Subordinated debt as bank capital: A proposal for regulatory reform.
Evanoff, Douglas D. ; Wall, Larry D.
Introduction and summary
Last year, a Federal Reserve Study Group, in which we participated,
examined the use of subordinated debt as a tool for disciplining bank
risk taking. The study was completed prior to the passage of the 1999
U.S. Financial Services Modernization Act and the results are reported
in Kwast et al. (1999). The report provides a broad survey of the
academic literature on subordinated debt and of prevailing practices
within the current market for subordinated debt issued by banking
organizations. Although the report discusses a number of the issues to
be considered in developing a policy proposal, providing an explicit
proposal was not the purpose of the report. Instead, it concludes with a
call for additional research into a number of related topics.
In this article, we present a proposal for the use of subordinated
debt in bank capital regulation. Briefly, our proposal would require
that banks hold a minimum level of subordinated debt and be required to
approach the marketplace on a somewhat regular basis to roll over that
debt. We believe the proposal is particularly timely for a variety of
reasons, one of which is that Congress recently demonstrated its
interest in the topic when it passed the U.S. Financial Services
Modernization Act (Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act). The act instructs the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve and the Secretary of the Treasury to
conduct a joint study of the potential use of subordinated debt to bring
market forces to bear on the operations of large financial institutions
and to protect the deposit insurance funds. [1] The act also requires
large U.S. national banks to have outstanding (but not necessarily
subordinated) debt that is highly rated by independent agencies in order
to engage in certain types of financial acti vities. Another reason to
consider alternatives now is that banks in most developed countries,
including the U.S., are relatively healthy. This reduces the probability
that a greater reliance on market discipline will cause a temporary
market disruption. Additionally, history shows that introducing reforms
during relatively tranquil times is preferable to being forced to act
during a crisis. [2]
Perhaps the most important reason that now may be a good time to
consider greater reliance on subordinated debt is that international
efforts to reform existing capital standards are highlighting the
weaknesses of the alternatives. In 1988, the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision published the International Convergence of Capital
Measurement and Capital Standards, which established international
agreement on minimum risk-based capital adequacy ratios. [3] The paper,
often referred to as the Basel Capital Accord, relied on very rough
measures of a bank's credit risk exposure, however, and banks have
increasingly engaged in regulatory arbitrage to reduce the cost of
complying with the requirements (Jones, 2000). The result is that by the
end of the 1990s, the risk-based capital requirements had become more of
a compliance issue than a safety and soundness issue for the largest and
most sophisticated banks.
Bank supervisors have recognized the problems associated with the
1988 accord, and the Basel Committee recently proposed two possible
alternatives: a standardized approach that uses credit rating agencies to evaluate individual loans in banks' portfolios and an internal
ratings approach that uses the ratings of individual loans that are
assigned by banks' internal ratings procedures. An important
element of both of these proposals is that they rely on risk measures
obtained from private sector participants rather than formulas devised
by supervisors. [4] The use of market risk measures has the potential to
provide substantially more accurate risk measurement than would any
supervisory formula. Market participants have the flexibility to
evaluate all aspects of a position and assign higher risk weights where
appropriate.
Whether either of these approaches would result in a significant
improvement, however, is questionable. The approaches share two
significant weaknesses. First, both ask for opinions rather than relying
on private agents' behavior. Economists have long been trained to
focus on prices and quantities established in arms-length transactions
rather than on surveys of individual opinions. The problem with opinions
is that individuals' responses may depend not only on their beliefs
but also on what they want the questioner to think. Second, the reliance
in this case on opinions is especially problematic because the two
parties being asked about a bank's risk exposure both have an
incentive to underestimate that exposure. The firm seeking a rating
compensates the ratings agencies. If the primary purpose of the rating
is to satisfy bank supervisors, then firms will have a strong incentive
to pressure the agencies to supply higher ratings. [5] The incentive
conflict for banks is even more direct. The intent of Basel's
capital proposal appears to be to require banks to hold more capital
than they otherwise would. If this is true, banks will have incentives
to systematically underestimate their risk exposure.
The use of a risk measure obtained from the subordinated debt
market has the potential to avoid both of these problems. The measure
could use actual prices rather than some individual's opinion.
Further, the interests of subordinated debt creditors are closely
aligned with those of bank supervisors, in that subordinated creditors
are at risk of loss whenever a bank fails.
Below, we summarize some of the existing subordinated debt
proposals. Then, we introduce our new proposal, address some of the
common concerns raised about the viability of subordinated debt
proposals, and explain how our proposal addresses these concerns.
Brief summary of past proposals
Since the mid- 1980s there have been a number of regulatory reform proposals aimed at capturing the benefits of subordinated debt
(sub-debt). [6] Below, we provide a partial review of previous proposals
that emphasizes the characteristics on which our proposal rests. (These
are surveyed in greater detail in Kwast et al., 1999). It was common in
the earlier proposals for the authors not to provide a comprehensive
plan, but instead to stress the expected benefits and describe how these
could be realized. Specific characteristics were typically excluded to
avoid having the viability of the proposals determined by the acceptance
of the details. The typical benefits of the proposals relate to the
ability of sub-debt to provide a capital cushion and to impose both
direct and derived discipline to banks and from the tax benefits of
debt. [7] These benefits include the following:
* a bank riskiness or asset quality signal for regulators and
market participants,
* a more prompt failure resolution process, resulting in fewer
losses to the insurance fund,
* a more methodical failure resolution process because debtholders
unlike demand depositors must wait until the debt matures to
"walk" away from the bank rather than run, and
* a lower cost of capital because of the tax advantages of
deducting interest payments on debt as an expense, enabling banks to
reduce their cost of capital and/or supervisors to increase capital
requirements.
Horvitz (1983, 1984) discusses each of these advantages in his
initial sub-debt proposal and extends that discussion in Benston et al.
(1986). He challenges the view that equity capital is necessarily
preferable to debt. While equity is permanent and losses can indeed be
charged against it, he questions why one would want to keep a troubled
bank in operation long enough to make this feature relevant. Similarly,
while interest on debt does represent a fixed charge against bank
earnings, whereas dividends on equity do not, a bank with problems
significant enough to prevent these interest payments has most likely
already incurred deposit withdrawals and has reached, or is approaching,
insolvency. Arguing that higher capital levels are needed at the bank
level and are simply not feasible through equity alone, Horvitz states
that subdebt requirements of "say, 4 percent of assets" are a
means to increase total capital requirements to 9 percent to 10 percent.
Without providing specifics, he argues that debtholders would logically
require debt covenants that would give them the right to close or take
over the bank once net worth was exhausted. Thus, sub-debt is seen as an
ideal cushion for the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC).
