Can alternative forms of governance help metropolitan areas?
Mattoon, Richard H.
Economic development theorists are increasingly promoting the
development of strong regional economies as the key to successfully
attracting and maintaining economic activity when global competition and
technological change are making business location choices increasingly
far-flung.(1) At the core of healthy regions are metropolitan areas that
offer the amenities and services that businesses demand. One school of
thought suggests that while metropolitan areas are particularly critical
to regional economic success, current growth patterns are leading to
urban sprawl and the inefficient delivery of public goods and services that will ultimately undermine the economic prospects of entire
metropolitan regions. Yet deconcentration of economic activity is
entirely rational given the present rules of the economic development
game. Research has shown that any town will receive a tax benefit from
securing commercial development even if that development has negative
spillover effects on the region.(2) However, since there are no
political and economic structures to promote the region's interests
over those of individual towns, the pattern of uncoordinated growth
continues. The most frequently suggested solution to this problem is
some form of centralized metropolitan or regional government that can
coordinate growth and help the entire region to share the benefits of
economic growth.
In addition to the potential benefits of coordinated regional growth,
supporters of consolidated metropolitan governments usually suggest that
economies of scale in the production and distribution of public goods
are available to larger government units.(3) These efficiencies lower
the cost of government while providing the types of uniform governmental
services that should appeal to businesses when making locating and
operating decisions.
The issue of metropolitan governance is of particular interest to the
Midwest. Central cities in the region have been experiencing population
declines. Recent economic and population growth in metropolitan areas
has been achieved largely by the spread of activity into more distant
suburbs, resulting in a pattern of uncoordinated land use. Such
development is occurring in metropolitan areas across the nation, but it
is more noticeable in the industrial cities of the Midwest, where
central cities historically had high densities of both economic activity
and population. While newer metropolitan areas can be designed to
accommodate the infrastructure that is needed to promote commerce,
midwestern cities are often left with an aging infrastructure that was
designed to support the commerce of the early 1900s, not that of the
1990s. Given this disadvantage, promoting a healthy and integrated
region is arguably more critical to the Midwest than to other regions.
The Midwest is an appropriate arena in which to examine the issue of
metropolitan governance, for it is home to some of the most extreme
examples of both consolidated and fragmented government in the nation.
From the relatively tightly knit structure of Unigov in Indianapolis to
the highly fragmented structure of overlapping governments in Chicago,
the full range of government types is available.
This article will address the question of whether there are
advantages to changing some aspects of metropolitan governance. It will
further assess some midwestern experiments in metropolitan government.
How have metropolitan areas in the Midwest changed?
Population movement in the early 1900s tended to be from rural areas
to the central city. Today, population is still moving from rural areas
to metropolitan areas, but at the same time, the population within
metropolitan areas is spreading out of the central city into the
surrounding suburbs and outskirts. Thus in many midwestern cities, while
metropolitan population has grown, the population of the central urban
areas has declined (see table 1). This is the most significant dynamic
influencing midwestern metropolitan areas.(4)
The spread of population out of the center city is not a bad thing in
itself. Some would argue that the high population density in the city
helped create pollution, overcrowding, and a variety of problems
associated with congestion. Some support for lower population density
can be drawn from the fact that density in the fastest growing Sun Belt
cities is significantly lower than in "sister" midwestern
cities. This fact is sometimes interpreted to indicate that lower
density is better suited to promoting growth in the current economy
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 1 OMITTED]. One urban analyst, David Rusk, has
even suggested that modern cities appear to have difficulty growing
economically once their population density exceeds 5,000 people per
square mile? This is at least partially due to Americans' apparent
preference for living in lower-density communities.
The economic conditions that once favored the development of
high-density central cities have moderated for several reasons. First of
all, many midwestern cities grew because they were close to a natural
resource that gave them a comparative advantage over other locations.
Often this was a river or other body of water on which commerce could be
transported. This economic advantage created others that encouraged the
clustering of the labor force in the city.(6) Today economic activity is
more often associated with concentrations of capital and human skills
than with natural resource endowments. Since both capital and labor are
significantly more footloose than natural resources, this has weakened
the comparative advantage that cities derived from their natural
resources. Accordingly, growth no longer needs to concentrate at a
central place. Instead, it has become multimodal, with pockets of
economic activity emerging throughout a metropolitan region, in
proximity to each other but spread over a larger area. In the process
the boundaries between urban, suburban, and rural areas have become
blurred, and the entire metropolitan region has become more economically
homogeneous.
TABLE 1
Population growth, 1950-90
Percent change
Chicago metropolitan 35
Chicago city -23
Cleveland metropolitan 19
Cleveland city -45
Columbus metropolitan 89
Columbus city 68
Detroit metropolitan 35
Detroit city -44
Indianapolis metropolitan 72
Indianapolis city 71
Milwaukee metropolitan 41
Milwaukee city -1
Sources: For Chicago, author's calculations. For other cities, Rusk
(1993).
