State-local business taxation and the benefits principle.
Oakland, William H. ; Testa, William A.
In recent years, interest in state and local taxation of business has
been fueled by concerns over the possible deleterious effects such taxes
may have on economic development and, in particular, on the ability of a
jurisdiction to provide jobs for its residents. Much ink has been
spilled over whether or not fiscal factors have a significant effect on
firm location decisions. However, without analyzing why business taxes
are on the books in the first place, it may be impossible to properly
evaluate the impact of such taxes on business location. In this article,
we advance the proposition that general business taxation should be
structured so as to recover the costs of public services rendered to the
business community.
Economic development may be but one objective of tax policy. Other
objectives, such as fairness, economic efficiency, and sound expenditure
policy, are also important. For example, a local community may want to
structure its taxes to discourage business activities which produce
noxious side effects; state government may wish to restrict business
activity in such a way as to promote monopoly power of home
enterprise(s) serving an out-of-state clientele. Even in the absence of
such motives for growth controls, business taxation may be desirable to
recover the cost of government services provided to businesses within a
jurisdiction. Not only does this promote fairness, by recouping the
costs of such services from those who ultimately benefit from them, it
also enhances economic efficiency by causing the prices of goods and
services to reflect their full costs of production. Such prices enable
people to make appropriate choices among consumer goods. Business
benefits taxes similarly promote appropriate choices between private and
public goods. Without recovery of the costs of business services, voters
may not support otherwise worthy public services provided to business.
Alternatively, the voting public and their representatives may believe
that business taxes can be ratcheted skyward as a way to subsidize those
public services provided to households.
One objective of this article is to develop a comprehensive framework
for evaluating the efficacy of state-local business tax structures. This
framework will then be applied to existing practices within the U.S.,
with specific focus upon the Seventh Federal Reserve District, which
encompasses Iowa and major portions of Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, and
Wisconsin. We will argue that the primary basis for general business
taxation is to recover the costs of government services rendered to the
business community. It follows that if general business taxes exceed or
fall short of the cost of providing government services to business, the
business tax structure is not neutral with respect to the location of
business activity in general. Furthermore, it will not be neutral with
respect to consumption patterns for consumer goods and the composition
of spending on private goods and public goods.
It should be emphasized that, even where there is correspondence
between business taxation and business expenditures, there may remain
non-neutral location incentives for specific firms. This will be the
case if the business tax structure is not neutral across firm types or
if there are wide disparities among firm types in terms of service benefits received from government. In effect, what is true on average
may not be true for particular firms. These issues should be considered
when designing the optimal business tax structure.
We begin by providing a framework under which businesses might be
taxed to optimal effect. Following definition and measurement of current
state-local business taxation, we discuss alternative business tax
structures. Among these alternatives, the benefits principle is
identified as the best by far. Turning to the specifics of how to
implement the benefits principle, today's practices are held up
against the theoretical standard that business tax revenues should
roughly cover direct public service costs. In the final section, we
suggest how state-local government might lower taxation of business by
levying uniform tax rates on a broad-based measure of business activity
- value added.
A framework for business taxation
Definitions
Business taxes are not easy to define. Many business taxes are
shifted from the legal or statutory taxpayer to other entities.
Tax-shifting mechanisms are frequently subtle and indirect; as a result,
theories of tax incidence are sometimes controversial. Furthermore,
because only individuals, in their capacities as consumers, workers,
entrepreneurs, or suppliers of land and capital, can bear the burden of
taxes, the incidence of particular taxes contributes little to a useful
definition of business taxes.
Our approach is to, define business taxes to include any levy upon a
firm's purchase of inputs, its transfer or ownership of assets, its
earnings, or its right to do business - in short, any levy which would,
in the absence of price adjustments, reduce the firm's bottom line.
Included in this definition are corporate profits taxes; real and
personal property taxes on business assets; franchise taxes and business
license fees; sales and use taxes and gross receipts taxes upon a
firm's purchase of equipment, services, and materials; and those
payroll taxes for which the firm is the statutory taxpayer.
By this definition, business taxes can be seen to produce a
prodigious flow of revenue to state and local governments. Table 1 shows
revenues for fiscal year 1992 by category of tax and in total for the
U.S. Business taxes accounted for 28.9 percent of all state-local tax
revenue, amounting to approximately $160 billion. Among the categories,
property taxes were the most significant single item, accounting for
42.8 percent of business taxes. Corporate income taxes, general sales
taxes, and payroll taxes (that is, unemployment insurance) each
accounted for a sizable share.
TABLE 1
State & local business taxes in the United States, 1992
Percent of Percent of total
Total business state-local taxes
Property $68,644 42.8 12.4
Sales $23,151 14.4 4.2
Unemployment
insurance $15,489 9.6 2.8
Corporate
income $21,937 13.7 3.9
Insurance $4,043 2.5 0.7
Utility $7,397 4.6 1.3
Motor fuel $9,165 5.7 1.6
Other(a) $10,687 6.7 1.9
Total business
taxes $160,514 100.0 28.9
Total taxes $555,479 - -
a Other taxes include occupational and business license taxes and
selective sales taxes.
Source: Staff calculations based on data reported by the U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Governments
Division and individual state fiscal agencies.
Together, these four categories accounted for more than 79 percent of
all business taxes.
Excluded from our definition, for the most part, are general and
selective sales taxes on items purchased by consumers; it is expected
that such taxes are shifted to the purchaser.(1) However, if the buyer
is a business enterprise, the tax payment will have been captured by our
definition above.
We also exclude personal income tax liabilities upon the profits of
unincorporated enterprises. While one might expect that profits taxes
would be treated independently of the legal form of organization, that
is not the case. Corporate income tax is an added layer of business tax;
dividends and capital gains of firms that pay corporate income tax are
also subject to personal income tax. Personal income tax applies to the
returns of all capital investments made by an individual, including
those arising from business ownership. Thus, if the individual
proprietor failed to engage in business within the state, the assets
would have been invested in other pursuits and subject to personal
income tax. The only persuasive case for including such taxes as
business taxes relates to those proprietors with out-of-state
residences. For such individuals, personal income taxes paid to the host
state are costs of doing business, which must be compared with costs
existing elsewhere. Fortunately, however, the vast majority of
unincorporated enterprises are owned by residents.(2)
Rationale for general business taxes
The widespread use of business taxes today does not in itself imply
that their level and structure are in accord with the principles of good
taxation.(3) In this section, we discuss the rationale for business
taxation. Our discussion will be confined to those taxes which are
imposed upon business enterprises in general, or on a large subset of
business firms, such as corporations. Taxes upon specific activities,
such as mineral extraction or chemical production, are not considered.