Keehn (1988) incorporates sub-debt as a centerpiece of the
comprehensive "FRB-Chicago Proposal" for deregulation. [8] The
plan calls for a modification of the 8 percent capital requirement to
require that a minimum of 4 percent of risk-weighted assets be held as
sub-debt. The bonds would have maturities of no less than five years,
with the issues being staggered to ensure that between 10 percent and 20
percent of the debt would mature and be rolled over each year. A
bank's inability to do so would serve as a clear signal that it was
in financial trouble, triggering regulatory restrictions and debt
covenants. [9] Debt covenants would enable the debtholders to initiate
closure procedures and would convert debtholders to an equity position
once equity was exhausted. They would have a limited time to
recapitalize the bank, find a suitable acquirer, or liquidate the bank.
Keehn argues that debtholders could be expected to effectively
discipline bank behavior and provide for an orderly resolution process
when fail ure did occur. The discipline imposed by sub-debt holders
could differ significantly from that imposed by depositors as holders of
outstanding sub-debt could not run from the bank, but could only walk as
issues matured. The potential for regulatory forbearance is also thought
to be less as holders of sub-debt would be less concerned with giving
the troubled bank additional time to "correct" its problems
and would pressure regulators to act promptly when banks in which they
had invested encountered difficulties.
To address concerns about the mispriced bank safety net and
potential losses to the insurance fund, Wall (1989) introduces a
sub-debt plan aimed at creating a banking environment that, while
maintaining deposit insurance, would function like an environment that
did not have deposit insurance. Wall's plan is to have banks issue
and maintain "puttable" sub-debt equal to 4 percent to 5
percent of risk-weighted assets. If debtholders exercised the put
option, that is, if they required the bank to redeem its debt, the bank
would have 90 days to make the necessary adjustments to ensure the
minimum regulatory requirements were still satisfied. That is, either
retire the debt and continue to meet the regulatory requirement because
of excess debt holdings, issue new puttable debt, or shrink assets to
satisfy the requirement. If the bank could not satisfy the requirement
after 90 days, it would be resolved. The put characteristic has
advantages in that it would force the bank to continually satisfy the
market of its s oundness. Additionally, while earlier plans discussed
the need for bond covenants to protect debtholders, all contingencies
would be covered under this plan as the market could demand redemption
of the bonds without cause. This would essentially eliminate the
practice of regulatory forbearance, which was a significant concern at
the time, and would subject the bank to increased market discipline.
Wall also stresses the need for restrictions on debtholders to limit
insider holdings.
Calomiris (1997, 1998, 1999) augments previous sub-debt proposals
by requiring a minimal requirement (say 2 percent of total assets) and
imposing a yield ceiling (say 50 basis points above the riskless rate).
The spread ceiling is seen as a simple means of implementing regulatory
discipline for banks. If banks cannot roll over the debt at the mandated
spread, they would be required to shrink their risk-weighted assets to
stay compliant. Debt would have a two-year maturity with issues being
staggered to have equal portions come due each month. This would limit
the maximum required monthly asset reduction to approximately 4 percent
of assets. To ensure adequate discipline, Calomiris also incorporates
restrictions on who would be eligible to hold the debt. [10]
The effectiveness of any sub-debt requirement depends critically on
the structure and characteristics of the program. Most importantly, the
characteristics should be consistent with the regulatory objectives,
such as increasing direct discipline to alter risk behavior, increasing
derived discipline, or limiting or eliminating regulatory forbearance.
Keehn, for example, is particularly interested in derived discipline.
Wall's proposal is most effective at addressing regulatory
forbearance. Calomiris's spread ceiling most directly uses derived
discipline to force the bank into behavioral changes when the spread
begins to bind.
We believe that sub-debt's greatest value in the near term is
as a risk signal. The earliest proposals had limited discussion of the
use of sub-debt for derived regulatory discipline. The next round of
plans, such as those by Keehn and Wall, use derived discipline, but the
only signal they obtain from the sub-debt market is the bank's
ability to issue the debt. We have considerable sympathy for this
approach. These types of plans maximize the scope for the free market to
allocate resources by imposing minimal restrictions while eliminating
forbearance and protecting the deposit insurance fund. However, the cost
of providing bank managers with this much freedom is to delay regulatory
intervention until a bank is deemed by the markets to be "too risky
to save." As Benston and Kaufman (1988) argue, proposals to delay
regulatory intervention until closure may be time inconsistent in that
such abrupt action may be perceived by regulators as suboptimal when the
tripwire is triggered. Moreover, market discipline wi ll be eroded to
the extent that market participants do not believe the plan will be
enforced. Benston and Kaufman argue that a plan of gradually stricter
regulatory intervention as a bank's financial condition worsens may
be more credible. A version of that proposal, prompt corrective action,
was adopted as part of the FDIC Improvement Act of 1991 (FDICIA).
Using sub-debt rates, Calomiris provides a mechanism for this
progressive discipline that in theory could last approximately two
years. Tn practice, however, his plan would likely provide the same sort
of abrupt discipline as the prior proposals, with the primary difference
being that Calomiris's plan would likely trigger the discipline
while the bank was in a stronger condition. His plan requires banks to
shrink if they cannot issue subordinated debt at a sufficiently small premium. This would provide a period during which the bank could respond
by issuing new equity. If the bank could not or did not issue equity,
then it would most likely call in maturing loans to good borrowers and
sell its most liquid assets to minimize its losses. However, the most
liquid assets are also likely to be among the lowest risk assets,
implying that with each monthly decline in size, the bank would be left
with a less liquid and more risky portfolio. This trend is likely to
reduce most banks' viability significantly within, a t most, a few
months. Yet, the previous proposals that would rely on a bank's
ability to issue subordinated debt at any price also give managers some
time to issue new equity either by automatically imposing a stay
(Wall's proposal) or by requiring relatively infrequent rollovers
(Keehn's proposal). Thus, Calomiris's proposal is subject to
the same sorts of concerns that arise with the other proposals.
Although Calomiris's proposal for relying on progressive
discipline is more abrupt than it appears at first glance, his
suggestion that regulators use the rates on sub-debt provides a
mechanism for phasing in stricter discipline. In the next section, we
describe our proposal, which offers a combination of Calomiris's
idea of using market rates with Benston and Kaufman's proposal for
progressively increasing discipline. [11]
Our sub-debt proposal differs from previous ones in that it is more
comprehensive, with an implementation schedule and a discussion of the
necessary changes from current regulatory arrangements. The timing for
such reform also seems particularly good as there is a growing consensus
that a market-driven means to augment supervisory discipline is needed.
Furthermore, banks as a group are relatively healthy, creating an
environment in which a carefully thought out plan can be implemented
instead of the hurriedly imposed regulations that sometimes follow a
financial crisis.
