The new view of growth and business cycles.
Fisher, Jonas D.M.
Introduction and summary
Two central concerns of economic policy are growth and business
cycle stabilization. There is considerable interest in devising
government policies and institutions to influence prospects for economic
growth and mitigate the distress associated with economic downturns.
Proper evaluation of the benefits and costs of a given policy proposal
requires knowledge of the determinants of growth and business cycles.
This is one reason for the considerable body of research aimed at
understanding these phenomena.
The last two decades have seen considerable advances in this
research. Recent empirical evidence, however, brings into question two
of its basic assumptions-first, that technological change is homogeneous
in nature, in that it affects our ability to produce all goods
symmetrically, including consumption and investment goods; and second,
that business cycles are driven by shocks which affect the demand for
investment goods.
In this article, I document the key evidence that challenges the
conventional views of growth and business cycles. I then discuss the
plausibility of alternative theories that have been advanced to meet the
challenge. To date, the evidence seems to support a new view of growth
and business cycles, one that is based on technical change biased toward
new investment goods like capital equipment.
The key evidence involves two observations on the behavior of the
relative price of business equipment over the last 40 years. First, in
almost every year since the end of the 1950s, business equipment has
become cheaper than the previous year in terms of its value in
consumption goods. This means that if one had to trade restaurant meals
for a piece of equipment that makes the same number and quality of, say,
bicycles, one would forgo fewer meals in 1998 than in 1958. Second, this
relative price tends to fall the most when the economy, and investment
expenditures in particular, are growing at relatively high rates, that
is, it is countercyclical.
The first piece of evidence is striking because it suggests that
much of post-WWII economic growth can be attributed to technological
change embodied in new capital equipment. This conflicts with
conventional views on what drives economic growth. A piece of capital
equipment is a good that is used to produce another good, such as a
crane or a computer. An improvement in capital-embodied technology is
the invention of equipment that takes the same amount of labor and
preexisting equipment to produce as the old equipment but that produces
more goods when combined with the same amount of labor as before. If a
new production process yields the same units of capital equipment with
less factor inputs, then this has the same economic implications as if
the capital equipment produced were itself more efficient. Hence, an
equivalent interpretation of what constitutes capital-embodied technical
change is that it involves an improvement in the technology that
produces capital equipment.
To understand the relationship between capital-embodied technical
change and the trend in the equipment price, suppose the technology for
producing consumption goods is fixed. With improvements in technology
embodied in equipment, the supply of (quality-adjusted) investment goods
increases relative to consumption goods, so the equipment price falls.
Greenwood et al. (1997) build on this insight to show that a large
ffaction of economic growth can be attributed to capital-emhodied
technical change. This conflicts with the conventional view that most
growth is due to disembodied technical change, or multifactor
productivity. Improvements in disembodied technology, usually measured
as the Solow (1957) residual, make it possible to produce all kinds of
goods, not just capital goods, with less capital and labor.(1) If this
were the dominant source of growth, then we should not have seen such a
large drop in the price of equipment over the last 40 years.
The second piece of evidence runs counter to standard views of the
business cycle. Standard theories hold that the business cycle is driven
by shocks which affect the demand for investment goods. For example,
consider the IS-LM model, which summarizes much of what is often called
Keynesian macroeconomics. This model is the focus of most textbooks on
macroeconomics and underlies much of the discussion of macroeconomic policy in the media.(2) In this model, business cycles are due to shocks
to aggregate demand, such as monetary and fiscal disturbances. For
example, expansionary monetary policy stimulates demand for investment
goods through lower interest rates. If there is an upward sloping supply
schedule for investment goods, we would expect the relative price of
investment goods to rise. The same holds for expansionary fiscal policy,
if government spending does not fully crowd out investment. Another view
of business cycles, often attributed to Keynes, is that they are
primarily investment cycles driven by variation in animal spirits, that
is, changes in confidence about future growth prospects.(3) With the
same assumptions on investment supply, we would expect investment prices
to be high when investment is high. In summary, traditional Keynesian
views of business cycles imply that investment good prices should be
procyclical, that is, be high when overall economic activity is
relatively high.
In recent years, an alternative view of business cycles, based on
"fundamentals" that influence aggregate supply, has gained
credence. This real business cycle view says that business cycles are
driven in large part by disturbances to multifactor productivity. Just
as the shocks to aggregate demand which are central to Keynesian
theories, these disturbances influence business cycles through their
effect on the demand for investment goods.(4) Hence, if there are costs
in terms of forgone consumption of expanding investment good production,
that is, if the supply schedule of capital is upward sloping, these
models also predict the relative price of investment goods to be
procyclical (Greenwood and Hercowitz, 1988).
Since the relative price evidence contradicts the major schools of
business cycle thought, it poses a challenge to our understanding of
business cycles. There are two leading hypotheses that could reconcile
the theory and evidence. One, the embodied technology view, is built
from the real business cycle tradition and takes into account the trend
evidence on equipment prices. Falling equipment prices are compelling
evidence of capital-embodied technological progress over long horizons.
Perhaps changes in the rate of such technological progress occur over
shorter horizons as well. Suppose the business cycle were driven, to a
large extent, by these disturbances. An increase in the rate of
capital-embodied technical change would lead to an outward shift in the
supply schedule for investment goods. With stable investment demand,
investment would rise and equipment prices would fall. This new view of
business cycles, which complements the new view of growth suggested by
the long-run evidence on equipment prices, has been explored by
Christiano and Fisher (1998), Fisher (1997), and Greenwood et al.
(1998).
The other leading theory is more easily understood in the context
of traditional Keynesian views of the business cycle. If shocks to
aggregate demand occur with a downward sloping investment supply curve,
then the price of equipment could fall in a boom. A downward sloping
investment supply curve would arise if increasing returns to scale
played an important part in the production of capital equipment, so this
is called the increasing returns view. This view has been advanced by
Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989).
Below, I document the trend and business cycle evidence on
equipment prices. There is no reason to expect that capital-embodied
technological change is unique to equipment. Equipment is one of many
investment good aggregates, that is, types of capital. Moreover, for
simplicity most economic models assume only one or two types of capital.
Therefore, in addition to equipment prices, I analyze other investment
good aggregates. Next, I discuss research that sheds light on the
plausibility of the alternative views, including some new evidence. To
date, the evidence seems to support the new view of growth and business
cycles based on capital-embodied technical change.
If growth and business cycles are originating from changes in
capital-embodied technology, then the models we use for policy analysis
have to incorporate this and, consequently, policy recommendations could
change. For example, to the extent that technological change is embodied
in capital equipment, government policies that affect equipment
investment could have a dual impact on growth via the quality and
quantity of capital goods. This could mean, for example, that investment
tax credits directed toward improvements in the efficiency of capital
equipment could have a significant impact on growth.
