Activating labor market and social policies in Germany: from status protection to basic income support.
Eichhorst, Werner ; Grienberger-Zingerle, Maria ; Konle-Seidl, Regina 等
1 Introduction
Although Germany has a long-standing reputation as a passive
welfare state with elaborate schemes of status-protecting income
replacement through social insurance in case of unemployment and a
full-blown system of active labor market policies, all benefit systems
had formal elements of activation and work requirement--but they had not
been enforced systematically. In recent years, however, reforms of
active and passive labor market policy were implemented in Germany in
order to create a more activating labor market and social policy regime
and awake dormant activation principles. Changing the system of
unemployment insurance benefits and basic income support as well as the
repertoire of active labor market policy instruments and making benefit
receipt more conditional upon job search and acceptance of job offers
was a major issue on the political agenda. This led to a system shift
away from "Bismarckian" status-protecting benefits towards a
more "Beveridgean" model of income support with strong
activation requirements. In the realm of unemployment benefits the
dominant regime is no longer a social insurance benefit but a
means-tested flat-rat transfer. The reform of the benefit system also
involved a major overhaul of the governance of labor market policy and
has far-reaching implications for the logic of the German welfare state.
All these reforms generated considerable public attention and interest
from foreign observers. This article provides an indepth account of the
institutional change, its practical implementation and midterm outcomes
and assesses if the desired economic and societal objectives of
activation could be achieved through the adopted reforms.
2 The Shift towards Activation
The Legacy of a Conservative European Welfare State
The German welfare state is typically depicted as the prime example
of the conservative welfare regime, for which the preservation of social
status is central (Esping-Andersen 1990). It has also been prominently
characterized as a "frozen welfare state" highly resistant to
change (Manow and Seils 2000). Facing a difficult economic environment
since the mid-seventies, policy makers and social partners used active
and passive labor market policies to reduce labor supply by taking
"surplus labor" out of the labor market and shifting the
unemployed to benefit schemes and active programs that were not
effectively oriented towards swift reintegration into the labor market
(Manow and Seils 2000). For some decades, active and passive labor
market policies provided a "convenient" and "socially
acceptable" way of subsidizing entrepreneurial adjustment to
dynamic global markets and help stabilize competitiveness of
manufacturing that was at the core of the German employment system
(Streeck 1997) while at the same time facilitating a "social
policy" approach to unemployment emphasizing income protection and
"benevolent" treatment through active policies. Availability
of rather generous insurance-based social benefits related to labor
market status and skills in the tradition of a "Bismarckian"
model helped limiting income inequality and wage dispersion. Rather than
creating a flexible and more inclusive labor market, the institutional
arrangement of the German labor market of the eighties and nineties was
conducive to limiting low-wage employment and wage inequality. This
model focusing skilled labor was also stabilized by rather restrictive
labor market regulation (Estevez-Abe et al. 2001).
Whereas this institutional pattern helped stabilize the core of the
labor market, it also resulted in a strong segmentation of the labor
market and high long-term unemployment. However, the German "high
equality, low activity" equilibrium (Streeck 2001) resulted in an
ever increasing burden of non-wage labor costs as a growing number of
benefit recipients in the labor market directly translated into rising
social security contributions and fiscal pressure on the state budget
that was used to cover deficits in social insurance. Thus, the
sustainability of the German "welfare state without work"
(Esping-Andersen 1996) was at risk as it tended to erode its own
financial basis in particular facing increasing pressure on wage costs
stemming from more intense international competition (Manow and Seils
2000).
The old system of unemployment benefits
Prior to the Hartz reforms that came into force between 2002 and
2005, Germany had a three-tier system of income protection in case of
unemployment:
* Unemployment insurance benefit (UB, Arbeitslosengeld) provided
earnings-related income replacement for a limited duration of up to 32
months if the unemployed had been in employment covered by social
insurance for at least 12 months. Unemployment insurance benefits were
funded through employer and employee contributions and administered by
the Federal Employment Agency which was also in charge of implementing
active labor market policies.
* Unemployment assistance (UA, Arbeitslosenhilfe) was a system of
means-tested, but earnings-related benefits for long-term unemployed
after the expiry of unemployment insurance benefits. Hence, it provided
income support for unemployed that had some prior employment experience
but had become long-term unemployed. Unemployment assistance was granted
for an unlimited period and funded through the Federal budget, i.e. by
general taxation. This scheme was also implemented by the Federal
Employment Agency, with recipients of unemployment assistance in
principle having access to similar active labor market schemes.
* Social assistance (SA, Sozialhilfe), finally, provided basic
income protection on a means-tested and flat-rate basis for all German
inhabitants--with or without employment experience--who could not rely
on sufficient resources from earned income, other social benefits or
family transfers. Thus, social assistance was the major protection
system for unemployed with either no employment record or unemployment
insurance/unemployment assistance claims that did not match the
guaranteed minimum income. Social assistance was funded by the
municipalities that were also responsible for reintegrating recipients
into the labor market through specific active measures.
In comparison to unemployment assistance, means-testing was harsher
in social assistance, moreover, any job was considered acceptable. For
labor market integration of employable social assistance recipients, a
fairly rudimentary labor market policy, the "Help to Work"
scheme, was available. It was operated by the municipalities with a
considerable scope of discretion. There was no entitlement to
integration measures by the public employment service (PES).
All these systems had formal elements of activation and work
requirements, but these provisions were not systematically enforced in
practice. For example, the "Help to Work" scheme (Hilfe zur
Arbeit) incorporated in the Social Assistance Act ([section][section] 18
to 20 BSHG) was based on the "rights and obligation"
principle. The BSHG nevertheless failed to state specific provisions on
the reasonability of job offers. Court rulings have tended to show that
a protection of former occupational status no longer exists. Personal
grounds are above all seen in age or sickness, while familial grounds
mainly take account of a single parent's care of a child under the
age of three. Despite the fact that the law on social assistance called
for individual efforts to search for work in order to be able to become
independent from public assistance, activating interventions were not
implemented systematically. Some local authorities were able to achieve
remarkably good results in reintegrating assistance applicants under the
"Help to Work" scheme. However, the intensity of activation
differed strongly between municipalities, and many local authorities
placed social assistance recipients in work opportunities that were
covered by social insurance in order to create new entitlements to
unemployment insurance benefits. This proved to be an effective way of
shifting the burden of transfer payment to unemployment insurance. The
fact that the two predecessor schemes of the current Unemployment
Benefit II ("Arbeitslosen geld II") were subject to different
rules and administered by different bodies hampered efficient activation
of recipients.
Suitability criteria in unemployment insurance were also tightened
over the nineties. The formal strictness of the unemployment protection
regime was increased as legal provisions on benefits being conditional
upon willingness to work and accept jobs not equivalent to prior
qualification were reformulated in a more restrictive direction with
occupational protection being revoked completely in 1997. The main
motivation, however, was not effective activation, but short-term fiscal
stabilization. At the same time, access to benefits became slightly more
difficult, and benefit generosity was reduced marginally. Nevertheless,
a rather "permissive" and benefit-centered approach to
unemployment was still dominant in practical implementation.
The Hartz reforms
With the number of recipients of unemployment and social assistance
benefits steeply rising, largely due to a continuous increase in
long-term unemployment, reforming these systems became a priority on the
agenda of labor market and social policy. In the late nineties, the
problem of fiscal disincentives was more widely discussed, thus paving
the way to some pilot projects on joint initiatives of local PES
agencies and municipal social assistance offices to reintegrate the
long-term unemployed into the labor market ("Mozart
initiative"). This was followed by the JobAqtiv Act of late 2001
that, for the first time, aimed at a more coherent activation principle
in Germany labor market policies. However, the moderate attempt of
JobAqtiv was superposed by the PES placement scandal and the work of the
Hartz Commission, a government-initiated expert committee that presented
its report in August 2002. This report formed the base for a package of
reforms aiming at activating both short-and long-term unemployed,
reforming the PES and the institutional repertoire of active schemes.
Finally, with the Fourth Hartz Act (widely known under the label
"Hartz IV") coming into force in January 2005, unemployment
assistance and social assistance were replaced by a single means-tested
benefit scheme for persons in need and able to work (Arbeitslosengeld
II, UB II) but not entitled to unemployment insurance benefit or after
expiry of this contribution-based benefit (Arbeitslosengeld I, UB I).