Presumably, the objective of such taxes is to correct for externalities,
such as environmental damage, or to capture benefits of natural
resources for the citizenry as a whole. The rationale for such taxes
does not apply to the argument for general business taxation. There may
be a good case for specific business taxes to control for environmental
damage or to capture some of the rents associated with a state's
unique resources, such as mineral wealth or favorable location. Such
taxes should be considered as supplements to the general business taxes
that we treat below.(4)
A number of possible motives for state-local taxation have been
suggested or can be inferred from current practice. These include
ability to pay, tax exporting, political expediency, and the benefits
principle. Each was analyzed by Oakland (1992). Only the benefits
principle was shown to survive scrutiny. Most other motives were seen to
be unattainable or based upon flawed economic reasoning. Only the three
most compelling types of rationale will be treated here. The first two
may account for the widespread use of business taxation. The third is
prescriptive - how business should be taxed.
Ease of raising revenue
Business taxation offers governments the opportunity to collect large
sums of revenue from relatively few taxpayers. In addition, because the
incidence of business taxes is often uncertain, it may encounter
relatively little political opposition. Many taxpayers may perceive that
such taxes are paid out of the "deep pockets" of rich
corporations and/or absentee rich shareholders. Others may not hold that
opinion, but would vigorously oppose attempts to raise their personal
taxes; in effect, business taxation may appear to public officials to be
the only course available.
While ease of collection is a valid criterion for tax policy,
particularly in less-developed economies, advances in tax administration
have enabled governments in advanced economies to collect personal taxes
at acceptable compliance costs.(5) Hence, collection costs cannot serve
as a principal criterion for the choice of tax structure. As far as
reducing citizen opposition to higher personal taxes is concerned, this
is more properly viewed as a serious disadvantage of business taxes.
Good tax policy should confront citizen-taxpayers with the true costs of
providing public services. If citizens consistently underestimate these
costs, they will support too large a range and level of public
services.(6) Viewed in this light, general business taxation has the
potential to do serious economic damage and should, therefore, be
discouraged.
To export the tax burden
A common rationale for business taxation is that it extends the reach
of the taxing jurisdiction to residents of other jurisdictions. We offer
as evidence the increasingly disproportionate weighting of sales in
allocation formulas to determine the state share of the profits of
multistate or multinational corporations when levying corporate income
tax.(7) We find further evidence in the rapid spread of legalized
gambling activity, apparently prompted by the desire to attract
out-of-state gamblers.(8)
Whether it be through taxing the profits of out-of-state
shareholders, taxing out-of-state consumers of goods produced locally,
or taxing the income of out-of-state landholders, business taxation may
be viewed as a means of transferring some of the costs of local
government to residents of other jurisdictions. While this may be
legitimate if the activity is limited to recovering costs of government
services extended to such "foreigners," there is no reason to
suppose that the practice would be so limited.(9) The prospect of a
"free lunch" has irresistible political appeal.
However, like most free lunches, the benefit is more illusion than
reality. The opportunities for successful tax exporting are quite
limited, and those that exist can be more successfully exploited by
finer instruments than general business taxes. For example, consider the
disproportionate use of sales factor by consuming states. The resultant
higher taxes increase the cost of selling in the taxing state; this
prompts a price increase so that the firm can receive the same net
revenue as from selling the item in some other market. In general, the
ability to export taxes is restricted to situations where the state has
some competitive advantage, owing to superior or unique natural
resources. Here the state can successfully capture the "rent"
of these resources through taxation. However, the appropriate tax is not
one on all businesses but a selective tax on the resource itself (for
example, a severance tax) or on a product that uses the resource (for
example, a tax on hotels). Hence, the case for general business taxation
cannot be based upon tax exportation.(10)
To recoup the costs of public services
Government provides the business community with a legal framework for
conducting its affairs, through its civil court system. It also offers
direct services to businesses and their employees, such as
transportation and public safety. These services make it possible for
the firm to produce more efficiently, allowing for lower prices and/or
higher wages and profits. Business taxation allows those who benefit
from these services, whether within or outside the jurisdiction, to
contribute to their costs. It also has the salutary effect of lowering
the taxes to citizen-taxpayers, enabling them to make a more accurate
assessment of the true costs of public services rendered directly to
them and to the business community.(11)
In such circumstances, business taxation promotes the benefits
approach to taxation. Without business taxation, this approach would be
difficult, if not impossible, to adopt. For example, if the
beneficiaries of business services are out-of-state individuals or
business entities, the home state simply has no means of taxing them
directly. On the other hand, if the beneficiaries are home-state
residents, the state would have to know how the services translated into
lower goods prices or higher wages and profits - an insurmountable task.
By taxing business directly for services received, such computations are
unnecessary, and ultimate beneficiaries would be taxed in proportion to
the costs incurred by the government sector.
The benefits principle has particular relevance for state and local
tax structures. Its rival criterion, the ability-to-pay principle, is
difficult to implement at these levels of government because of mobility
limitations. For household service provision and taxation, the
well-to-do tend to flee from jurisdictions with punitive tax burdens.
Mobility becomes a more compelling issue for businesses and may play an
important role in economic development. In contrast, business taxes
which conform to the benefits principle will be neutral with respect to
economic development. They place the jurisdiction at neither a
competitive advantage nor disadvantage per se.(12)
Can the benefits principle be implemented?
The merits of the benefits approach to business taxation have been
noted in the tax literature. However, many analysts have questioned
whether it can be implemented (ACIR 1978). These analysts argue that
because most government services are provided to businesses free of
charge, there is no objective measure of use by different business
entities; ergo, the benefits principle cannot be implemented.
The major premise that business utilization rates of government
services cannot be finely measured must go unchallenged. However, it
does not follow that relative business utilization rates cannot be
approximated. It surely is the case that within a broad industry
grouping, for example, the finance, insurance, and real estate industry
or manufacturing, larger firms utilize more services than smaller firms.
Even among disparate industry groups, it is also likely that government
services arising from employment are more heavily used by large
employers than small ones. So business size is a likely important
correlate of business service costs.
