Midwest approaches to school reform.
Mattoon, Richard H. ; Testa, William A.
Paul Courant, Edward Gramlich, and Susanna Loeb (University of
Michigan)
School finance reform: The view from Wisconsin Andrew Reschovsky and
Michael Wiseman (University of Wisconsin) Respondants:
Illinois--Theresa McGuire (University of Illinois) Indiana--Larry
DaBoar (Purdue University) Iowa--Thomas Pogue (University of Iowa)
The South Carolina experience with incentives
On October 26 and 27, 1994, researchers and policymakers met at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago to exchange information and research
about current attempts to reform education finance and delivery. School
reforms and experiments are taking place across the U.S., and the
Midwest currently lays claim to diverse reform efforts. On the finance
side, the states of Michigan and Wisconsin have recently voted to
diminish the local property tax as the primary source of school funding
and to increase the state government's role in funding. As to
delivery of school services, the city of Milwaukee has the nation's
only system of cash vouchers from public coffers that can be used to pay
tuition at local private schools. Charter schools, a public-private
hybrid, have been authorized in both Michigan and Minnesota, while
programs allowing students to choose public schools across local school
district boundaries are now in effect in Minnesota, Iowa, and
metropolitan Milwaukee. Minneapolis schools have contracted with an
outside agency for provision of some school services. The Chicago public
school system has chosen a reform approach of site-based management with
local communities participating in school management and budgeting. The
Chicago Fed's conference addressed these diverse efforts and
evaluated each of them in an attempt to help the region's
policymakers as they choose among these and other models.
In an opening presentation, Michael H. Moskow, President of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, outlined a framework for the conference
proceedings. He noted that one of the key determinants of our
economy's rate of growth is the skills and training of our work
force--what economists call human capital. He stated that the Midwest
has been somewhat of an incubator for finance and delivery reform
experiments. For example, Michigan has made a major overhaul of its
system of school financing, as a result of which the state government
has become responsible for providing nearly 80 percent of educational
funding. However, fiscal strains can be seen in other school districts
throughout the Midwest, both urban and rural. The state of Illinois
continues to wrestle with school funding problems; the Chicago public
schools in particular face an impending $300 million deficit in school
year 1995-96.
Moskow then turned to the many experiments with choice among public
and private schools. Such experiments introduce competition into the
provision of schools services in the expectation that this will improve
the quality and reduce the cost of education. However, Moskow cautioned
that it is difficult to evaluate education vouchers and similar
experiments in school choice. In order to measure whether such
experiments improve learning and reduce costs, one must simulate a
full-scale program for an extended period of time. The long-term
benefits of choice such as opening of new private schools, improvement
of existing public schools because of competition, and increased
research and development spending cannot reasonably be expected to occur
unless the program covers a sufficient number of students for a
guaranteed, extended period of time.
In closing, Moskow posed some questions that he hoped the conference
would address:
1. Insofar as education is a public good that benefits our society
and economy, do school financing systems in the Midwest ensure a
sufficient and stable level of funding for every child? What criteria
should be used to determine what this level is?
2. State and local electorates hold the purse strings to school
finance, and increasingly, voters are refusing to fund schools without
further evidence that their money is being well spent. Can experiments
with incentives and accountability improve public school performance?
And can such experiments satisfy voter concerns that public schools have
become divorced from incentives to excel? If so, can programs such as
these be transferred to Midwest school systems, particularly urban
schools where lagging performance is most evident?
3. One longstanding alternative to tightening the incentive
structures in existing schools has been to impose the discipline of the
marketplace by allowing parental choice among schools. Most of these
experiments have allowed choice among public schools only, including
magnet schools, open enrollment, and most recently the creation of the
public-private hybrid called charter schools. Can a half-step towards
choice (that is, limiting choice to public institutions) achieve the
market discipline and competition that is predicted to bring meaningful
reform and innovation to public schools that are not working well? Or
can we reach that outcome only with competition from the private sector
as well? Can the private sector do a better job than our public schools,
and if so, can it do that for sufficient numbers of students?
4. The reform currently underway in Chicago schools reflects the
belief that it is not the publicness of our schools, but rather their
organization that needs to be improved. The Chicago approach is to
empower local schools and communities with the authority to make
decisions regarding educational services. Can site-based management
work? More important, what must all groups do to make it work in
Chicago?
5. Finally, one question that has dominated educational reform
movements in America from the beginning is, who should shape our
schools--local government, state government, federal government,
parents, professional educators, or voters in general?
Issues and experience in school finance reform
The conference's first session addressed the issue of school
finance reform, with particular attention to recent changes enacted in
Michigan and Wisconsin. By nature, questions of finance relate not only
to school services themselves, but also to the tax structure that
affects each taxpayer and every economic sector. Michigan has
dramatically restructured its school finance mechanism by sharply
increasing the state government's responsibility for education.
Wisconsin is also considering such a shift. An important question
surrounding such measures is whether greater state participation in
school funding will help or hinder the movement to improve the quality
of education that public schools offer.
Michigan's recent reform of school finance
Perhaps no place in the nation has received more attention for a
recent experiment in education reform than the state of Michigan. In
1993, the legislature, with bipartisan support, decided to eliminate the
use of the local property tax to fund local education. When it did this,
the state enacted a $6 billion tax cut without identifying how the lost
revenue would be replaced. The following year, voters approved a package
of tax changes to fund the schools. But the story of Michigan's
sweeping education reform goes beyond deciding which tax source should
fund local schools. In their presentation, Paul Courant, Edward
Gramlich, and Susanna Loeb discussed the implications of Michigan's
new school financing structure.
The elements of Michigan's new funding structure are well known.
Through a referendum in the spring of 1994, voters agreed to increase
the state sales tax, establish a state-wide property tax (with
differential rates for homeowners and businesses), and increase the tax
rates for two other small revenue sources to help replace the lost
property tax revenue. The motivation for largely abandoning the local
property tax as a funding mechanism had less to do with education reform
and more to do with the fact that Michigan's property tax rates
were already above the national average and had been steadily climbing.
Property taxes had risen from 4.3 percent of personal income in 1978 to
5 percent by 1991. However, because this new group of taxes replaced the
local property tax, the character of Michigan's school funding has
been radically changed. To begin with, state tax revenues now account
for nearly 80 percent of local school financing. Under the old system,
the state's share had been 31 percent. The other elements of the
Michigan plan focused on school improvement and received less attention.
These included adding requirements to the academic core curriculum,
establishing pupil performance standards, and authorizing the creation
of charter schools.