Besides UB II, the new basic income scheme provides social
allowance (Sozialgeld) to persons who live together with needy persons
capable of working in a joint household (Bedarfsgemeinschaft) (1). The
recipients of social allowance are normally children below the working
age of 15 years. Those incapable of work receive social assistance
according to SGB XII which continues to be the responsibility of the
municipalities (see table 1).
Table 1: The Old and the New Benefit System
Old System (until 2004) New System (since 2005)
Arbeitslosengeld(unemployment Arbeitslosengeld I (UB I): funded
insurance benefit): funded through through
contributions, earnings-related, contributions,earnings-related,
limited duration limited duration
Arbeitslosenhilfe(earnings-related Grundsicherung fur Arbeitsuchende
unemployment assistance): (Basicincomescheme for needy
tax-funded, earnings-related, jobseekers) Consisting of
means-tested, infinite duration Arbeitslosengeld II (UB II):
tax-funded, means-tested, flat
rate, after expiry of UB I (and
temporary supplement), infinite
duration (integration of
"Arbeitslo-senhilfe" and
"Sozialhilfe" for people capable
of working ) but stronger
principle of activation
Sozialgeld(social allowance)
especially for kids below the
working age of 15 living in a
household of an UB II recipient
Sozialhilfe(social assistance): Grundsicherung fur
tax-funded, means-tested, flat Erwerbsgeminderteund im
rate, infinite duration Alter(social assistance):
means-tested, tax-funded for
those working age people not
capable of working and for needy
persons above 65 years
Hartz IV radically changed the German system of unemployment
benefits. The new Unemployment Benefit II scheme has a dual aim: on the
one hand it was designed to prevent poverty--but not to secure previous
living standards. Thus, for those having received social assistance
before, the new legislation actually allows them to receive marginally
higher benefits and access to job employment services. For many former
recipients of unemployment assistance the level of transfer payment
decreased.
Apart from its social policy objective, the aim of this reform was
to lower unemployment but also to ease the burden of taxation and
non-wage labor costs by reducing benefit dependency. The major lever to
achieve this goal was the shortening of individual unemployment spells
through accelerated job placement and more coherent activation of the
beneficiaries of unemployment insurance benefits and unemployment as
well as social assistance. Less generous benefits for long-term
unemployed, stricter job suitability criteria and more effective job
placement and active labor market schemes were the instruments to
achieve this goal. However, as termination of need is the core
objective, there is no formal labor market availability criterion for UB
II recipients. But the suitability criterion was further tightened.
Benefit recipients can be demanded to take up any job and follow
obligations stemming from integration agreements. For activation to
become an effective answer to benefit dependency, the labor market,
however, must improve its capacities to create jobs (Eichhorst and
Konle-Seidl 2006). Therefore part of the Hartz package was devoted to a
(limited) flexibilization of the labor market (Jacobi and Kluve 2006,
Eichhorst and Kaiser 2006). This was not right at the core of activating
labor market policy, but should facilitate it.
The explicit practical enforcement of "rights and
duties", how-ever, is the core element of the Hartz reforms. The
activation strategy is implemented in virtually every element of the
labor market policy framework. The Hartz reforms shift priority towards
active measures that require proactive behavior of the unemployed and
promote their direct integration into regular employment. To this end,
the reform re-designed integration subsidies, introduced new forms of
wage subsidies, start-up subsidies and jobs with reduced social security
contributions.
The political logic behind the policy shift
Germany's rather late, but broad and massive shift to
activation or--more precisely--awakening of "dormant"
activating principles was the direct result of a long period of reform
blockage and postponement in labor market policy. One explanation is
German reunification. As a consequence of reunification in Germany, not
the restructuring, but the expansion of traditional instruments of
active labor market policies, particularly job creation schemes, but
also passive income support was on the agenda in the beginning of the
1990s (Manow and Seils 2000). Another explanation refers to the strong
role of social partner self-administration in the public employment
service (Trampusch 2002) that were interested in controlling resource
allocation to favor their clientele, take "surplus labor" out
of the labor market and shift it to active and passive labor market
policies and other social benefit schemes while deficits in unemployment
insurance were covered by the federal government or higher
contributions. Labor market policies in Germany helped to create and
sustain the illusion that the "implicit contract" of rewarding
previous contributions of the unemployed to the German economy--through
benefits and labor market measures--was still intact. In fact, this
contract had been undermined to a considerable degree for an increasing
number of long-term unemployed who, in addition to their often meager
Arbeitslosenhilfe, had to rely on So-zialhilfe payments, thus receiving
financial support that was only related to need and not to previous
labor market achievement.
This resulted in rising non-wage labor costs which in turn hampered
employment creation. Despite the fact that rather critical evaluation
studies on active labor market policies and employment disincentives in
benefit systems had become available in the late 1990s, a more
fundamental overhaul of active and passive labor market policies was
virtually a non-issue in the Germany political economy until the early
years of the current decade. Reforms in this area would have questioned
the implicit "social treatment" of unemployment and implied a
more prominent role of low-wage employment as a tool of labor market
re-entry for the long-term unemployed as well as a more general
flexibilization of the labor market.
The Red-Green coalition that came into power in 1998 was divided on
this issue, with the major fragmentation between different wings of the
social democratic parties. On the one hand, the new government revoked
some of the restrictive provisions of the prior
Christian-Democratic/Liberal government (i.e. full continuation of
payments to sick workers) and tried to stabilize the "social
policy" approach to unemployment. On the other hand, it tried to
develop a more coherent normative framework for labor market and welfare
state reforms referring to the concept of the "activating
state" which was mainly inspired by New Labor and "third
way" approaches formulated in the United Kingdom (Giddens 1999).
The concept of the "activating state" would have meant
focusing public interventions on "enabling" programs that
could help individuals take their own responsibility. In labor market
policy, this implied stressing the conditionality of benefits upon
individual efforts and cooperation, thus emphasizing the fundamental
symmetry of "rights and obligations". As it would also mean a
break with the tradition of a status-protecting and occupation-oriented
welfare state, this concept met only limited acceptance and strong
opposition from major fractions within the Social Democrats. Maybe the
best example for this reluctance is the rejection of the alleged
"neo-liberal" Schroder/Blair paper in 1999. Hence, activation
could not become a more systematic point of reference or an elaborated
concept in the early years of the Red-Green coalition.
Reform stalemate could only be overcome in the face of the window
of opportunity of the "placement scandal" and the sub-sequent
Hartz report in 2002 with an expert commission legitimizing further
reforms of labor market policy and regulation, changing the role of
social partner tripartism in the German PES, the Bundesagentur fur
Arbeit (BA) and national policy-making, thus paving the way for more
determined government action (Streeck and Trampusch 2005).
Activation was reintroduced by the report of the Hartz Commission
who made references to good practices at the national levels, e.g.
models of effective cooperation between BA and municipalities in
selected "Mozart" projects, as well as international
"best practices" and benchmarking of labor market performance
and policies. Hence, the Hartz reforms focus was inspired by activating
policies for the unemployed in other European countries that were
perceived to be more successful in lowering unemployment such as the
United Kingdom, the Netherlands or Denmark (Bruttel and Kemmerling 2006,
Eichhorst et al., Fleckenstein 2004).
Government's willingness to implement the Hartz proposals in a
comprehensive way implied further clarification of crucial issues such
as the level of the unified benefit for long-term unemployed that was to
replace unemployment assistance and social assistance for people capable
of working (erwerbsfahige Hilfebedurftige). With the "Agenda
2010" announced in March 2003 in a situation of high and rising
unemployment and considerable political pressure it became clear that
the government would opt for a flat-rate benefit with about the same
level as social assistance thus effectively severing the link with prior
earnings. This was to be implemented with the fourth Hartz Act in
January 2005. In addition, the government announced shortening
unemployment insurance benefit duration for older workers from 32 to 18
months and to cut dismissal protection and other elements of labor
market regulation (Jantz 2004).