Using size as the sole measure of relative service benefits would
undoubtedly be subject to error. However, the degree of error in
relative treatment would be far less than that of a policy which charged
business nothing for government services. A tax based upon size would
eliminate the relative subsidy to large firms. Moreover, the failure to
charge business taxes would distort the price facing citizens for their
public consumption goods. To get this price right, business taxes in the
aggregate should equal the cost of providing business services.
Therefore, we believe there is merit in business benefits taxation on
the average. While there will remain errors and distortions in the
resulting pattern of business taxation, these errors will be smaller
than if no tax at all were imposed. In the absence of any other sound
basis for business taxation, it follows that the imposition of
size-related business taxes is the appropriate policy prescription.
The case for business taxation
On the plus side, business taxes can be used to promote the principle
of benefits taxation, which places the burden of taxation on those who
enjoy the ultimate benefits of certain public services, and at the same
time neither penalizes nor subsidizes economic development. On the
negative side, because it may not be perceived as a cost to the
citizen-taxpayer, business taxation may be pushed to excessive levels,
encouraging wasteful expansion of publicly provided consumption services
and leading to a diminution of job opportunities within a jurisdiction.
Given that political expediency may prevail over economic efficiency,
one might expect general business taxation to be carried to levels
beyond that suggested by the benefits approach. In the empirical work to
follow, this hypothesis will be examined in the Seventh District and in
other regions. In addition, we measure how state-local governments might
maintain the current level of business tax collections by levying taxes
as a uniform percentage of value added.
Business taxes and business expenditures
Taxes
Businesses are taxed by both local and state governments. While
authority for particular tax bases varies from state to state, generally
speaking local governments rely primarily on the property tax for
funding, while state governments generally collect sales taxes and
corporate income taxes, as well as the bulk of tax revenues on insurance
premiums, motor fuel sales, and the gross receipts of public utilities.
In the Seventh District states, corporate income taxes, unemployment
compensation, and insurance premiums are major business taxes which are
exclusively collected for state government operations; taxes on general
sales, public utility gross receipts, and motor fuel are levied at the
state level and, to a lesser degree, at the local level. The property
tax has been, in recent decades, almost exclusively a local tax source.
Drawing from data collected by the Bureau of the Census and from
state fiscal authorities, business tax revenues at both the state and
local levels can be distinguished from tax revenues from the household
sector. Corporate income tax revenues and business license taxes can be
wholly allocated to the business sector. In all other instances, the
business and household sectors are taxed under the same statutes. For
example, state sales taxes are imposed on the final retail purchases of
households and on certain intermediate purchases made by businesses.
Accordingly, revenues must be parceled between the household sector and
the business sector for major revenue sources, which include the general
sales tax, public utility gross receipts, insurance premiums, motor
fuel, and property tax.
According to studies of business taxes for states and regions of the
United States, business taxes declined from 42 percent of total
state-local tax collection in 1957 to 29 percent in 1992 (ACIR 1967,
1981; Tannenwald 1993) [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 1 OMITTED]. The
declining share of taxes attributed to business largely reflects the
rising dominance of personal income taxation by states over the past 25
years, rather than any marked slowing in the pace of business tax
collections. The rise in personal income taxation corresponds to the
growing share of public services provided to households by state-local
government - especially health and education.
Variation in the dependence on business taxes (as most commonly
defined) in 1992 among regions, as defined by the U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis, lies within a fairly narrow band. When we update this
methodology, originally developed by the U.S. Advisory Commission on
Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR), for the 1992 fiscal year, we find
that in the Great Lakes region (that is, Illinois, Indiana, Michigan,
Ohio, and Wisconsin), business taxes comprise 29.0 percent of
state-local taxes, compared with 30.7 percent in the U.S. The Southwest
leads with 41.3 percent, because of its heavy use of state severance
taxes on energy minerals. All other regions lie within 3 percentage
points of the national average [ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 2 OMITTED].(13)
In measuring business taxes for the states of the Seventh District,
we differ from much of the literature in both definition and
methodology. We exclude from our business tax definition selective
excise taxes, such as severance or lodging taxes, because they are often
targeted to a specific industry, indicating to us that the intent of the
tax is other than to cover the government expense of providing business
services. Perhaps these selective taxes are intended to compensate for
environmental damage or to expropriate the income on assets of
out-of-state owners.
Some taxes that we do include may appear to be selective, such as
insurance premiums, public utility gross receipts, and motor fuel tax.
We include these because they are applied to a wide spectrum of each
state's business sector and can, therefore, be considered a tax on
intermediate inputs to business production. For these revenue sources,
some care must be taken to apportion tax revenues accurately to the
business sector rather than to the government and household sectors. So
too, following De-Boer (1992) and Oakland (1992), data provided by state
fiscal agencies can often be grouped more finely than nationally
reported data for important hybrid taxes such as the property tax. Data
collected nationally by federal agencies must understandably compromise
some detail in exchange for a broad reporting of data.(14) (See appendix
for methodology.)
In reviewing our business tax measurements, property tax collections
dominate business tax collections in states of the District
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 3 OMITTED].(15) An estimated 47 percent of 1992
business tax collections were derived from this revenue source.
Corporate income (17.2 percent), unemployment compensation (11.4
percent), and the state sales tax portion collected on intermediate
purchases by the business sector (11.6 percent) also represent major
business taxes.
While we have chosen to define business taxes by their broad-based
application to the business sector, there is at least one noteworthy
imbalance in the business tax structure which suggests a lack of
evenness and neutrality across types of businesses. Specifically, a
heavy share of state-local business taxes in the Seventh District and in
the nation is initially imposed on business capital by way of property
tax and state corporate income tax. Such a system may skew any burden of
taxation toward goods-producing industries and away from the
service-producing industries which tend to employ more labor than
capital. Heavy state taxation of public utility inputs and sales
taxation of tangible inputs to production would only tend to aggravate
such an imbalance.
We and others have long noted other imbalances in the structure of
state-local business tax systems (ACIR 1978; Stocker 1972). The taxation
of profits (within corporate net income tax) would seem to penalize exactly those (profitable) firms that may have desirable prospects for
rapid growth and development.(16) Another imbalance may involve the
unemployment insurance system, which frequently taxes new firms (having
no employment history) at a very high rate. Many such firms tend to be
labor intensive, small, and innovative.
Expenditures
Expenditures by function for state-local governments are reported
annually by the Governments Division of the Bureau of the Census, U.S.