The implications for stabilization policy of the embodied
technology view are less obvious. The fact that it seems to supplant the
increasing returns view means that the arguments for interventionist
stabilization policy that this view lends support to are less
compelling. For example, increasing returns could provide scope for
policy intervention, as it either involves externalities or is
inconsistent with perfect competition. Moreover, it makes models based
on animal spirits more plausible, which also has implications for
stabilization policy (see Christiano and Harrison, 1999). The embodied
technology view is more in line with the real business cycle tradition,
in which policy interventions are counterproductive.
Evidence on investment good prices
To study the trend and business cycle properties of investment good
prices, we need two things - a way to extract real prices and quantities
from data on nominal investment expenditures; and a precise definition
of what we mean by the business cycle component of the data. Below, I
address these issues. Then, I introduce the data and present the results
characterizing the trend and cycle behavior of investment good prices.
Measuring prices and quantities
This section describes how relative prices and real quantities of
investment goods are measured. My measures of prices and quantities are
based on measures published in the "National income and product
accounts" (NIPA) of the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA).
The basis of the BEA procedure is to construct a price deflator. To
be concrete, a given nominal quantity of expenditures on some good i,
[[X.sub.i].sub.t], is decomposed into a price deflator, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], (which measures the nominal price of the good)
multiplied by a quality-adjusted index of the real quantity of the good,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The BEA measures [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] for different goods using a so-called
chain-weighting procedure, which is summarized in box 1. My measure of
quantity is simply [Mathematical Expression Omitted], measured in units
of 1992 dollars. My measure of the real price, alternatively the
relative price, of good i at date t, [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
is the real quantity of consumption goods that would need to be sold in
order to purchase one unit of good i at time t. It is defined as the
price deflator for good i divided by the price deflator for consumption
of nondurables and services. The rationale for this measure is described
in box 1.
Measuring the business cycle component of the data(5)
In the introduction I described how the price of producer durable
equipment (PDE) varies over the business cycle. Below, I provide a brief
description of how I measure the business cycle component of the data. A
detailed discussion of the procedure is given in Christiano and
Fitzgerald (1998).
Figure 1 illustrates the basic idea behind the procedure. The
colored line in panel A of figure 1 displays real 1992 dollar
chain-weighted gross domestic product (GDP). The reported data are the
logarithm of the raw data. The advantage of using the logarithm is that
the resulting movements correspond to percent changes in the underlying
data. The deviations between the data and the trend line (graphed in
panel B) contain the rapidly varying, erratic component, inherited from
the choppy portion of the data that is evident in panel A. The colored
line in panel B is my measure of the business cycle component of real
GDP. This measure excludes both the trend part of the data and the
rapidly varying, erratic component. It includes only the component of
the data that contains fluctuations in the range of two to eight years.
According to this approach, the economy is in recession when the
business cycle measure is negative and in prosperity when it is
positive.
Figure 1 also compares this measure of the business cycle with the
one produced by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). This
organization decides, based on an informal examination of many data
series by a panel of experts, when the economy has reached a business
cycle peak or trough. The start of each shaded area indicates the date
when, according to the NBER, the economy reached a business cycle peak.
The end of each shaded area indicates a business cycle trough. Note how
real GDP falls from peak to trough and then generally grows from trough
to peak. An obvious difference in the two business cycle measures is
that the measure used in this article is a continuous variable, while
the NBER's takes the form of peak and trough dates. As a result, my
measure not only indicates when a recession occurs, but also the
intensity of the recession. Apart from these differences, the two
measures appear reasonably consistent. For example, near the trough of
every NBER recession, my measure of the business cycle is always
negative. However, the two measures do not always agree. According to my
measure, the economy was in recession in 1967 and 1987, while the NBER
did not declare a recession then. In part, this is because there must be
several quarters of negative GDP growth before the NBER declares a
recession. The procedure I use only requires a temporary slowdown.
The data
I consider a broad variety of investment goods, as outlined in
table 1. The broadest measure of investment is total private investment
(TPI). This measure includes all private expenditures on capital goods
and consumer goods designed to last more than three years.(6) This is a
broader measure of investment than the conventional NIPA measure of
investment, private fixed investment (PFI), which excludes expenditures
on consumer goods. Within TPI, I define two main components,
nonresidential and residential. Nonresidential has two main
subcomponents, structures (NRS, for example, factory buildings and
office buildings) and producer durable equipment (PDE, for example,
auto-assembly robots and personal computers). Similarly, residential is
broken down into residential structures and equipment (RSE, for example,
single family homes and refrigerators) and consumer durables (CD, for
example, televisions and vacuum cleaners). These four major
subcomponents of TPI are then broken down further.(7)
The "Nominal share" and "Real share" data
provide information on the relative magnitudes of expenditures on the
different measures of investment, as well as a preliminary indication of
interesting trends in relative prices. The nominal and real shares for
TPI are calculated as the ratio of nominal and real TPI relative to
nominal and real GDP, respectively. For example, in 1958 nominal TPI
expenditurcs were 22 percent of nominal GDP and real TPI expenditures
were 16 percent of real GDP. The remaining shares are calculated using
TPI as the base for the share calculations. For example, PDE
expenditures accounted for 24 percent of nominal TPI and 20 percent of
real TPI in 1958.(8) (I explain the last two columns in table 1 in the
section on prices of investment goods over the business cycle, which
begins on page 40.)
Table 1 reveals several interesting facts about how expenditures on
investment have changed since 1958 and underlying trends in relative
prices. First, nominal TPI expenditures have been roughly stable
(abstracting from short-run movements) as a fraction of nominal GDP
since the late 1950s. Yet, the real quantity of this broadest measure
has been growing as a fraction of real GDP. In 1958, TPI was 16 percent
of 1992 chain-weighted GDP, compared with 26 percent in 1998. The fact
that nominal and real shares behave in this way is an indication that
the relative price of this bundle of investment goods fell between 1958
and 1998. Notice that there are differences between real and nominal
shares for many of the components of investment listed in table 1,
suggesting that trends in relative prices are exhibited by many of the
subcomponents of TPI. Second, the difference between the real shares of
TPl and PFI (the former is a fraction of GDP, while the latter is a
fraction of the former) is seen to be due to the increasing quantities
of consumer durables being purchased. Third, the much talked about
"information age" manifests itself here as the huge increase
in the fraction of TPI that has been due to expenditures on information
and related equipment since 1960. In 1960 this type of investment
accounted for less than I percent of real TPI. By 1995, its share had
grown to 13 percent. Finally, note that both residential and
nonresidential structures account for less of TPI in 1998 than in 1958.
Trends in investment good prices
In this section, I explain two main findings relating to the
long-run behavior of relative prices for the various components of
investment listed in table 1. First, the relative price of TPI has
fallen consistently since the mid-1950s. Second, there is considerable
heterogeneity in the long-run behavior of the prices of the
subcomponents of TPI. Generally, the behavior of the price of TPI is
dominated by dramatic drops in the prices of PDE and CD, which are also
evident in the prices of most of the main subcomponents of these
investment aggregates. The prices of RSE and NRS and their
subcomponents, while exhibiting trends over subsamples of the period
studied, have not fallen as consistently and their changes over time are
much smaller than those of PDE and CD.