Not all aspects of this deconcentration are benign, and numerous
analysts have questioned whether it represents a new pattern of rational
economic growth or simply unregulated sprawl.(7) While the forces
leading metropolitan areas to spread out may reflect the natural demands
of the economy, the response of local governments in dealing with the
trend may be producing new problems. Anthony Downs argues that as
development has moved out of the cities, individual towns have adopted
policies that protect their interests but create a patchwork of
regulations that ultimately harm region-wide development prospects.(8)
Initially towns often pursue new commercial development at virtually any
cost, using tax breaks and land write-downs as incentives. Little
attention is paid to the increased congestion and pollution that may
spill over into surrounding communities, which may lack the
infrastructure to support these new burdens. Since the property tax
advantages of commercial development are limited to the town in which
the development occurs, adjacent communities are often forced to
accommodate the development without any greater fiscal resources. Once
residents decide that additional growth is not desired, towns may move
to the next stage of this process, instituting growth-management
policies to force development elsewhere or to regulate closely the type
of development that can occur.
A second issue: Optimal government size
Even if the potential harmful effects of urban sprawl were not a
consideration, metropolitan governance may be warranted on the grounds
of optimal government size. The efficiency with which government
provides its services is receiving growing attention, as efficient firms
need efficient government to help (or at least not hinder) their
performance in the world economy.
A substantial body of research since the 1920s has examined whether
larger consolidated governments are more efficient in producing services
than smaller, more fragmented units. Bish and Nourse (1975) summarize
the assumptions in favor of a single consolidated government across
three dimensions. First, a metropolitan area is actually a single
community linked by a shared economy but artificially divided by
fragmented government jurisdictions. Second, the metropolitan-wide needs
of citizens and businesses cannot be met by this fragmented governmental
structure. Third, the elimination of fragmented jurisdictions will
eliminate duplication and overlap among governmental units in favor of a
single metropolitan government that can more efficiently provide public
goods and services at greater economies of scale.(9) As the authors
point out, evidence as to whether this last assumption is true has been
contradictory.
In an attempt to identify the optimal size of government, economists
have tried to estimate the spillover effects and the scale economies
that are produced when a central government provides a uniform service
across a metropolitan region.(10) If positive spillovers and significant
scale economies exist, centralized provision of services may be
warranted. In general, this appears to be the case most often with
government services that are well-suited to technical solutions. For
example, water, sewage disposal, and electric services appear to be most
efficiently provided by a centralized metropolitan-wide government.
Supporters of such government also argue that mass transit, transit
planning, and even land use planning also appear to benefit from central
provision. Services that tend to be poorly provided by centralized
governments are many social services such as education and welfare.
Moreover, localities may prefer to decide for themselves what levels of
these services to provide.(11)
Economists in general have been careful not to overstate the
potential benefits of having governmental services provided by single,
metropolitan-wide governments. Much of the criticism of such government
rests on the work of Tiebout (1956), who suggested that consumers are
best served when they are free to move and can choose communities that
provide their desired level of public services. The resulting
competition among communities not only allows individual towns to
provide their own unique set of services, but also should in principle
control the size of government.
This view is supported by Eberts and Gronberg (1988), who found a
statistically significant relationship between the number of
general-purpose governments at the metropolitan and county level and
their size as measured by the share of personal income devoted to local
governmental expenditures. The more general-purpose governments there
are, the smaller the share of personal income required to support local
government. While this finding supports the idea that decentralized government promotes fiscal competition and holds [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE
2 OMITTED] down the cost of government, it does not indicate whether
such governments can provide better-quality services than more
centralized governments. Not surprisingly, this uncertainty has led to
the policy prescription that a hybrid approach to providing governmental
services works best. Rather than uniformly supporting either a
centralized or a fragmented government structure, this prescription
argues that one should consider the nature of the service and assign its
provision to the appropriate level of government.
Can centralized metropolitan governance help with sprawl?
Whether a more centralized model of governance could alter the
current pattern of metropolitan deconcentration really depends on which
forces are causing the population to spread out.(12) If deconcentration
is occurring because more efficient production and lower transportation
costs are available outside the central city, then policies to reverse
deconcentration may simply promote inefficiency. If, however, it is due
to negative externalities associated with the city such as social
problems, then deconcentration may indicate an inefficient distribution
of available resources. In this latter case, deconcentration may not
reflect some optimal reconfiguration of regional resources, but rather,
a type of sorting process in which people and firms relocate to areas
that serve their individual needs but do not necessarily promote the
interests of the region. Anecdotal evidence about the growing pains associated with suburban growth suggests that deconcentration is at
least partially being driven more by "flight from blight" than
from some optimal reconfiguring of resources to maximize efficiency in
the regional economy.(13)
However, a frequent criticism of efforts to introduce metropolitan
governance is that they are thinly disguised attempts to force
development back into the central city. Those analysts who believe
metropolitan deconcentration will improve regional economic efficiency
suggest that central cities may be an anachronism, and that the
increasing preference of firms for suburban locations can result in
healthy suburbs able to function without a healthy central city. In the
Midwest, Detroit is often presented as an example of such a scenario. On
the surface, it appears that the suburbs surrounding Detroit have
continued to flourish despite the sharp decline of the central city.