Department of Commerce. Total direct expenditures by function include
all payments to employees, suppliers, contractors, beneficiaries, and
all other final recipients of government payments. Intergovernmental
expenditures - payments and grants between state and local governments -
are excluded. Such expenditures become expenditures of those governments
where the funds come to rest. Since we are interested only in those
expenditures made by state-local government, federal grant monies by
function are netted out of these same functional expenditures.
Similarly, revenues derived from user charges and fees (such as college
tuition and roadway tolls) are netted out of appropriate expenditures
made by state-local government. The remainder represents those direct
expenditures by function that are funded by state-local own-source tax
revenues.
In allocating state-local spending to the Seventh District's
business sector, we classify expenditure programs into business,
household, prorated, and joint (shared). "Business" programs
are identified as dedicated solely to business, for example,
agricultural programs and water transportation terminals. These are
estimated at less than 1 percent of total state-local direct
expenditures in 1992 for the Seventh District states as a whole
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 4 OMITTED]. In contrast, "household"
expenditures comprise 62.5 percent overall, and are assumed to benefit
households only, for example, education, welfare, health, parks and
recreation, and housing.
"Prorated" programs include "overhead" functions,
such as general public buildings, legislative and financial
administration. These expenditures are allocated to the business sector
proportionately, based on the share of business expenditures to the
total of business plus household expenditures. For the Seventh District,
we find that prorated business expenditures account for 2.0 percent, in
comparison to the 12.8 percent share commanded by the household sector.
Finally, "joint" or shared expenditures are perhaps the
most difficult to allocate between the business and the household
sectors, because of the broad categories into which state-local
expenditure data are classified. We choose to liberally allocate shared
expenditures to the business sector. Accordingly, these programs, which
include police and fire, corrections, and transportation, are assumed to
be shared equally between the business and household sectors, so that
each sector commands 10.9 percent of state-local direct expenditure. All
told, public spending that can be classified as an intermediate input to
business production amounts to 13.8 percent of the total.
The large remaining share of state-local spending attributable to the
household sector may seem disproportionate to some observers. While
state-local government does provide essential business services, such as
transportation infrastructure and protection of business property, its
role has increasingly come to focus on welfare and education. From 1950
to 1992, the share of state-local government's direct general
expenditure on education and social welfare (including health and
hospitals) climbed from 44.4 percent to 58.9 percent. (Other services
such as police, fire, transportation, and general administration are
shared by the household sector.) While the business sector arguably benefits indirectly from such services, the direct benefits mainly
accrue to households. To the extent that these services raise labor
productivity, businesses will pay for higher productivity through wages
paid to the household sector. More to the point, our intention here is
to measure those expenditures and taxes directly accruing to business
and directly paid by business. To the extent that general business
expenditures are in alignment with general taxes paid by business, it
can be argued that the price signals between the voting public and its
government sector are not distorted, so that the correct degree of both
business services and household services will be chosen by public
decisionmakers.
Even with somewhat generous assumptions about the direct benefits of
shared expenditure programs, figure 5 suggests that in the Seventh
District states overall and in each state individually business taxes
exceed business expenditures by healthy proportions. In fiscal year
1992, business taxes in the District states overall exceeded
expenditures almost twofold. This indicates that, taking the benefits
principle approach, discussions of tax reform should be directed toward
bringing business taxation and business expenditures into closer
alignment.
Given the approximate nature of our calculations, especially in
classifying expenditures on public services to businesses versus
households, individual states have no reason to be alarmed about
competitive harm vis a vis neighboring district states due to excess
taxation. Expenditure classifications as reported by the Census Bureau are necessarily broad. Rather, the finding that general business tax
collections tend to exceed expenditures suggests the need for further
study, using individual state and local fiscal reporting systems that
more finely distinguish business from household service expenditures.
Based on the 1992 data, states in every Census region appear to have
taxed business in excess of direct business service expenditures (table
2). For fiscal 1992, state-local general business taxes in the U.S.
exceeded expenditures by 70 percent, on average. Nonetheless, across the
nine Census regions, the aggregate ratio of taxes to expenditures lies
with a fairly tight band, ranging from 1.45 in the South Atlantic region
to a high of 2.08 for the West South Central states. The Seventh
District average of 1.87 is close to the national average.
Tax structure: Which business taxes to employ?
It is important to think about the combined effects of all general
business taxes employed. It may well be that any particular tax is too
narrow in application but that, in combination with some other tax, it
provides a suitably broad basis of business tation. It is also clear
from the above discussion, that any acceptable system must meet the test
of comprehensiveness. The business tax system should reach all segments
of the business community. This would rule out taxes such as the state
corporation income tax, because there is no countervailing tax that
would apply exclusively or mainly to unincorporated private sector
enterprises or to nonprofit business enterprises, which do not earn
taxable income.
TABLE 2
State and local business taxes and expenditures, 1992
Business Ratio of taxes
Region expenditures Taxes to expenditures
(-millions of dollars-)
U.S. $94,136 $160,514 1.71
New England 5,076 $9,022 1.78
Mid-Atlantic 16,762 29,899 1.78
East North Central 15,077 27,781 1.84
West North Central 6,228 $9,843 1.58
South Atlantic 15,735 22,837 1.45
East South Central 4,290 6,768 1.58
West South Central 8,589 17,909 2.08
Mountain 5,471 8,169 1.49
Pacific 16,906 28,285 1.67
Seventh District 12,760 23,816 1.87
Source: Staff calculations based on data reported by the U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Governments Division
and individual state fiscal agencies.
Given that business benefits taxes should be size-related, what
measures of size can be used? Here are two possibilities: (1) amounts of
specific inputs; (2) amounts of output. It is possible to assess tax
liabilities in accordance with labor inputs, capital inputs, or material
inputs. The latter is unacceptable, given the widespread use of
materials produced outside the jurisdiction. While labor or capital
taxes would apply to all business entities, to focus on one or the other
would induce the firm to move away from the taxed input to the
non-taxed. It also would tend to favor or punish firms with differing
degrees of capital intensity. In general, there is no reason to believe
that capital-intensive firms consume more public services than
labor-intensive firms. For some services, say fire protection, capital
may be a preferred indicator. While for others, such as police
protection, employment measures may be preferable.
Since neither measure is a superior benefit indicator, avoidance of
substitution distortions and inequities is enhanced by a system which
utilizes both measures. This raises the question of weights. One
attractive weighting scheme would utilize input earnings; this is
tantamount to an origin-based value-added tax. The outcome could be
approximated by a combination of property taxes and payroll taxes. The
quality of the approximation would, of course, depend upon the relative
use of the two taxes.