This sequence of rather "harsh" reforms that were
perceived as a break with traditional social policy approach to labor
market problems provoked broad public unrest that eventually resulted in
a significant decline in political support for the red-green coalition,
in particular the Social Democrats, the emergence of a new left-wing
party and the electoral defeat of Red-Green coalition in autumn 2005
(Eichhorst and Sesselmeier 2006). (2)
Opposition was strongest in the Eastern part of Germany (Rucht and
Yang 2004). There, long-term unemployed could rely on relatively high
and unlimited unemployment assistance payments due to widespread
full-time employment of both men and women in the former GDR. Hence,
abolishing earnings-related benefits, replacing them with flat-rate
benefits and introducing a stricter activation policy was perceived as a
threat to individual well being in particular given the poor labor
market perspectives in East Germany.
Therefore, Hartz IV was perceived as a "social cruelty"
that would result in severe benefit cuts, increasing poverty, strict
supervision of jobseekers and forcing people in low-wage jobs, thus
leading to a growing number of "working poor" and a tacit
"Americanization" of the German labor market, something that
had to be avoided by any means. Thus, Hartz IV became the symbol for a
policy that was seen as a break with the principle of "the social
insurance state" of providing status-oriented benefits while
imposing only limited demands on unemployed. Even to date, there is no
societal consensus on policy objectives in labor market policies. Hence,
the paradigm shift to activation is not complete yet. Moreover there is
a dominating sense of injustice. It is fair to argue that the broad
rejection of the Hartz IV reform is due to a fundamental deficit of
legitimating the "hidden" or silent shift from a social
insurance state to a welfare state dominated by basic income support and
stronger activation.
The Silent Change of the Welfare State Logic: From Bismarck to
Beveridge?
Despite on-going reforms since the mid-1990s, it is frequently
argued that the Hartz IV law marks a critical juncture resulting in the
departure from a conservative welfare state securing acquired standards
of living and a move towards an Anglo-Saxon welfare state relying on
means-tested welfare and securing only basic needs. Activation is not an
entirely new thing for Germany and has been reinforced step by step even
before the Hartz Reforms, but the activation paradigm was not seriously
implemented until the Hartz reforms. More specifically, the Hartz IV
reform is part of a long-term shift from "Bismarck" to
"Beveridge" in that it weakened the principle of status
protection and contribution-equivalence in unemployment benefits for the
long-term unemployed and strengthened the role of means-tested flat-rate
benefits providing a minimum income floor only. (3) At the same time,
however, stricter means-testing and flat-rate benefits imply a higher
degree of interpersonal redistribution. Table 2 shows the relationship
between recipients of contribution-based and means-tested flat-rate
benefits in 2005 and 2007.
Table 2: Contribution-based and means-tested unemployment
benefits (2005 and 2007), in 1.000
Type of benefit Total Registered Share of
number unemployed registered
of benefit unemployed
recipients in %
2005
Insurance scheme (UB I) 1.730 2.091 43
Means-tested scheme (UB II) 4.980 2.770 57
Total UB I and UB II 6.710 4.861 100
2007
Insurance scheme (UB I) 1.079 1.253 33
Means-tested scheme (UB II) 5.277 2.523 67
Total UB I and UB II 6.247 3.776 100
Source: Bundesagentur fur Arbeit.
To secure social status and the acquired standard of living, the
unemployment benefit and the previous unemployment assistance referred
to the former income. The duration of the unemployment benefit varied
strongly according to age. Until early 2006 drawing benefits for up to
32 months was possible for older workers, thus stressing a widely
perceived "savings account logic" of unemployment insurance.
In the old system, a person becoming unemployed was entitled to
unemployment insurance benefits for a certain period if he/she had an
employment record of at least one year during the past few years. This
benefit initially amounted to more than two thirds of the previous
income with an inbuild ceiling in accordance to the "equivalence
principle", and thus "rewarded" prior earnings and
effort. The higher an individual's achievements during his or her
employment career, the higher the benefits. Older workers with a longer
employment record could rely on extended unemployment insurance
benefits.
When unemployment benefits were exhausted, the unemployed could
apply for unemployment assistance which was still related to previous
earnings but on a lower level. Although unemployment assistance was
tax-funded, it was seen as a prolongation of unemployment insurance
benefit (Karl et al. 2002). The "equivalence principle" was
complemented by the principle of "occupational protection"
that defined the "suitable job" an unemployed person had to
accept as more or less adequate to the position held before becoming
unemployed. Last but not least, persons relying on unemployment
insurance benefits could also benefit from heavy investment in
"enabling" active labor market policy schemes. These programs
were not primarily used as a work-test but as instruments to stabilize
human capital and restore benefit claims.
Hence, removing occupational protection (as early as in 1997), but
more specifically, shortening benefit duration in unemployment insurance
for older workers and abolishing earnings-related unemployment
assistance means a departure form status protection and the strong
reliance on the insurance principle and the equivalence of contributions
and benefits. Abolishing longer benefit durations for older unemployed
and earnings-related unemployment assistance was seen as an
"expropriation". As the reform interfered with widely accepted
principles of "social justice" embodied in an insurance-based
system, this change was perceived as "unfair" in particular
given the fear of increased economic pressure not only due to lower and
less sufficient benefits but also due to the announcement of stricter
activation and placement even in low-wage jobs. While such prospects are
well established and generally accepted in countries like the United
States or the UK, they mean an overhaul of established notions of the
German social model which strongly rests on what could be called
"social security citizenship" (Ludwig-Mayerhofer 2005). (4)
This is not to say that means-tested benefits and activation provisions
did not exist before, but they have now become the major principle of
the German unemployment benefit regime both in terms of claimant figures
and normative points of reference.
3 Activating Labor Market Policy after Hartz
The general framework
The first and foremost objective of activating labor market policy
in Germany is the reduction of individual unemployment duration by
bringing unemployed persons, in particularly the long-term unemployed,
back to work.
The basic principle of activating labor market policy in Germany is
"Fordern und Fordern", i.e. enabling or supporting the
jobseekers on the one hand and demanding individual effort on the other.
The recent reforms are in fact a recalibration of the Janus-faced nature
of the German welfare state emphasizing both the role of demanding
provisions (Fordern) and the enabling or empowering elements of social
and labor market policy (Fordern). In the past, benefits could be
received without meeting activation requirements in practice but rather
expecting to be placed in active labor market schemes in a
"benevolent" way. While activation principles have been in
place for some time under former social assistance and in the well
established active labor market policy framework, what is new is a
tighter conceptual and practical linking of promoting and demanding
elements (Fordern durch Fordern). These general orientations were
explicitly fixed in the new SGB II (Second Book of the German Social
Security Act, Sozialgesetzbuch II).
The concept of individual "co-production" by needy
persons "capable of work" replaces the former paternalistic
model. As participation in the labor market is assumed to be the high
road to societal integration, taking up work is superior to receiving
passive benefits only. Formal terms defining the basic orientation of
German activating labor market policy, however, open up ample space for
divergent interpretations that are crucial for actual implementation.
Complementary to activating instruments in a more narrow sense, SGB
II comprises enabling schemes such as labor market policy programs
([section] 16 (1) SGB II) and other social services like child care
provision or help in case of social problems like drug abuse or debts
([section] 16 (2) SGB II) that have been conceived in order to
facilitate labor market integration of employable benefit recipients,
but do not reinforce benefit conditionality.
Target Groups
First and foremost, activating measures address the target group of
unemployed persons--both UB I and UB II recipients. To avoid long-term
unemployment, which begins after 12 months according to both the German
and the European definition, these persons have to register promptly
with the local employment offices as soon as unemployment is
foreseeable.
The medical definition of "capability of working" (not
employability) with three hours a day in the foreseeable future under
the usual conditions of the labor market results in a rather broad
demarcation of the target groups which exceeds the focus of activation
in many other European countries. This contributes to higher figures of
open (registered) unemployment while in other countries a narrow
definition of employability means fewer people registered as unemployed
but assigned to passive schemes such as disability benefits.
"Capability of working" (Erwerbsfahigkeit) features
prominently as the overall concept of this approach. The individual
working ability is evaluated purely from a medical standpoint. It is
decided by the institution responsible for the safety net, i.e. usually
the local employment office.