Those suburbs may have absorbed the industries that have left the city,
in which case economic activity has not left the area but simply has
redistributed itself. Since commercial development usually benefits the
community in which it is located,(14) it is not clear that suburban
communities would embrace a new form of governance that was expected to
channel commercial development back into the urban area. If they did so,
they would surrender the tax benefits they would receive if they
captured the development themselves. However, evidence suggests that
healthy suburbs need healthy cities in order to grow.(15) Furthermore,
anecdotal evidence suggests that many of the healthiest metropolitan
areas rely more heavily on various forms of regional governance.
Establishing a structure to promote regional problem-solving and
consensus-building has become more important as cities and their suburbs
appear to have become more interdependent in important ways. A variety
of research has found links between the health of central cities and the
development prospects of the suburbs.(16) Gains in city and suburban
populations, per capita income, and housing values are positively
correlated, and these relationships have strengthened every decade since
1960 (see table 2).(17) Such positive relationships suggest that
population, income, and housing values in the suburbs are related to (or
at the very least not independent of) the vitality of the central city.
However, one must interpret such correlations carefully. Rather than
reflecting greater interdependence between city and suburbs, they may
simply indicate that as economic activity has moved to the suburbs,
suburban economies have begun to resemble city economies and now react
to external forces in the same manner as their city counterparts.
While much of this research is still quite new, it has yielded two
interesting findings. First, the age of the city matters when it comes
to growth prospects. Second, the period over which deconcentration is
examined matters when it comes to measuring whether suburbs can flourish
without a healthy central city. Norton (1979) found that U.S. cities
that developed before 1920 have faced significantly different economic
prospects than cities developed after 1920. The pre-1920 or
"old" cities are characterized as being largely landlocked,
constructed before automobile transportation was the dominant form of
transportation, and having high population densities. The younger,
post-1920 cities have lower population densities, tend to have fewer
spatial restrictions, and have grown through active annexation of
surrounding areas. Norton examined the trends in population, density,
age of housing stock, and the ratio of household incomes of city
dwellers versus suburbanites from 1950 to 1975 in order to assess how
the age of a city influenced growth. The "old" cities in the
sample, which had large percentages of housing stock built before 1939,
shrank during this era; the young cities grew. Norton's sample
included four midwestern cities - Chicago and Detroit labeled old,
Indianapolis labeled young, and Milwaukee somewhere in-between and
labeled anomalous. If the variables Norton examined are updated to 1990
for these cities, the pattern remains much the same except in Milwaukee,
which now appears to behave more like the old cities than the new (see
table 3).
Initial decline in the central city may not seem to set off any alarm
bells, but over time, it will affect the suburbs as well. Scholars of
metropolitan development have suggested that [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3
OMITTED] it passes through six stages, as illustrated in table 4.(18)
According to Rothblatt, the majority of U.S. cities are operating at
stage 5, "absolute decentralization."(19) In this stage, the
central city's population is shrinking, the metropolitan
area's population is growing, and the perceived characteristics of
the metropolitan area (such as tax burden, infrastructure, or
congestion) are seen as worsening. If the process moves to the next
stage, the decline of these characteristics will accelerate. Rothblatt
points out that the consequences of this evolution are particularly
worrisome in an increasingly global economy, in which firms have more
choice in location and can leave declining areas. As urban markets
expand and become more competitive, firms must be efficient in order to
survive. This in turn requires well-managed and supportive metropolitan
areas. If deconcentration leads to metropolitan diseconomies such as
traffic congestion and higher housing prices, firms will begin to seek
other locations. Initially these may only be farther-outlying suburbs,
but as diseconomies spread throughout the metropolitan area, economic
activity will begin to leave the area altogether.
Such a scenario makes clear that the problems and growth prospects of
metropolitan areas have become more interdependent. It also makes clear
the importance of establishing regional mechanisms to promote regional
consensus-building and problem-solving.
TABLE 4
Metropolitan development and population change
Metropolitan
Stage Core Ring area
1. Centralization + - +
2. Absolute centralization ++ + ++
3. Relative centralization + ++ +
4. Relative decentralization - + +
5. Absolute decentralization - + -
6. Decentralization - - -
Source: Rothblatt (1993).