The use of outputs as measures of business services leads to similar
conclusions. Basically, there are two possible measures: gross receipts
and value added. Gross receipts are an unacceptable measure for the same
reason that materials are an unacceptable indicator of input - they
include a major component of materials produced outside the district.
Gross receipts taxation would also tend to be pyramided to the extent
that materials flow from one producer to another within a jurisdiction.
Hence, we are left with value added as our output indicator of firm
size. Since value added also serves as an adequate measure of input use,
it would seem to be the best candidate for allocating the cost of
business services.
The administrative costs of levying business taxes according to value
added by origin are not formidable for most industries. Michigan has
been imposing a form of value-added tax since 1975.(17) Value added can
be derived for each firm by summing its payments for factors of
production, including payroll, interest paid, capital consumption,
rents, and profits. Alternatively, value added can be derived by
subtracting firm purchases of intermediate components and services from
gross receipts. Either way, the tax base would reflect the degree of
productive activities within the state, it would be largely neutral with
respect to capital/labor proportions, and it would be neutral with
respect to industry and legal form of business organization.
The viability of subnational value-added taxation is best illustrated
by the relative ease with which a rough approximation of the state tax
rates needed to raise revenue can be presented.(18) The Bureau of
Economic Analysis (BEA) publishes annual estimates (by industry) of
value added.(19) Taking our estimates of FY 1992 business tax
collections as a numerator, and BEA value added for the nongovernment
sector as a denominator, we produce the uniform ad valorem tax rates
necessary to raise equivalent business tax revenues in District states
(table 3). These figures show that a business tax rate running between
1.5 percent and 2.5 percent of value added would generate the revenue
equivalent of all state-local business taxes, based on data for 1992.
These rates are low compared with the statutory rates now on the
books for taxing corporate income, gross receipts, sales on intermediate
inputs, and the like. These low rates reflect the much broader basis of
taxation implied by using value added as a tax base. Using value added
would go a long away toward avoiding the skewness of the present system
of state-local business taxation which tends to assess many service
firms lightly (even though the service sector has become a much larger
share of nominal output).
We would expect these low rates to mitigate state-local concerns over
competitive fiscal disadvantages arising for certain capital-intensive
industrial sectors. Remaining rate differences would become smaller as
the tax burden is spread over more industries. The tax rates would need
to be cut in half if the state-local sector were to bring business
expenditures into line with public expenditures directly benefiting the
business sector. More importantly, remaining tax rate differences would
come to reflect differing public service needs among states as reflected
by industry mix. Remaining tax rate differences might also reflect
different regional approaches to development policy as some states and
local communities, perhaps acting in partnership with their business
communities, choose to offer differing levels, mix, and delivery of
public inputs to private production.
TABLE 3
Taxes as a percentage of nongovernment gross state product
Current Hypothetical
Region business taxes business taxes
U.S. 3.1% 1.8%
New England 2.9 1.6
Mid-Atlantic 3.4 1.9
East North Central 3.2 1.7
West North Central 2.8 1.8
South Atlantic 2.7 1.9
East South Central 2.5 1.6
West South Central 3.3 1.6
Mountain 3.1 2.1
Pacific 3.1 1.9
Seventh District 3.4 1.8
Illinois 3.6 1.8
Indiana 2.9 1.3
Iowa 3.5 2.2
Michigan 3.3 1.8
Wisconsin 3.2 2.3
Note: Gross state product (GSP) is net of government GSP.
Source: Staff calculations based on data provided by the U.S.
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Governments Division
and state fiscal agencies.
Conclusion
It should be acknowledged that our approach to business location
neutrality departs sharply from the rate-of-return approach in recent
studies of state business tax climates.(20) These studies examine how
the financial returns on investment are influenced by state and local
tax structures. As such, they inherently deny the value of government
services that may accrue to businesses at different sites. Also, they
focus almost exclusively on taxes on business capital and profits taxes,
overlooking important differentials in taxes paid by business firms on
their intermediate purchases and on their payroll.
By incorporating all taxes directly affecting business and taking
into account the costs of government services offered to the business
community, our approach offers a more comprehensive measure of the
business tax climate. It also enables us to detect important disparities
in the business tax base. While it is true that other properties of a
state's fiscal system, such as personal taxes and expenditure on
education, may influence business profitability, without a complex
general equilibrium model, such effects are difficult to quantify. The
absence of such a complete model also rules out the accurate assessment
of the marginal fiscal climate. Given these limitations, the best we can
do is compare the average fiscal climate of competing states.
Because of their relative simplicity and transparency, our measures
offer a useful alternative to complex cost-of-capital models for tax
analysts in state capitols, whose job it is to enlighten legislators on
the possible consequences of alternative business tax policies. With
regard to competitive tax climates in particular, firms may prefer
regions that offer a level and mix of business services for which the
business community pays a proportionate price and where household
expenditures are not subsidized by general business taxes. Taxing
business in line with business services can also help the voting public
choose the best levels and mix of publicly provided goods and services.
Voters and their elected representatives will be able to perceive the
accurate price signals for these goods. A dynamic dialogue between the
business community and government services providers can develop which
can, in turn, stimulate income creation or quality of life improvements
in those regions that choose to follow the benefits principle.
APPENDIX
Methodology for business taxes and expenditures
Taxes
Unemployment insurance tax - Taxes are imposed by both the federal
and state governments on the basis of payroll of those workers covered
by unemployment insurance. We report state collections only, as reported
by the Governments Division, Bureau of the Census, U.S Department of
Commerce.
General sales tax collected from business - The hybrid nature of the
sales tax as consumer-business tax presents formidable obstacles in
distinguishing the business sector's share of revenues from that of
consumers. State revenue departments typically report data by type of
store or vendor from which the sale takes place, with no information
about the buyer. The existence and variety of exemptions and partial
exemptions for business purchases further complicates the matter, as
does the varying exemption and coverage of certain consumer items, such
as food, clothing, and prescription drugs.(1)
One estimation method has been to survey vendors within a state as to
their thoughts on who purchases their taxable sales (Fryman 1969; ACIR
1981). Another method applies sales tax rates to government-reported
data of consumer expenditures; the residual represents an estimate of
business and tourist payments of the sales tax (Ring 1989; Blume 1983).