Figure 2 displays the relative price trend evidence. The black
lines in figure 2 are measures of the (natural logarithm of the)
relative price of each of the investment components listed in table 1
over the period for which data are available.(9) The colored lines are
the trends calculated in the same way as the trend of real GDP displayed
in figure 1. The first column of panels in figure 2 displays prices and
trend lines for the main aggregates. The remaining columns display
prices and trends for the four broad categories of TPI and their main
subcomponents.
Figure 2 shows that the relative prices of different components of
investment have behaved quite [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED]
differently in the postwar era. The price of the broadest investment
measure, TPI, has been falling consistently since the early 1950s. Since
the plot of the relative price of TPI is in natural logarithms, one can
take the difference between the prices for two years to calculate the
percentage change. This procedure indicates that the price of TPI in
terms of consumption goods fell about 42 percent between 1958 and 1998.
Studying the other plots in figure 2, we see that this large drop
in the price of TPI can be attributed to strong downward trends in PDE
(particularly information and related and transportation equipment) and
CD (all three types). The drop in the relative price of information
equipment is particularly dramatic, at almost 200 percent since 1961.
The prices of NRS and its components were generally rising until the
late 1970s, were falling for most of the rest of the sample period, and
have started to rise again in the 1990s. RSE and its components display
a similar pattern. Generally, the long-run changes in structures prices
have been much smaller than in PDE and CD prices. When the investment
components are aggregated into nonresidential and residential, the
strong downward trends in PDE and CD prices dominate the changing trends
in structures.(10)
Prices of investment goods over the business cycle
My objective here is to determine the extent to which investment
good prices are generally procyclical, countercyclical, or acyclical (do
not display any distinctive pattern over the business cycle). I find
that. generally speaking, prices of PDE, NRS, and their components are
countercyclical, prices of RSE and its components are procyclical, and
prices of CD and its components are acyclical. There is some sample
period sensitivity, as outlined below.
In table 1, the column headed
[[Sigma].sub.[q.sup.i]]/[[Sigma].sub.[q.sup.y]], indicates the relative
volatility of the different investment components over the business
cycle. This is the standard deviation of the business cycle component of
the indicated real quantity series divided by the standard deviation of
the business cycle component of real GDP. We see that TPI varies almost
three times as much as GDP. The most volatile components of investment
are single family structures, multifamily structures, and consumer
expenditures on motor vehicles and parts. The least volatile components
are NRS, furniture and household equipment, and the "other"
component of CD. The column headed
[[Sigma].sub.[p.sup.i]]/[[Sigma].sub.[q.sup.y]] indicates the relative
volatility of the prices of different investment components over the
business cycle. This is the standard deviation of the business cycle
component of the indicated relative price series divided by the standard
deviation of the business cycle component of real GDP. The prices are
much less volatile than the quantities. With one exception (mining
exploration, shafts, and wells), all the prices are less volatile than
real GDP over the business cycle.
As a preliminary look at the cyclicality of investment good prices,
figure 3 displays the business cycle components of the prices (colored
lines) and quantities (black lines) of seven of the broadest measures
listed in table 1, along with the business cycle component of the
deflator for consumption ofnondurables and services. The latter price is
used in the denominator of all the investment relative prices, so its
business cycle dynamics will influence all the relative price measures
discussed here.(11)
Notice first that the consumption deflator rises in all but one
recession, 1981:Q3-82:Q4 (see shaded areas in [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 3
OMITTED]). This is a force for procyclicality of investment good prices.
For example, if the price deflator for an investment good were constant,
then the real price of that good would be procyclical. As expected, the
quantities are generally procyclical, although the peaks and troughs do
not exactly coincide with the NBER dates. The prices do not display as
consistent a pattern as the quantities. For example, sometimes the price
of TPI moves with the quantity of TPI (1950s, 1960s, and 1990s) and
sometimes it moves in the opposite direction (1970s and 1980s). More
distinct patterns emerge when TPI is decomposed into nonresidential and
residential. In the 1950s and 1990s, the prices and quantities of
nonresidential appear to move closely together. In the 1960s, 1970s, and
1980s, prices and quantities of this investment measure generally move
in opposite directions. Prices and quantities of residential show more
evidence of moving together. The most striking pattern to emerge among
the subcomponents of nonresidential and residential is in PDE. With the
exception of the 1950s, almost every time the quantity of PDE moves up,
the price of PDE moves down. This suggests countercyclical behavior in
the real price of PDE.
For a more formal examination of how the prices of investment goods
vary with the business cycle, I use a cross-correlogram. A
cross-correlogram is a diagrammatic device for describing how two
variables are related dynamically. For example, it provides a measure of
whether, say, movements in one variable tend to occur at the same time
and in the same direction as movements in another variable. It can also
be used to measure whether, for example, positive movements in a
variable tend to occur several quarters ahead of positive movements in
another variable.
The basis for the cross-correlogram is the correlation coefficient,
or correlation. A correlation is a measure of the degree to which two
variables move together and always takes on values between - 1 and 1.
Ifa correlation is positive, then the two variables are said to be
positively correlated. Similarly, ifa correlation is negative, the
variables are said to be negatively correlated. Larger absolute values
in a correlation indicate a stronger pattern of moving together. A
correlation for two variables measured contemporaneously is a measure of
how much two variables move together at the same time. A correlation can
be computed for two variables measured at different times. For example,
we can measure the correlation between variable x at time t and variable
y at time t - k, where k is a positive integer. This would measure the
degree to which variations in y occur before movements in x. A
cross-correlogram plots these correlations for various values ofk.
Figure 4 displays cross-correlograms (along with a
two-standard-deviation confidence interval, a measure of how precisely
the correlations are estimated) for various business cycle components of
real investment and GDP, - 6 [less than or equal to] k [less than or
equal to] 6. For example, panel A of figure 4 displays the correlations
of real nonresidential investment at date t and real GDP at date t - k
for the various values of k. The fact that the correlation for k = 0 is
positive and close to 1 for all the plots in figure 4 shows that all the
components of investment displayed are strongly positively correlated
with GDP contemporaneously. This confirms the impression given by figure
3 that real expenditures on these investment goods are strongly
procyclical. Notice that the largest correlations for nonresidential and
its two main subcomponents, NRS and PDE, are for k [greater than] 0.
This says that these components of investment tend to lag GDP over the
business cycle. Another way of saying this is that movements above trend
in GDP tend to occur before movements above trend in these measures of
investment. On the other hand, the largest correlations for residential
and its main subcomponents, RSE and CD, are all for k [less than] 0.
This says that these components of investment lead output over the
business cycle. Because the correlations in figure 4 are mostly
positive, this figure shows that the main components of investment are
generally procyclical. (If they had been mostly negative, then this
would have been evidence of countercyclicality. If the correlations were
mostly close to zero, this would have been evidence of acyclicality.)