One of the most significant changes that emerged from this reform
effort was a change in the state mechanism for providing aid to local
school districts. Before, the state had used a modified power
equalization plan as a way to reduce spending differentials between rich
and poor districts. Now, a modified foundation program would be used. As
the authors pointed out, the power equalizing program aimed to lower the
price of purchasing education in property-poor districts by guaranteeing
these districts a minimum tax base per student. In practice, however,
the program did not eliminate significant spending disparities among
districts. Wealthy districts often had a tax base above the state's
guaranteed level; moreover, they were often more willing to spend more
on education. Since those districts were "out of formula,"
they received no state aid from the power equalizing formula but were
still able to raise more revenue per mill of tax rate than districts
receiving state aid. The lack of success of programs such as these, even
among districts "in formula," has been explained by the fact
that the wealth elasticity of demand for education exceeds the price
elasticity for education in absolute value.
The new foundation grant system will eventually reduce the disparity in spending levels between school districts. In the 1994-95 school year,
all districts have been raised to a basic foundation level that will
eventually reach $5,000 per pupil. Future increases will be determined
by what the authors termed the School Aid Fund Index (SAFI). This switch
to a foundation grant system will have differing effects depending on
the previous expenditure habits of individual districts. The 365
districts that spent less than $4,772 per pupil in 1993-94 will be
brought up to the foundation level. The 122 districts currently spending
between $4,772 and $6,500 per pupil will be allowed to continue their
current spending levels but will receive only small real spending
increases per pupil. The 37 wealthiest districts, which spent more than
$6,500 per student in 1993-94, will receive a grant of $6,500 in 1994-95
and will be allowed to levy an additional local tax on homestead
property to restore their spending to $160 million more than 1993-94
levels.
The authors suggested that the effect of this new formula will be to
increase education spending dramatically in the lowest-spending
districts, while largely freezing the nominal dollar differences in
spending in middle-range districts (those currently spending between
$5,000 and $6,500 per pupil). The authors also predicted that real
spending on education in the wealthiest districts would decline over
time. Greater equalization in expenditures will occur as spending levels
at the bottom rise while those at the top decline.
One problem in this equalization plan is that it does not compensate
for price differences in providing education across districts. It tends
to cost more to operate a school in an urban area than in suburban and
rural areas. As a result, some districts will be receiving significantly
more resources than other districts even if all get the same numbers of
dollars per pupil. But measuring the differences in the cost of
providing education is not an easy matter. In an attempt to do so, the
authors presented a series of models that are essentially reduced form regressions of per-pupil spending using some demand variables and some
cost variables. These models yielded a truer picture of the real
disparities in spending among districts.
The authors next examined how the new funding system will play itself
out. Assuming that the law remains in effect as currently written, they
estimated that the distribution of spending between districts would be
significantly equalized by 1999-2000. The current coefficient of
variation of spending is .21; by 2000 it will have dropped to .12. Real
per-pupil spending in the poorest districts will increase by $1,850,
while the highest spending districts will be limited to increases of
around $250 per pupil.
In addition, the authors believe that wealthy districts will be
reluctant to maintain or increase spending once voters realize the tax
increase this will require. Since only homestead property can be taxed
and not all taxable property in the community, the price of these local
option taxes will be very high, and voters may ultimately reject them.
If this happens, the authors estimate that maximum spending per pupil in
real terms will be $8,836 by 2000. By comparison, if wealthy districts
continued to levy these optional local taxes, the maximum per-pupil
expenditure would be $10,376.
A final question is what will happen if the state finds it cannot
raise enough revenue and must significantly change the foundation
formula. The current law permits several legislative options to address
a state funding shortfall, including allowing the basic grant to grow
more slowly than the formula, and permitting a rise in the millage for
the state property tax. It is hard to predict how such adjustments might
be made. In the short run, any pressures in this direction will be small
since per-pupil expenditure levels will be roughly what districts are
accustomed to. But this may not be so for long. The foundation program
does change the tax price of paying for education for the local
districts while not allowing much flexibility to increase or decrease
funding levels. As local districts experience changes in their economic
fortunes, those with growing wealth may want to spend more on education,
but the current program would not allow that. In such a case, pressure
may grow to revise the formula, allowing districts more flexibility to
increase or decrease spending at the margin. This could unravel the
foundation program.
Another aspect of the Michigan reform that bears watching is the
development of charter schools. These are schools set up by private
groups with a maximum grant of $5,500 per pupil in state money, an
amount that the schools may supplement with their own resources. Charter
schools must meet all state curriculum requirements and may not be
religiously affiliated. The existence of charter schools may change the
nature of the educational debate in Michigan. For years, that debate
focused on finance reform. With the development of charter schools and a
new funding structure, attention may shift to the content and
effectiveness of schooling.
Finally, there is the question of what effect school reform will have
on economic development in the state. From a narrow perspective, the
most immediate effect is to reduce significantly the intrastate variation in taxes that businesses must pay. This should make intrastate
location decisions for businesses easier, although as the authors
explained, it will not necessarily make the state's business
property taxes significantly less than they were before. Under the
previous system, roughly 50 percent of eligible capital investments
received a 50 percent property tax abatement lasting for twelve years.
If under the old system the school district levied the state average 32
mill-age tax rate, the district might offer a 50 percent abatement in
the rate to the new capital. This would bring the millage rate to 16.
Under the new system, the uniform local tax rate for schools is reduced
to 18 mills, which can be abated to 9. However, the state also levies a
statewide tax of 6 mills that is unlikely to be abated. The total tax
rate with the 50 percent abatement under the new system is 15 mills
versus 16 mills under the old system. However, this will significantly
limit the range of property taxes that businesses face at the intrastate
level, Communities abating taxes will be at a low of 15 mills for
business property, and those choosing not to abate will be at a maximum
of 24 mills.
In general, Michigan's reform will reduce variance in education
spending. Moreover, by substituting more slowly growing state tax
sources for the property tax, the reform will likely slow the rate of
growth on education spending in the state. While the
district-to-district variation in per-pupil expenditures will narrow
over time, the new system does initially preserve the current
differences in funding levels. This may allow the plan to be more
politically popular than if it had radically revised expenditure levels.
The challenge is to see how this new structure continues to influence
education reform at the classroom level.
School finance reform: The view from Wisconsin
The system of school finance in Wisconsin is undergoing major
changes. Last year the legislature restricted the annual growth of
school district revenues to the rate of inflation. In spring 1994,
legislation was passed committing the state to fund two-thirds of total
school spending beginning with the 1996-97 school year. This commitment
will require the state to distribute an additional $1 billion in state
funds to local school districts. In Wisconsin, educational funding
issues have been shaped somewhat more than in other states around issues
of equity. In part, this is because the state's constitution
requires that the state's schools "be as nearly uniform as
practicable." For decades, Wisconsin's policymakers have
struggled to develop a school finance system that achieves an acceptable
level of uniformity. Andrew Reschovsky and Michael Wiseman distinguished
several alternative definitions of school finance equity. They evaluated
the effectiveness of Wisconsin's current system of school finance
in achieving these equity goals and assessed the likelihood that the
newly enacted reforms will improve the fairness and overall quality of
education in the state's public schools.
The predominant type of state aid system that Wisconsin now uses is
generally known as district power equalizing (DPE). Approximately 80
percent of state school aid in Wisconsin is provided under this program.
