is 2.03 days prior to October 15, 1934, and 2.26 days
after that date. Both measures indica te an increase in the time between
reversals following the introduction of regulatory oversight. Thus,
reversals occur less often after this date. This is consistent with the
decline in the relative frequency of reversals depicted in figure 2.
To relate this effect to margin regulation, we regress
[[tau].sub.t] on the percentages of required initial margin at t. This
specification considers the relationship of margin with the mean time
between reversals. [11] Measuring the dependent variable in calendar
units, the coefficient is .0175; and measured in trading time units it
is .0066. Standard distributional assumptions about the errors of this
regression imply that the coefficients of both regressions differ
significantly from zero at better than the 1 percent level. [12] These
coefficients imply that higher levels of margin increase the mean time
between reversals. In terms of the primary focus of this article, higher
levels of margin decrease the relative frequency of reversals. Thus,
these statistics, the average times between reversals and the regression
coefficients, offer an alternative means of stating the results
indicated by figures 1 and 2: margin levels rose in 1934 and reversals
declined after that date. In the next section, we restate these
preliminary results in terms of their effects on conditional
probabilities.
Logit specification
Estimating reversal probabilities conditional on margin level
Let [Z.sub.i] represent an index, which measures the propensity of
the market to produce a reversal. Under the null hypothesis that low
margins encourage overreactions as demonstrated by stock price
reversals, then the index should be negatively related to levels of
required margin. Linearizing this relationship, we can write
4) [Z.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][M.sub.i],
so that levels of the index are predicted by the product of [beta]
and the level of margin. The overreaction null predicts that
[[beta].sub.1], will be less than zero. The level of this index can also
be described as determining the probability of encountering a reversal
at the ith level of margin. We can write this as [P.sub.i] =
F([Z.sub.i]). Taking FO to be the cumulative logistic probability
function, then the probability of a reversal is given by
5) [P.sub.i] = F([Z.sub.i]) = 1/1 + [e.sup.-[z.sub.i]] = 1/1 +
[e.sup.-([[beta].sub.0]+[[beta].sub.1][M.sub.i])
Taking logs and rearranging gives the following logit
specification:
6) log [[P.sub.i]/1-[P.sub.i]] = [[beta].sub.0] +
[[beta].sub.1][M.sub.1] + [[epsilon].sub.i]
We estimate equation 5 using the method of maximum likelihood.
Matrix notation simplifies exposition of the likelihood function. Note
that the expected value of [Z.sub.i] can now be written
[x.sub.i]'[delta], so that the expression for the log likelihood is
7) log l = [[[sigma].sup.T].sub.i=1] [r.sub.t] log
[F([x.sub.i]'[beta])] + (1-[r.sub.t]), log
[1-F([x.sub.i]'[beta])].
It is useful to compare our approach to studying reversals with
that used by Stoll and Whaley (1990). Their measure of reversals signs
the return at t based on the return at t - 1: They multiply the return
at t by-1 when the previous return is positive and by +1 when the return
at t - 1 is negative. Thus, their measure is positive when a reversal
occurs and negative otherwise. Tests of hypotheses employing the Stoll
and Whaley measure examine associations between explanatory variables
and the expected portion of the reversal measure. Confirmation or
rejection of these hypotheses requires the explained portion to exceed a
quantity proportional to the estimated residual variance. Thus, their
approach is subject to heteroskedasticity when the underlying return
series is heteroskedastic. The logit approach introduced here uses only
the sign of subsequent returns; this avoids dependence on the
stationarity of the return distribution.
Table 3 reports our estimates of the logit specification given in
equation 6. For each of the expected-return models, conditional
probabilities are negatively related to initial margin requirements. We
use the likelihood ratio test to evaluate the specifications. The null
of no effect is rejected for each of the return-generating models at
better than the 5 percent level. The impact of a 1 percent change in
required margin on the probability of a reversal is obtained from the
expression
8) [delta]PROB [approximate]
[[beta].sub.0][[P.sub.i](1-[P.sub.i])].
To obtain the effect of margin on reversal probabilities, we
evaluate this expression at the unconditional probabilities given in the
last row of table 2. In each case, the effect of margin on reversal
probabilities, while statistically significant, is economically small.