Figure 5 displays cross-correlograms (with standard errors) for the
prices of the broadest measures of investment and real GDP. The plots in
figure 3 indicate that there may be some sample period sensitivity in
the estimation of the underlying correlations, so figure 5 displays
cross-correlograms based on two sample periods. The first column of
panels in figure 5 is based on the sample period 1947:Q1-98:Q3 and the
second column is based on 1959:Q1-98:Q3. Notice that none of the
correlations for the TPI price based on the longer sample are
significantly different from zero. This means that the price of the
broadest measure of investment is essentially acyclical. There is some
evidence of countercyclical movements in this price for the shorter
sample, although the correlations in this case are generally not very
large in absolute value or statistically significant.
The cyclical behavior of prices for the narrower investment
aggregates displayed in figure 5 reveals that the lack of any distinct
cyclical pattern for the price of TPI masks interesting differences
between the prices of nonresidential and residential goods. Over the
longer sample, the nonresidential price is estimated to be essentially
acyclical, but the residential price is clearly procyclical. Over the
shorter sample the nonresidential investment price is clearly
countercyclical and the residential price remains procyclical. The
difference in the estimated cross-correlogram for nonresidential over
the two sample periods turns out to be due to differences in the
behavior of the price of PDE in the 1950s compared with the later sample
period [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 3 OMITTED].
The evidence in figure 5 suggests two things. First, the cyclical
behavior of investment good prices depends to some extent on the sample
period examined. Second, considering a broad investment aggregate masks
potentially interesting cyclical characteristics of more narrowly
defined investment good prices. Figures 6 and 7 try to uncover whether
the cyclical behavior of nonresidential and residential prices also
masks different cyclical behavior among the subcomponents of these broad
investment aggregates. These figures display price-output
cross-correlograms for the main subcomponents of nonresidential and
residential. Due to data availability, the sample period for estimating
the correlations is 1959:Q1-98:Q3.
The first column in figure 6 pertains to NRS and its main
subcomponents, nonresidential buildings, utilities, and mining. The
price of NRS is significantly countercyclical. This appears to be mainly
driven by the price of utilities and mining. The second column of figure
6 pertains to PDE and its main subcomponents, information and related
equipment, industrial equipment, and transportation equipment. There are
two observations to make here. First, the price of PDE is strongly and
significantly countercyclical. The contemporaneous (k = 0) correlation
is -0.63 with a standard error of 0.03. The largest correlation in
absolute value is for k = 2, indicating that this price lags output by
about two quarters, about the same as the quantity of PDE [ILLUSTRATION
FOR FIGURE 4 OMITTED]. The second observation is that the prices of the
main components of PDE behave almost identically: They are strongly and
significantly negatively correlated with output and lag output by about
two quarters. The behavior of the industrial equipment price is
particularly striking, given that the long-run behavior of this price is
so different from that of the other two subcomponents of PDE
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 2 OMITTED].
Figure 7 is constructed similarly to figure 6, with RSE and its
subcomponents in the first column and CD and its subcomponents in the
second column. This figure shows that prices of RSE are generally
procyclical and prices of CD goods are mostly acyclical. The behavior of
RSE is driven mostly by the cyclicality of single and multifamily
structures. Interestingly, despite the fact that investment in RSE tends
to lead output over the business cycle, the real price of RSE and its
components lags output. The real price of CD is driven mostly by motor
vehicles and other. Of the subcomponents of C D, only the furniture
price displays significant countercyclicality.
Summary of the evidence
The key features of the evidence presented in this section can be
summarized as follows. First, there is strong evidence of a downward
trend in the price of investment goods in terms of consumption goods.
This downward trend is concentrated among components of PDE and CD.
Second, the broadest category of investment, TPI, displays little
distinct cyclical variation over the sample period 1947:Q1-98:Q3, but is
moderately countercyclical in the later period, 1959:Q1-98:Q3. If we are
willing to abstract from the 1950s, say because of the dominating
influence of the Korean war, then it seems reasonable to say that the
price of the broadest component of investment is weakly countercyclical.
Certainly it is difficult to make the case that this price is
procyclical, regardless of the sample period considered.
Many components of TPI display distinct cyclical characteristics,
even if we include the 1950s. The prices of the two main components,
nonresidential and residential, behave differently. The former is
significantly countercyclical and the latter is significantly
procyclical. The behavior of the nonresidential price is dominated by
the PDE price. The PDE price is strongly countercyclical, as are the
prices of all its subcomponents. The price of NRS is mildly
countercyclical, but this pattern is not shared by all its
subcomponents. The behavior of the residential price is dominated by RSE
prices, which are strongly procyclical. CD prices are acyclical or
weakly countercyclical.
Implications for growth and the business cycle
How does the trend and cycle behavior of investment goods prices
presented above challenge conventional views about growth and business
cycles? Next, I discuss various attempts to reconcile theory with the
evidence and some empirical work that sheds light on the plausibility of
competing theories.
Growth theory
Recent years have seen an explosion of theoretical and empirical
research into economic growth.(12) On the theoretical side, two leading
classes of models of the determinants of economic growth have emerged.
The first is based on the accumulation of human capital and follows from
the work of Lucas (1988). Human capital consists of the abilities,
skills, and knowledge of particular workers. The basic idea behind this
view of economic growth is that it is fundamentally based on
improvements in the stock of human capital of workers over time. This
view of growth holds that, other things being equal, the larger is the
stock of human capital of workers, the more productive they are. This
means that one expects an improvement in the stock of human capital to
increase the amount of output of any good that can be produced for a
fixed quantity of workers and capital. In this sense, growth due to the
accumulation of human capital has a homogeneous impact on the
economy's ability to produce goods.
The second leading class of models focuses on research and
development. Pioneering work along these lines includes Romer (1990),
Grossman and Helpman (1991), and Aghion and Howitt (1992). One of the
key insights of this literature is that growth can emerge if there are
nondecreasing returns to produced factors of production (such as
knowledge or capital, but not labor).(13) The bottom line of this theory
is similar to that of the human capital models. Improvements in
technology due to research and development usually increase the
productivity of all factors of production. Consequently, if there is
such an improvement in technology, more of all goods can be produced
with a fixed quantity of capital and labor. Again, technological change
is assumed to have a homogeneous impact on produced goods.
The evidence on trends in investment good prices, particularly the
trend in the price of PDE, challenges these views of growth, because it
strongly suggests that there have been substantial improvements in
technology that have affected one kind of good but not another.
Specifically, the data suggest that the quality and technology of
capital goods production have advanced almost nonstop since the end of
World War II. Why do the data suggest this? Assuming that the prices and
quantities of PDE are correctly measured, the real price of PDE measures
how many (constant quality) consumption goods need to be sold in order
to raise the funds to purchase one (constant quality) unit of PDE, If
this price has been falling, then fewer and fewer consumption goods are
needed to buy a unit of PDE. This suggests that the supply of PDE has
grown relative to the supply of consumption goods. One way the supply of
PDE can rise in this way is if the technology for producing capital
goods improves at a faster rate than that for producing consumption
goods. In this case, the same amount of capital and labor applied to
producing PDE or consumption goods will yield more PDE than consumption
as time passes. That is, the supply of PDE will grow relative to
consumption goods. The basic logic of supply and demand then dictates
that the price of PDE. in terms of consumption goods must fall.