Other studies use interindustry relationships, perhaps as reported in
input-output models, to estimate the volume of business purchases
subject to states sales taxation (DeBoer 1992; KPMG Policy Economics
Group 1993), while other estimates are derived from reported collections
by type of vendor (DeBoer 1992; Oakland 1992).
Our estimates take a decidedly conservative approach, based on the
Fryman and ACIR estimates. We adjust and update those earlier estimates
by examining changes in tax-base coverage that have occurred over time.
For these changes, the business share of the sales tax intake is
adjusted by regression elasticities, which capture the sensitivity of
sales tax revenues to specific tax exemptions, such as that on
industrial machinery and equipment in Illinois during the 1980s.
Estimates of the business sector's share of state sales tax
revenue collections are applied to Census Bureau figures of general
sales tax collections at the state-local level for fiscal 1991-92 to
arrive at estimates of sales tax paid by businesses. By our estimates,
the sales tax comprised 14.4 percent of state-local business taxes in
the U.S. in fiscal year 1992. The corresponding share in the Seventh
District lies close to this estimate at 11.6 percent, with
Indiana's 20.2 percent share being the highest among District
states. Michigan's relatively low 7.8 percent share for 1992 has
increased since that year; Michigan raised its state sales tax from 4
percent to 6 percent in 1994.
Corporate income tax - These collection figures are reported by the
Census Bureau for fiscal 199192 and, within the Seventh District, all
collections derive from state taxes. Michigan imposes its single
business tax on the business activity or value added of businesses
operating within the state, rather than on corporate net income. Indiana
is one of only three states in the nation that taxes gross receipts of
corporations rather than net income. The Indiana tax is levied on the
greater of tax due from gross receipts or an alternative tax on
corporate net income. In some 22 states, taxes are also levied on
capital stock or net worth, and then sometimes under a corporate
franchise tax. Illinois imposes corporate levies on capital stock or net
worth, which may be termed corporate franchise taxes.
Property tax - Beginning with a 1963 study, the U.S. Advisory
Commission on Intergovernmental Relations began estimating property
taxes paid by commercial, industrial, and agricultural enterprises.
These estimates are based on tables of assessment and collection values
reported at five-year intervals by the Census of Governments. We depart
from that practice and instead use property tax collections as reported
by individual state fiscal agencies for business classes of property in
the Seventh District. For Michigan only, such collections by class must
be estimated.
Taxation of real property is predominantly imposed by local
governments rather than by state governments. Because tax rates are
usually applied in an even fashion to classes of property, and because
business property comprises a substantial portion of real estate, a
sizable share of the local property tax falls on business property.(2)
The gross assessed value of commercial, industrial, and acreage combine
to account for one-third of all value (commercial and industrial
combined account for one-fourth).(3)
The practice of taxing personal property (non-realty tangible
property) of business firms can also be a great concern for those firms
making heavy use of industrial machinery and equipment, and firms that
own significant stocks of tangible inventory. Over time, most states
have moved toward exempting tangible personal property of both firms and
households, as Illinois did across the board in 1979.(4) Most district
states liberally exempt business personal property or are moving in that
direction.
Business licenses and fees - We follow the ACIR practice of including
fees and taxes imposed on the right to do business, at the state or
local level. These data are collected and grouped by the Governments
Division of the Bureau of the Census.
Taxes on broad-based inputs to production - We exclude selective
taxes such as those levied on tobacco, alcohol, and amusement.
Presumably, these are intended to be shifted forward to consumers, or
their taxation is intended to discourage the activity rather than to act
as a broad-based payment for government services rendered. Likewise,
taxes on specific industries, such as motel/hotel or severance taxes,
are not broad-based business taxes but are intended to discourage or
compensate for damages imposed on the state or local community. In
contrast, we do include the following selective sales taxation of items
which are broadly purchased as intermediate inputs by the business
community:
Insurance - Most states tax the premiums on insurance sold in the
state. Since businesses broadly purchase insurance, we estimate the
business sector's share of such purchases in allocating total
insurance premium tax collections. The sector's share is calculated
for reported premiums sold by in-state companies to other businesses in
each of the respective states. Such estimates are provided courtesy of
the Regional Economics Applications Laboratory, which is a joint venture
between the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and the University of
Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. We average the latter estimates with
groupings of insurance premiums sold by type for each state, making
reasonable assumptions concerning likely types of insurance purchased by
the business sector versus the household sector. In contrast, ACIR
estimates typically include total insurance premiums, including those
sold to households.
Motor fuels taxes - Following DeBoer (1992), we estimate motor fuel
purchases by the business sector as opposed to households in allocating
revenues collected. These data are collected and grouped by the
Governments Division of the Bureau of the Census.
Public utility gross receipts taxes - The business portion of
revenues is allocated using data on investor-owned public utilities. The
Statistical Yearbook of the Electric Utility Industry reports gross
receipts derived by sector, household versus commercial and industrial
sector. These data are collected and grouped by the Governments Division
of the Bureau of the Census.
Expenditures
Expenditures by function are reported annually by the Governments
Division of the Bureau of the Census, U.S. Department of Commerce. Total
direct expenditures by function include all payments to employees,
suppliers, contractors, beneficiaries, and all other final recipients of
government payments. Intergovernmental expenditures payments and grants
to other governments between state and local - are excluded. Such
expenditures become expenditures of those governments where the funds
come to rest. Since we are interested only in those expenditures made by
state-local government, federal grant monies by function are netted out
of these same functional expenditures. Similarly, revenues derived from
user charges and fees (such as college tuition and roadway tolls) are
netted out of appropriate expenditures made by state-local government.
The remainder represents those direct expenditures by function that are
funded by state-local own-source tax revenues.
Two categories of expenditures must be allocated. "Shared"
expenditures are those for which little information on benefits to
business versus households are available, for example, police, fire,
transit, sewerage, sanitation, and parking. For these, a liberal 50
percent is allocated to the business sector.
Those expenditures representing general government overhead, such as
all financial administration services, all general public buildings, all
other miscellaneous government, interest on general debt, all
legislative, and other-unallocable, are assigned to the business sector
on a prorated basis. The proration reflects the share of business
expenditures, plus shared business expenditures to total direct
expenditures (net of prorated expenditures).
Other categories of spending are allocated directly to the business
or to the household sector.
1 For state-by-state coverage of consumer items in the sales tax
base, see ACIR (1994).