Results reported in table 3 indicate that an increase in required
margin from the present 50 percent to 60 percent would reduce reversal
probabilities by less than 1 percent, a very modest impact. The
magnitude of this effect should be compared with the change in trading
costs. Holding rates constant, the conjectured increase in required
margin would increase the interest cost of placing margin deposits by 20
percent. Thus, a relatively large increase in the cost of carrying
margined positions appears to have a small effect on reversal
probabilities. However, table 1 of Salinger (1989, p. 126) indicates
that margined positions seldom exceed 2 percent of the market value of
outstanding stock. [13] Thus, since relatively few positions are
affected by the cost increase, the magnitude of the effect from a cost
increase can also be expected to be small. While this explanation is
consistent with the small magnitude we report, it also increases the
importance of investigating alternative possibilities. One might, fo r
example, conclude that the higher margin levels observed after 1934 are
capturing impacts that are more properly attributable to other changes
coming after that date. We explore this possibility next.
Possibility that margin proxies for other effects
To control for the possibility that margin levels proxy for other
explanations of reversal probabilities, we augment the logit
specification with several additional variables. Campbell, Grossman, and
Wang (1993) find that return autocorrelations are negatively related to
lagged trading activity. This implies that reversals are more likely in
periods following heavy trading activity. We use indicator variables as
controls for differences in regulation in the pre- and post-1934
periods, for the effects of Monday trading, [14] for the effects of
stock index futures since their introduction in 1982, and as a means of
conducting a "Salinger" test for market volatility differences
before and after 1946. Finally, we add the observation year to capture
innovations in information and trading technology occurring during the
sample period. Information technology might be expected to increase the
speed at which information is disseminated and, thereby, impounded into
stock prices. In particular, one might expect thin tra ding to decline
over the sample period.
These considerations suggest the following specification:
9) log[[P.sub.i]/1-[P.sub.i]]= [[beta].sub.0]
[[beta].sub.1][M.sub.i]] + [[beta].sub.2] [Year.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3]
[REG.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i],
where [Year.sub.i] is the year the reversal occurred, and
[REG.sub.i] is an indicator variable set to unity following the
introduction of stock market regulation by the SEC on October 15, 1934,
and to zero on the prior dates. As in the previous specification, the
relevance of the classifying variables is indicated by a nonzero coefficient.
Table 4 reports results from this specification. As before, we use
maximum likelihood procedures. The magnitude of the coefficients on
margin levels declines but remains significantly less than zero. We
reject the explanation that the margin coefficients of the previous
specification are capturing the effects of regulatory oversight or
innovations in trading and information technologies. Thus, we reject the
possibility that margin levels proxy for these other explanatory
variables. As the focus of this article is on the relevance of margin,
we only summarize the remaining coefficients here. The coefficients on
year variables are significantly less than zero. This is consistent with
the proposition that reductions in reversals can be attributed to
innovations in information or trading technology during the sample
period. On the other hand, the coefficient on regulatory oversight is
reliably positive, suggesting that regulation has increased the odds of
reversals.
Conclusion
Autocorrelations of the returns for a broad index are higher in
periods when required margin is high. This implies an increase in the
probability of non-trading and is suggestive of a negative relationship
between margin and stock market participation. To see if the
participation of fad-based trading is more or less sensitive to changes
in trading costs, we examine return reversals for a stock index for the
period 1902 through 1987. Preliminary evidence suggests that reversal
frequencies decreased substantially after 1934. This coincides with
higher levels of required margin and with increased regulatory oversight
of the stock markets. The results of our logit specifications imply that
margin levels are negatively related to the probability of reversals.
This permits us to reject the null that margin levels are unrelated to
reversals. We also investigate alternative explanations for this result.
We find that controls for time and for the introduction of regulatory
oversight in 1934 do not explain changes in reversal probability. Also,
our logit specifications appear to be robust to day-of-the-week effects.