Is there a better way?
Developing a better structure for governing metropolitan growth has
long been of interest to planners and academics. Voters and politicians,
however, have viewed such proposals with suspicion, envisioning an
additional layer of government that would only duplicate existing
governmental functions without providing any clear benefits. In
addition, local governments are unlikely to want to cede powers to a new
level of government.
Nevertheless, some notable examples of metropolitan governance allow
us to assess its potential benefits. In the Midwest, these include the
Metropolitan Council of Minneapolis/St. Paul, Unigov in Indianapolis,
and the Allegheny Regional Asset District in Pittsburgh. None of these
has been as ambitious or as successful in many ways as large-scale
efforts such as Toronto's.(20) In most cases, metropolitan
governments have been established to fill planning gaps between other
existing levels of government. These governments are not designed to
function in any comprehensive fashion. As such, they provide limited
examples of the potential for metropolitan governance rather than
serving as ready-made models to be implemented elsewhere.
Minneapolis-St. Paul
Metropolitan governance has a longer history in the Twin Cities than
in virtually any other U.S. city. As early as 1957, the Metropolitan
Planning Commission (MPC) was established to coordinate issues of
regional growth.(21) However, this was a voluntary council of
governments that proved largely ineffective in managing growth. While
the MPC was well equipped to study the nature of growth problems and to
suggest potential solutions, it could not enforce any of its
suggestions. Once this became apparent, the MPC was supplanted by the
Metropolitan Council of the Twin Cities in 1967. The council has been
credited with notable successes, but significant obstacles still prevent
it from operating as a fully developed regional policymaker.
The Metropolitan Council covers seven counties in the metropolitan
area containing roughly 272 governments: 7 county, 138 city, 50
township, 49 school district, 6 metropolitan, and 22 special purpose
districts. Probably none of these governments has a significant interest
in reducing its own authority. Accordingly, the role of the council from
the beginning was to fill the gaps, handling issues that other
governments were unwilling or unable to manage. Its charge was to
coordinate planning, particularly in the area of physical
infrastructure.
The council's structure has several unique aspects. First,
although its interactions are with local and county governments, it was
created by the state legislature, to which it reports. This suggests
that the council's primary audience may be state rather than local
government, although over time, local considerations appear to have
become more influential in the council's deliberations. Second, all
17 council members are appointed by the governor, with some input from
legislators from the metropolitan area's districts. Being appointed
may help protect council members from feeling particularly beholden to
parochial interests, since they are not forced to respond to a local
constituency. On the other hand, it reduces the leverage of the council
members, since they lack broad-based public support and are rarely well
known within the metropolitan area. Third, by design the council has
very little operating authority. While it oversees and approves the
budgets of some smaller regional operating authorities, its main charge
is to review and plan for long-range expenditures in the region. The
council has proven to be reasonably effective in carrying out this
charge in the area of physical infrastructure. Critics have suggested
that the council has been less effective in social policy; its efforts
in health care and education have so far been largely unsuccessful.
Two widely acknowledged partial successes for the council were its
1973 Metropolitan Development Guide and its successful tax-base sharing
program. The former was an ambitious state-mandated plan to rationalize growth within the region in order to prevent urban sprawl. Its major
goal was to stop development from leap-frogging into rural locations,
directing it instead to the central city and the already heavily
developed first-ring suburbs with existing infrastructure. In addition
to this primary goal, the plan had subsidiary goals of preserving the
natural environment, expanding people's social choices, lowering
the concentration of minorities in the central city, and diversifying
the sources of regional economic growth. Two other objectives were to
increase the equitability of financing for public services and increase
citizen involvement in regional governance.
Assessments of the council's efforts to channel development have
been mixed. Clearly, the Twin Cities shifted some development into the
central city during the mid-1970s and 1980s. Commercial construction in
the city remained strong, and the economic prominence of Minneapolis-St.
Paul was enhanced. The central city did lose population during this
period, particularly in comparison to the outer-ring suburbs. But there
is some evidence that growth was channeled into the first-ring suburbs,
which suggests that the council's efforts were at least partly
successful. Population density in the close-in suburbs rose, perhaps
because in-fill development appeared more attractive. While population
growth accelerated in the outlying suburbs, commercial development did
not leap-frog in the usual pattern. Enforcing this containment were
limitations on sewer and water extensions onto working farmland.
The plan's success was limited in another way as well. While
development within the designated planning area was influenced,
uncontrolled development continued in the fringe area just outside the
five districts under the council's jurisdiction. Since the plan did
not allow the districts to annex the surrounding areas, growth on the
fringe went largely unchecked.