2 The practices under which tax rates and/or property assessment
ratios vary by type of property is called classification. Only a handful
of states authorize classification. Among the five district states,
classification is authorized only for Cook County, Illinois. There,
commercial and industrial property is assessed at a rate more than
double that for single-family residential properties.
Of course, there are many selective tax abatements that can be
applied (usually on commercial properties) at the discretion of local
governments (which may be acting on economic development concerns). So
too, state property tax systems often contain "circuit
breakers" and "exemptions," which exclude assessed value
or offer tax reductions to classes of residential taxpayers, such as the
elderly, the poor, or veterans. See ACIR, ibid.
3 See table 4, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census
(1987).
4 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census (1988) reports in
table 2 (p. 4) that personal property comprises 10.3 percent of locally
assessed property (not all of which is business property).
State-assessed property also includes personal property in some states,
especially that belonging to public utilities. However, in total,
state-assessed property (real and personal) comprised only 5 percent of
overall state-local gross assessed value in 1987.
NOTES
1 If the tax cannot be shifted forward, then this procedure is
flawed. For example, if a state levies a sales tax on petroleum products
refined in a particular state, and the price of refined products are
determined in world markets, the tax would have to be added to the
firm's cost of doing business within that state. Fortunately, such
situations are not commonly the case.
2 For small states, however, this point is more telling. Business
owners in the New York metropolitan statistical area may have the option
of relocating their businesses in several states, making the issue of
personal income taxes a relevant factor in the location decision.
However, this is mitigated by the common practice of crediting taxes
paid by host states.
3 These issues are dealt with at greater length in Oakland (1992).
4 Indeed, the motor vehicle fuels tax could be treated under either
rubric. It could be viewed as a user charge for the wear and tear and
highway congestion associated with business transportation. However,
fuel consumed is not a good measure of general environmental costs, such
as congestion and other nonpriced costs. Accordingly, we choose to treat
motor fuels tax revenues as part of general business taxation.
5 In many instances the administrative cost advantages are
exaggerated because they include costs shifted from government to the
taxpayer.
6 A substantial body of empirical studies provide evidence that
voters respond to the perceived cost (that is, "tax price") in
making public expenditure decisions (see Rubinfeld 1985).
7 Typically a three-factor formula is employed for such purposes:
payroll, capital investment, and sales. States with few production
facilities often put heavy, sometimes exclusive, weight on the sales
factor to capture a larger share of the profits of multistate
corporations. Multistate corporations in Iowa can use sales by
destination as the sole factor in apportioning taxable income.
8 Now, the main objective may be to stem the outflow of gambling
money to other jurisdictions or, in effect, to reduce tax importing.
9 One might think that if all states adopt the practice, there will
be no such "other" market; hence the firm will have to absorb
the tax. However, from the taxing state's vantage point, the
policies of other states are irrelevant. In the case under discussion,
local residents would enjoy lower prices than consumers elsewhere if the
tax were not imposed.
10 If the superior resource provided competitive advantages to all
production activities within the jurisdiction, a general tax might be in
order. This might be true for certain local governments - for example,
cities with outstanding harbors. However, even here the ubiquitousness
of the advantage is questionable.
11 While the business community can exert political influence, only
individuals can vote. Therefore. support for desirable business services
requires that voters not perceive a fiscal loss.
12 Of course, if other jurisdictions do not implement the benefit
principle, this neutrality would be vitiated.
13 For details see Greco, Oakland, and Testa (forthcoming).
14 Our finer measurements are carried out, not for each region, but
only for the states in the Seventh District.
15 The state of Michigan has since reduced its reliance on property
taxes and hiked its reliance on general sales taxes for funding
elementary and secondary education in the state. However, we do not
believe that overall reliance on taxes imposed on the business sector
has changed; property tax reductions, if any, have probably been offset
by increased business tax payments made under the state's
now-higher sales tax rate. See Courant, Gramlich, and Loeb (1995). A
reduction in property taxes in Wisconsin is also imminent, but the
sources of revenue compensation have not yet been decided.
16 States may be implicitly changing the nature of their corporate
taxes away from "profits or capital" taxes and toward a type
of sales or import tax. Specifically, states have been changing the
formulas by which they allocate the tax base of multistate companies. By
"double-weighting" the allocation factor which counts the
proportion of the firm's sales that are in-state, the corporate
income tax implicitly taxes the sales of out-of-state firms that are
being sold in the home state. That is, the tax liability correlates, not
with firm profits, but with sales of imports into the home state. To the
extent that the firm sells to a national market, such a tax would tend
to raise the price of the goods sold in the home state.
17 The single business tax (SBT) is levied on a tax base of value
added for firms in the state, calculated by adding factor payments
including interest paid, business income, depreciation, and labor
compensation. The tax base deviates from value added by origin in that
multistate firms are allowed to apportion business activity according to
a formula that gives 50 percent weight of the taxable base to the
firm's Michigan share of sales to total sales nationwide, and 25
percent weight each to the Michigan location of firm property and
payroll. Other reductions or credits involve small firms, low-profit
small firms, and all firms characterized by labor compensation bills
which exceed 63 percent of the tax base. See Citizen's Research
Council of Michigan (1995). The state previously imposed another form of
the tax, the business activities tax, from 1953 to 1967.
18 Value-added taxes are used by many countries, and a lively debate
is now under way in the U.S. over whether to impose the tax at the
national level. Such a tax would likely differ in intent and structure
from that envisioned herein for state governments. A national tax in the
U.S. is often envisioned as a "consumption-type" value-added
tax, a national sales tax which would be imposed on consumption and
might be designed to replace some existing revenue sources to encourage
national savings behavior. In contrast, the tax base for state
value-added taxation could include capital consumption, thereby relating
more closely to business benefits received as reflected in total
business activity in a state.
In many other countries, value-added taxes were enacted to eliminate
significant imbalances in "turnover" type taxes, which tended
to tax the gross receipts of firms at each stage of production.
19 These value-added data by industry sector are derived by both the
addition method and the substraction method. See U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (1985). Gross state product is
equivalent in concept to national gross domestic product (which included
capital consumption and indirect taxes in its definition).
20 Such studies often follow the "rate-of-return" approach
developed by James Papke. For example, see Tannenwald (1993).
REFERENCES
Aaron, Henry, "Differential price effects of a value-added
tax," National Tax Journal. Vol. 21, No. 2, June 1968, pp. 162-78.
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR),
"State-local taxation and industrial location," Washington,
DC: ACIR, 1967.