A new comprehensive Sub-debt proposal
As discussed earlier, banking organizations' entry into new
activities is raising additional questions about how best to regulate
their risk behavior. Ideally, the new activities would avoid either
greatly extending the safety net beyond its current reach or requiring
costly additional supervision procedures. A plan incorporating sub-debt
could help in meeting these challenges. Markets already provide most of
the discipline on nondepository financial institutions, as well as
virtually all nonfinancial firms. A carefully crafted plan may be able
to tap similar market discipline for financial firms to help limit the
safety net without extending costly supervision.
Below, we describe our detailed sub-debt proposal. Although our
target is the U.S. banking sector, the plan has broader implications as
international capital standards come into play. [12] While others have
argued that U.S. banking agencies could go forward without international
cooperation, we think there are benefits from working with the
international banking agencies, if possible. The explicit goals of the
proposal are to: 1) limit the safety net exposure to loss, 2) establish
risk measures that accurately assess the risks undertaken by banks,
especially those that are part of large, complex financial
organizations, and 3) provide supervisors with the ability to manage
(but not prevent) the exit of failing organizations. The use of sub-debt
can help achieve these goals by imposing some direct discipline on
banks, providing more accurate risk measures, and providing the
appropriate signals for derived discipline and, ultimately, failure
resolution.
Setting the ground rules
As a starting point, we need to consider whether a new sub-debt
program should fit within the existing regulatory framework or require
adjustments to the framework in order to effectively fulfill its role.
In our view, the goals of the proposal cannot be effectively achieved in
the current regulatory environment, which allows banks to hold sub-debt,
but does not require that they do so. As a result, banks are most likely
to opt out of rolling over maturing debt or introducing new issues
precisely in those situations when sub-debt would restrict their
behavior and signal the market and regulators that the bank is
financially weak. Only a mandatory requirement would achieve the
expected benefits. Thus, our proposal requires banks to hold minimum
levels of sub-debt.
Similarly, other restrictions in the current regulatory environment
limit the potential effectiveness of a sub-debt program. In the current
regulatory environment, the role of sub-debt in the bank capital
structure is determined by the Basel Accord, which counts sub-debt as an
element of tier 2 capital, with the associated restrictions, and limits
the amount that may be counted as regulatory capital.
Maintaining the current restrictions has two bothersome
implications. First, it dictates almost all of the terms of the sub-debt
proposal. For example, U.S. banks operating under current Basel
constraints have generally chosen to issue ten-year sub-debt. If there
are perceived benefits from having a homogeneous debt instrument, in the
current regulatory environment the optimal maturity would appear to be
ten years. This is not to say that if left unconstrained financial firms
would prefer ten-year maturities. Indeed bankers frequently criticize
the restrictions imposed on sub-debt issues that, as discussed above,
make it a less attractive form of capital. Ideally, without the
restrictions imposed by Basel, the maturity would be much shorter to
allow it to better match the duration of the bank balance sheet. However
once the ten-year maturity is decided upon as a result of the
restrictions, the frequency of issuance is operationally limited to
avoid "chopping" the debt requirement too finely. For example,
wit h a 2 percent sub-debt requirement, mandating issuance twice a year
would require a $50 billion bank to regularly come to the market with
$50 million issues--significantly smaller than standard issues in
today's markets. Thus, adhering to the current Basel restrictions
would determine one of the interdependent parameters and thus drive them
all. Adjusting the Basel restrictions frees up the parameters of any new
sub-debt proposal.
The second implication of following the current Basel Accord is
that sub-debt is not designed to enhance market discipline. Given that
sub-debt is considered an equity substitute in the capital structure, it
is designed to function much like equity and to provide supervisory
flexibility in dealing with distressed institutions. In particular, the
value of the sub-debt is amortized over a five-year period to encourage
banks to use longer-term debt. Furthermore, the interest rate on the
debt does not float, thus it is limited in its ability to impose direct
discipline when there are changes in the bank's risk exposure.
Finally, because sub-debt is regarded as an inferior form of equity, the
amount of sub-debt is limited in the accord to 50 percent of the
bank's tier 1 capital. [13]
If indeed there are benefits to giving sub-debt a larger role in
the bank capital structure, then consideration should be given to
eliminating the current disadvantages to using this instrument as
capital. That is the approach we take in our proposal.
The proposal
Our sub-debt program would be implemented in stages as conditions
permit.
Stage 1: Surveillance stage (for immediate implementation)
* Sub-debt prices and other information would be used in monitoring
the financial condition of the 25 largest banks and bank holding
companies in the U.S. [14] Procedures would be implemented for acquiring
the best possible pricing data on a frequent basis for these
institutions, with supplementary data being collected for other issuing
banks and bank holding companies. Supervisory staff would gain
experience in evaluating how bank soundness relates to debt prices,
spreads, etc., and how changes in these elements correlate with firm
soundness.
* Simultaneously, in line with the mandate of the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, staffs of regulatory agencies would complete a
study of the value of information derived from debt prices and
quantities in determining bank soundness and evaluate the usefulness of
sub-debt in increasing market discipline in banking. Efforts would be
made to obtain information on the depth and liquidity of debt issues,
including the issues of smaller firms. [15]
* If deemed necessary, the regulatory agencies would obtain the
necessary authority (via congressional action or regulatory mandate) to
require banks and bank holding companies to issue a minimum amount of
sub-debt with prescribed characteristics and to use the debt levels and
prices in implementing prompt corrective action. The legislation would
explicitly prohibit the FDIC from absorbing losses for sub-debt-holders,
thus excluding sub-debt from the systemic risk exception in FDICIA.
* The bank regulatory agencies would work to alter the Basel Accord
to eliminate the unfavorable characteristics of sub-debt (the 50 percent
of tier 1 limitation and the required amortization).
Stage 2: Introductory stage (to be implemented when authority to
mandate sub-debt is obtained)
* The 25 largest banks would be required to issue a minimum of 2
percent of risk-weighted assets in sub-debt on an annual basis with
qualifying issues at least three months apart to avoid long periods
between issues or "bunching" of issues during particularly
tranquil times. [16]
* The sub-debt would have to be issued to independent third parties
and be tradable in the secondary market. The sub-debt's lead
underwriter and market makers could not be institutions affiliated with
the issuing bank, nor could the debt be held by affiliates.
Additionally, no form of credit enhancement could be used to support the
debt. [17]
* The terms of the debt would need to explicitly state and
emphasize its junior status and that the holder would not have access to
a "rescue" under the too-big-to-fail systemic risk clause. It
is imperative that the debtholders behave as junior creditors.
* Failure to comply with the issuance requirement would trigger a
presumption that the bank is critically undercapitalized. If the
bank's outstanding sub-debt trades at yields comparable to those of
firms with a below investment grade rating (Ba or lower--that is, junk
bonds) for a period of two weeks or longer, then the bank would be
presumed to be severely undercapitalized. [18]
* Regulators would investigate whether the remaining capital
triggers or tripwires associated with prompt corrective action could be
augmented with sub-debt rate-based triggers. The analysis would consider
both the form of the trigger mechanism (for example, rate spreads over
risk-free bonds or relative to certain rating classes) and the exact
rates/ spreads that should serve as triggers.