DPE systems distribute state grant monies in such a way that, in making
decisions over the local school district property tax rate, each
district raises total funds as if it were drawing from the same or
"guaranteed" property tax base. The guaranteed tax base can be
set equal to the tax base per pupil of the wealthiest school district in
the state or, as in Wisconsin, it can be set at a lower level. For those
school districts at or below the guaranteed tax base per pupil, DPE
systems equalize the total of state and local funds raised per pupil for
any two districts that impose the same tax rate on themselves. (In
Wisconsin, school districts with property tax wealth above the guarantee
also receive a small amount of "minimum" aid.)
The authors maintained that, in guaranteeing equal school funding for
any given local property tax rate, DPE systems are designed to fulfill a
rather narrow notion of equity which they call "taxpayer
equity." Standards of equity oriented toward equal funding per
pupil, equal educational outcomes, or an assured minimum level of
education for all pupils are not addressed by DPE. For several reasons,
and despite generously funded DPE systems, some property-poor districts
do not choose to impose property tax rates on themselves as high as
their property-rich counterparts, implying lower spending per pupil in
some low-wealth districts. Since states do not typically require local
school districts to enact any minimum local tax rate, the authors
believe that not every district will necessarily reach the goal of
adequate school funding per pupil. Finally, a DPE funding mechanism does
not account for the fact that some students, such as those from
disadvantaged households, may be more costly to educate. In sum, by
design, DPE formulas cannot satisfy equity notions of equal and/or
adequate provision of education services across all school districts.
Wisconsin's version of DPE contains several particular features
which further limit the extent to which school districts' per-pupil
spending levels are equalized. To some extent, these disparities arise
because a small number of districts contain property wealth in excess of
the state guaranteed base; in addition, 20 percent of Wisconsin grant
monies for local education are distributed outside of the DPE system.
Despite its limitations, Reschovsky and Wiseman showed that
Wisconsin's DPE has been partly successful in weakening the link
between school district property wealth and education funding. This has
been accomplished because the state has funded the DPE program
generously enough to set the guaranteed tax base per pupil at a high
level. For the 1992-93 school year, 90 percent of all pupils lived in
districts where the actual property tax base was below the DPE
guaranteed tax base. The authors also noted that, as expected with a
well-funded DPE system, low-spending districts have lower property tax
rates than high-spending districts.
Despite evidence that Wisconsin has achieved a considerable amount of
fiscal equalization, that it has moved toward greater equity, and that
the state's equity compares favorably with that of other states,
there has been widespread discontent with Wisconsin's school
finance system in recent years. The major issue has been high and rising
reliance on the property tax to finance government in Wisconsin, with
local schools accounting for the largest draw on the property tax base.
As recently as FY91, property taxes as a share of personal income were
31 percent above the national average, making Wisconsin 11th among all
the states.
In an attempt to stem the rate of increase in property tax levies,
the legislature has enacted a cap on year-to-year school district
revenue growth, as defined by the sum of equalization aid and property
taxes. The caps are slightly less restrictive for lower-spending
districts and thus should serve to enhance equalization objectives to a
modest degree.(1) A second leg of revenue reform was added in spring
1994, when the legislature committed the state to fund two-thirds of
total public spending on K-12 education (up from the present 48 percent)
starting in 1996-97. To meet this commitment, the state must come up
with $1 billion in additional state school aid. (A bipartisan commission
will determine the source of funds and the method of distribution).
Together, the revenue caps and the two-thirds state revenue commitment
will work to lower overall local property tax rates by 22 percent by the
end of the century.
To date, discussion has centered on how these new monies will be
raised and not on how school funds will be distributed. The state's
Department of Public Instruction and some school districts have been
pushing simply to allocate additional state monies through the existing
DPE equalization aid formula. In opposition, the authors argued that the
state's current system of school finance and the contemplated
changes in funding fail to provide adequate resources to districts that
must spend more money if they are to educate children of disadvantaged
families or with special needs. If the additional state monies which are
now promised to bring up the overall state share of funding are
distributed through the existing equalization aid formula rather than
through a modified formula reflecting varying costs of educating
children across school districts, then the recent revenue reforms may
provide property tax relief, but they will do little to improve equity
in educational provision.
Drawing on their analysis of Wisconsin's DPE system and
experience drawn from other states, Reschovsky and Wiseman advanced five
characteristics of an equitable system of school finance as a guide for
policymakers in Wisconsin:
1. A minimum expenditure guarantee should be established.
Wisconsin's current system does not guarantee a minimum acceptable
level of educational provision. The authors believe that a foundation
level of spending should be mandated and funded to the extent necessary
by the state. This foundation level should be adjusted over time for
inflation and adjusted across districts to reflect differing costs of
provision.
2. School aid formulas should take explicit account of cost
differences among school districts.
3. The distribution of aid should be tied to educational performance
standards. Insofar as educational quality derives from more than just
dollars spent, taxpayers are demanding evidence of rising educational
quality. More efforts are needed to ensure that school districts have
incentives to spend educational dollars effectively.
4. State funding for public schools should be increased in order to
provide taxpayers with property tax relief.
5. Consistent with other goals, school districts should retain
maximum possible local control over educational and budgetary decisions.
Evidence from other states, notably California, suggest that if schools
do not provide the education that parents want for their children,
public commitment to education will deteriorate rapidly. Flight to
private schools has been to the outcome under such conditions.
The authors concluded that the recent revenue reforms in Wisconsin do
not fully or wholly address the aforementioned concerns. So-called
foundation-type grant schemes are used in a number of other states. Such
plans require a minimum tax rate, while at the same time, the state
government assures a level of state aid at the foundation tax rate to
provide a minimum adequate level of school funding.(2) Critics of
foundation-type systems allege that significant spending disparities can
arise under foundation plans because wealthy communities can raise
spending above the foundation level using lower tax rates than would be
required in poorer districts. However, the authors believe that this may
be an acceptable trade-off for Wisconsin. In contrast to a
well-structured and well-funded foundation system, the current DPE
system in Wisconsin fails to ensure an adequate education for all
students; neither does it eliminate spending disparities.
The South Carolina experience with incentives
The second session explored one state's experience with an
incentive program designed to reward schools that demonstrate
improvements in student test scores. Incentives are often viewed as a
mechanism for encouraging performance gains without making sweeping
system-wide changes in the status quo. South Carolina has used a system
of centrally administered incentives for ten years, which makes this
almost the longest-standing incentive program in the country. How has
this program performed? Is it a model that other states would do well to
emulate?
As Garrett K. Mandeville described it, the program began in the
1985-86 school year with the straightforward objective of rewarding
schools and school districts that demonstrated measurable gains in
student achievement levels compared with prior years. This apparently
simple objective required the extremely complex tasks of choosing
appropriate measures of achievement, establishing an incentive system,
and designing a methodology for judging which schools were producing
achievement gains. Mandeville helped design much of this methodology.