Greenwood et al. (1997) build on this intuition to show how the trend in
the relative price of PDE and the associated increase in the share of
PDE in aggregate output (see table 1) can be accounted for in a growth
model in which most growth is due to capital-embodied technical change.
In addition, the authors argue that other potential explanations for the
price and quantity trends are implausible or boil down to essentially
the same explanation.(14)
Greenwood et al. (1997) apply their model of growth to reevaluate
conventional estimates of the importance of technological change in
improving standards of living. This line of research is called growth
accounting. The effects of technical change using standard models, like
the ones briefly described above, can be summarized by multifactor
productivity, which is also called the Solow residual. Multifactor
productivity is an index of the quantity of aggregate output that can be
produced using a fixed quantity of (quality-adjusted) capital and labor.
The higher the multifactor productivity, the more output can be
produced. Traditionally, most of growth is viewed as being due to
improvements in multifactor productivity. Greenwood et al. (1997) use
their model to show that approximately 60 percent of all improvements in
productivity can be attributed to capital-embodied technical change,
while the multifactor productivity index accounts for the rest. This
says that capital-embodied technical change is a fundamental part of
growth.
Business cycle theory
To assess the cyclical evidence on relative prices, we need to
understand how various shocks to the economy might influence the cost of
investment goods compared with consumption goods. Figure 8 displays a
production possibilities frontier (PPF) for consumption and investment
goods. The PPF depicts the various quantities of consumption and
investment goods that can be produced if capital and labor are fully
employed and used efficiently. The shape of the frontier reflects the
fact that, holding fixed the quantity of labor and capital employed in
producing goods, it is costly to shift production toward either
producing more consumption goods or more investment goods.(15) This is
reflected in the figure by the increase in the (absolute value of the)
slope of the frontier as one moves from the upper left to the lower
right. In a competitive equilibrium, the slope of the frontier equals
the relative price of the goods. Hence, as more investment goods are
produced, the relative price of investment goods rises.
The PPF summarizes the supply side of the economy. The actual price
in a competitive equilibrium is determined by the interaction of the
demand for consumption and investment goods with the supply. Suppose
that the demand for consumption and investment goods dictates that the
quantity of consumption goods and investment goods actually produced is
given by [C.sub.0], and [I.sub.0] in figure 8. Now, suppose a Keynesian
demand shock - for example, an increase in the money supply which lowers
interest rates - increases the demand for investment goods relative to
consumption goods. Since this is a demand shock, the PPF in figure 8
does not change. The change in demand leads to a movement down the
frontier, say to a point where consumption and investment are given by
[C.sub.1] and [I.sub.1]. Since the slope of the frontier is steeper at
this point, the relative price of investment goods must rise. If
aggregate output is driven by shocks to investment demand, then the
price of investment goods is predicted to be procyclical.
An aggregate supply shock has a similar implication. The
conventional assumption about these kinds of shocks is that they raise
multifactor productivity and influence all produced goods symmetrically.
This is shown in figure 9 as a proportional shift out in the solid line
PPF to the dashed line PPF. The dashed line PPF has been drawn so that
its slope is identical to the slope of the solid line PPF along a
straight line from the origin. This means that if the ratio of
consumption to investment goods produced before and after the technology
shock is constant, then the relative price of investment goods will be
unchanged. However, this is not what is predicted in standard models.
These models say that when a good technology shock arrives, which raises
the productivity of all factors of production, the optimal response of
individuals is to smooth consumption. That is, not have consumption
change too much in the short run. The result of this is that investment
rises more than consumption. In figure 9, this is represented by
consumption and investment changing from [C.sub.0] and [I.sub.0] before
the productivity shock to [C.sub.1] and [I.sub.1] after the shock. It
follows that the price of investment goods must rise in this case as
well. Since output also rises with a positive technology shock, the
price of investment goods is predicted to be procyclical.(16)
In view of the cyclical evidence presented earlier, these model
predictions are problematic. They are consistent with the behavior of
residential investment, but inconsistent with the behavior of the other
major components of investment and the broadest measure, TPI. Why are
investment goods prices not procyclical? The two leading explanations
involve assumptions about the technology for producing investment goods.
One is based on increasing returns to scale in the production of
investment goods (but not consumption goods). The other is based on a
variation in the rate of capital-embodied technical change. The
increasing returns view assumes that the more investment goods that are
produced, the less costly it is to produce a unit of investment goods.
One way to represent this is shown in figure 10, which displays a
pseudo-PPF.(17) Notice that the shape is different from figures 8 and 9.
Now when more investment goods are produced relative to consumption
goods, the price of investment goods falls. In this case, both aggregate
technology shocks and Keynesian demand shocks can lead to
countercyclical relative prices.
To understand the embodied technology view, consider an increase in
the productivity of producing investment goods that has no direct impact
on the production of consumption goods. This could take the form of
improvements in the efficiency of producing investment goods. It could
also take the form of an improvement in the quality of investment goods
produced so that a given quantity of capital and labor can produce a
higher quantity of quality-adjusted goods. Either way, we can represent
the change in technology as in figure 11. The improvement in technology
is shown by the shift from the solid to the dashed frontier. Along the
dashed frontier, for each quantity of consumption goods produced, more
investment goods can be produced. Moreover, along any straight line from
the origin, the slope of the dashed frontier is flatter than the solid
frontier. That is, for any fixed ratio of consumption to investment
goods, the investment goods are cheaper in terms of consumption goods
after the change in technology. Now, after the increase in technology,
there will be a shift in favor of the production of investment goods. If
this shift is strong enough, the movement along the dashed frontier
could in principle raise the investment good price. In practice, this
does not happen. Since aggregate output rises after this kind of
technology shock, if business cycles are in part driven by this kind of
disturbance, then investment good prices could be countercyclical.
Evaluating the theories
Beyond the work of Greenwood et al. (1997), little has been done to
evaluate the plausibility of the capital-embodied technological change
theory of the trend evidence on investment prices. However, more work
has been done to evaluate the differing views on the cyclicality of
investment good prices.
Generally, the empirical evidence seems to go against the
increasing returns interpretation of the cyclical evidence on prices.
Harrison (1998) examines annual data on capital, labor, and value added in various industries in the consumption good sector and the investment
good sector. She finds some empirical support for increasing returns
associated with capital and labor in the production of investment goods.
However, she does not find a sufficient degree of increasing returns to
generate increasing returns in the factor of production, labor, that is
variable in the short run. Consequently, the work does not support the
increasing returns view. Other research on measuring increasing returns
focuses on the manufacturing sector. Basu and Fernald (1997), Burnside
(1996), and Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995) have overturned
previous empirical claims of increasing returns in the manufacturing
sector, including capital equipment industries.