* The sub-debt requirement would be phased in over a transition
period.
Stage 3: Mature stage (to be implemented when adjustments to the
Basel Accord allow for sufficient flexibility in setting the program
parameters, or at such time as it becomes clear that adequate
modifications in the international capital agreement are not possible)
* A minimum sub-debt requirement of at least 3 percent of
risk-weighted assets would apply to the largest 25 banks, with the
expressed intent to extend the requirement to additional banks unless
the regulators' analysis of sub-debt markets finds evidence that
the costs of issuance by additional banks would be prohibitive. The
purpose is to allow for an increase in the number of banks that can cost
effectively be included in the program.
* The sub-debt must be five-year, noncallable, fixed rate debt.
* There must be a minimum of two issues a year and the two
qualifying issues must be at least two months apart.
Discussion of the proposal
Stage 1 is essentially a surveillance and preparatory stage. It is
necessary because the rest of our proposal requires that regulators have
the ability to require sub-debt issuance and access to data to implement
the remaining portion of the plan.
At stage 2, regulators introduce the sub-debt program and begin
using sub-debt as a supplement to the current capital tripwires under
prompt corrective action. The ultimate goal of stage 2 is to use
subdebt-based risk measures to augment capital-based measures, assuming
a satisfactory resolution of some practical problems discussed below.
The sub-debt tripwires initially set out in stage 2 may reasonably be
considered "loose." Banks that cannot issue subdebt are
probably at or near the brink of insolvency, especially given that they
only need to find one issuance window during the course of a year. If a
bank's sub-debt is trading at yields comparable to those of junk
bonds, then it is most likely having significant difficulties, and
supervisors should be actively involved with the bank. We would not
ordinarily expect supervisors to need assistance in identifying banks
experiencing this degree of financial distress. However, the presence of
such tripwires would reinforce the current mandate of prompt corrective
action. Further, it would strengthen derived discipline by other market
participants by setting lower bounds on acceptable sub-debt rates.
The use of sub-debt yields for all of the tripwires under prompt
corrective action could offer significant advantages. As discussed
earlier, market-based tripwires are expected to be more closely
associated with bank risk. However, two dimensions need further work
before heavy reliance on sub-debt spreads is possible. First, regulators
need to review the history of sub-debt rates to determine how best to
use them as risk measures and how best to deal with periods of
illiquidity in the bond market. [19] Second, the linking of sub-debt
rates to prompt corrective action will imply a tighter link between the
prompt corrective action categories and the risk of failure than is
possible under the Basel Accord risk measures. Senior policymakers will
need to decide where to set the tripwires. What risk of failure is
acceptable for a bank to be considered "well capitalized,"
"adequately capitalized," or "undercapitalized"?
Thus, at this stage we recommend further study by regulators, academics,
and bankers to determin e the proper course.
At stage 3, the mature stage, the increased amount of required
sub-debt and the shorter maturity should significantly enhance the
opportunity for sub-debt to exercise direct market discipline on banks.
Another advantage of this proposal is that banks would be somewhat
compensated, via the increased attractiveness of sub-debt as regulatory
capital, for any increased regulatory burden from holding the additional
debt. The removal of the restrictions would make the cost of holding the
debt less burdensome than under current regulatory arrangements. While
it is not certain, it seems likely that the net regulatory burden would
also be less. The five-year maturities in this stage allow for more
frequent issuance, which should increase direct market discipline and
market information. At the same time, we believe five years is
sufficient to tie the debt to the bank and avoid bank runs.
The principal difference in this stage is the recommendation to
shorten the maturity of the sub-debt. Requiring a shorter maturity will
allow more frequent issuance and result in a larger fraction of the
sub-debt being repriced every year. Banks should find this advantageous,
because the maturity would more closely align with the maturities on its
balance sheet. A minor downside is that it may require regulators to
recalibrate the sub-debt yield trigger points for prompt corrective
action for the categories of well capitalized, adequately capitalized,
and undercapitalized. However, as indicated above, this recalibration
will most likely be an ongoing process as regulators obtain additional
market expertise.
One aspect of our proposal that may appear to be controversial is
the movement toward eliminating the sub-debt restrictions imposed by the
Basel Accord. However, once the decision is made to employ subdebt for
overseeing bank activities, the restrictions appear unnecessary and
overly burdensome. They only serve to increase the cost to participating
banks and to limit the flexibility of the program. Without the current
restrictions, banks would prefer to issue shorter-term debt and, in some
situations, would be able to count more sub-debt as regulatory capital.
Similarly, as discussed above, the parameters of any sub-debt policy
will be driven in great part by current regulatory restrictions. Keeping
those restrictions in place would therefore place an unnecessary burden
on participating banks, and would limit regulators, without any obvious
positive payoff. [20] The effort to adjust Basel also does not slow the
movement toward implementation of a sub-debt program since it would be
phased in through the three -stage process. However, laying out the
broad parameters of the complete plan in advance would indicate a
commitment by regulators and could increase the credibility of the
program. [21] Once fully implemented, sub-debt would become an integral
part of the regulatory structure.
Concerns and frequently asked questions about sub-debt
There are a number of issues raised about the viability of sub-debt
proposals. Below, we address some of these issues and clarify exactly
what we expect sub-debt programs to accomplish. [22] We also highlight
where our proposed sub-debt program specifically addresses these issues.
Won't the regulatory agencies "bail out" troubled
institutions by making sub-debt holders at failed institutions whole if
they would have suffered losses otherwise, thus eliminating the
purported benefits of a sub-debt program? This is probably the most
fundamental concern raised about the viability of sub-debt proposals. An
implicit guarantee may at times be more distorting to market behavior
than an explicit guarantee. If debt holders believe that regulators will
make them whole if the issuing bank encounters difficulties and cannot
make payment on their debt, then they will behave accordingly. Acting as
if they are not subject to losses, they will fail to impose the
necessary discipline on which the benefits of sub-debt proposals rely.
There was evidence of such indifference to bank risk levels in the 1980s
when the bailout of the Continental Illinois National Bank ingrained the
too-big-to-fail doctrine into bank investors' decision making. In
essence, if the market discipline is not allowed to work, it w ill not.
This applies to sub-debt.
However, a sub-debt bailout is unlikely under current arrangements
and our proposal makes it even less likely. Holders of sub-debt are
sophisticated investors, who understand their position of junior
priority and the resulting potential losses should the issuing firm
encounter difficulties. Additionally, since banks are not subject to
bankruptcy laws, debtholders cannot argue for a preferred position by
refusing to accept the bankruptcy reorganization plan. Thus, they are
unable to block the resolution. So pressures to rescue debtholders
should not arise either from a perceived status as unsophisticated
investors or from their bargaining power in the failure resolution
process.