-----, "The Michigan single business tax: A different approach
to state business taxation," Washington, DC: ACIR, 1978.
-----, "State-local taxes with an initial impact on
business," Regional Growth: Interstate Tax Competition, Washington,
DC: ACIR, March 1981, pp. 61-77.
-----, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1988.
-----, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1993.
-----, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office. 1994.
Bartik, T., "The effects of property taxes and other local
public policies on the intrametropolitan pattern of business
location," in Industry Location and Public Policy, Henry Herzog and
Alan Schlottman (eds.), Knoxville. TN: Univ. of Tennessee Press, 1991,
pp. 57-80.
Blume, L., "The sales and use taxes," in Michigan's
Fiscal and Economic Structure, Harvey E. Brazer and Deborah S. Laren
(eds.), Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1983, pp. 595-619.
CCH, Incorporated, State Tax Handbook as of December 31, 1994,
Chicago: CCH, Incorporated, December 1994.
Citizens Research Council of Michigan, Outline of the Michigan Tax
System, 18th ed., report, No. 315, July 1995.
Congressional Budget Office, Federal Taxation of Tobacco, Alcoholic
Beverages and Motor Fuels, August 1990.
Courant, Paul N., Edward Gramlich, and Sussana Loeb, "A report
on school finance and educational reform in Michigan in 1995," in
Midwest Approaches to School Reform, T. Downes and W. Testa (eds.),
Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1995, pp. 5-33.
DeBoer, L., "Shares of major Indiana taxes paid by businesses
and individuals, 1991," Report prepared for the Commission on State
Tax and Financing Policy, 1992.
Due, John, and J. Mikesell, Sales Taxation: State and Local Structure
and Administration, 2nd ed., Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press,
1995, pp. 1-106.
Ebel, Robert D., The Michigan Business Activities Tax, Value-Added in
a Subnational Economy, East Lansing, MI: Michigan State University Business Studies, 1972.
Ebel, Robert D., and James A. Papke, "A closer look at the
value-added tax," Proceedings of the Sixtieth Annual Conference of
the National Tax Association-Tax Institute of America, Columbus, OH,
1967, pp. 155-170.
Edison Electric Institute, Statistical Yearbook of the Electric
Utility Industry 1992, Washington, DC, 1992.
Fryman, R., "Sales taxation of producer's goods in
Illinois," National Tax Journal, Vol. 12, No. 2, June 1969, pp.
273-281.
Greco, J., W. Oakland, and W. Testa, "State-local business
taxation in the Seventh District," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
regional working paper, forthcoming.
Insurance Information Institute, 1992 Property/Casualty Insurance
Facts, 1993, pp. 34-40.
KPMG Policy Economics Group, A Study of the Iowa State and Local Tax
Structure, Report submitted to the Tax Equity and Fairness Study
Committee - General Assembly of Iowa, January 1993.
Oakland, W. H., "How should business be taxed?" in State
Taxation of Business: Issues and Policy Options, Thomas Pogue (ed.),
National Tax Association, 1992.
Papke, James A., and Leslie E. Papke, "The competitiveness of
Indiana's business tax structure," in Indiana's Revenue
Structure, James Papke (ed.), Lafayette, IN: Purdue University, 1983.
Papke, L., "Interstate business tax differentials and new firm
location: Evidence from panel data," Journal of Public Economics,
Vol. 45, 1991, pp. 47-68.
Parker, Robert P., "Gross state product by industry,
1977-90," Survey of Current Business, Vol. 73, No. 5, May 1993, pp.
33-54.
Pogue, T., State Taxation of Business: Issues and Policy Options,
National Tax Association, 1992.
Ring, R., "The proportion of consumers' and producers'
goods in the general sales tax," National Tax Journal, Vol. 42, No.
2. 1989, pp. 167-179.
-----, "Consumers' share and producers' share of the
general sales tax," Presented to the National Tax Association
Annual Conference on Taxation, St. Paul, MN, mimeo, 1993. (Do not cite
without permission.)
Rubinfeld, D.L., "The economics of the local public
sector," in Handbook of Public Economics, J. Auerbock and M.
Feldstein (eds.), Vol. 2, New York: North-Holland, 1985.
Stocker, Frederick D, "State and local taxation of business: An
economist's viewpoint," Business Taxes in State and Local
Governments, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1972, pp. 37-46.
Studenski, Paul, "Toward a Theory of Business Taxation,"
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 68, October 1940, pp. 621-654.
Tannenwald, R., "Massachusetts tax competitiveness: Working
paper prepared for the Massachusetts Special Commission on Business Tax
Policy," Massachusetts Special Commission, April 1993.
Tax Foundation, Facts & Figures in Government Finance, 1992
Edition, Washington, DC, 1992.
Tax Institute, Inc., How Should Corporations be Taxed? Proceedings
from a symposium conducted by the Tax Institute, New York, NY, 1946.
-----, A Reappraisal of Business Taxation, Proceedings from a
symposium conducted by the Tax Institute, Princeton, NJ, 1961.
Tax Policy League, Inc., How Shall Business Be Taxed? Proceedings
from a symposium conducted by the Tax Policy League, 1936.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Assessed
Valuations for Local General Property Taxation, Vol. 2, No. 1 of 1987
Census of Governments, Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
1988.
-----, Assessed Valuations for Local General Property Taxation, Vol.
2, No. 1 of 1992 Census of Governments, Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office, 1994.
-----, Compendium of Government Finances: 1977, Vol. 4, No. 5 of
Census of Government, Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
1978.
-----, Government Finances: 1986-87, Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office, No. GF/92-5P, 1988.
-----, Government Finances: 1991-92 (Preliminary Report), Washington,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, No. GF/92-5P, 1994.
-----, State Government Finances: 1987, Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office, No. GF/89-3, 1988.
-----, State Government Finances: 1992, Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office, No. GF/92-3, 1993.
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis,
"Experimental estimates of gross state product by industry,"
staff report, No. SP85-042, May 1985.
Wheaton, W., "Interstate differences in the level of business
taxation," National Tax Journal, Vol. 36, No. 1, March 1983, pp.
83-94.
William H. Oakland is a professor of economics at Tulane University.
William A. Testa is assistant vice president at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago. The excellent research assistance of James Greco is
gratefully acknowledged. The authors also thank the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago library staff, past and present. Helpful comments were
contributed by Richard Mattoon, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and
Thomas Pogue, University of Iowa.