A second major effort of the council that has met with some success
is mandated tax-base sharing. In 1974, Minnesota's Fiscal
Disparities Act was passed with the goal of reducing the disparities in
the tax base between towns caused by the concentration of commercial
activity. Proponents of the act argued that towns that attracted
commercial activity received significant tax benefits, while neighboring areas had to deal with the spillover effects without receiving any tax
benefit. Using 1971 as the base year, the law stipulated that 40 percent
of the net gain in new commercial and industrial development would be
dedicated to a tax-base-sharing pool that would channel money to
communities unable to attract commercial development. Allocations would
be based on a formula that took into account population growth and the
fiscal capacity of each town. With this plan, the ratio between the
highest and lowest commercial and industrial tax base per capita in 1991
was 4 to 1; without the plan, it would have been 22 to 1.(22) The
primary beneficiaries of this plan have been fast-growing residential
areas lacking commercial development. Ironically, because of the
concentration of commercial construction downtown, the central city has
ended up a net contributor.
Many analysts have rated the Metropolitan Council as at least a
partial success. It has had a significant influence in planning
infrastructure, ranging from development of the metropolitan airport to
the siting of the Metrodome sports complex and the giant retail center,
the Mall of America. However, because the council lacks enforcement
power, its influence is largely limited to its powers of persuasion.
Part of its success is attributed to the belief that the Twin Cities
region appears to be more accepting of the notion that without a strong
and vital central city, the region will be unable to compete for jobs
and new industries. The region's alleged acceptance of this notion
in turn appears due to two factors. First, it is the only significant
metropolitan area within a 400-mile radius. This relative isolation
means that no other place in the region is likely to be a significant
draw for new economic activity. Second, intraregional options for
economic growth are few. Growth in the region's agricultural
industries appears limited, and the region's traditional mining
activity has faded. Accordingly, the health of Minnesota's economy
has become more heavily dependent on the success of the metropolitan
Minneapolis-St. Paul area.
Perhaps another reason for the greater acceptance of metropolitan
governance is cultural. The northern European population that was
initially drawn to this area embraced cooperative ventures, with
farming, dairy, electrification, and even housing co-ops relatively
common. Some analysts have suggested that this has carried over into a
greater acceptance of government structures drawing on broad networks of
resources. A final reason for the success of the Twin Cities'
regional governance may be the area's cultural homogeneity. Some
evidence suggests that the more racially different the populations of
the central city and the surrounding suburbs, the less likely the region
is to embrace metropolitan governance, particularly when it perceives
such governance as primarily a measure to help the central city at the
suburbs' expense. As the Twin Cities' minority population
stands at only 12 percent, this is the most homogeneous metropolitan
area of the thirty largest in the country.(23)
These factors may have combined to make acceptance of metropolitan
governance more likely in the Twin Cities region. However, even in this
more friendly environment, such a structure is seen largely as filling
gaps between other layers of government. Without enforcement powers and
without the ability to annex new areas as the region grows, the future
of the Metropolitan Council is still unclear. It has yet to demonstrate
that it can successfully address social infrastructure problems. As with
most governments, once its role is defined, it may have difficulty
reinventing itself.
Indianapolis and Unigov
Another Midwest experiment in regional governance is Unigov in
Indianapolis. In the late 1960s, Indianapolis Mayor Richard Lugar
established the Governmental Reorganization Task Force to investigate
the potential for creating a unified county-city governance structure
for Indianapolis and the surrounding municipalities in Marion County.
The original goal was not a single body responsible for all governmental
functions in the area, but only a unified legislative body - the
City-County Council, with the mayor of Indianapolis as its Chair.(24)
Initial support for Unigov was not overwhelming. Many city
constituents, particularly black residents, saw it as an attempt to
dilute their political influence. Although minorities were a growing
segment of the city's population, Unigov would add 113,000 mostly
white suburban residents to the electorate that would then total 406,000
voters. These numbers would swing the city-county elections to the
Republicans. Proponents of Unigov recognized that support for the new
consolidated structure might not run deep and chose not to seek a voter
referendum to approve it. Instead, Unigov was ultimately approved only
by the Indiana legislature. Unigov's proponents brought a voluntary
lawsuit against themselves in order to ratify the legitimacy of the new
structure and forestall potential court challenges.(25)
Marion County still contains 50 separate local governments and 100
taxing units. But the Unigov legislation created Indiana's only
consolidated city, with geographic boundaries that roughly equate to
those of Marion County. The boundaries of Indianapolis expanded from 82
to 402 square miles, its population from 480,000 to 740,000. The
legislative body responsible for governing the area is the 29-member
City-County Council elected to four-year terms, 25 from single
districts, 4 at large. The mayor is the executive of the consolidated
city and is elected city-wide.
The consolidated city has six administrative departments below the
mayor's office: Administration, Metropolitan Development, Parks and
Recreation, Public Safety, Public Works and Transportation, and Public
Health. Housed in the executive branch, these departments provide
county-wide services that had previously been performed by 16
independent special-purpose corporations. Six independent municipal
corporations remain outside the consolidated city's direct control.