Other empirical work attempts to address a key implication of the
increasing returns view - that the supply curve for investment goods
slopes down. That is, holding other things constant, the cost of
investment goods is diminishing in the quantity of investment goods
produced. Shea (1993), in a study of many sectors of the economy, uses
instrumental variables econometric techniques to distinguish supply
shocks from demand shocks to trace out the slope of supply curves. The
author's main conclusion is that, broadly speaking, supply curves
slope up. Goolsbee (1998) focuses specifically on the supply of capital
goods and uses a series of "natural experiments" (involving
periodic changes in federal laws providing for investment tax credits)
to identify a disturbance that affects the demand for investment goods
but not the supply. He finds clear evidence of an upward sloping
investment supply curve. To summarize, empirical work on the sign of the
slope of the investment good supply schedule finds that it is positive.
Other research assesses the plausibility of the embodied technology
view. Christiano and Fisher (1998) and Greenwood et al. (1998) evaluate
business cycle models in which a major driving force for fluctuations is
variations in capital-embodied technical change. They test the embodied
technology view by examining the ability of their models to account for
various business cycle phenomena. Both studies find that their models do
about as well as other business cycle models in accounting for business
cycle phenomena. As a measure of the importance of capital-embodied
technical change as a driving force for business cycles, Greenwood et
al. (1998) find that about 30 percent of business cycle variation in
output can be attributed to this kind of shock. Christiano and Fisher
(1998), in a very different model, find that about three-quarters of
output fluctuations are due to this shock. Either way, the evidence
suggests that variation in the rate of technical change embodied in
capital equipment accounts for a significant proportion of business
cycle variation in output.
New evidence
Some new research attempts to distinguish the increasing returns
view from the embodied technology view of the cyclical behavior of
investment good prices. This evidence is based on two econometric
procedures designed to identity, disturbances to the aggregate economy
that influence the demand for investment goods, but leave supply
unchanged. The specific shocks considered are an exogenous increase in
government purchases (that is an increase in government purchases that
is unrelated to developments in the economy) and an exogenous monetary
contraction.
In the government spending case, the idea is to investigate how
particular investment quantities and prices respond to an exogenous
increase in government purchases. The exogenous increase in government
spending takes the form of a large military buildup (specifically the
Korean war, the Vietnam war, and the Carter-Reagan buildup.) The
methodology is identical to that employed by Eichenbaum and Fisher
(1998).(18) Figure 12 displays the estimates, which are based on
quarterly data for 1947:Q1-98:Q3. The first row of figure 12 plots the
response to an exogenous increase in government purchases of real
investment in PDE and RSE (solid lines) along with a 68 percent
confidence band (colored lines). The second row plots the corresponding
relative price responses. Interestingly, PDE investment rises and RSE
investment falls.(19) Under the increasing returns view, we would expect
the PDE price to fall and the RSE price to rise. The second row of plots
indicates that the RSE price response is inconsistent with the
increasing returns view, while the PDE price response seems to confirm
it.
The monetary shocks case examines how quantities and prices of PDE
and RSE respond to an estimate of a contractionary monetary disturbance.
The methodology is standard(20) and has been summarized by Christiano
(1996) (see also Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans, 1999). The estimated
responses (along with a 95 percent confidence interval) are presented in
figure 13. Looking at the quantities in the first row of plots, notice
that both PDE and RSE fall after an exogenous monetary contraction.
Under the increasing returns view. one would expect the prices of both
investment goods to rise. Studying the second row of plots, we see that
the PDE price response is not significantly different from zero and the
RSE price drops significantly.
Taken together, the evidence on the responses of RSE prices and
quantities to government spending and monetary. shocks goes against the
increasing returns view. It conforms to a standard neoclassical view of
investment, in the sense that it is consistent with the discussion of
the production possibilities frontier in figure 8. Of course, the
increasing returns view is really intended to apply to PDE investment.
The responses of PDE prices and quantities provide mixed signals. The
responses to a monetary shock provide evidence neither for nor against
increasing returns, since the quantity falls but the price response is
not very precisely estimated and could be either positive, negative, or
zero. The responses to a government spending shock might be viewed as
evidence in favor of increasing returns. However, one interpretation of
the PDE price response in this case is that it is dominated by the
Korean war military buildup. This occurred just after World War II, when
military spending had fallen from very high levels. The increasing
returns that could support a lower price with higher investment might
conceivably be due to the resumption of large-scale production at
facilities that had been operating far below minimum efficient scale. If
this is true, it seems more like a special case than an enduring feature
of the U.S. economy.
Conclusion
In this article, I have presented evidence on trends and business
cycle variation in the prices of investment goods relative to
nondurables and services consumption. This evidence seems to go against
conventional views of both business cycles and growth. How can one
reconcile theory with the evidence? The leading views include one based
on increasing returns to scale in the production of investment goods and
another based on capital-embodied technical change. While some of the
evidence I presented could be viewed as supporting the increasing
returns view, generally, there is little empirical support for
increasing returns. At this point, then, the leading candidate to
reconcile theory with the data appears to be the one based on
capital-embodied technical change, that is, the embodied technology
view.
This conclusion has implications for our understanding of growth
and business cycles, future research on these subjects, and policy. The
prospect of a comprehensive theory of growth and business cycles is
appealing because of its simplicity. Disembodied technical change has
gained credence for its supposed ability to account for growth and
business cycles. Yet, the theory of business cycles based on disembodied
technology has always been problematic because the shocks are hard to
interpret. The growth accounting results of Greenwood et al. (1997)
bring into question the growth implications of this theory as well. In
the search for a comprehensive theory of growth and business cycles,
then, advances in capital-embodied technology seem to offer a promising
alternative. In addition, they provide a much more tangible notion of
growth. These considerations suggest that future research on growth and
business cycles that emphasizes capital-embodied technical change may be
fruitful.
If growth and business cycles are originating from changes in
capital-embodied technology, then the models we use for policy analysis
have to incorporate this and, consequently, policy recommendations could
change. To the extent that technological change is embodied in capital
equipment, government policies that affect equipment investment could
have a dual impact on growth via the quality and the quantity of capital
goods. This could mean, for example, that investment tax credits
directed toward improvements in the efficiency of capital equipment
could have a significant impact on growth. More research is required to
uncover the full implications of this.
The implications for stabilization policy of the embodied
technology view are less obvious. The fact that it seems to supplant the
increasing returns view means that the arguments for interventionist
stabilization policy that this view supports are less compelling. For
example, increasing returns could provide scope for policy intervention,
because it either involves externalities or is inconsistent with perfect
competition. Moreover, it makes animal spirits models more plausible,
which also has implications for stabilization policy (see, for example,
Christiano and Harrison, 1999). The embodied technology view is more in
line with the real business cycle tradition, in which policy
interventions are counterproductive. Real business cycle theory says
that the business cycle is largely the result of optimal behavior by
individuals in the economy interacting, for the most part, in perfectly
competitive markets. Any policy interventions in such an environment
tend to reduce overall welfare. To the extent that the embodied
technology view is more compelling than previous incarnations of real
business cycle models, it lends greater support to the argument that
interventionist stabilization policy cannot improve the well-being of
any individual in the U.S. economy without hurting some other
individual. Of course, this still leaves open the possibility that
equity considerations might be used to defend interventionist
stabilization policy.