Our statistical results indicate that high margins increase the
extent of nontrading, and that margin levels are negatively related to
the probability of stock price reversals. Rejection of the null of no
association implies that margin levels do influence the observed
distribution of stock returns. These results are consistent with the
conclusion of Summers and Summers (1989): The cost of placing margin
deposits acts as a tax. At low levels of this "tax," noise
traders enter the market, increasing the odds that prices will diverge from their fundamental levels. Reversals occur when prices return to
their fundamental levels. At high levels of the "tax," noise
traders find it costly to participate and overreactions occur less
often. Our findings suggest that information traders are less sensitive
to these trading costs.
Do the results indicate that low margins lead to higher volatility?
We think not. What we can say is that margin levels do appear to be
positively related to the price reversals we would expect to observe
were fads a frequent and pervasive motive for trading. But this is
inadequate support for a change in margin policy. Further research is
needed for two reasons. First, to rule out other causes for our observed
association between margin levels and price reversals. Second, to more
firmly establish a link between fad trading and the extent of volatility
that might result. With clearer evidence on these matters in hand,
policymakers would then face a question of which instrument is best
suited to managing volatility. It may be the case that a transactions
tax would be a more effective instrument for this purpose than
controlling margins.
Paul Kofman is a professor in the Quantitative Finance Research
Group, University of Technology, Sydney, Australia. James T. Moser is a
senior economist and research officer at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago.
NOTES
(1.) Hsieh and Miller (1990) provide a technical explanation for
this point.
(2.) We also examine the robustness of these logit specifications.
We augment the specification with various controls. Introduction of
these controls does not alter our primary conclusion that the
probability of price reversals is negatively related to the level of
margin.
(3.) We are grateful to Bill Schwert who supplied the stock return
data.
(4.) The rationale is that nontraded stocks within the index are
affected by market-wide events; however, the price implication of that
news is evidenced after its impact on the stock index. This induces a
positive correlation in the observed returns of an index.
(5.) We also ran regressions allowing for shifts in the intercept.
The coefficients on margin interacted with lagged returns are
substantially the same as those reported here.
(6). Other characterizations of noise-trading activity can also
produce price reversals. Admati and Pfleiderer (1988) and DeLong,
Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann (1990) describe some alternative modes
of noise trading.
(7.) A Student's t test adjusted for unequal variances rejects
the equality of these means. The statistic is 5.61, indicating a
reliable difference in the means of annual pre- and post-1934 reversal
percentages at better than the 5 percent level.
(8.) Reversals occurring at t + 1 are classified by the level of
margin at t. Classifying by the level of margin at t + 1 does not alter
our conclusions. This is not unexpected; as figure 2 demonstrates,
required margin changes occur infrequently.
(9.) At the beginning of World War I, trading was suspended on the
New York Stock Exchange. Thus, the first observation (a reversal dated
December 12, 1914) at the resumption of trading is excluded from the
calculation of this mean.
(10.) Dependence of reversals on the occurrence of a nontrading
interval is suggested by evidence that expected returns vary by day of
the week. DeGennaro (1993) summarizes the literature for day-of-the-week
effects in stock prices. We introduce a control for this effect in the
next section.
(11.) Changes in margin are much less frequent than reversals;
thus, relatively few observations are affected by a change of required
margin during the period between reversals.
(12.) However, Cox (1970, chapter 3) suggests this may be a strong
assumption. The logit specifications of the next section avoid this
criticism.
(13.) Moser (1992, p. 9) reports similar percentages of margined
positions through 1988.
(14.) DeGennaro (1993) summarizes extensive evidence that stock
returns vary by day of the week.
REFERENCES
Admati, Anat R., and Paul Pfleiderer, 1988, "A theory of
intraday patterns: Volume and price variability," Review of
Financial Studies, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 3-40.
Bessembinder, Hendrik, and Paul J. Seguin, 1993, "Price
volatility, trading volume, and market depth: Evidence from futures
markets," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 28,
No. 1, pp.21-39.
Black, Fisher, 1986, "Noise," Journal of Finance, Vol.
41, No. 3, pp. 529-544.
_____, 1971, "Random walk and portfolio management,"
Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 27, pp. 16-22.
Campbell, J. Y., S. J. Grossman, and J. Wang, 1993, "Trading
volume and serial correlation in stock returns," Quarterly Journal
of Economics, Vol. 108, pp. 905-939.