Certain subgroups of persons "capable of working" are
exempted from the availability criterion under the unemployment
insurance regime (UB I) and the conditional job search requirement under
basic income support (UB II). This holds for sick people and for persons
that take care of children under the age of three or care for family
members as well as for older persons. However, there is a contradictory
approach regarding to older persons with some enabling schemes on the
one hand (wage subsidies and wage insurance) and an explicit provision
exempting them from the obligation to be available for work.
Accordingly, these persons receive public support but are not obliged to
seek or accept employment--nor are they recorded as unemployed in the
statistics as they are expected to move to the old-age pension system as
soon as possible (Eichhorst 2006).
Persons with disabilities form an additional group at the core of
the legislator's activating strategy. These persons are not subject
to the same requirements as other unemployed persons, in particular
their rights to support are less tightly linked to duties. The prime
objective since many years, however, is to promote participation in
working life. The principle of supporting rehabilitation measures
instead of paying passive income support for disabled people is a basic
feature of German active labor market policy. Furthermore, access to
passive schemes like disability allowance is rather restrictive and not
seen as an attractive "escape route" like in most other
European countries (Konle-Seidl and Lang 2006). (5)
Demanding and promoting under SGB III (unemployment insurance)
The role of demanding and promoting elements (Fordern und Fordern)
differ with respect to individual rights and obligations between
unemployment insurance (Third Book of the Social Security Act, SGB III)
and basic income support (Second Book of the Social Security Act, SGB
II).
The claim to unemployment insurance benefit under [section] 118(1)
SGB III arises in the event of unemployment and further vocational
training. Workers entitled to this unemployment benefit must be
unemployed and registered with the employment office and must have
fulfilled the qualifying period.
Unemployed persons pursuant to [section] 119(1) SGB III are persons
without work, seek to end their unemployment (personal efforts) and are
available for the placement efforts of the Employment Agency
(availability). Persons are considered to be without work if they do not
work at all or if they work less than 15 hours per week. To be
available, the unemployed person must be capable of working and be
prepared to work, i.e. have the subjective will to work.
Unemployed persons have to devote personal efforts in order to
utilize all possibilities available for their occupational integration
([section] 119 (4) SGB III). These efforts include the performance of
duties set forth in the integration agreement, participation in
third-party placement services and the use of self-information
facilities provided by the Employment Agencies.
The concept of personal effort bears activating features in that
the search for employment is a precondition for the receipt of
unemployment benefit. The nearest sanction for lack of personal effort
is the imposition of a disqualification period. Unemployed are deemed
available for the placement efforts if, inter alia, they are capable of
and allowed to exercise an occupation which can be reasonably expected
of them under the usual conditions of the labor market to be considered
by them, and which is subject to compulsory insurance and comprises a
weekly working time of no less than 15 hours. An important criterion of
this definition is "suitability", which is detailed in
[section] 121 SGB III and purports that an unemployed person can be
expected to perform all occupations conforming to his or her working
capabilities to the extent that general or personal grounds do not
oppose the reasonability of such an employment offer.
In contrast to basic income protection, not all jobs are considered
suitable for unemployment insurance beneficiaries. There is not only a
minimum threshold of 15 hours per week, but also a minimum level of
earnings to be achieved that is related to prior wages and to the
benefit levels. In earlier times, the protection of an acquired earnings
level and occupation was even stronger. But the principle of
occupational protection had been eroded to a considerable degree in 1997
when new legislation stipulated that after six months of unemployment
any job was suitable that provides at least earnings equivalent to
unemployment compensation.
Nevertheless, until 1998 it was possible to stabilize and renew
claims for unemployment insurance benefits through participation in
publicly funded training programs and until 2003 in direct public job
creation. These options have now been abolished. Additionally, the Hartz
legislation strengthened availability criteria by defining removal
reasonable and just in case of single unemployed and by shifting the
burden of proof in case of rejection of job offers to the unemployed.
Last but not least, the cut in maximum benefit duration from 32 to 18
months for unemployed aged 55 and over (effective since 1 February 2006)
means that older unemployed move to means-tested basic income support
earlier in their unemployment spell.
Demanding and promoting principles under SGB II (Basic Income
Scheme)
Basic income support for needy jobseekers (Grundsicherung fur
Arbeitsuchende) has the double aim of
* providing sufficient minimum resources to ensure a decent
standard of living in order to avoid poverty and
* ending benefit dependency through reintegration into gainful
employment.
Basic income support for jobseekers is awarded under [section] 7
SGB II to persons who have attained the age of 15 but are still under
65, are capable of gainful employment, in need of assistance and have
their customary place of abode in the Federal Republic of Germany.
According to [section] 1 Abs. 1 SGB II "people capable of
working" should overcome need through their own efforts and their
own means. An individual is needy if he/she is unable to earn a living
for him/herself and for the other family members living together in one
household. The individual in question is required to take on an
acceptable job and use his own income and (certain) assets as well as
that of his/her partner. Legislation on basic income support (SGB II)
pursues foremost social objectives. It provides a needs-oriented income
so that all needy persons in Germany have sufficient means of
subsistence.
Although basic income support for needy jobseekers is foremost a
genuine social policy program to avoid poverty it has a strong focus on
the labor market. With Hartz IV, the interface of social and labor
market policy has been redefined and the traditional divide between both
policy areas eroded. It focuses on need (not on unemployment as such)
and on interventions to reduce need--with attempts at labor market
integration featuring prominently as a promising way to end benefit
dependency.
Thus, the new regime of basic income points at personal
responsibility and at enabling and supporting interventions in order to
enhance individual capacities to overcome need. Labor market
availability and willingness to take up any job--even below wages set by
collective agreements or public employment opportunities--are therefore
crucial elements of activation addressing recipients of basic income
support as long as they are capable of work. At the same time, however,
UB II recipients can keep their benefit if they take up low-wage jobs
that fit into the earnings disregard clause. The current provision
stipulates that the first EUR 100 of monthly earnings are not taken into
account when benefits are calculated whereas between EUR 100 and 800 20%
remain with the beneficiaries as is true for 10% of earnings between EUR
800 and EUR 1.200 for singles or EUR 1.500 in case of UB II recipients
with children.
Pursuant to [section] 19 SGB II, UB II consists of benefits to
secure subsistence, including reasonable costs of accommodation and
heating and a fixed-term supplementary allowance under [section] 24 SGB
II to cushion the transition from unemployment insurance to Unemployment
Benefit II. It provides two thirds of the difference between UB I and UB
II for twelve months and one third for an additional year.
The normal benefit under [section] 20(2) and (4) SGB II is a
lump-sum amount that is supposed to cover all living expenses. From 1
July 2008, this amount has been fixed at a standard rate of EUR 351
throughout the federal territory. Benefits for accommodation and heating
are specified in [section] 22 SGB II. Their amount is equivalent to the
actual expenses, provided these are reasonable.
This standard payment is higher than former social assistance (EUR
295 as of July 2004). For children the standard payments are lower.
Nevertheless SA benefits included more additional payments than UB II.
In comparison to former unemployment assistance (on average EUR 550 in
2003 in Western Germany) UB II is less generous. This should result in
pressure on the jobless to take on work. However, it should to be taken
into account that, whereas the recipients of UB II receive payments for
housing and heating, the former UA recipients could only qualify for
supplementary housing and social assistance if they fulfilled special
conditions.
Hence, contrary to widespread beliefs, the new UB II is not in
general lower than prior benefits. This holds for virtually all former
social assistance beneficiaries, but also for a relevant share of all
former unemployment assistance recipients. Simulation studies show that
about one sixth of them lost its benefit entitlement due to the stricter
consideration of wealth or earned income. Of the remaining persons with
continued benefit claims, about 47 percent receive higher benefits, and
about 53 percent have net losses (Blos and Rudolph 2005). Former
unemployment assistance beneficiaries are affected unequally, however,
with net gains concentrated among the young and the lone parents while
older beneficiaries and couples with relatively high benefits under
earnings-related unemployment assistance suffered from considerable
cuts. This is mainly true for East Germany (65% losers) where long-term
unemployed with a substantial employment record in the GDR and
subsequent receipt of higher unemployment assistance are now transferred
to flat-rate UB II (Becker and Hauser 2006, Blos and Rudolph 2005, see
figures 1 and 2).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Basic income can also be received in all cases of need where
resources from work and other income are not sufficient to pass the
threshold income set by law (i.e. additional UB II). Hence, basic income
support does not only focus on registered unemployed without
entitlements to unemployment insurance benefits, but also on people in
school and training or in dependent employment if they pass the
means-test. The same holds for self-employed. In contrast to former
social assistance, UB II recipients are covered by both statutory health
insurance and old-age pension insurance which also means that
self-employed can receive health insurance coverage at a low premium
under UB II.