BOX 1
Measuring real quantities and prices from nominal expenditure data
The U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) uses the chain-type
Fisher index to measure real output and prices. For a thorough
discussion of the procedures the BEA uses, see Landereld and Parker
(1997), which this box draws on. This index, developed by Irving Fisher,
is a geometric mean of the conventional fixed-weighted Laspeyres index
(which uses weights of the first period in a two-period example) and a
Paassche index (which uses the weights of the second period). The
Laspeyres price index for period t constructed using base year t-1,
[L.sub.t] is given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The Paassche price index for period t constructed using base year
t, [S.sub.t] is given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Here N is the number of goods whose prices are being summarized by
the index, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the date t dollar price
of the ith quality-adjusted good, and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
is the quality-adjusted quantity of good i purchased at date t. The
Fisher price index at date t, F, is
[F.sub.t] = [square root of [L.sub.t] x [S.sub.t]].
From this definition we see that changes in [F.sub.t] are
calculated using the "weights" of adjacent years. These period
to period changes are "chained" (multiplied) together to form
a time series that allows for the effects of changes in relative prices
and in the composition of output over time. Notice that a quantity index
can be computed in a manner analogous to the price index. A nice feature
of the Fisher index is that the product of these two indexes equals
nominal expenditures. Landereld and Parker (1997) discuss several
advantages of this index over previously used fixed weight indexes.
To measure relative prices we need to choose a numeraire. In the
introduction the term "value in consumption goods" was used.
Implicit in this statement is the assumption that consumption goods,
specifically nondurable and services consumption, is the numeraire.
Define the price deflator for nondurable and services consumption as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Then the relative price of the good i
at time t, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is defined as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Notice that the units of the price are what we require. The BEA
does not provide a measure of price deflator for nondurable and services
consumption. To construct the consumption deflator used in this article,
I applied the chain-weighting methodology outlined above, treating the
NIPA quantity and price indexes for nondurable consumption and service
consumption as the prices and quantities in the formulas.
NOTES
1 Equivalently, higher quality goods of all kinds can be produced
with the same amount of capital and labor. As described in more detail
below, new models of endogenous growth have reduced forms, which have
similar implications for growth accounting to those of models written in
terms of exogenous disembodied technical change.
2 Examples of textbooks that emphasize the IS-LM model are Abel and
Bernanke (1997), Gordon (1998), Hall and Taylor (1997), and Mankiw
(1997).
3 For a survey of theories based on animal spirits, see Farmer
(1993).
4 A good summary of this view is Prescott (1986). For a discussion
of how this view can be used to explain the 1990-91 recession, see
Hansen and Prescott (1993).
5 This section relies heavily on Christiano and Fitzgerald (1998,
pp. 58-59).
6 This is the empirical counterpart to investment as it is usually
defined in the real business cycle literature.
7 The aggregation in this table is identical to the aggregation
used by the BEA, except for "residential," which is calculated
as the chain-weighted aggregate of "residential structures and
equipment" and "consumer durable." See box 1 for the
chain-weighting procedure.
8 For TPI and GDP, y, the nominal shares in the first row are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and the real shares are [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]. Nominal and real shares for investment good i in
the other rows are given by [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and the
real shares are [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
9 In the notation used above. the black lines are (the natural
logarithm of) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] for i corresponding to
the 20 types of investment listed in table 1 over the period for which
data are available.
10 Many of the trends evident in figure 2 are not apparent in the
NIPA fixed-weighted constant 1982 dollar and earlier NIPA data. In a
very influential book, Gordon (1989) argued that the conventional BEA
treatment of investment good quality severely underestimated the degree
of quality change in investment goods. His analysis was the first to
show that there is a substantial downward trend in the prices of PDE and
CD. The BEA now incorporates many of the adjustments for quality change
advocated by Gordon (1989).
11 The procedure used to extract the business cycle component of
the relative price data involves the application of a linear filter.
This, combined with the fact that this filter is applied to the natural
logarithm of the relative prices, implies that the business cycle
component of each relative price is the business cycle component of the
relevant investment deflator minus the business cycle component of the
consumption deflator.
12 For a comprehensive review of this literature, see Barro and
Sala-i-Martin (1995).
13 The assumption of constant returns to scale is usually based on
a replication argument. A fixed quantity of capital and labor applied to
produce x amount of some good can always be applied again to produce
another x of the good. That is, increasing the quantity of factors of
production by some proportion changes the amount produced by the same
proportion. This argument seems harder to apply in the case of
technology. For example, suppose a group of researchers have discovered
a new process for making steel. If another group of researchers make the
same discovery, there is no net improvement in knowledge. In this case,
there would be decreasing returns. On the other hand, fixed costs or
advantages to having many researchers working on similar projects may
mean that increasing returns to scale are important in the process of
knowledge creation.
14 Greenwood et al. (.1997) show how the research and development
and human capital classes of models can be used to account for the
evidence, if these activities have a disproportionate impact on the
production of equipment compared with consumption goods. Two
explanations they consider differ fundamentally from their basic story.
They both involve a two-sector interpretation of the evidence, in which
equipment and consumption goods are produced in separate sectors (using
separate production functions). In one case, the production functions
have different factor shares, that is, the different goods require
capital and labor in different proportions to produce a unit of the
good. The authors conclude that the "prospect for explaining the
relative price decline with a two-sector model based on differences in
share parameters looks bleak, given the implausibly large differences
required in the structure of production across sectors (p. 358)."
The other explanation involves an externality in the production of
investment goods. Specifically, the productivity of factors in the
investment good sector is increasing in the quantity of investment goods
along the lines described in Romer (1986). Greenwood et al. (1997) show
that this explanation can, in principle, account for the trend evidence.
However, this theory, relies on an externality which is difficult to
identify empirically. Some evidence on increasing returns to scale,
which the production externality implies, is discussed below. Generally;
there is little empirical support for this view.
15 The shape of the frontier can be justified by standard
neoclassical assumptions about how goods are produced, in particular
that they are produced using constant returns to scale production
functions in labor and capital and that it is costly to transfer labor
and/or capital across sectors producing consumption goods and sectors
producing investment goods. Note that adjustment costs in the
installation of investment goods affect the relative price of installed
capacity, not the relative price of investment goods.
16 This discussion assumes that the shares of factors in production
are identical in producing consumption and investment goods and/or that
there are costs of adjusting factors of production across sectors. It is
possible for the price of investment goods to be countercyclical in this
type of model if the share of labor in production is greater in the
consumption sector than in the investment goods sector. As long as
factors of production are perfectly mobile across sectors (that is,
there are no costs to shifting factors across sectors), an increase in
technology lowers the price of investment goods in this case. Factor
shares are difficult to measure, so assessing the plausibility of this
possibility is difficult. However, the Greenwood et al. (1997) results
for long-run trends suggest that the differences in factor shares
required to reconcile the empirical evidence on prices with this
explanation may be implausible. Also, it is implausible to assume that
there are no costs of shifting factors of production across sectors.