Chance, Don, 1991, "The effect of margin on the volatility of
stocks and derivative markets: A review of the evidence," Salomon
Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, New York
University, Monograph Series in Finance and Economics, working paper,
No. 1990-2.
Cox, D. R., 1970, Analysis of Binary Data, London: Methuen.
DeGennaro, Ramon P., 1993, "Mondays, Fridays, and Friday the
Thirteenth," in Advances in Quantitative Analysis of Finance and
Accounting, Vol. 2A, C. F. Lee (ed.), Greenwich, CT: JAI Press Inc., pp.
115-137.
DeLong, B. J., A. Shleifer, L. H. Summers, and R. J. Waldmann,
1990, "Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing
rational speculation," Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, No. 2, pp.
379-395.
Fama, E., 1970, "Efficient capital markets: A review of theory
and empirical work," Journal of Finance, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp.
383-417.
France, Virginia Grace, 1992, "The regulation of margin
requirements," in Margins and Market Integrity, Lester G. Telser (ed.), Chicago: Mid America Institute and Probus Books, pp. 1-47.
Hardouvelis, Gikas A., 1990, "Margin requirements, volatility,
and the transitory components of stock prices," American Economic
Review, Vol. 80, No. 4, pp. 736--762.
Hsieh, David, and Merton Miller, 1990, "Margin regulation and
stock market volatility," Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, No. 1, pp.
3-29.
Judge, George G., W. E. Griffiths, R. Carter Hill, Helmut
Lutkepohl, and Tsoung-Chao Lee, 1985, The Theory and Practice of
Econometrics, New York, NY: John Wiley and Sons.
Lo, Andrew W., and A. Craig MacKinlay, 1990, "An econometric analysis of nonsynchronous trading," Journal of Econometrics, Vol.
45, No. 112, pp. 181-211.
Moser, James T., 1992, "Determining margin for futures
contracts: The role of private interests and the relevance of excess
volatility," Economic Perspectives, March/April, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, pp. 2-18.
Niederhoffer, V., and M. F. M. Osborne, 1966, "Market making
and reversal of the stock exchange," Journal of the American
Statistical Association, Vol. 61, No. 316, pp. 897-916.
Salinger, Michael A., 1989, "Stock market margin requirements
and volatility: Implications for the regulation of stock index
futures," Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 3, No. 3,
pp. 121-138.
Schwert, G. William, 1990, "Indexes of U.S. stock prices from
1802 to 1987," Journal of Business, Vol. 63, No. 3, pp. 399-426.
_____, 1989, "Business cycles, financial crises, and stock
volatility," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
Vol. 31, pp. 83-126.
Stoll, Hans, and Robert Whaley, 1990, "Program trading and
individual stock returns: Ingredients of the triple-witching brew,"
Journal of Business, Vol. 63, No. 1, Part 2, pp. s165-s192.
Summers, L. H., 1986, "Does the stock market rationally
reflect fundamental values?," Journal of Finance, Vol. 41, July,
pp. 591-601.
Summers, Lawrence H., and Victoria P. Summers, 1989, "When
finance markets work too well: A cautious case for a securities
transactions tax," Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 3,
No. 2/3, pp. 261-286.
TABLE 1
Autocorrelation coefficients interacted with required margin levels
Margin
level Coefficient t statistic
[[delta].sub.0] n.a. 0.00033 4.95
[[delta].sub.1] 20 0.02334 1.35
[[delta].sub.2] 25 0.02405 2.24
[[delta].sub.3] 30 -0.07724 -2.46
[[delta].sub.4] 40 0.03527 1.90
[[delta].sub.5] 45 0.02995 0.60
[[delta].sub.6] 50 0.16991 10.36
[[delta].sub.7] 55 -0.03639 -1.14
[[delta].sub.8] 60 0.14610 1.09
[[delta].sub.9] 65 0.33593 7.52
[[delta].sub.10] 70 0.13267 4.33
[[delta].sub.11] 75 0.12949 3.26
[[delta].sub.12] 80 0.36414 4.90
[[delta].sub.13] 90 0.17883 2.22
[[delta].sub.14] 100 0.12257 2.54
Notes: [R.sub.t] = [[delta].sub.0] + [[[sigma].sup.14].sub.i=1]
[[delta].sub.i] [[D.sup.t-1].sub.i] [R.sub.t-1] +
[[epsilon].sub.t], where [R.sub.t] is the return on date t; and
[[D.sup.t-1].sub.l] are indicator variables for the 14 levels of
margin during the sample period 1902 to 1987 ordered from lowest to
highest.
n.a. indicates not applicable.