The state decided to restrict the achievement criteria to
improvements in standardized reading and math tests. Clearly, skills in
these subjects are critical to student success, and both areas were seen
as needing improvement. In addition, math and reading were selected
because standardized tests in those areas were already being given at
more than one grade level. Since student performance within the same
school varied across different grade levels, it was decided to evaluate
improvement in test scores at multiple grade levels. In regard to
assessing achievement gains, two options seemed to be available. Gains
could be assessed at the individual student level or aggregated for all
students within the school. Data availability and time constraints led
policymakers to choose school-level data as the appropriate measure for
the first year.
By the end of the first program year, the state Department of
Education had some concerns about the initial method and decided to
judge performance gains on the basis of differences between actual and
predicted performance in longitudinally matched student data. This
approach, while requiring significant data preparation and analysis, was
seen as yielding a more accurate picture of the performance of students
and schools. This process was enhanced with additional information that
made it possible to categorize schools according to their students'
socioeconomic status. Schools whose students had higher socioeconomic
status were required to show larger gains in student improvement than
were low-resource schools in order to qualify for incentive grants.
Eventually, a similar approach was developed that allowed for different
standards to be applied to elementary, middle, and high schools. This
alternate approach was introduced because initial experience showed that
elementary schools could more easily demonstrate student achievement
gains than schools with older students.
In addition to the methodological hurdles South Carolina faced in
setting up its incentive program, Mandeville also discussed the
characteristics of successful school incentive programs. They must be
fair; understandable by school administrators, faculty, and the public;
technically defensible; equitable in outcome; and productive of useful
diagnostic feedback. Unless school personnel feel the performance
criteria are within their control, and that the information that
extensive testing yields is useful in improving their performance, the
incentives are not likely to serve as much of a motivator. There is also
the question of how big an award must be in order to work as a
motivating influence. With a School Incentive Reward budget of $5
million, the typical award works out to about $25 per student. The state
tries to augment this by providing nonmonetary recognition to add
prestige value to incentive grants. In the ten years of the awards
history only 18 percent of the schools in the states have failed to win
an incentive grant; the percentage of repeat winners from one year to
the next is only about 10 to 12 percent. Mandeville suggested that this
wide distribution in incentive grant winners is beneficial since it
encourages all schools to continue to strive to win an award.
Mandeville reviewed several other approaches that have been used to
identify school factors that promote achievement. Primary among these is
the "effective schools" research movement. These studies were
in part a response to the controversial Coleman report (1966) that
suggested that schools had little influence on student achievement once
a student's home background was taken into account. Dissatisfied
with this conclusion, the effective schools researchers paired schools
with students of similar socioeconomic background but different levels
of aggregate student achievement, then searched for factors that seemed
to account for the differences. These efforts have given way to more
sophisticated modeling approaches as researchers have begun to question
what the appropriate level of analysis is for judging where
differentials in student performance are produced. The analysis has
moved from looking at factors specific to individual schools to
two-level modeling where influences are examined with a recognition that
students may share a school but not share the same classes. Still other
researchers have argued for three-level analysis on the grounds that the
school is not the basic unit of instruction, but rather the classrooms
and teachers that are directly responsible for learning. Such a
three-level analysis might produce a more accurate picture of the roots
of variation in student performance but obviously requires significantly
more data.
Mandeville concluded that while the more sophisticated approaches to
analyzing student achievement will lead to a better understanding of the
factors that influence performance, in the current environment such an
approach could not have been used to award incentive grants in South
Carolina. While it is hard to demonstrate that the grants have had a
systematic effect on student and school performance, they do provide a
starting point for examining the necessary components of a statewide
incentive program.
Experiments and experience with choice
One highly visible avenue of school reform has been to allow the
primary customers of education to choose their local schools. Public
school choice, it has been argued, can promote such diverse goals as
school desegregation, increased school productivity, and improved
educational outcomes. Such improvements are expected because, first, in
exercising the option to purchase or enroll in a school program, parents
and students may be able to customize school services to fit their own
needs and preferences. Second, proponents of choice suggest that
competition among schools will produce greater accountability. Finally,
magnet school programs and urban-suburban transfer programs have been
designed to achieve greater racial balance within the nation's
metropolitan areas. Magnet schools are now the most common form of
school choice, but there are also other options, including charter
schools, interdistrict transfer plans, controlled choice programs, and
voucher plans that allow parents to choose between public and private
schools. How do parents and students choose the "right"
school? Do choice programs improve public education?
Charter public schools: A brief history and preliminary lessons
Among the various models for expanding school choice, the use of
charter public schools appears to be gaining acceptance. Colorado,
California, Michigan, Minnesota, and Massachusetts either have
established or plan to establish such schools in the next year. Joseph
Nathan expressed his belief that school choice is much like electricity.
Handled carefully, it has many benefits: handled badly, it can cause
many problems. The charter school is designed to increase educational
opportunity for students expand options for educators, and encourage
public school systems to be more responsive.
In his presentation, Nathan discussed the elements needed to create
charter schools as well as the experience of the state of Minnesota,
where the state legislature authorized 35 charter schools. The movement
started in California in 1985, when public school educators suggested
that the state authorize educators to create new public schools.
Legislators turned them down. The first charter school law was adopted
in Minnesota in 1991, when the legislature passed legislation to set up
eight charter schools. Charter schools in Minnesota now include a school
for the deaf, a variety of inner-city schools designed to work with
low-income students, several rural schools that stress greater parental
involvement and the more extensive use of technology in the classroom,
and a Montessori school.
One encouraging response to charter schools is that in a number of
places, the idea has encouraged districts to establish other new
programs. For example, after several groups in Minnesota proposed
charter schools. the school board receiving the proposal agreed to
establish a new school similar to the charter school. In Massachusetts,
Boston public schools and the local school board agreed to establish at
least six new pilot schools themselves, with many similarities to
charier schools. Philadelphia and New York City school districts have
newly developed policies in place encouraging educators and community
members to start new kinds of schools.
The concept behind a charter public school is simple. It involved a
shift from accountability for process to accountability for results. The
idea is that a group of individuals can come together and establish a
school with a special curriculum without being subject to the usual
administrative constraints that ordinary public schools face, being
accountable instead for increased student achievement. If achievement
does not improve over the period of the contract, the contract can be
terminated. Enrollment is voluntary. Students will still receive the
same basic education as students attending traditional schools, but
through its charter, the school can define a special purpose for itself.
Many charter schools serve special needs students or use innovative
teaching methods.
Nathan reported that there are common elements for establishing a
charter public school. Since charter schools are allowed to bypass many
of the rules and constraints faced by traditional schools, they are held
accountable for improved student performance and enter into a
performance contract with the state. The state may specify the expected
student outcomes, but how the school achieves those outcomes is left up
to those who operate the school. Charter schools should be nonsectarian
and open to all kinds of students. They should not be allowed to charge
tuition.