The FDIC guaranteed the sub-debt of Continental of Illinois in
1984, but it did so to avoid having to close the bank and not to protect
the sub-debt investors per se. The effect of FDICIA and its prompt
corrective action, least cost resolution requirements, and
too-big-to-fail policies was to significantly curtail and limit the
instances when uninsured liability holders would be protected from
losses. Benston and Kaufman (1998) find that policy did change as a
result of FDICIA, as significantly fewer uninsured depositors were
protected from losses at both large and small banks after passage of the
legislation. Similarly, Flannery and Sorescu (1996) find evidence that
the markets viewed FDICIA as a credible change in policy and, as a
result, sub-debt prices began reflecting differences in bank risk
exposures. Thus, the market apparently already believes that
sub-debt-holders will not be bailed out in the future.
Under our sub-debt proposal, there would be still lower potential
for debtholder rescue. Unlike depositors, who can claim their assets on
demand, holders of the intermediate-term debt could only claim their
assets as the debt matured instead of initiating a "bank run,"
the kind of event that has typically prompted the rescues we have seen
in the past. Additionally, there is much less subjectivity if the
sub-debt price spreads are used for prompt corrective action rather than
book value capital ratios. Finally, under our proposal, the sub-debt
holder would be explicitly excluded from the class of liabilities that
could be covered under the systemic risk exception. This exclusion
should be viewed favorably by banks. Under the terms of the
too-big-to-fail exception in FDICIA, losses from the rescue would have
to be funded via a special assessment of banks. Therefore, banks should
encourage the FDIC to strictly limit the extent of the liabilities
rescued.
Are there cost implications for banks? Interestingly, the costs
associated with issuing sub-debt have been used as an argument both for
and against sub-debt proposals. The standard argument is that there are
relative cost advantages from issuing debt resulting from the favorable tax treatment. [23] It is also argued that closely held banks may find
debt to be a less expensive capital source as new equity injections
would come from investors who realize they will have a minor ownership
role. [24] Both arguments suggest that an increased reliance on sub-debt
would result in cost savings.
There are, however, some additional actual or potential costs
associated with increased sub-debt issues. First, increased reliance on
relatively frequent debt rollovers would generate transaction costs or
issuance costs. There is disagreement as to just how expensive these
costs would be. Some argue that the cost would be similar to that
required for issuing bank certificates of deposit, while others argue
that the cost could be quite substantial. The issuance frequency
discussed in most sub-debt proposals, however, is not very different
from the current frequency at large banking organizations. Two issues
per year, which is well within the recommendations in most sub-debt
proposals, is relatively common in today's banking markets. [25]
A more significant concern seems to be where, within the overall
banking organization, the debt would be issued. Most sub-debt proposals
require the debt to be issued at the bank level whereas, until recently,
most sub-debt was issued at the bank holding company level. This allowed
the holding company the flexibility to distribute the proceeds
throughout the affiliated firms in the organization. This occurred in
spite of the fact that the rating agencies typically rated bank debt
higher than the debt of the holding company, and, similarly, holding
company debt typically traded at a premium to comparable bank debt. [26]
This would suggest that the additional flexibility from issuing debt at
the holding company level is of value to the banking organization.
Removal of this flexibility would impose costs. The recent trend toward
issuing more debt at the bank level, however, would suggest the value of
this flexibility is becoming less important.
A more important cost implication is imbedded in our sub-debt
proposal. In the past, regulators have restricted the use of sub-debt by
limiting the amount that could count as capital and by requiring that
the value of the sub-debt be amortized over the last five years before
maturity. These restrictions are imposed because the firm needs to make
periodic payments on the debt, regardless of its financial condition.
However, this does not decrease the effectiveness of sub-debt in serving
the capital role as a cushion against losses. It still buffers the
insurance fund. By eliminating these restrictions in our sub-debt
proposal, we enhance the value of the debt as capital and decrease the
net cost of introducing the proposal.
Isn't there a problem in that sub-debt proposals are
procyclical? A possible concern with sub-debt requirements is that they
may exacerbate procyclical behavior by banks--increased lending during
economic expansions and reduced lending during recessions. However, this
is not unique to sub-debt programs; any regulatory requirement that does
not adjust over the course of a business cycle has the potential to be
procyclical if banks seek to only satisfy the minimum requirements. For
example, appendix D of Kwast et al. (1999) points out that bank capital
adequacy ratios are likely to decline during recessions as banks
experience higher loan losses, implying that regulation based on capital
adequacy ratios has the potential to be procyclical. [27]
The procyclicality of a regulatory requirement may be at least
partially offset if banks seek to maintain some cushion above minimum
regulatory requirements that they may draw on during economic downturns.
In the case of the regulatory capital adequacy requirements, both casual
observation of recent bank behavior and formal empirical analysis from
the 1980s and early 1990s suggest that banks do indeed seek to maintain
such a cushion for contingencies. [26]
Moreover, a regulatory program that uses sub-debt yields as
triggers for regulatory action may be designed to induce less
procyclical behavior than would other types of regulatory requirements.
Consider two ways to design the sub-debt triggers as discussed in Kwast
et al. (1999). One design is to base regulatory action on a constant
basis point spread over bonds with little or no credit risk, such as
Treasury securities. Such a standard is more likely to become binding
during recessions when banks are experiencing loan losses and investors
demand higher risk premiums to continue holding bank bonds. Thus, a
policy that sets triggers at a constant premium over Treasuries may
result in procyclical regulation in a manner similar to that of standard
capital requirements.
Another way of designing the triggers, however, is to base them on
a measure that offers countercyclical yields over the business cycle,
for example, the yields on corporate bonds of a given rating. There is
evidence that bond-rating agencies seek to smooth ratings through
business cycles. For example, Theodore (1999, p. 10) states Moody's
policies:
Moody's bank ratings ... aim at looking to the medium- to
long-term, through cyclical trends. For example, a drop in quarterly,
semi-annual or even annual earnings is not necessarily a reason to
downgrade a bank's ratings. However, if the earnings drop is the
result of a structural degradation of a bank's fundamentals, credit
ratings need to reflect the new developing condition of the bank.
If the rating agencies are trying to "look through the
business cycle," then the spreads on corporate bonds over
default-free securities should be small during expansions because
investors, but not the rating agencies, recognize a lower probability of
default during expansions. Similarly, the spreads on corporate bonds
over default-free bonds should rise during recessions as the markets,
but not the rating agencies, recognize the increased probability of
default. Thus, prompt corrective action triggers based on sub-debt
yields relative to corporate yields introduce an element of smoothing.
The triggers may be relatively tight during expansions when banks should
be building financial strength and relatively loose during downturns as
they draw down part of their reserves.