These corporations tend to be single-function governments (the Health
and Hospital Corporation, the Airport Authority, the Public Transit
Authority, and the Public Library), but they also include the more
broadly chartered Capital Improvement Board and the City-County Building
Authority. Even though these remain independent corporations, the
City-County Council has been given the power to review their budgets and
appoint governing members to their boards.
Other notable government units not contained in Unigov include the
Marion County government, which still exists in a diminished form, and
the county court system. In addition, when Unigov was created, four
municipalities received "excluded cities" status and retained
their own government structures. Another 17 municipalities received the
ambiguous designation of "included towns," which meant that
while they maintained their own local government, they could vote in the
county-city elections because they paid taxes and received certain
consolidated city services. Finally, independent school districts were
left out of the Unigov structure. The disadvantage of this structure is
that it makes for a patchwork in terms of the geographic area and way in
which services are provided.(26)
Despite this somewhat awkward framework, Unigov has provided revenue
benefits to the consolidated city and has permitted revenue
diversification that probably would not have occurred otherwise. Some of
this diversification has been forced on the consolidated city by actions
of the state and federal government, but the enlarged scope of the city
has enabled greater flexibility in dealing with changes in revenue
structure. For example, in 1973 the state legislature passed a
property-tax reform measure designed to limit the growth in the
property-tax rate. Towns were compensated through a state property-tax
replacement fund, whose revenues were derived from an increase in the
sales tax. Since this measure put a limit on future growth in the
property tax, the search for alternative revenues became increasingly
important. Similarly, the decline in federal support, particularly block
grants, made local revenue-raising more important. Unigov helped expand
the fiscal base of the city and allowed the passage of new
revenue-raising options that have not made the central city
prohibitively more expensive (from a tax perspective) than adjacent
communities. A county option income tax was adopted in 1983; a 10
percent county excise tax on automobiles and a wheel tax on trucks were
also adopted. Fees and charges on sewers, solid waste collection,
building permits, and other services have also been adopted, but since
these are county-wide, they do not unduly distort the city's tax
base relative to other communities.
Similarly, Indianapolis has pursued the usual array of tax incentives
to attract and retain businesses in the area, but because it can draw on
the larger tax base of the consolidated city, the cost of the incentives
to the individual town is reduced. In turn, the benefits of added
economic development can be shared countywide. The city-county
government has also used its powers of eminent domain to rationalize
economic development by assembling appropriate parcels of land for
development.
While these measures have helped with both economic growth and
revenue-raising, they have not eliminated disparities in property tax
rates between counties. In 1992 there were 60 applicable property tax
levies and 63 defined taxing jurisdictions within Marion County. Nominal
property tax rates ranged from $7.92 to $13.09 per $100 assessed
valuation. This variation is because certain services are still
supported only by the local tax base, not that of the consolidated city.
In the community with the highest tax rate (Center Township in downtown
Indianapolis), public assistance needs run high and are supported
exclusively by property taxes imposed on Center Township properties.
Finally, one fiscal advantage that Unigov has provided is the ability
to borrow money. The expansion of the city's boundaries to include
the surrounding suburbs has made it easier to finance large-scale
capital projects, since the expanded tax base can support them. It has
also arguably lowered debt costs, since the increased flexibility
provided by the larger and more diverse tax base has led bond rating
agencies to give Indianapolis consistently high debt ratings.(27)
Allegheny Regional Asset District
One of the most recent attempts at regional government is the
Pittsburgh-area Allegheny Regional Asset District.(28) Established in
1994, this governmental body was designed by the County Commissioners to
address five policy objectives: improving and stabilizing funding for
regional assets, correcting funding inequities for Pittsburgh, relieving
overreliance on selected taxes (particularly property taxes), reducing
fiscal disparities between rich and poor communities, and enhancing
regional cooperation. The district has no direct taxing authority but
receives 50 percent of the proceeds from the 1 percent county-wide local
option sales tax. It uses these funds to support so-called regional
crown jewels - amenities located in Allegheny County that benefit all
residents.
In 1995, 30 percent of the district's funds went to parks and 32
percent to libraries. Other recipients were sports venues, cultural
entities, and special facilities such as zoos. Many of these regional
assets are in the city of Pittsburgh and have a recent history of
financial distress. City resources for funding them have become strained
as the central city's growth has lagged that of the suburbs. This
left Pittsburgh in an awkward position. While it was still the heart of
the region's economy, it was having to fund amenities that no
longer primarily benefited city residents. For example, the city zoo was
funded primarily by the city before the district was created, although
75 percent to 85 percent of the visitors to the zoo lived outside the
city limits. The creation of the district has saved the city
approximately $16 million in annual expenditures on this and other crown
jewels.