When states decide to allow charter schools, Nathan believes it is
important that a broad range of groups be allowed to propose differing
types of schools so that public school boards no longer have the only
say in what kind of public education is available. Such groups may
include parents, teachers, community members, or a combination of all
three. Once the organizers have a model for their school, they can
approach a public body for sponsorship, such as the local school board,
a college or university, or some nonprofit non-sectarian group. Once the
state approves the charter, the school must admit any student who wishes
to attend without administering admissions tests or charging tuition.
The state provides the school's funding. Each student may be funded
at either the state-wide average per-pupil allocation or the average
funding level that the student would have received in his or her former
school district. Finally, the participation of students, faculty, and
administration in a charter school must be voluntary. While these
schools may provide an alternative for many students, many other
students, teachers, and parents will prefer traditional schools.
Nathan suggested that during the planning stage, it is important that
a charter school establish its core beliefs about learning along with a
clear understanding of the skills and knowledge that students will be
expected to learn by the time they graduate. These are key elements in
enabling a system of accountability. It is also important to recruit
broad community support for the school. This means involving not only
parents, teachers, and students, but also community members and
businesspeople. It is also important to include experienced educators in
the planning process so that process is not dominated by well-meaning
but inexperienced school reformers.
Two final elements that Nathan discussed were recruiting students and
faculty for the new school. Recruiting students requires a well-defined
public information campaign. The school's objectives and philosophy
must be well articulated and the charter school should be presented as
an option to traditional education. Expected student outcomes should be
highlighted so that potential clients can decide whether the charter
school provides a suitable alternative to their current school. In
selecting a faculty, it is helpful to include some of the people who
were involved in the planning process so that at least some of the
faculty will feel a sense of ownership from the start. A motivated
faculty comprised of teachers with specific ideas about working with
students is a key to the school's success. The faculty must
understand the goals of the school and have the teaching skills to bring
them into the classroom.
Charter public schools are still in their infancy, and given their
variety and differing objectives, it is likely that some will prove
successful while others will fail. However, they provide an opportunity
for those who are dissatisfied with traditional public schools to
organize their own alternative, and in doing so, to increase the options
available for educating children. They also appear to be stimulating
some districts to improve their existing schools and open new ones.
Public school choice in Minneapolis
Public school choice programs often are designed to do more than just
improve student achievement. In Minneapolis, desegregation has also been
part of the city's evolving choice program since the early 1970s.
Robert Meyer and Steven Glazerman explored a choice program that
attempts to address multiple goals of reform while satisfying the
preferences of students for a particular school. While the Minneapolis
program requires students and their parents to choose among differing
schools, the authors refer to this as a controlled choice system since
racial desegregation targets must also be met when students are assigned
to schools.
Meyer and Glazerman addressed two questions. First, how successful is
the Minneapolis program at matching students with diverse preferences to
schools with differing characteristics? Second, has the program reduced
or eliminated the racial segregation that would have occurred if
students had simply attended their neighborhood school? Many school
choice programs reflect a desire to improve schools by forcing them to
compete for students. But the Minneapolis program de-emphasizes
competition among schools, so the authors did not evaluate it according
to the criteria of school improvement.
School choice in Minneapolis can be traced back to two efforts in the
early 1970s. The first was spurred when the state of Minnesota issued
mandatory minority enrollment ceilings for schools in 1970. In the next
year, Minneapolis was found to be out of compliance, and in 1972 it
instituted a mixed-strategy desegregation program to meet state
standards. The program included enlarging district attendance
boundaries, creating magnet schools to attract white students into
predominantly minority neighborhoods, and introducing limited busing. At
the same time, the Minneapolis school district launched the Southeast
Alternative (SEA), which created six federally funded schools, each with
its own educational philosophy and instructional strategy. The SEA
program was not part of the school desegregation plan, but it provided
the city with a group of alternative school models that became the basis
for the categorization of schools that is now part of the city's
choice program. In 1982, this effort was broadened, and every school in
the city was classified either as a magnet school with a special theme
(math/science, urban environment, language immersion, etc.) or as an
alternative school such as Montessori, open school, fundamentals school,
or continuous progress school.
Beginning in 1989, all students in the Minneapolis school district
were required to choose a school. The system currently requires parents
of every kindergartner to submit their top three school preferences from
a menu of 12 or 13 schools that are available given the student's
home address. This menu includes both magnet schools and alternative
schools but does not permit parents to select any school within the
city. For the most part, each school in Minneapolis has a localized
attendance area. In some cases the attendance area is city-wide, but
usually it is more narrowly drawn, reflecting individual schools'
space limitations and transportation costs. Still, the menu of schools
does allow parents a choice of schools with differing structures and
educational philosophies.
The choice system is also constrained by other factors. First is the
continuing goal of system-wide racial desegregation. Students' race
is a factor that helps determine which school choice they are given.
Second, siblings are given preference in school assignment so that
family members can attend the same school. Finally, children with
special needs are assigned according to which school can best meet those
needs.
Despite these limitations, the Minneapolis program does a reasonably
good job of giving students either their first or second choice of
school. Anecdotal evidence suggests that the safety of the neighborhood
where the school is located is the most important factor in determining
how parents choose the schools they want their children to attend.
The authors expressed the judgment that the Minneapolis program has
succeeded in furthering school desegregation. The city's schools
are now significantly more racially integrated than the city's
neighborhoods. The controlled choice program helps promote desegregation
for two reasons. First, in Minneapolis, neighborhoods dominated by one
racial group tend to be adjacent to neighborhoods dominated by another
racial group. Families seem to be willing to choose schools located in
an adjacent neighborhood. Second, since the system offers such a diverse
array of school types, students may even be willing to travel a
considerable distance to attend a school that is particularly well
matched to their interests.
In sum, the Minneapolis program seems to be succeeding in allowing
school choice and in meeting desegregation targets. Elsewhere, however,
most experiments with school choice are intended to improve the schools
and students' performance. Whether a controlled choice program can
promote these objective still needs to be examined.
The authors concluded with a model for evaluating controlled choice
programs with potentially conflicting objectives such as allowing
students to choose their school and promoting racial integration. The
authors present a model that examines an individual student's
utility for a specific school as a function of the school's
characteristics, neighborhood characteristics, academic quality,
distance from the student's home, and some unmeasured determinants
of utility. The authors assume that students rank alternative schools by
comparing utility with all of the schools in their choice set. The
advantage of such a modeling approach is that it allows one to measure
whether controlled choice programs do better than neighborhood schools,
busing, uncontrolled choice, or random assignment in enabling a school
system to reach desegregation targets.
Who chooses? Voucher and interdistrict choice programs in Milwaukee
John F. Witte and Christopher A.Thorn analyzed the types of students
and families now participating in two specific choice programs in
metropolitan Milwaukee. Such information is needed because critics argue
that choice programs may leave certain groups of students behind in weak
public schools, perhaps because their families are unable to make
optimal school choices. Conversely, the critics contend, better-informed
and generally wealthier families tend to benefit disproportionately from
choice programs by leaving the lower-quality public and private schools.