Although the legislator defined the prerequisite for UB II
receipt--capability of working--in a legally unequivocal manner, two
problematic issues have been quick to emerge: For one thing, unequivocal
assignment is not a question of law; rather, whether a person can work
for at least three hours daily is a factual problem that is certain to
raise dispute. The term "capable of working" is a criterion of
delimitation vis-a-vis social assistance, since only persons capable of
gainful employment can be expected to earn their living consistently and
primarily through their own work. Consequently, there is a need for the
various benefit institutions to reach a uniform decision on this issue.
The essential aim of consistently placing persons able to work for at
least three hours a day and also members of their Bedarfsgemeinschaft
under a single regime (either SGB II or SGB XII) has been judicially
confirmed, and the relevant decisions have found approval in the
literature (Berlit 2005, Luthe 2005).
In January 2005, more than 90 percent of former social assistance
have been assessed as "capable of working" and consequently
transferred from municipal responsibility to the new basic income
support scheme financed out of taxes at the Federal level. However,
first analyses by the BA regarding the structure of long-term unemployed
recipients of UB II show that about half of all UB II beneficiaries have
a considerable distance to the labor market. This holds in particular
for long-term unemployed without vocational training, over 50 years of
age, with severe health problems or a migration background especially in
regions with high unemployment. About 400.000 to 600.000 people assessed
as capable of working obviously have severe barriers to labor market
integration.
The Personal Integration Agreement
The results of an individual profiling process at the employment
offices are set out in a binding integration agreement. This written
agreement states both the services that will be provided to the job
seeker as well as the job seeker's obligation regarding job search
activities and program participation, where required. An unemployed
individual will be threatened by sanctions if he or she deviates from
the integration agreement or does not cooperate appropriately.
Integration agreements pursuant to [section] 35(4) SGB III for UB I
recipients are not a precondition for participating in active measures.
Rather they are regarded as an instrument for improving the placement
procedure. Under the insurance scheme integration agreements have a
limited significance. They are linked only to active measures, but not
to passive benefit receipt. The agreement therefore cannot be used to
sanction unemployed persons. As a consequence, integration agreements
are scarcely applied within the legal ambit of SGB III. The
agreement's mere restriction to the acquisition of more
comprehensive information for the unilateral decision on active
employment promotion measures fails to do adequate justice to the
potential inherent in agreed strategies. In contrast to integration
agreements for UB II claimants, the merits of negotiated strategies
under the insurance scheme mainly lie in the psychological sphere.
In contrast to the insurance scheme personal agreements for UB II
claimants are mandatory pursuant to [section][section] 2(1) sent. 2 and
15 SGB II. The two parts have to conclude an integration agreement
stipulating the necessary services and obligations. This duty is not a
duty in the legal sense, but a so-called incidental obligation, meaning
its fulfillment is not legally enforceable. But it is indirectly
"compelled" via the imposition of a financial sanction.
Jobseekers face financial disadvantages if they refuse to enter into an
integration agreement ([section] 31(1) SGB II).
Sanctions
According to [section] 144 SGB III benefit receipt could be
suspended temporarily if a UB I recipient
* refuses suitable work or a suitable activation measure
* resigns work without good reason or
* shows insufficient effort to look for a new job
* fails to notify in the case of dismissal to the employment
office.
The sanction consists in the imposition of a disqualification
period of normally 12 weeks.
A key element has been introduced through a reversal of the onus of
proof in respect of the "good reason" which can justify a
disqualification period. Now it is the unemployed person who must prove
the facts within his or her sphere of activity and scope of
responsibility--and not the administrative authority, who only bears the
burden of proof under the general rules of evidence.
In contrast to unemployment insurance, however, basic income
support (UB II) cannot be suspended completely in case of lack of
willingness to work or to participate in reintegration programs, but
only reduced to a certain extent as minimum resources needed for
physical existence cannot be withdrawn even if the behavior of the
recipient violates general principles of activation. In extreme cases,
benefits in kind can replace cash benefits.
The sanction regulation under [section] 31(1) sent. 1 no. 1c SGB II
implies that the duty to take up reasonable work is not a legal duty,
but a mere incidental obligation. This is because the regulation makes
clear that work need not actually be taken up for the receipt of
benefits under SGB II, but that the refusal to accept reasonable work
only has financial consequences for the job-seeker. The subsequent
provisions of [section] 31 SGB II moreover do not entail a complete
denial of all benefits under SGB II in case of the beneficiary's
persisting unwillingness to work, but instead specify the sanctions to
be adopted.
The possible curtailment of UB II and its ultimate withdrawal as
provided under [section] 31 SGB II, constitute important enforcement
measures. UB II recipients are obliged to accept any offer to suitable
work. The definition of suitable work was broadened. Both the
beneficiary's refusal to conclude an integration agreement and his
or her non-compliance with agreed duties, but also the rejection of a
reasonable job offer, an immediate offer or a public employment
opportunity without a valid reason lead to a 30 percent reduction of
benefits upon first breach of duty. A second breach of duty incurs a 60
percent reduction, followed by the complete withdrawal of benefit if a
renewed breach occurs within a year. To ensure the constitutionally
guaranteed subsistence minimum, the provision of in-kind benefits is
left to the duty-bound discretion of the institution granting basic
security--[section] 31(3) SGB II (Wunder and Diehm 2006). These refined
sanctioning provisions addressing UB II claimants are a result of legal
fine-tuning effective as of August 2006 and January 2007 after an
unexpected increase in numbers of beneficiaries. This also led to
stricter sanctioning clauses for beneficiaries under 25 that stipulated
that after the first incidence of misconduct, benefits can be restricted
to benefits in kind. However, the duration of sanctions can be reduced
from 12 to 6 weeks.
Activation Measures for UB I recipients
Active employment promotion include a variety of measures
stipulated under [section] 3(1) SGB III. Examples of active employment
measures are: counseling and career guidance, job placement, job
creation schemes, wage subsidies, training measures to improve
integration prospects, and the defrayal of retraining costs during
participation in further vocational training.
In the early days of labor market policies, as expressed in the
Federal Employment Promotion Act (Arbeitsforderungsgesetz) of 1969, not
only the unemployed but also persons with insufficient training were
entitled to long-range training measures, receiving generous support
during these measures and even for six months afterwards if they did not
immediately find a job. Thus, active labor market policies offered
possibilities of upgrading the labor force, both to the benefit of the
individual (upwards mobility) and the collective (maintaining a
well-trained labor force). Soon after the first labor market crisis in
the mid-1970s, the entitlements of the individuals to training
measures--and to the accompanying payments--were severely curtailed.
With the Hartz reforms a number of new instruments were created
that aim at a more effective re-integration of the unemployed although
they are not "activating" in a narrow sense, i.e. used to
enforce benefit conditionality. These innovative instruments comprise
different forms of flexible and subsidized employment apart from
"classical" employer-oriented wage subsidies:
* temporary agency work for the unemployment provided by specific
agencies associated with the PES (Personal-Service-Agenturen),
* part-time work up to EUR 400 per month exempt from
employees' contributions to social insurance and taxes (Mimjobs)
replacing older models of minor employment (geringfugige Beschaftigung)
with a lower earnings threshold,
* jobs between EUR 400 and 800 per month with employees'
social insurance contributions increasing proportionally with earnings
(Midijobs),
* start-up grants for small business providing subsidies for up to
three years (Ich-AG or "Me Inc."). (6)
Additionally, preventive measures like "job-to-job
placement" have been enforced. Pursuant to [section] 37b SGB III,
persons whose employment or training relationship is due to end are
obliged to report personally as jobseekers to the local employment
office no later than three months prior to the termination of that
relationship. Non-compliance with this reporting obligation entails a
disqualification period of one week. It is hoped that early reporting
will permit the Employment Agencies to become active faster and thus
more successfully, than in the past. The financial loss set by law for
late reporting has met opposition and has therefore become a matter for
the courts. (7) In the last instance, the Federal Social Court
(Bundessozialgericht) came to the conclusion that unemployment insurance
benefits could only be reduced on account of belated reporting if the
jobseeker was to blame for this.