17 This frontier does not necessarily reflect true technological
possibilities, but takes into account the restrictions on individual
decisionmaking, such as individuals not internalizing a production
externality, such that the points on the frontier are consistent with
optimizing behavior of producers.
18 The methodology is identical to that employed by Eichenbaum and
Fisher (1998). This methodology uses four variables, in addition to the
investment good quantity and price variables, in a vector
autoregression, along with a dummy variable which takes on the value
zero at all dates except 1950:Q3, 1965:Q1 and 1980:Q1, in which cases
the variable equals unity. These dates correspond to the beginning of
three large military buildups. The key identifying assumption is that
these buildups were exogenous events. For further discussion, see
Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999). The four variables are the log
level of time t real GDP, the net three-month Treasury bill rate, the
log of the Producer Price Index of crude fuel, and the log level of real
defense purchases, [g.sub.t], Six lags were used. The plotted responses
in figure 12 correspond to the average response of the indicated
variable across the three military buildup episodes, taking into account
the endogenous variation in the variable.
19 See Edelberg, Eichenbaum, and Fisher (1999) for a discussion of
how this evidence can be explained within the context of a standard
neoclassical model.
20 Technically, I estimate a vector autoregression in the deflator
for nondurables and services, real GDP, an index of changes in sensitive
materials prices, the federal funds rate, plus the investment price and
quantity I am interested in. All variables except the federal funds rate
are first logged. The impulse response functions in figure 13 correspond
to an orthoganalized innovation in the federal funds rate. The
orthoganalization procedure assumes the order of the vector
autoregression is the same as listed in the text and a triangular
decomposition. Ordering is not important for the investment responses as
long as standard assumptions are made about the variables that precede
the federal funds rate in the ordering (see Christiano, Eichenbaum, and
Evans, 1999). Finally, the standard errors are computed using the
procedure described by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1999).
REFERENCES
Abel, Andrew, and Ben Bernanke, 1997, Macroeconomics, 3rd edition,
New York: Addison-Wesley.
Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt, 1992, "A model of growth
through creative destruction," Econometrica, Vol. 60, No. 2, March,
pp. 323-351.
Barro, Robert, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1995, Economic Growth, New
York: McGraw-Hill.
Basu, Susanto, and John Fernald, 1997, "Returns to scale in
U.S. production: Estimates and implications," Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 105, No. 2, April, pp. 249-283.
Burnside, Craig, 1996, "Production function regressions,
returns to scale, and externalities," Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 37, No. 2, April, pp. 177-201.
Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo, 1995,
"Capacity utilization and returns to scale," in NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1995, Vol. 10, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg
(eds.), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Christiano, Lawrence J., 1996, "Identification and the
liquidity effect: A case study," Economic Perspectives, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 20, No. 3, May/June, pp. 2-13.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans,
1999, "Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what
end?," in Handbook of Macroeconomics, John Taylor and Michael
Woodford (eds.), Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, forthcoming.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Jonas D. M. Fisher, 1998, "Stock
market and investment good prices: Implications for
macroeconomics," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Terry Fitzgerald, 1998, "The
business cycle: It's still a puzzle," Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 22 No. 4, Fourth Quarter, pp.
56-83.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Sharon Harrison, 1999. "Chaos,
sunspots, and automatic stabilizers," Journal of "Monetary
Economics, forthcoming.
Edelberg, Wendy, Marty Eichenbaum, and Jonas D. M. Fisher, 1999,
"Understanding the effects of a shock to government
purchases," Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 2, forthcoming.
Eichenbaum, Marty, and Jonas D. M. Fisher, 1998, "How does an
increase in government purchases effect the economy?," Economic
Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 22, No. 3, Third
Quarter, pp. 29-43.
Farmer, Roger, 1993, The Macroeconomics of Self-Fulfilling
Prophecies, Cambridge: MIT Press.
Fisher, Jonas D. M., 1997, "Relative prices,
complementarities, and comovement among components of aggregate
expenditures," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 39, No. 3,
August, pp. 449-474.
Goolsbee, Austen, 1998, "Investment tax incentives, prices,
and the supply of capital goods," Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 113, No. 1, February, pp. 121-148.
Gordon, Robert, 1998, Macroeconomics, 7th edition. New York:
Addison-Wesley.
-----, 1989, The Measurement of Durable Goods Prices, Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Greenwood, Jeremy, and Zvi Hercowitz, 1988, "Investment,
capacity utilization, and the real business cycle," American
Economic Review, Vol. 78, No. June, pp. 402-417.
Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Per Krusell, 1998, "The
role of investment-specific technological change in the business
cycle," University of Rochester, manuscript, January.
-----, 1997, "Long-run implications of investment-specific
technological change," Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 3, June, pp.
342-362.
Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman, 1991, Innovation and Growth in
the Global Economy, Cambridge. MA: MIT Press.
Hall, Robert, and John Taylor, 1997, Macroeconomics, 5th edition,
New York: W. W. Norton.
Hansen, Gary, and Edward Prescott, 1993, "Did technology
shocks cause the 1990-91 recession?," American Economic Review.
Vol. 83, No. 2, May, pp. 280-286.
Harrison, Sharon G., 1998, "Evidence on the empirical
plausibility of externalities and indeterminacy in a two sector
model," Barnard College, Columbia University, unpublished
manuscript.
Hornstein, Andreas, and J. Praschnik, 1997, "Intermediate
inputs and sectoral comovement in the business cycle," Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 40, No. 3, December, pp. 573-595.
Huffman, Gregory, and Mark Wynne, 1999, "The role of
intratemporal adjustment costs in a multisector economy," Journal
of Monetary Economics, Forthcoming.
Krusell, Per, Lee Ohanian, Victor Rios-Rull, and Giovanni Violante,
1995, "Capital-skill complementarity and inequality,"
University of Rochester, manuscript.
Landefeld, J. Steven, and Robert P. Parker, 1997, "BEA's
chain indexes, time series, and measures of long-term economic
growth," Survey of Current Business, pp. 58-68.
Lucas, Robert E., 1988, "On the mechanics of economic
development," Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22, No. 1, July,
pp. 3-42.
Mankiw, Gregory, 1997, Macroeconomic,s, 3rd edition, New York:
Worth.
Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1989.
"Building blocks of market clearing business cycle models," in
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1089, Olivier J. Blanchard and Stanley
Fischer (eds.), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Prescott, Edward, 1986, "Theory ahead of business cycle
measurement," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, Fall, pp. 9-22.
Romer, Paul, 1990, "Endogenous technical change," Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2. October, pp. S71-S102.
-----, 1986, "Increasing returns and long-run growth,"
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No. 5, October, pp. 1002-1037.
Shea, John, 1993, "Do supply curves slope up?," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 108, February, pp. 1-32.
Solow, Robert, 1957, "Technical change and the aggregate
production function," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39,
pp. 312-320.
Jonas D. M. Fisher is a senior economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. This article has benefited from conversations with
Larry Christiano. The author thanks Judy Yoo for excellent research
assistance.