The county government and 128 municipal governments spend the
remaining 50 percent of the sales tax proceeds on the other policy
objectives endorsed by the County Commissioners. Allegheny County uses
its 25 percent of the total sales tax revenues to reduce property taxes
by 25 percent and to eliminate the county-wide personal property tax.
The remaining funds are distributed to municipalities on a formula basis
that recognizes municipal need. The local governments are required to
use two-thirds of the revenue to reduce local taxes. Specifically,
Pittsburgh is required to use all of its sales tax revenues to eliminate
the city's portion of the personal property tax and to cut the
city's admissions tax for sports and entertainment events from 10
percent to 5 percent.
The district is run by a seven-member citizen board. Board members
may not be public employees, elected officials, or relatives of elected
officials. Four members of the board are appointed by the County
Commissioners and two by the mayor of Pittsburgh; the seventh member is
chosen by the other six from a list of nominees provided by regional
agencies within the area. The governor is also allowed to appoint an
eighth non-voting member. Board members decide which regional assets are
eligible for funding. Although a few assets are specifically excluded
(schools, health care facilities, and parks of less than 200 acres),
virtually anything else can qualify. Funding is provided only if six of
the seven board members approve.
It is too soon to assess the success of the Allegheny County effort,
but as a new experiment in regional government, this method of
supporting regional assets will receive a great deal of attention in the
future. The concept of identifying and supporting assets that benefit
the entire region and enhance its image as a good place to live and work
is intuitively appealing. Thanks to a regional funding structure, the
area's crown jewels can be maintained even if they are located in
places whose tax base can no longer provide the support they require.
Finally, the regional governance structure may foster a more coordinated
strategy for promoting the benefits of the region, rather than those of
individual towns. By supporting regional assets, this structure may
lessen the friction between urban and suburban interests.
Conclusion: Why is metropolitan governance important now?
The purpose of creating a more cohesive metropolitan region is worth
restating. Efficient firms cannot function for very long in
inefficiently configured metropolitan regions. With efficiency and
productivity considerations guiding the development of many firms, local
barriers that prevent firms from improving their situation will
certainly hurt the development prospects of most regions. Metropolitan
governance, or at the very least a mechanism for recognizing regional
goals for development, can help rationalize growth and help prevent the
many problems that occur when each town charts a development course that
provides only for its own interests.
Much of what metropolitan governance can do is related to better land
use planning. Infrastructure and development plans can be coordinated to
ensure that balanced development can occur and that commercial
development is balanced with needed regional amenities such as parks and
open spaces. Ultimately, the purpose of metropolitan governance is to
promote a highly efficient metropolitan region that is properly
configured to support growth in a more rational form. The
characteristics of this metropolitan region would most likely include a
governmental structure that promotes regional planning and
problem-solving, high- or mixed-density bounded-growth communities
surrounded by open space, and greenbelt areas related to mass transit
facilities that move people to and from jobs and shopping centers.
Finally, new jobs would be concentrated in defined employment clusters
where employment growth could best be accommodated.
While the above characteristics are perhaps the ideal, simply
recognizing the linkages within metropolitan regions would benefit
midwestern cities as they attempt to reinvent themselves for the economy
of the next century. Clearly the current pattern of economic growth does
not appear sustainable.
NOTES
1 See Mattoon (1993).
2 Oakland and Testa (1995).
3 For a discussion of issues concerning optimal government size, see
Zax (1988). For a different perspective, see Eberts and Gronberg (1990).
4 Szatan and Testa (1994) chronicle this dynamic.
5 Rusk (1993), p. 14.
6 Hansen (1974).
7 See, for example, Downs (1994) or Rusk (1993).
8 Downs (1994).
9 Bish and Nourse (1975), p. 200.
10 Oates (1977), p. 6.
11 Bish and Nourse (1975), p. 201.
12 Voith (1993), p. 3.
13 For a discussion of "flight from blight," see Voith
(1992).
14 Oakland and Testa (1995).
15 Savitch et al. (1993); Voith (1993).
16 Voith (1992 and 1993), Van Der Veer (1994), and Savitch et al.
(1993).
17 Voith (1993), p. 2.
18 Rothblatt (1993).
19 Ibid.
20 Metro Toronto was created in 1953 to fuse the city of Toronto and
12 of its suburbs into a metropolitan government. It has been widely
hailed as a model of efficiency in land use and infrastructure
development. For an evaluation of Metro Toronto, see Frisken (1993).
21 The following description of Minneapolis-St. Paul's
experience with metropolitan governance is based on Martin (1993).
22 Smith (1994).
23 Martin (1993), p. 207.
24 Blomquest (1994a).
25 Blomquest (1994c).
26 Blomquest (1994b).
27 Kirk (1994).
28 Turner (1995).
REFERENCES
Bish, Robert L., and Hugh O. Nourse, Urban Economics and Policy
Analysis, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1975.