One case where the use of sub-debt yields may tend to reinforce the
business cycle is when liquidity drops in all corporate bond markets and
risk premiums (including liquidity risk premiums) temporarily soar. [29]
However, our proposal recognizes this potential problem and provides for
temporary relief until liquidity improves.
Aren't supervisors better gauges of the riskiness of a bank
because they know more about each bank's exposure than the market
does? If so, then why not rely exclusively on the supervisors instead of
holders of sub-debt? In some cases the market's knowledge of a
bank's exposure may indeed be a subset of the examiner's
knowledge. However, we rely on markets to discipline firm risk taking in
virtually every other sector of our economy, so markets must have some
offsetting advantages. One such advantage is that the financial markets
are likely to be better able to price the risks they observe because
market prices reflect the consensus of many observers investing their
own funds. Another advantage of markets is that they can avoid
limitations inherent in any type of government supervision. Supervisors
are rightfully reluctant to be making fundamental business decisions for
banks unless or until results confirm the bank is becoming unsafe or
unsound. Further, even when supervisors recognize a serious potential pr
oblem, they have the burden of being able to prove to a court that a
bank is engaged in unsafe activities. In contrast, in financial markets
the burden of proof is on the bank to show it is being safely managed. A
further weakness of relying solely on bank supervisors is that they are
ultimately accountable to the political system, which suggests that
noneconomic factors may enter into major decisions no matter how hard
supervisors try to focus solely on the economics of a bank's
position. [30] Sub-debt investors have no such accountability; they may
be expected to focus solely on the economic condition of individual
banks.
A typical concern surrounding sub-debt proposals is that the
perceived intent is to supplant supervisors and rely solely on the
forces of the marketplace to oversee bank behavior. In our proposal, the
intent is to augment, not reduce supervisory oversight. If supervisors
have additional information about the condition of a bank, there is
nothing in the sub-debt proposals limiting their ability to impose
sanctions on the activities of the bank. In addition to sub-debt serving
the standard role as a loss-absorbing capital cushion, it serves as an
additional tool for use by both the private markets and the regulators
to discipline banks objectively. In fact, one of the major components of
our proposal is to have the supervisors incorporate the yield spreads
for use in prompt corrective action. With private markets providing
information, supervisors can focus their efforts on exceptional
circumstances, leaving the well-understood risks for assessment by the
marketplace.
Do we currently know enough about the sub-debt market to proceed?
Although we would like to know more about the sub-debt market, we think
considerable information is already available. The studies surveyed and
the new evidence presented in K wast et al. (1999) provide considerable
insight into the subordinated debt market. These studies suggest that
investors in sub-debt do discriminate on the basis of the riskiness of
their portfolios.
Moreover, a review of the regulatory alternatives suggests that any
durable solution to achieving an objective measure of banks' risk
exposure will look something like our proposal. The problems that plague
the existing risk-based capital guidelines are inherent in any attempt
by the supervisors to measure the riskiness of a bank's portfolio
based on a pre-specified set of criteria. Over time, banks will find or
will manufacture claims whose intrinsic contribution to the riskiness of
the bank's portfolio is underestimated by the supervisory criteria.
[31] That is, banks will attempt to arbitrage the capital requirements.
An alternative to supervisory determined criteria is to use market
evaluations. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision correctly moved
in this direction with its proposed new capital adequacy framework.
However, it chose to ask opinions of market participants rather than
observing market prices and quantities. The committee then compounded
this by proposing to ask the opinions of the two parties, the banks and
their rating agencies, that have incentives to underestimate the true
risk exposure.
A superior system for obtaining a market-based risk measure will
use observed data from financial markets on price or quantity, or both.
That is, it will use a market test. The relevant question to be
addressed is which instruments should be observed, how these instruments
should he structured, and how supervisors can best extract the risk
signal from the noise generated by other factors that may influence
observed prices and quantities. In principle, any uninsured bank
obligation can provide the necessary information. We favor sub-debt
because we think it will provide the cleanest signal.
There are alternatives to sub-debt. Common equity may currently
have the advantages of being issued by all large banks and of trading in
more liquid markets. However, investors in bank common equity will
sometimes bid up stock prices in response to greater risk taking, so
their signal can only be interpreted in the context of a model that
removes the option value of putting the bank back to the firm's
creditors (including the deposit insurer). In contrast, valuable
information can be extracted from subordinated debt without a
complicated model. If a bank's debt trades at prices equivalent to
Baa corporate bonds, then its other liabilities are at least Baa
quality.
Banks also issue a variety of other debt obligations that could be
used to measure their risk exposure. [32] The use of any debt obligation
that is explicitly excluded from the systemic risk exception in FDICIA
could provide a superior risk measure to those proposed by the Basel
Committee. Thus, we conclude that sub-debt is the best choice because it
is the least senior of all debt obligations if a bank should fail and,
therefore, its yields provide the clearest signal about the potential
risk that the bank will fail. We think sufficient information exists to
adopt a sub-debt proposal with the understanding that the plan will be
refined and made more effective as additional information and analysis
become available.
Conclusion
FDICIA sought to reform the incentives of both banks and their
supervisors. The least cost resolution provisions were intended to
expose banks to greater market discipline and the prompt corrective
action provisions were intended to promote earlier and more consistent
supervisory discipline. Ongoing developments are undercutting both
sources of discipline. Whether the government would have been willing to
take the perceived short-term risks associated with least cost
resolution procedures for a very large bank immediately after their
introduction is debatable. Arguably, those risks have increased
significantly as banks have grown larger and more complex. Whether
prompt corrective action based on book values would have been effective
in closing banks before they became economically insolvent is also
questionable. Unquestionably, however, banks' ability to
"game" regulatory risk measures has grown over the last
decade.
Although ongoing developments are undercutting the intent of
FDICIA, the premise that banks and their supervisors should be subject
to credible discipline remains. Ideally, this discipline would come from
financial markets. While markets do not have perfect foresight, they are
both flexible enough to accept promising innovations and willing to
acknowledge their mistakes, even if such recognition is politically
inconvenient.
Sub-debt provides a viable mechanism for providing such market
discipline. It is already providing useful signals in today's
financial markets. We propose to combine these signals with the gradual
discipline provided under prompt corrective action in a form that is
credible to banks and other financial market participants.
This article provides a feasible approach to implementing enhanced
discipline through sub-debt. Our proposal draws on the existing evidence
on market discipline in banking and the insights of previous proposals
and policy changes. The new plan provides for phased implementation and
leaves room for future modifications as additional details concerning
the market for sub-debt are determined. The plan calls for specific
changes in those areas where we believe the evidence is relatively
clear, such as the fact that large solvent banks should be able to issue
sub-debt at least once a year. In those areas where the evidence is weak
to non-existent, we defer decisions pending additional study. This
approach should enhance the credibility of the plan. Although the
details of the plan would evolve over time, once the basics are
implemented the industry and the public would see bank behavior being
significantly influenced by both market and supervisory oversight. The
combination should make for a more effective, safe, and sound industry.