Activation Measures for UB II recipients
Provision of services is based on individual need for assistance.
UB II recipients are no longer excluded from most of the instruments of
ALMP provided by SGB III. The implementing institutions
(Arbeitsgemeinschaften, ARGEn, i.e. joint bodies of federal PES and
municipal welfare offices, or, as in some districts, opting-out
municipalies, Optionskommunen) are in principle entitled, as set forth
in [section] 16(1) SGB II, to apply all the instruments available for UB
I recipients by reference to the relevant provisions of SGB III.
Moreover, SGB II has introduced additional measures which have been
designed specifically for welfare recipients and their particular
barriers to employment like debt, abuse of alcohol or other drugs,
socio-psychological counseling and child care services stipulated in
[section] 16(2) SGB II or a start-up allowance pursuant to [section] 29
SGB II. The promotion of reintegration measures is regulated in
[section] 14 SGB II, meaning the institutions responsible for providing
basic security to jobseekers primarily become active with the aim of
reintegrating needy persons capable of working into the labor market.
In a recent amendment by 20 July 2006, [section] 15a SGB II now
provides that persons capable of working who within the past two years
have not received cash benefits under either SGB II or SGB III are
immediately to be offered benefits for integration into work upon
applying for benefits pursuant to SGB II. This "immediate
offer" of integration services is to avoid the need of assistance
or at least prevent long spells of such need and to test the
applicant's readiness to accept employment.
If needy persons capable of working find no job, public employment
opportunities are to be created on their behalf ([section] 16(3) SGB
II). Prerequisites governing the admissibility of job opportunities are
not to be discussed further here. Important, rather, is how the
legislator's conceptions are put into practice. The legislative
intent was that the provision of time-limited job opportunities
(so-called "One-Euro-Jobs") would avoid the emergence of a
subsidized, state-financed "third" labor market, as was the
case with the largely unsuccessful public job creation measures in the
1990s. Activation programs should be applied only if they avoid,
eliminate, shorten or reduce benefit dependency through integration into
a regular job.
The activating effect of One-Euro-Jobs is seen in re-accustoming
jobless persons to activities with a steady work rhythm, punctuality,
and so forth, and, hence, to improve their integration prospects
("work-pedagogic objective") (Bieritz-Harder 2005). The
foremost aim is always to achieve integration into the regular labor
market, possibly also to regain fully-fledged employment in the wake of
such job opportunities. The approach of regarding these additional jobs
as a quid pro quo for the receipt of Unemployment Benefit II does not
conform to the enacted text, nor can this be inferred from the judgments
so far delivered in respect of [section] 16(3) SGB II.
Implementation and outcomes so far
The Hartz reform package not only changed the benefit and
activation regime, it also created new implementation structures with
the ARGEn and opting-out municipalities. (8) After more than three years
of actual activation practice under the new regime, one can assess the
effectiveness of the reforms and their overall outcomes. As shown above,
the curtailment of social insurance benefits meant a major structural
change regarding the composition of the benefit recipients. In summer
2008, about three quarters are under UB II. At the same time, the change
in policy orientation and governance led to a strong decline in
participation and expenditure for traditional active labor market
schemes, such as training and direct job creation, whereas start-up
grants expanded significantly. Between 2002 and 2007 expenditure for
active schemes went down from 22.1 billion EUR to 15.2 billion EUR.
Hence, the shift towards activation by way of more demanding
interventions was associated with a decline in active labor market
policy expenditure, not with an increase. With regard to UB recipients,
One-Euro-Jobs are by far the most important scheme, as figure 3 shows.
They have virtually replaced other forms of direct job creation.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In terms of overall expenditure, however, the decline of benefit
expenditure and active schemes for UB I claimants was offset by
increases in UB II expenditure, i.e. by a shift from contribution-based
to tax-funded benefits (see figure 4).
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The number of beneficiaries and the expenditure data are only rough
approximations of the reform effects. In terms of evaluation of
individual labor market integration, available evidence suggests that
the labor market policy instruments only show mixed effects with broad
similarities across UB I and UB II activation. There seem to be positive
effects of subsidization, sanctioning and support self-employment at
least in the short run whereas some evidence suggests positive long-term
effects of training (Bernhard et al. 2008, Eichhorst and Zimmermann
2007).
One-Euro-Jobs are less promising. This scheme is also a good
example to demonstrate the still insufficient implementation of the
Fordern und Fordern principles of activation. On the one hand, these
jobs have been designed to promote the employability of unemployed
persons with a bad prognosis for a quick integration into the regular
labor market. On the other hand, they serve as a work-test for
individuals with good chances but low search efforts. However, results
from a survey of case managers carried out in fall 2005 show that
One-Euro-Jobs are offered mostly on a voluntary basis, i.e. on a
consensual basis. Case managers see their prime objective in
re-establishing or stabilizing employability and in strengthening
societal integration through structuring daily life, improved
self-confidence and additional resources for debt redemption. Immediate
reintegration into the labor market is not a principle objective of this
scheme in their view (Wolff and Hohmeyer 2006). Nevertheless, the use
and purpose of the One-Euro-Jobs is still highly controversial. In a
recent report, the Federal Audit Court (Bundesrechnungshof) found out
that about two thirds of these public employment opportunities do not
meet the legal requirements of "public interest" and
"additionality". Using a fixed-effects panel-estimation of the
years 2004 and 2005 on the substitution of regular jobs, the analysis
shows that One-Euro-Jobs tend to have negative effects in Eastern
Germany, but no corresponding negative effect could be identified in
Western Germany (Hohendanner 2007). The Federal Audit Court also
continues to criticize the implementation of Hartz IV by point out at
the fact that activating interventions start too late to prevent
long-term benefit receipt.
At the same time, however, the shift to activation was associated
with a decline in reservation wages of German unemployed. Unemployed now
accept lower wages (Kettner and Rebien 2007, Schneider 2008), and
persons threatened by unemployment take the eventual receipt of a
means-test basic income benefit into account and intensify job search.
This has contributed to more employment-intensive economic growth during
the recent upswing. In this respect, Hartz IV contributed to making the
German labor market more flexible. From a critical perspective, some
observers point at the growth of low-wage jobs and benefit recipients
who enter the labor market only at the margin and do not earn enough to
leave the benefit system completely (Brenke and Ziemendorff 2008).
Although the majority of these 1.3 million "Aufstocker" are
part-time workers and the full-time employees in need of additional
benefit top-up tend to live in large households, there is an issue of
sustainability of labor market integration. Many low-skilled benefit
recipients find it difficult to achieve earnings that help them out of
benefit receipt. In a broader sense, the growth of low-wage sector
contributes to fears of downward mobility and income erosion of the
middle class expressed in survey data (Grabka and Frick 2008). Empirical
evidence also shows that upward mobility is rather limited in Germany
(Schank et al. 2008). Hartz IV has become a major point of reference not
only for the unemployed, but also for the labor force in more general
terms.
4 Conclusion: Germany on the Way to a Means-Tested Welfare State?
Germany embarked on the shift towards activation much later that
its European neighbors, but this policy change was in many respects more
fundamental and comprehensive as it implied a major break with the
welfare state tradition which had been characterized by the social
insurance logic of a "Bismarckian" system. Passive, status
protecting benefits had been used in the past to buffer economic
adjustment. Against this background, policy change from status and
occupational orientation in the benefit regime to basic income support
for the long-term unemployed in combination with the stricter
formulation and potential enforcement of "dormant" demanding
elements is a major element of "path departure" and
recalibration of rights and obligations in the German welfare state.
This also implied a major overhaul of active labor market policy schemes
and governance. But the shift towards activation is not just a
"technical" issue and an example of implementing New Public
Management principles in Germany.