Blomquest, William, "Creation of Unigov," in The
Encyclopedia of Indianapolis, D. Bodenhamer and R. Barrows (eds.),
1994a, pp. 1350-1352.
-----, "Structure of Unigov," in The Encyclopedia of
Indianapolis, D. Bodenhamer and R. Barrows (eds.), 1994b, pp. 1353-1355.
-----, "Unigov and political participation," in The
Encyclopedia of Indianapolis, D. Bodenhamer and R. Barrows (eds.),
1994c, pp. 1355-1358.
Bodenhamer, David J., and Robert G. Barrows, eds., The Encyclopedia
of Indianapolis, Bloomington and Indianapolis, IN: Indiana University
Press, 1994.
Downs, Anthony, New Visions for Metropolitan America, Washington, DC:
The Brookings Institution and Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land
Policy, 1994.
Eberts, Randall W., and Timothy J. Gronberg, "Can competition
among local governments constrain government spending?" Economic
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, First Quarter 1988, pp. 2-9.
-----, "Structure, conduct and performance in the local public
sector," National Tax Journal, Vol. 43, No. 2, 1990, pp. 165-173.
Frisken, Frances, "Planning and servicing the greater Toronto
area: The interplay of provincial and municipal interests," in
Metropolitan Governance: American/Canadian Intergovernmental
Perspectives, D. Rothblatt and A. Sancton (eds.), 1993, pp. 153-204.
Hansen, Niles M., "Regional policy in the United States,"
in Public Policy and Regional Economic Development, Niles M. Hansen
(ed.), Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Press, 1974, pp. 271-304.
Kirk, Robert, "Unigov and public finance," in The
Encyclopedia of Indianapolis, D. Bodenhamer and R. Barrows (eds.), 1994,
pp. 1358-1360.
Martin, Judith, "In fits and starts: The Twin Cities
metropolitan framework," in Metropolitan Governence:
American/Canadian Intergovernmental Perspectives, D. Rothblatt and A.
Sancton (eds.), 1993, pp. 205-244.
Mattoon, Richard H., "Economic development policy in the 1990s -
Are state economic development agencies ready?" Economic
Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 17, No. 3, May/June
1993, pp. 11-23.
Norton, R.D., City Life-Cycles and American Urban Policy, New York:
Academic Press, 1979.
Oakland, William H., and William A. Testa, "Does business
development raise taxes?" Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, Vol. 19, No. 2, March/April 1995, pp. 22-32.
Oates, Wallace E., "An economist's perspective on fiscal
federalism," in The Political Economy of Fiscal Federalism, Wallace
E. Oates (ed.), Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1977, pp. 3-20.
Rothblatt, Donald N., "Summary and conclusions," in
Metropolitan Governance: American/Canadian Intergovernmental
Perspectives, D. Rothblatt and A. Sancton (eds.), 1993.
Rothblatt, Donald N., and Andrew Sancton, eds., Metropolitan
Governance: American/Canadian Intergovernmental Perspectives, Berkeley,
CA: Institute of Government Studies Press, 1993.
Rusk, David, Cities Without Suburbs, Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson
Center Press, 1993.
Savitch, H.V., David Collins, Daniel Sanders, and John P. Markham,
"The ties that bind: Central cities, suburbs and the new
metropolitan region," Economic Development Quarterly, Vol. 7, No.
4, November 1993, pp. 341-357.
Smith, David A., "Comprehensive tax base sharing,"
Commentary, Center for Urban Economic Development, Washington, DC,
Summer 1994, pp. 17-22.
Szatan, Jerry W., and William A. Testa, "Metropolitan areas
spread out," Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
No. 83, July 1994.
Tiebout, C., "A pure theory of local expenditures," Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 64, No. 5, October 1956, pp. 416-424.
Turner, James W., "The Allegheny Regional Asset District:
Communities thinking and acting like a region," Government Finance
Review, June 1995, pp. 19-22.
Van Der Veer, Jeroen, "Metropolitan government and city-suburban
cleavages: Differences between old and young metropolitan areas,"
Urban Studies, Vol. 31, No. 7, 1994, pp. 1057-1079.
Voith, Richard P., "City and suburban growth: Substitutes or
complements?" Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, September/October 1992, pp. 21-33.
-----, "Does city income growth increase suburban income growth,
house value appreciation, and population growth?" Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, working paper no. 93-27, November 1993.
Zax, Jeffrey S., "The effects of jurisdiction types and numbers
on local public finance," in Fiscal Federalism: Quantitative
Studies, Harvey Rosen (ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988,
pp. 79-103.
Richard H. Mattoon is a senior regional economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. The author wishes to thank William A. Testa for
reviewing earlier drafts of this article.