Douglas D. Evanoff is a vice president and senior financial
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Larry D. Wall is a
research officer at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. The authors
acknowledge constructive comments from Charles Calomiris, Diana Hancock,
George Kaufman, Myron Kwast, and Jim Moser.
NOTES
(1.) See Title 1, Section 108 of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act
entitled "The use of subordinated debt to protect the deposit
system and deposit system funds from 'too big to fail'
institutions."
(2.) During crises, the pressure of having to respond quickly
increases the likelihood of introducing poorly structured regulation.
Industries where regulatory reforms introduced during crises may have
caused significant long-term problems include banking in the 1930s
(Kaufman, 1994) and the pharmaceutical industry following the infamous
Thalidomide incidents in the 1950s (Evanoff, 1989).
(3.) An index of papers that can be downloaded from the Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision website may be found at
www.bis.org/publ/index.htm.
(4.) See Bank for International Settlement (1999).
(5.) The rating agency obviously has an incentive to maintain its
credibility as an objective entity and could resist the pressure. The
incentives, however, would work in this direction.
(6.) More generally, in recent years there has been growing concern
about the need to increase the role of market discipline in banking.
See, for example, Ferguson (1999), Meyer (1999), Stern (1998), Boyd and
Rolnick (1988), Broaddus (1999), and Moskow (1998).
(7.) Direct discipline would result from an expected increase in
the cost of issuing debt in response to an increase in the bank's
perceived risk profile. To avoid this increased cost the bank would more
prudently manage risk. Derived discipline results when other agents (for
example, supervisors) use the information from sub-debt markets to
increase the cost to the bank. For example, as discussed below, bank
supervisors could use debt yields as triggers for regulatory actions.
(8.) Additional discussion of the role of sub-debt in this plan can
be found in Evanoff (1993, 1994).
(9.) Regulatory restrictions would be prompt-corrective-action-type
constraints such as limits to dividend payments or deposit and asset
growth rates once core equity fell below 2 percent of risk-weighted
assets.
(10.) The sub-debt requirement is one component of Calomiris's
regulatory reform proposal aimed at modifying industry structure and the
operating procedures of the International Monetary Fund. It would also
include a mandatory minimum reserve requirement (20 percent of bank debt
in Calomiris, 1998), minimum securities requirement, and explicit
deposit insurance. Although some details of his proposal, such as
requiring the debt be issued to foreign banks, may not be feasible for
U.S. banks, the general approach provides interesting insights into the
issues in designing a sub-debt plan for the U.S.
(11.) "This is not the first time proposals have suggested
sub-debt be linked with prompt corrective action; see Evanoff (1993,
1994) and Litan (2000).
(12.) The term banking is used generically and could include all
depository institutions.
(13.) As discussed earlier, the current bank capital requirement
framework is being reevaluated (see Bank for International Settlements,
1999). As part of the debate, some have recommended total elimination of
the tier 1 versus tier 2 distinction, (for example Litan, 2000). If this
approach is taken, we would recommend that minimum leverage requirements
be maintained to ensure sufficient levels of equity (although it would
be in sub-debt holders self interest to ensure this occurs) and to
provide supervisors with an official tool for intervening when equity
levels fall to unacceptable levels.
(14.) When fully implemented, the policy would apply to
"banks" instead of the bank holding company. During this
surveillance stage, however, information could be gained at both levels.
(15.) Actually, progress is currently being made on these first two
items. The Board staff are actively involved in collecting and analyzing
sub-debt price data, and System staff are evaluating how the markets
react to debt spreads.
(16.) The only exception would occur if general market conditions
precluded debt issuance by the corporate sector (both financial and
nonfinancial firms). This exception requires more specific details, but
it would be an industry-wide rather than a bank-specific exception.
(17.) The objective is to limit "regulatory gaming"; see
Jones (2000). Additional minimum denomination constraints could be
imposed to further ensure that debtholders are sophisticated investors,
(for example, see U.S. Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, 2000).
(18.) Depending on the depth of the secondary market, this may need
to be extended to a couple of weeks. Again, the timeframe could be
modified as more market information is obtained. Additionally, to allow
for flexibility under extreme conditions, procedures could be introduced
by which the presumption could be over-turned given the approval of the
FDIC upon request by the bank's primary federal supervisor. The
procedures for this exception, however, would be somewhat similar to
those currently in place for too-big-to-fail exceptions, for example,
submission of a public document to Congress, etc.
(19.) For example, should risk be measured as the spread between
the yield on a sub-debt issue and a comparable maturity Treasury
security, the yield on a bank's sub-debt versus the yield on com
parable maturity corporate bonds in different ratings classes, or the
spread over LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) after the bond is
swapped into floating rate funds.
(20.) This is not to say that initiating changes to the accord
would be costless. Obviously negotiations would be required since other
country members may want to continue to have sub-debt be an inferior
form of capital. But from the participating U.S. banks' perspective
and the regulators' perspective (concerning program flexibility),
the elimination of these restrictions should result in net benefits.
(21.) We are not saying that detailed parameters should be
introduced at this time. As argued above, additional analysis is
required before these could be decided upon.
(22.) Another potential issue is how the banks will respond to the
new regulation in an attempt to avoid sub-debt discipline. A review of
this issue is included in Kwast et al. (1999), and our proposal raises
no new concerns. The recently passed Financial Services Modernization
Act addresses some of these potential concerns by significantly limiting
credit enhancements on sub-debt.
(23.) Jones (1998) suggests the cost of equity could be twice that
of debt once the tax differences are accounted for. Benston (1992)
discusses the cost differences and other advantages of sub-debt over
equity capital.
(24.) Alternatively, the current owners could inject equity but
that may be costly in that it places them in a situation where they are
relatively undiversified.
(25.) For example, see Kwast et al. (1999). The exception is
Calomiris (1998) which would require monthly changes via either debt
issues or asset shrinkage.
(26.) This holding company premium is typically associated with the
bank having access to the safety net and the associated lower risk of
default during times of financial stress. Alternatively, it has been
argued the differential results from the different standing of the two
debtholders. Holders of bank debt have a higher priority claim on the
assets during liquidation of the bank than do the holders of holding
company debt which essentially has an equity claim on the bank.
(27.) The appendix was prepared by Thomas Brady and William English of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Most of the
comments in this section attributed to Kwast et al. come from this
appendix.