The late, but fundamental change in Germany is most notable in
comparison with other European countries such as the UK, Denmark, the
Netherlands or Sweden as the German approach to activation is relatively
broad and ambitious as "capability of working" is defined
mainly in a medical sense so that the number of people to be activated
is much higher than elsewhere, in particular given the fact that
alternative escape routes do not play a prominent role in Germany these
days (i.e. disability benefits) or are being closed (e.g. early
retirement). This dramatically increases transparency regarding
non-employment and lead to high open (registered) unemployment at the
beginning of the activation of the long-term unemployed with the Hartz
IV reform.
Contrary to widespread perceptions, however, stronger activation is
not associated with a general decline in benefit levels--even not for
the long-term unemployed--as Hartz IV is not only activation, but also a
social policy reform widening access to benefits and assistance. Rather
the severance of the link between benefits for the long-term unemployed
and prior earnings changed the perception of benefit generosity. There
is some evidence that this--in conjunction with more demanding
interventions by administrative bodies--leads to lower acceptance wages
and stronger job search effort due to increased fears of downward
mobility in case of longer unemployment spells.
This has more fundamental consequences as it signals the departure
from status protection and a "benevolent" welfare state to a
more basic, means-tested system of social protection and stricter
"workfare" although these very principles had been in place
before. This is not only a result of the abolition of earnings-related
unemployment assistance but also due to the associated cut in maximum
duration of unemployment insurance benefits for older workers. In
empirical terms this becomes evident with respect to the diminishing
role of contribution-based and earnings-related unemployment insurance
benefits relative to the number of beneficiaries of means-tested basic
income schemes. Hence, both in terms of claimant numbers and expected
benefit levels, basic income support is now the dominant regime and
major point of reference for the unemployed in Germany.
Basic income for jobseekers, but also means-tested earnings top-up
for low-wage earners is now by far the more important benefit scheme
than unemployment insurance for short-term unemployed with sufficient
prior employment record. This new arrangements questions the status of
lifetime achievement and occupational orientation that was
characteristic for the German model of industrial production in the
past. On the one hand, this may reduce incentives to pursue professional
careers as acquired rights in the social insurance system depreciate
more quickly than in the past, and after (accelerated) expiry of
unemployment insurance benefits, virtually all jobs are suitable. On the
other hand, however, reduced benefit generosity in case of long-term
unemployment and even the threat of being transferred to means-tested
flat-rate basic income may lead to higher individual effort in order not
to lose track of the regular labor market and raise individual job
search intensity in case of unemployment. This may even have positive
effects on human capital investment. Anyway, the reform reinforces
individual responsibility and reduces the possibility to rely on
status-oriented benefits and human capital enhancing labor market
policies.
Given this broad paradigm shift, acceptance deficits come as no
surprise. Cuts in UB I duration, replacing earnings-related unemployment
assistance with a flat-rate benefit for the long-term unemployed and
fears of "enforced" low-wage employment as a result of
stricter activation motivated major public unrest before and after the
Hartz IV reform came into effect. However, despite a broad public
controversy, the long-term implications of this institutional change
remain rather implicit. Part of the acceptance deficit can be explained
by the lack of a general normative framework developed in order to
explain the necessity of these changes and to emphasize the potential of
this reform. This may also be partly responsible for reluctant
implementation in practice as the implicit normative assumptions are not
shared by all actors charged with implementation.
The difficulties experienced with the politics and the
implementation of activation in Germany points at more fundamental
issues as both policy makers and the general public are very reluctant
with regard to a complementary liberalization of the labor market and
higher wage dispersion which would help strengthen the supply of entry
jobs for the activated. The concept of "work first" may be
embodied in current German legislation, yet the idea of "any job is
better than no job" still raises widespread opposition. Hence, the
question whether a higher degree of inequality is inevitable in the
general labor market in order to overcome benefit dependency is still
unsolved. Being accustomed to a "high equality, low activity"
arrangement, activation of the long-term unemployed and the low-skilled
implies a major shift of paradigm as there is now a combination of less
equality, but higher activity although this is probably not a stable new
equilibrium yet.
With regard to the foreseeable future, the German activation regime
will most probably be subject to further, sometimes contradictory
modification. One more coherent policy solution implying a general
lowering of basic income is virtually ruled out, therefore there is no
prominent role for strong in-work benefits (see e.g. Sachverstandigenrat
2006). This is also true for a bold flexibilization of the labor market
which would be complementary to this approach inspired by the
Anglo-Saxon experience. Both the public and the policy makers are highly
reserved with regard to these issues. Activation will most probably
remain in place as the major principle of unemployment protection, but
strong social justice considerations already led to stabilizing wages
through introducing a general statutory minimum wage or extending
collectively agreed sectoral minimum wages even if this might be
detrimental to the labor market integration of the long-term unemployed.
Policy makers currently aim at "softening" activation
policies. UB I has been prolonged again for the older unemployed in
order to restore "social justice", and some tend to resort to
a more limited definition of "capability of working", to
liberalizing access to disability pensions and continuing old-age
part-time work and assigning part of the hard-to-place to public sector
employment where some new models of direct public job creation or
heavily subsidized jobs have already been introduced. These policy
corrections reflect the fact that the German labor force and the
electorate feel uneasy about the consequences of activation on the
dynamics of the labor market. Yet, opening up new exit routes from the
labor market is in stark opposition to tackling the major barriers to
sustainable employment experienced in activation of long-term inactive
and low-skilled benefit recipients, namely early activation associated
with basic training and continuous education to ensure employability and
make upward mobility a real option.
References
Becker, I., Hauser, R. (2006). Verteilungseffekte der Hartz
IV-Reform: Ergebnisse von Simulationsanalysen. Berlin: Edition Sigma.
Berlit, U. (2006). Das neue Sanktionensystem. In: Zeitschrift fur
Sozialhilfe und Sozialgesetzbuch 2005, 707-715, 2006, 11-19.
Bernhard, S. et. al. (2008). Aktive Arbeitsmarktpolitik in
Deutschland und ihre Wirkungen. IAB Forschungsbericht 2/2008. Nurnberg:
IAB.
Bieritz-Harder, R. (2005). Die Arbeitsgelegenheiten des [section]
16 Abs. 3 Satz 2 SGB II. In: Zeitschrift fur Sozialhilfe und
Sozialgesetzbuch, 259-263.
Blanke, B. (2001). Aktivierender Staataktive Burgergesellschaft:
Eine Analyse fur das Bundeskanzleramt. Hannover: Universitat Hannover.
Blos, K., Rudolph, H. (2005). Simulationsrechnungen zum
Arbeitslosengeld II: Verlierer, aber auch Gewinner. IAB Kurzbericht
17/2005. Nurnberg: IAB.
Brenke, K., Ziemendorff, J. (2008). Hilfebedurftig trotz Arbeit:
kein Massenphanomen in Deutschland. DIW Wochenbericht 75 (4), 33-40.
Berlin: DIW.
Bruttel, O., Kemmerling, A. (2006). New Politics in German Labor
Market Policy? The Implications of the Recent Hartz Reforms for the
German Welfare State. In: West European Politics, 29 (1), 90-112.
Eichhorst, W. (2006). Beschaftigung Alterer in Deutschland: der
unvollstandige Paradigmenwechsel. In: Zeitschrift fur Sozial-reform 52
(1), 101-123.
Eichhorst, W., Profit, S., Thode, E. (2001). Benchmarking
Deutschland: Arbeitsmarkt und Beschaftigung. Berlin: Springer.
Eichhorst, W., Kaiser, L. C. (2006). The German Labor Market: Still
Adjusting Badly? IZA Discussion Paper 2215. Bonn: IZA.
Eichhorst, W., Sesselmeier, W. (2006). Die Akzeptanz von
Arbeitsmarktreformen am Beispiel von Hartz IV. Bonn: Friedrich Ebert
Stiftung.
Eichhorst, W., Konle-Seidl, R. (2006). The Interaction of Labor
Market Regulation and Labor Market Policies in Welfare State Reform. In:
Comparative Labor Law and Social Policy Journal, Volume 28, Number 1,
Fall 2006.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Esping-Andersen, G. (1996). Welfare States Without Work: the
Impasse of Labor Shedding and Familialism in Continental European Social
Policy. In: Esping-Andersen, G. (Ed.): Welfare States in Transition.