TABLE 2
Initial margin requirements and stock price reversals, 1902-87
Percentage of observations in
which stock index reversed
Standard
Initial margin deviation
(percent) Observations of return
E([R.sub.t]) = 0
20 206 2.97 50.24
25 8,944 1.01 48.21
30 326 1.83 53.68
40 2,182 1.20 47.48
45 390 1.04 50.00
50 5,137 0.89 43.33
55 770 1.17 46.75
60 77 0.86 40.26
65 679 0.89 35.94
70 2,382 0.69 41.52
75 1,298 0.73 42.68
80 454 0.66 38.11
90 448 0.60 44.20
100 307 1.23 45.93
All levels 23,803 1.04 45.54
Initial margin
(percent) E([R.sub.t]) = E([R.sub.t]) =
[alpha] [alpha][[sigma].sub.t]
20 50.24 50.24
25 48.75 48.96
30 52.15 52.76
40 48.81 48.26
45 51.80 50.26
50 44.16 44.16
55 47.92 48.18
60 37.66 40.26
65 36.97 36.38
70 42.15 42.11
75 43.99 44.30
80 38.11 38.99
90 43.30 42.41
100 45.28 43.97
All levels 46.22 46.23
TABLE 3
Maximum likelihood estimates of price reversal variable on margin
Expected return method
E([R.sub.t]) = 0 E([R.sub.t]) =
[alpha]
[[beta].sub.0] 0.061594 0.087633
(0.02213) (0.01226)
[[beta].sub.1] -0.005387 -0.005355
(0.00049) (0.00035)
[delta]PROB -0.00134 -0.00133
E([R.sub.t]) =
[alpha][[sigma].sub.t]
[[beta].sub.0] 0.090183
(0.01148)
[[beta].sub.1] -0.005515
(0.00034)
[delta]PROB -0.00137
Notes: log[[P.sub.i]/1-[P.sub.i]] = [[beta].sub.0] +
[[beta].sub.1][M.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i] where [P.sub.i] are the
ratios of reversals observed during each margin-level regime to the
number of trading dates during that interval; and [M.sub.i] are the
levels of initial margin in percent. Standard errors are in parentheses.
All coefficients are significant at the 1 percent level.
TABLE 4
Maximum likelihood estimates for the augmented regression
Expected return method
E([R.sub.t]) = 0 E([R.sub.t]) = [alpha]
[[beta].sub.0] 7.838990 7.907148
(0.02420) (0.01903)
[[beta].sub.1] -0.003882 -0.004756
(0.00081) (0.00077)
[[beta].sub.2] -0.004068 -0.004083
(0.00002) (0.00002)
[[beta].sub.3] 0.100239 0.145948
(0.02294) (0.01935)
[delta]PROB -0.000963 -0.001182
E([R.sub.t]) =
[alpha][[sigma].sub.t]
[[beta].sub.0] 8.156308
(0.02336)
[[beta].sub.1] -0.004186
(0.00077)
[[beta].sub.2] -0.004217
(0.00002)
[[beta].sub.3] 0.115890
(0.01913)
[delta]PROB -0.001040
Notes: log[[P.sub.i]/1-[P.sub.i]] = [[beta].sub.0] +
[[beta].sub.1][M.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.2] [Year.sub.1] +
[[beta].sub.3][REG.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i] where [P.sub.i] are the
ratios of reversals observed during each margin-level regime to the
number of trading dates during that interval: [M.sub.i] are the levels
of initial margin in percent; and Year is the year that the reversal
occurred. Standard errors are in parentheses. All coefficients are
significant at the 1 percent level.
[Graph omitted]
[Graph omitted]