Meanwhile, the students who remain in those schools may be ill-served
because higher-achieving peers are now absent, or because those parents
who tend to act as agents of school change are no longer involved there.
Information about the participants in choice programs can be helpful in
assessing how evenly the benefits of choice programs are distributed
across the range of the student population. Moreover, information
gathered within specific contexts can help policymakers design choice
programs to ensure that targeted groups of students will benefit.
Witte and Thorn analyzed the participants in two choice programs now
operating in the Milwaukee area: the Milwaukee Parental Choice Program
and the Milwaukee Suburban Transfer Program, the latter of which is
widely known as the Chapter 220 program. The Choice Program, now in its
fifth year of operation, is a small program that provides cash vouchers
to students of low-income families in the Milwaukee public school (MPS)
system. Vouchers can be applied toward several private nonsectarian
schools in the city. Chapter 220 has been operating since 1976 in
response to court orders concerning racial imbalance in the metropolitan
area's public schools. Chapter 220 allows Milwaukee-area minority
students (largely from Milwaukee public schools) to attend other public
schools in the metropolitan area (chiefly in the suburbs). During the
1994-95 school year, approximately 6,500 students participated in
Chapter 220. The Choice Program does not allow schools to use prior
behavioral or achievement data in selecting students. If more students
apply than there are positions available, students must be randomly
selected. In Chapter 220, poor attendance or serious behavioral problems
can lead to rejection of students. Academic achievement can also be
taken into account.
Witte and Thorn compared students in the Choice Program between 1990
and 1993, participants in Chapter 220 in 1990-91, and a randomly
selected control group of students who stayed in the MPS during 1990-91.
In addition, they surveyed a sample of parents drawn from each of these
student groups. Descriptive statistics were compiled describing who
participates in the two programs and why. Beyond the descriptive
statistics, the authors estimated logistic regressions to ascertain
whether some of the individual characteristics remain as significant
indicators in the simultaneous presence of other characteristics. The
regressions allowed the authors to estimate the likelihood of a
characteristic affecting a choice decision within a particular school
program.
Several findings emerged. As of spring 1991, in comparison to the
MPS, Chapter 220 students were more likely to come from two-parent
families and families with higher income. Parents had higher educational
expectations for their children and were much less satisfied with their
children's prior school than the average MPS parent. Students in
the program had been scoring higher on standardized achievement tests
than the average MPS student.
Families involved in the Choice Program are opposites of Chapter 220
families in economic and family status; the average income of Choice
families is lower (they are more likely to be receiving income
assistance), and they are far less likely to be two-parent families.
Choice Program students are likely to be performing less well than the
typical MPS student before they enter the Choice Program. However, there
are some similarities between Choice and Chapter 220 clients. Choice
parents, like Chapter 220 parents, are likely to be more highly educated
than MPS parents. In addition, the educational expectations that Choice
parents have for their children are as high as those of Chapter 220
parents, and Choice parents were equally dissatisfied with their
children's prior school. Finally, Choice parents participate much
more in their children's education than do any other parents.
Why the differences in characteristics of the clientele of these two
choice programs and the Milwaukee public schools? Some of the
differences reflect program design, such as the income ceiling
constraint in the Choice program. Others, such as the higher education
of Choice parents, probably is due to self-selection. The reasons for
the Chapter 220 outcomes are less clear because it is impossible to
discern the extent to which suburban districts are screening applicants.
The authors clearly believe that both programs are providing
alternatives to the families involved. The strength of the desire for
such alternatives is indicated by the fact that thousands more families
have applied for Chapter 220 than can be accommodated, and by the strong
dissatisfaction that Choice parents felt for their children's
previous schools.
In assessing the impact of these two programs, proponents of school
choice will note that the programs are allowing families choice and that
specific features of program design, such as the Choice Program ceiling
on family income, are ensuring that benefits are targeted as intended.
By contrast, others will point out that because of the Choice Program,
some public schools may be losing parents who could be effective agents
of change.
Directions in management and delivery in urban school systems
The final session explored the steps that urban school systems are
taking to change their structure and delivery systems to improve
performance in some of the most besieged school systems. In Chicago,
this has led to the creation of local school councils in an attempt to
increase local participation in the schools and to move more
responsibility for decision-making to individual schools. Will
decentralized decisionmaking improve the schools?
A different form of administrative reform is to allow the private
sector to take over the day-to-day management of the schools. Baltimore
has done this, with a consortium of private firms banding together to
run some of the city's weakest schools. Can such an approach bring
meaningful reform to urban systems in which public efforts have failed?
Redesigning accountability at the system-wide level: The politics of
school reform in Chicago
Kenneth Wong and Gail Sunderman examined the problem of district-wide
governance in a decentralized system. The authors argued that the
current governance structure of the Chicago public schools is fragmented
as various institutional actors, from both inside and outside the school
system, compete for influence. Currently, the structure of governance of
the schools has moved from centralized authority to fragmentation as
local institutions compete for influence and higher levels of government
expand their programmatic demands.
The authors noted that recent school reforms place a premium on
increasing accountability and control at the local school level. Efforts
such as site-based management, parent empowerment, school choice, and
professional development programs all favor reducing the role of the
central bureaucracy in determining education policy. This focus on
decentralization has ignored the role of electoral, policy, and
administrative institutions, as well as special interest groups, that
shape education policy and resource allocation. Despite this move to
decentralization, key institutional actors remain instrumental in the
governance of the schools. The school board, the state legislature, the
mayor, the governor, and unions all influence the resources that are
available for local school use. The authors argued that to understand
education policy and practice, one must consider the system-wide
institutional arrangements that make up the structure of school
governance.
Chicago provides an excellent case study of the issues involved in
the governance of an increasingly decentralized school system. The
Chicago public schools have been decentralizing authority since the
passage of the Chicago School Reform Act in 1988. Among the notable
features of the act was the creation of local school councils (LSC) to
serve as the primary policymakers at the individual school level. These
councils are composed of six parents, two community members, two
teachers, and the school principal. LSCs are responsible for making
budget and policy decisions for their schools and can even hire or fire
the principal. Under this structure, the principal is also given greater
authority in staff hiring decisions, and both principal and teachers
have more input into the selection of subdistrict school
superintendents. Individual school budgets are provided largely in a
lump sum, and it is up to the LSC to establish spending priorities.
The authors cited a number of reasons for the erosion of the central
authority of the Chicago school system. Court rulings, state laws, and
federal mandates have limited the decision-making role of the central
bureaucracy. In addition, the trend towards site-based school governance
has made the system more responsive to political concerns of local
constituents. Even in those areas in which central administration has
been retained, as for example, with categorical programs, accountability
is often to state and federal agencies. As a result, the Chicago school
system is increasingly governed by a complex set of institutions and
actors that often are motivated by different policy goals. For example,
the mayor, governor, and state legislature are primarily interested in
electoral outcomes, while the school board and central office are
interested in managerial and administrative outcomes. Likewise, local
interest groups are primarily interested in gaining policy influence.