National Adaptations in Global Economies. London: Sage, 66-87.
Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T., Soskice, D. (2001). Social Protection
and the Formation of Skills. In: Hall, P. A., Soskice, D. (Eds.):
Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative
Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 145-183.
Fleckenstein, T. (2004). Policy-Lernen in der Arbeitsmarktpolitik:
Das Beispiel der Hartz-Kommission. In: Zeitschrift fur Sozialreform 50
(6), 646-675.
Gagel, A. (Ed.) (2005). Sozialgesetzbuch III--Arbeitsforderung.
Munchen: C. H. Beck.
Giddens, A. (1999). Der dritte Weg: die Erneuerung der sozialen
Demokratie. Frankfurt: Campus.
Grabka, M. M., Frick, J. R. (2008). Schrumpfende Mittelschicht:
Anzeichen einer dauerhaften Polarisierung der verfugbaren Einkommen? DIW
Wochenbericht 75 (10), 101-108. Berlin: DIW.
Hohendanner, Christian (2007). Verdrangen Ein-Euro-Jobs
sozialversicherungspflichtige Beschaftigung in den Betrieben? IAB
Discussion Paper 08/2007. Nurnberg: IAB.
Jacobi, L., Kluve, J. (2006). Before and After the Hartz Reforms:
The Performance of Active Labor Market Policy in Germany. IZA Discussion
Paper 2100. Bonn: IZA.
Jantz, B. (2004). Zusammenfuhrung von Arbeitslosen-und Sozialhilfe,
in: Jann, W., Schmid, G. (Eds.) (2004): Eins zu eins? Eine
Zwischenbilanz der Hartz-Reformen am Arbeitsmarkt. Berlin: Edition
Sigma, 38-50.
Kettner, A., Rebien, M. (2007). Hartz-IV-Reform: Impulse fur den
Arbeitsmarkt. IAB Kurzbericht 19/2007. Nurnberg: IAB.
Konle-Seidl, R., Lang, K. (2006). Von der Reduzierung zur
Mobilisierung des Arbeitskraftepotenzials. IAB Forschungsbericht
15/2006. Nurnberg: IAB.
Ludwig-Mayerhofer, W. (2005). Activating Germany. In: Bredgaard,
T., Larsen, F. (Eds.) Employment Policy from Different Angles.
Copenhagen: DJOF Publishing, 95-114.
Luthe, E.-W. (2003). Der aktivierende Sozialstaat im Recht. In:
Nachrichtendienst des Deutschen Vereins fur offentliche und private
Fursorge, 167-177.
Manow, P., Seils, E. (2000). Adjusting Badly: The German Welfare
State, Structural Change, and the Open Economy. In: Scharpf, F.
W./Schmidt, V. A. (Eds.): Welfare and Work in the Open Economy, Vol 2.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 264-307.
Papier, H.-J. (2003). Der Einfluss des Verfassungsrechts auf das
Sozialrecht, in: Maydell, Bernd von/Ruland, Franz: Sozialrechtshandbuch.
Baden-Baden: Nomos, A 3.
Rucht, D., Yang, M. (2004). "Wer demonstrierte gegen Hartz
IV?" In: Forschungsjournal Neue Soziale Bewegungen, Sonderdruck,
Dezember 2004, 21-27.
Sachverstandigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen
Entwicklung (2006). Arbeitslosengeld II reformieren: Ein zielgerichtetes
Kombilohnmodell. Expertise im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums fur
Wirtschaft und Technologie. Wiesbaden, August 2006.
Schank, T., Schnabel, C., Stephani, J., Bender, S. (2008).
Niedriglohnbeschaftigung. Sackgasse oder Chance zum Aufstieg? IAB
Kurzbericht 8/2008.
Schneider, H. (2008). Die Veranderung der Lohnersatzleistungen und
die Reform der Vermittlungsprozesse im SGB III. In: Zimmermann, Klaus F.
(Ed.): Funf Jahre Agenda 2010, DIW Vierteljahrsheft zur
Wirtschaftsforschung, 20-37.
Streeck, W. (1997). German Capitalism. Does it Exist? Can it
Survive? In: Crouch, Colin/Streeck, Wolfgang (Eds.): The Political
Economy of Modern Capitalism. Mapping Convergence and Diversity. London:
Sage, 33-54.
Streeck, W., Trampusch, C. (2005). Economic Reform and the
Political Economy of the German Welfare State. In: German Politics 14
(2), 174-195.
Trampusch, C. (2002). Die Bundesanstalt fur Arbeit und das
Zusammenwirken von Staat und Verbanden in der Arbeitsmarktpolitik von
1952 bis 2001. MPIfG Working Paper 02/5. Koln: MPIfG.
Wolff, J., Hohmeyer K. (2006). Forderung von arbeitslosen Personen
im Rechtskreis des SGB II durch Arbeitsgelegenheiten: Bislang wenig
zielgruppenorientiert. IAB Forschungsbericht 10/2006. Nurnberg: IAB.
Wolff, J., Hohmeyer K. (2008). Wirkungen von Ein-Euro-Jobs: Fur ein
paar Euro mehr. IAB-Kurzbericht 2/2008. Nurnberg: IAB.
Wunder, A., Diehm, A. (2006). SGB II--Fortentwicklungsgesetz
verscharft die Sanktionen: Sind Kurzungen des Arbeitslosengeldes II um
bis zu 100 Prozent verfassungswidrig? In: Soziale Sicherheit, 195-199.
Zacher, H. F. (2004). Das soziale Staatsziel. In: Isensee, J.,
Kirchhof, P. (Eds.): Handbuch des Staatsrechts, Vol. 2. Heidelberg: C.
F. Muller Verlag, [section] 28.
(1) The term Bedarfsgemeinschaft includes: the needy persons
capable to work; the parents living in the household, or the parent,
respectively, of an under-age, unmarried employable child and this
parent's partner living in the household; the not permanently
separated spouse as partner of the employable person in need of
assistance; the person living with the employable person in need of
assistance as a cohabitant; the partner not permanently living apart
from the employable person in need of assistance; the under-age
unmarried children belonging to the household of the aforementioned
persons to the extent that they are unable to procure their means of
subsistence from their own income or assets.
(2) This was also due to the fact that Hartz IV led to a change in
unemployment statistics. As the reform changed the rules for eligibility
criteria for unemployment benefits, requiring all recipients of former
social assistance "capable of working at least three hours a
day" to register as unemployed, the number of registered unemployed
exceeded 5 million for the first time in January 2005. Although this was
only a statistical effect and did not mean a substantial increase in
non-employment or broad unemployment, it was perceived as a major policy
failure and the proof of the fact that the Hartz reforms did not work.
(3) This is also true in the public old-age pension regime where
the Riester reform implemented in 2001 brought about a departure from
the principle of status-preserving public pensions.
(4) Moving from extended social insurance through earnings-related
benefit both in unemployment insurance and unemployment assistance also
means a weakening of the traditional conservative "bread
winner" model that was applied not only to the employed but also to
the unemployed. The new basic income support does not take into account
derived family responsibilities but generated individual entitlement for
partners/spouses and children, thus furthering individualization of
welfare claims and stressing job search requirements for all employable
members of a needy household and breaking with a more conservative
family model.
(5) This means that the share of recipients registered as
unemployed and included in mandatory job search activities or activation
programs is higher in Germany (12.1 percent of working age population)
and that of "inactive" recipients of passive welfare benefit
schemes (3.5 percent of working age population) lower than in other
countries.
(6) This was replaced by a new and integrated start-up allowance as
of mid-2006.
(7) Despite the meanwhile mitigated version of the sanction
regulation, court rulings remain relevant: BSG (Federal Social Court),
judgment of 25 May 2005, SGb 2006, 49 ff.; BSG, judgment of 18 Aug.
2005.
(8) The ARGE structure has been ruled unconstitutional by the
Federal Constitutional Court in late 2007 so that a new legal basis for
cooperation between federal PES and the municipal level.
Werner Eichhorst Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) (Germany)
Maria Grienberger-Zingerle Bavarian Ministry of Labour and Social
Affairs (Germany)
Regina Konle-Seidl Institute for Employment Research (IAB)
(Germany)