(28.) Arguably, to the extent the capital requirements caused a
reduction in bank lending during the early 1990s, it was because banks
were trying to increase their capital ratios due to new requirements at
the same time they were experiencing higher loan losses. A discussion of
the "capital crunch" is provided in Hancock and Wilcox (1997,
1998). After banks have time to rebalance their portfolios in response
to new capital requirements they are likely to have a cushion to absorb
the higher loan losses incurred during recessions. Wall and Peterson
(1987, 1995) find evidence that banks seek to maintain capital ratios in
excess of regulatory requirements and speculate that part of the reason
for the higher ratios is to absorb unexpected losses.
(29.) The liquidity crunch in the fall of 1998 and the Long-Term
Capital episode are possible examples of such a problem period.
(30.) For example, the American Banker reports that the Office of
the Comptroller of the Currency is threatening to downgrade bank's
safety and soundness rating if they fail to supply accurate Community
Reinvestment Act data; see Seiberg (1999).
(31.) Supervisory agencies could short circuit this avoidance by
having their examiners conduct subjective evaluations but that could
easily result in examiners serving as shadow managers of banks.
(32.) Preferred stock is a form of equity but it would yield a
clean signal unlike common equity. We do not propose the use of
preferred stock for two reasons. First, dividend payments on preferred
stock are not a deductible expense to the bank. Thus, forcing them to
issue preferred stock would increase their costs. Second, discussions
with market participants, as reported in Kwast et al. (1999. p. 45),
indicated that the preferred stock market is more heavily influenced by
"relatively uninformed retail investors."
REFERENCES
Bank for International Settlements, 1999, "A new capital
adequacy framework," Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
consultative paper, June.
Benston, George J., 1992, "The purpose of capital for
institutions with government-insured deposits," Journal of
Financial Services Research, Vol. 5, October, pp. 369-384.
Benston, George J., Robert A. Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J.
Kane, and George G. Kaufman, 1986, Perspectives on Safe and Sound
Banking, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Benston, George J., and George G. Kaufman, 1998, "Deposit
insurance reform in the FDIC Improvement Act: The experience to
date," Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Second Quarter, pp. 2-20.
_____, 1988, "Regulating bank safety and performance," in
Restructuring Banking and Financial Services in America, William S.
Haraf and Rose Marie Kushmeider (eds.), Washington: American Enterprise
Institute for Public Policy Research.
Boyd, John H., and Arthur J. Rolnick, 1988, "A case for
reforming federal deposit insurance," Annual Report, Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Broaddus, J. Alfred, 1999, "Incentives and banking,"
speech before the National Conference for Teachers of Advanced Placement
Economics, Richmond, Virginia, September 26.
Calomiris, Charles W., 1999, "Building an incentive-compatible
safety net," Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 23, October, pp.
1499-1519.
_____, 1998, Blueprints for a New Global Financial Architecture,
Washington: American Enterprise Institute, September 23.
_____, 1997, The Postmodern Bank Safety Net, Washington: American
Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Evanoff, Douglas D., 1994, "Capital requirements and bank
regulatory reform," in Global Risk Based Capital Regulations:
Capital Adequacy, Charles A. Stone and Anne Zissu (eds.), New York:
Irwin.
_____, 1993, "Preferred sources of market discipline,"
Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol. 10, Summer, pp. 347-367.
_____, 1989, "Returns to R&D and regulation of the U.S.
pharmaceutical industry," Review of Industrial Organization, Vol.
4.
Ferguson, Roger W., Jr., 1999, "Evolution of financial
institutions and markets: Private and policy implications," speech
at New York University, New York, February 25.
Flannery, Mark J., and Sorin M. Sorescu, 1996, "Evidence of
bank market discipline in subordinated debenture yields:
1983-1991," Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 4, September, pp.
1347-1377.
Hancock, Diana, and James A. Wilcox, 1998, "The 'credit
crunch' and the availability of credit to small business,"
Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 22, August, pp. 983-1014.
_____, 1997, "Bank capital, nonbank finance, and real estate
activity," Journal of Housing Research, Vol. 8, No. 1, pp. 75-105.
Horvitz, Paul, 1984, "Subordinated debt is key to new bank
capital requirements," American Banker, December 31, p. 5.
_____, 1983, "market discipline is best provided by
subordinated creditors," American Banker, July 15, p. 3.
Jones, David S., 2000, "Emerging problems with the Basel
Capital Accord: Regulatory capital arbitrage and related issues,"
Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 24, January, pp. 35-58.
_____, 1998, "Emerging problems with the Basel Accord:
Regulatory capital arbitrage and related issues," paper presented
at a conference on Credit Risk Modeling and the Regulatory Implications,
Bank of England, September.
Kaufman, George G, 1994, Reforming Financial Institutions and
Markets in the United States, Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishing.
Keehn, Silas, 1988, Banking on the Balance: Powers and the Safety
Net, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Kwast, Myron L., Daniel M. Covitz, Diaaa Hancock, James V. Houpt,
David P. Adkins, Norah Barger, Barbara Bouchard, John F. Connolly,
Thomas F. Brady, William B. English, Douglas D. Evanoff, and Larry D.
Wall, 1999, "Using subordinated debt as an instrument of market
discipline," report of a study group on subordinated notes and
debentures, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, M. Kwast
(chair), staff study, No. 172, December, available on the Internet at
www.bog.frb.fed.us/pubs/staffstudies/l72/default.htm.
Litan, Robert E., 2000, "International bank capital standards:
Next steps," in Global Financial Crises: Lessons From Recent
Events, Joseph R. Bisignano, William C. Hunter, and George C. Kaufman
(eds.), Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishing, pp. 221-231.
Meyer, Laurence H., 1999, "Market discipline as a complement
to bank supervision and regulation," speech before the conference
on Reforming Bank Capital Standards, Council on Foreign Relations, New
York, June 14.
Moskow, Michael, 1998, "Regulatory efforts to prevent banking
crises," in Preventing Bank Crises: Lessons from Recent Global Bank
Failures, Gerard Caprio, William Hunter, George Kaufman, and Danny
Leipziger (eds.), Washington: Economic Development Institute of the
World Bank, pp. 13-26.
Seiberg, Jaret, 1999, "CAMELs penalty threatened if flaws
found in CRA data," American Banker, April 27, p. 2.
Stern, Gary H., 1998, "Market discipline as bank
regulator," The Region, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, June.
Theodore, Samuel S., 1999, Rating Methodology: Bank Credit Risk,
New York: Moody's Investor Services, Global Credit Research, April.
U.S. Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, 2000, Reforming bank
capital regulation, Washington: The AEI Press, policy statement, No.
160, March 2.
Wall, Larry D., 1989, "A plan for reducing future deposit
insurance losses: Puttable subordinated debt," Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, July/August, pp. 2-17.
Wall, Larry D., and David R. Peterson, 1995, "Bank holding
company capital targets in the early 1990s: The regulators versus the
markets," Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 19, June, pp.
563-574.
______, 1987, "The effect of capital adequacy guidelines on
large bank holding companies," Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol.
11, December, pp. 581-600.