All of these actors are generally accountable to differing
constituencies.
Wong and Sunderman suggested that in such a situation, three types of
fragmentation are likely to arise. First is vertical fragmentation, in
which higher levels of government impose regulations and mandates on the
schools. Second is horizontal fragmentation, in which diverse and often
competing sources of authority have overlapping jurisdiction over the
same policy area. This occurs, for example, when different institutions
such as the School Finance Authority, the school board, and central
bureaucracy all are responsible for the school budget. Third is
organizational fragmentation, or fragmentation within the central
office. This is particularly the case when categorical programs,
responding to mandates from higher levels of government, operate as
largely autonomous units within the central office. Additionally,
central office policy decisions that are driven by fiscal and budgetary
concerns are often disconnected from instructional and curriculum tasks
at the classroom level.
An additional force that has eroded the central authority of the
school system is the district's dependence on appropriations from
the state legislature and its vulnerability to the politics of state
aid. Jurisdictional contention between Chicago and the suburbs, as well
as between the metropolitan area and downstate, has made it increasingly
difficult to address Chicago's budgetary problems. Efforts to
arrive at a new funding structure to alleviate chronic funding problems
in the system have failed. Instead, political impasse has led to a
series of patchwork funding schemes that still leave the system with a
projected deficit of $290 million in FY96. Another consequence of
decentralization is the politics of shared decisionmaking. As
decisionmaking has become increasingly shared among teachers, community
groups, parents, and principals, competition for a voice in the system
has developed. This has produced, for example, a school board nominating
process that is driven by opposing political and constituency concerns,
with competition between the mayor and the nominating commission to
appoint school board members. There are also operational inconsistencies
such that the authority for spending funds is lodged with the local
schools, but accountability for how the funds are spent remains at the
board level. If money is misused at the school level, it is still the
board that is legally obligated to repay improperly spent funds.
To help correct some of these governance problems, Wong and Sunderman
suggested that efforts should focus on the appropriate division of
functions among policy actors and that reform strategies should be
designed to promote policy coherence. They suggested three initial
strategies to help achieve these objectives. First, in order to secure
the additional funding needed for the Chicago system, a state-wide
coalition could help defuse the policy impasse among city, suburban, and
downstate interests. The primary task of this coalition would be to
promote the understanding that educational problems in Chicago are a
collective challenge and that solving them will advance the state's
long-term economic competitiveness.
Second, they argued that new types of performance indicators, in
addition to those reflecting student achievement, are needed to judge
school success. These could include indicators measuring the
effectiveness of institutional leaders in addressing educational
problems. Such indicators would extend accountability beyond the schools
and students themselves to include policy actors. Finally, the central
office needs to be better connected to the classroom. Particularly
important is to focus on basic instruction as it applies to all
students, rather than specific categories of students, and to provide
the instructional support needed at the school level.
Analysis of the effect of the Chicago school reform on student
performance
As in many other large urban school systems across the country, test
scores and dropout rates for students of Chicago's public school
system have been sub-par and getting worse. Moreover, by the end of the
1980s the Chicago public school system had been through political and
financial chaos with intermittent funding crises and delayed school
openings. Chicago's answer to its travails was to pass the Chicago
School Reform Act in December 1988. Aided by state legislative action,
this act significantly changed the governance and organization of the
Chicago public school system by shifting budgetary, personnel, and
educational planning functions away from central administration and
toward the schools themselves.
Decentralization and site-based management plans have been tried, to
varying degrees and in various forms, in many U.S. school districts in
recent decades, including New York City and Miami. The Chicago effort
will undoubtedly be a useful example for others to study. The plight of
Chicago's school system had been widely reported, and its reform
has been extensive.
The potential benefits of decentralization are varied. Service
providers may be better able to customize their services to fit the
needs of their clientele, and they become directly accountable to those
served, at the point of delivery--the local school. At the same time,
site-based management is said by some to create a greater sense of
involvement and community. In addition, decentralized governance is said
to promote competition among schools, with attendant gains in cost
efficiency and output productivity. Conversely, a centralized system may
be less costly if there are scale economies in the provision of
educational services. So too, some critics argue that some forms of
decentralization only serve to create another bureaucratic layer in the
system of educational provision. Still others believe that
centralization ensures that school services will be more equitably
distributed.
The Chicago School Reform Act had three main components: the
formulation of a set of goals to be met by each school by 1994, a
reallocation of resources to the individual schools, and the creation of
local school councils at every school. The primary goals for schools
were raising student achievement levels, attendance rates, and
graduation rates to national norms.
While significant resources have been shifted to the school level, it
is questionable whether local schools have been given sufficient funds
and autonomy. At the same time, however, the school system's
finances in general continue to be severely constrained. Other research
has found that decentralization is ineffective unless accompanied by
increased funding to enable organizational change.
The Chicago School Reform Act created LSCs to be the budgetary,
administrative, and educational planning vehicle at each school. The
LSCs are composed of six parents, two community members, two teachers,
and the principal, all of whom except the principal are elected every
two years by the groups they represent. Chicago's site-based
management differs from others around the country by including more
input from parents and community representatives, and somewhat less from
professional staff. Among other things, LSCs were given the task of
producing a school improvement plan and an operating budget.
Thomas A. Downes and Jacquelyn L. Horowitz evaluated the
reform's success in reaching some of its primary goals: raising
student achievement levels, attendance rates, and graduation rates to
the national norm. They also investigated whether any particular
features of individual schools or neighborhoods seemed to be associated
with differential effects on those student outcomes.
Data from 524 Chicago elementary and high schools and 893 school
districts elsewhere in Illinois were assembled for the pre-reform school
years 1987-88 and 1988-89 and the post-reform years 1990-91, 1991-92,
and 1992-93. These data included student outcome measures such
graduation rates, attendance rates, and standardized test scores such as
the Illinois Goal Assessment Program (IGAP). Test scores are only one
measure of school and student outcomes and may fail to measure important
effects of reform such as increased self-esteem or greater family
satisfaction with school. In addition, any changes in test scores may
not be attributable to reform. Accordingly, the authors also gathered
data on student and school characteristics such as racial and ethnic
composition, enrollment, percentage of students with limited English
proficiency, percentage eligible for subsidized school lunches, and
population mobility between communities. Community data included racial
and ethnic composition and the level of educational attainment of
adults.
Analyses were performed at the school level rather than the
individual student level. Because interpretation of such results may be
difficult if a school's student body is changing because of
household relocation over time, the population mobility of the
surrounding community was used to control for varying student mobility.
Using graduation rates, IGAP scores, and ACT(3) scores as outcomes to
be explained, the authors estimated multiple regression equations to
identify the effects of student and community characteristics, the
effects of Chicago school reform (using binary variables for time), and
the effects of specific community and student demographic
characteristics on school reform efficacy. The latter included
characteristics such as percentage of students with limited English
proficiency and percentage eligible for subsidized lunches.
Observations of schools were also added from Illinois school
districts comprised of a single school. By doing so, the authors hoped
to account for general unobserved influences on outcomes, such as
changes in the test itself. Such influences are assumed to affect city
schools and control group schools alike, and to exert their influences
via community/school characteristics in equal magnitude as well.
Since Chicago's school reform was launched, student performance
on standardized tests and graduation rates have fallen. Nonetheless,
after accounting for the effects of other influences on test scores in
Chicago, the authors concluded that reform has produced some benefits in
the city's public schools. Community and student population
characteristics appear to be significant determinants of measurable
achievement, and changes in Chicago's demographics have tended to
obscure real performance gains by students. Similarly, when
single-school districts in Illinois were used as a control group,
statistical results show that reform acted to mitigate a downward trend
in raw mean test scores in Chicago schools. For example, the authors
found that Chicago's third-grade IGAP reading scores in 1992-93
were 1.80 points higher than they would have been in the absence of
reform.
Other results are less encouraging, however. Schools with high
proportions of students with limited English proficiency and students
eligible for subsidized lunch programs actually have fared worse during
the reform era. Some observers may find these results disheartening since the reforms were intended to allow such schools additional
flexibility by giving them greater discretion over the use of so-called
Chapter 1 funds. The authors note that the disappointing results may
reflect the fact that discretionary income has actually been restricted
recently because of the severe fiscal crunch within which the schools
are operating. Findings elsewhere indicate that decentralization of
school governance is less likely to succeed in the absence of funding
increases and under conditions of fiscal austerity. The authors suggest
that, if possible, greater efforts should be directed to those types of
schools where reform may not be succeeding.
Evaluation of these and other questions is still in its infancy, yet
it already seems clear that Chicago's reform efforts offer lessons
for the future, here and in other urban school systems.
Baltimore city public schools: Experimenting with private operation
Can student achievement be enhanced by allowing private firms to
operate public schools? That is the question examined by Sammis B.
White. The city of Baltimore, facing increased frustration in operating
the public schools, embarked on a two-track approach to improving the
school system. First, the city moved toward site-based management in an
effort to increase local participation and management of the schools.
Second, in 1992 the city decided to turn over the daily operations of
nine public schools to a consortium of private firms called the Alliance
for Schools that Work. The nine schools selected were among the weakest
in the system. The hope was that private management would improve the
efficiency of day-to-day operations of the schools and ultimately
improve student achievement. After only two years of experience, it is
still difficult to judge whether achievement has been enhanced, but the
consortium is claiming a number of successes, and it appears that many
key elements needed to improve achievement have been put in place.
The Alliance for Schools that Work has a five-year contract with the
school system and is paid $5,918 per student per year, which represents
the average cost per pupil system-wide. The Alliance is a consortium of
four companies: Education Alternatives, Inc. (EAI), Johnson Controls,
KMPG Peat Marwick, and Computer Curriculum Corporation. Each company has
expertise in a particular aspect of school management, but EAI is the
lead partner. It manages the operations and resources of the schools and
promotes the Tesseract model of education for reforming the schools.
This model tries to weave together various "best practice"
techniques for enhancing student achievement: having an individualized education plan for each student, enhancing staff development, using
instructional interns in the classroom as aides to teachers, improving
access to technology, and increasing parental involvement. Johnson
Controls is responsible for the physical operation of the school
buildings, including maintenance and repair. It also runs
noninstructional operations such as the cafeteria, security, and
transportation, which the school system does not provide directly. KMPG
Peat Marwick is working to improve financial control so that a better
accounting system can be created and more accurate financial statements
generated. Computer Curriculum Corporation is designing software that
will enable the use of more technology in the classroom.
If the methods of the Alliance are to work, it must change the way
funds are distributed. EAI in particular argues that too many resources
are being channeled into noninstructional activities. The Alliance seeks
to reverse this trend and to increase the efficiency of instructional
delivery by improving technology and using instructional interns.
Increasing parental involvement in the education process is also key;
individual education plans are developed for each student and require
parental approval.
While the Alliance may make many decisions about employees and
operations, it may not select teachers or principals; these are drawn
from the existing city school system. However, the Alliance does hire
classroom aides, called instructional interns. These are
college-educated adults paid $7 per hour to work in the classroom and
assist the teacher. Previously classroom aides were mostly
non-college-educated paraprofessionals who were paid $10 per hour. The
Alliance believes that the presence of college-educated adults, many of
whom aspire to become teachers, will enhance learning. Other
noninstructional employees such as custodians, security guards, and
cafeteria workers are hired directly by the Alliance and usually work at
lower wage rates than their predecessors did.
The Alliance's efforts to date have been promising. Gains have
been particularly noticeable in the physical condition of the school
buildings. All of the school buildings have been physically
rehabilitated and are now maintained in an impressive condition.
Building systems have been updated and operations are vastly more
efficient than previously. Similarly, accounting procedures have been
improved. Through better tracking of resources, the Alliance has been
able to redeploy spending levels and increase the number of computers in
the classrooms. At the elementary school level, computers are used
extensively to supplement classroom instruction. Experience at the
middle school level has been less promising, but White suggested this
may have more to do with providing teachers with more appropriate ways
of integrating computers into class work. The new accounting system also
makes it easier to keep track of the student body. Finally, the Alliance
reports that by reallocating spending priorities, it has been able to
devote $1 million more to direct expenditures in the nine schools by
reallocating spending priorities than the city of Baltimore would have
under traditional management.
White reported that it is harder to measure whether the Alliance has
had any effect on student performance. In the two years the Alliance has
been in charge, test scores have moved little in either direction. White
suggested this may be due to two reasons. First, improvement in student
performance should be cumulative, and after only two years, it is simply
too early to expect much change in test scores. Second, test scores have
been reported on an aggregate basis rather than longitudinally by
individual student. White suggested that given the high turnover in the
school population, tracking the performance of individual students will
produce a more accurate picture of the effects the reforms are having.
Another aspect that is showing only limited success is the effort to
increase parental involvement. Parents have not shown as much interest
in individualized education plans as had been hoped, but perhaps as they
become more familiar with them, this will change.
White concluded that while it is too early to judge the effect of the
Baltimore experiment on student achievement, the efforts to date do seem
to have significantly improved the quality of the educational inputs
that research suggests will improve student performance.
NOTES
1 As part of the same legislative package, the apparent strength of
local districts in collective bargaining situations was effectively
strengthened. Note also that spending caps can be circumvented through
local referenda. However, nation-wide experience suggests that voter
approval of local spending referenda is far from automatic.
2 In a few states with foundation plans, local school districts are
not required to levy a minimum property tax rate.
3 A test widely taken and used for college admissions.
Midwest approaches to school reform October 26-27, 1994 Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago
Introductory remarks and welcome
Michael H. Moskow, President, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Issues and experience in finance reform
Michigan's recent reform of school finance