The effect of poverty, gender exclusion, and child labor on out-of-school rates for female children.
Castillo, Leopoldo Laborda ; Salem, Daniel Sotelsek ; Sarr, Leopold Remi 等
In this article, the authors analyze the effect of poverty, social
exclusion, and child labor on out-of-school rates for female children.
This empirical study is based on a dynamic panel model for a sample of
216 countries over the period 1970 to 2010. Results based on the
generalized method of moments (GMM) of Arellano and Bond (1991) and the
tests of causality and zero autocorrelation to the panel data show a
negative and significant relation between contributing family workers
(female) and number of primary school-age children out of school
(female) in Europe and Central Asia region. However, the authors cannot
find empirical evidence between primary school-age children out of
school rates (female) and the variables used to analyze the effect of
poverty and social exclusion (poverty headcount ratio at national
poverty line and total vulnerable employment). Moreover, the article
identifies effects of other variables like proportion of seats held by
women in national parliaments. In addition, this article examines
geographic regions separately, with the anticipation that differentials
in livelihood strategies and opportunities could be reflected in female
child schooling decisions.
Keywords: child labor, poverty, social exclusion, out-of-school
rates
**********
Education is a human right that ought to be accessible to everyone,
without any discrimination. According to Miles and Singal (2010), all
children must be able to go to school and thereby benefit from the same
opportunities to build a future. Education also must be free so that
children from disadvantaged environments are able to enjoy this right.
(1) However, according to Lewis and Lockheed (2006), nearly three
fourths of the 60 million girls still not in school belong to ethnic,
religious, linguistic, racial, or other minorities. Before this
disheartening fact became known, many authors (e.g., Herz &
Sperling, 2004; Lewis & Lockheed, 2006; Tembon & Fort, 2008)
tried to analyze female child education.
Herz and Sperling (2004) consider that policymakers will need to
make special efforts to address the economic, social, and cultural
barriers that keep even larger proportions of girls in poor countries
out of school. In a similar way, Lewis and Lockheed (2006) point out
that enrolling and retaining excluded children, in particular girls, in
school requires new strategies, and reaching them can be costly because
it requires new methods tailored to each group.
Taking into account these recommendations, Tembon and Fort (2008)
suggest several strategic directions for advancing gender equality in
education, such as improving the quality of not only primary but also
secondary education and focusing on the most vulnerable groups. On the
other hand, it is important to improve the relationship between public
sector, private sector, and nonprofit organizations. All this implies
improving studies regarding gender, poverty, and the development and
presentation of policymakers' information. (2)
Taking into account the above considerations, we propose an
empirical study based on some of the patterns of inequalities in
educational attainment proposed by Filmer (2006). These include
significant differences between and within countries and inequality associated with economic status, gender, child labor, and so on. (3)
To conduct the empirical analysis, we employ a dynamic panel model
for a sample of 213 countries over the period 2003 to 2007. With this
objective in mind, the work is organized as follows: In the next
section, we present a brief empirical background about the effect of
poverty, social exclusion, and child labor on out-of-school female
children rates. In the third section, we develop the methodology used
for the empirical analysis. In the fourth section, we present the main
empirical results obtained. In the fifth section, we present a summary
of the main conclusions. Finally, the last section ends with some policy
implications.
BACKGROUND: OUT-OF-SCHOOL FEMALE CHILDREN RATES FACTORS
According to Yu (2007), each country has its own educational
policies and goals/functions and these system-wide differences in
educational goals emphasize that the criteria for judging/determining
school effectiveness should take into account the contextual factors
within which each school/nation operates.
Taking into account the above consideration, the main object of
this section is to find some empirical support that allows a
satisfactory understanding of the role that poverty, social exclusion,
and child labor could play in the out-of-school female children rates.
With this idea in mind, we propose a systematic revision of the most
relevant empirical studies (according to our objectives) conducted at
the country level.
The Effect of Poverty
To analyze the effect of poverty in education, we selected some
studies country by country in the developing world, focusing on the
works published by several important authors, and considered their main
conclusions about this issue.
To begin with, we can see that family structure and a child's
relationship to the head of the household are found to be significant
influences and important factors on investments in children's
education, according to Shapiro and Tambashe (2001), along with the
place of residence and the economic status of the household. Jonathan
Morduch (1999) believes that poverty can be related to vulnerability, as
numerous poor households are exposed to many risks, including economic
ones, that carry negative implications for the oncoming generation,
reducing rates of children in school.
In regard to family structure, by the examination of the
possibility that parents obtain informal income insurance by letting
their children work, Gubert and Robilliard (2006) conclude that
transitory income affects children's school dropout behaviors
significantly but not their school entrance. The probability of school
entrance nevertheless appears to be sensitive to shocks in the
demographic structure of the household, because it is negatively
correlated with the death or moving out of elderly household members.
Monetary and nonmonetary costs of education are a great burden on the
poorest households and act as a significant barrier to education. The
indirect costs are also considerable, with seasonal variations relating
to the demand for labor, according to Boyle, Brock, Mace, and Sibbons
(2002). As a result, this seasonal cycle of opportunity costs impacts
attendance patterns, which, in turn, influence permanent premature
removal from school.
As we find that increased economic well-being translates into
greater investments in children's education for females and males,
Shapiro and Tambashe (2001) determine that improved economic status does
not necessarily result in reduced gender differences in school outcomes.
As well, Brown and Park (2002) use direct measures of credit limits and
women's empowerment, finding evidence of gender bias in which
academically weak girls are more likely to drop out in primary school
whereas most boys continue on to junior secondary school.
Analyzing the areas of location of the household, Mugisha (2006)
explores patterns of school enrollment comparing urban slum, urban
nonslum, and rural children. The results suggest that school enrollment
is higher in urban nonslum areas than in urban slum areas and is higher
in slums than in rural areas at younger ages. Factors contributing to
these results point to the poor quality of primary schools in slums,
limited access to secondary schools for slum children, increased
vulnerability to coercion into sexual activity and other ills that
hinder school participation, disabling environment at home, and
increased child labor.
Another subject, studied by Deon Filmer (2005), is the relationship
between whether young people have a disability, the poverty status of
their household, and their school participation. According to Filmer,
youth with disabilities are almost always substantially less likely to
start school and, in some countries, have lower transition rates
resulting in lower schooling attainment. The order of magnitude of the
school participation disability deficit is often larger than those
associated with the other characteristics we have read before, such as
gender, area of residence, or economic status differentials.
A very important matter we have to consider as we deal with the
effect of poverty on households and children's education are the
possible benefits of conditional cash transfers (CCT). As the authors
agree that conditional transfers can provide a high and positive impact
in increasing school attendance, acting as safety nets for the schooling
of the poor, certain kind of conditions (e.g., requiring enrolling
children into public schools) and right strategies are necessary in
order to make these transfers reach their real purpose.
De Janvry, Finan, Sadoulet, and Vakis (2006) found that conditional
transfers helped protect enrollment but did not prevent parents from
increasing child work in response to shocks. In this sense, to reduce
the poverty headcount ratio by increasing incomes among poor households,
cash transfers would have to be sizeable. Even then, an increase in
income, by itself, would not suffice to significantly increase school
attendance. Higher impacts at lower cost could be achieved by making
transfers targeted and conditional (Kakwani, Soares, & Son, 2006).
Extending this conclusion, Son and Florentino (2008) found that the
targeted CCT program would lead to greater school attendance and poverty
reduction. Designing a program with a weak or nonexistent targeting
strategy not only reduces the transfer cost per beneficiary but also
leads to leakages to the nonpoor, driving down its impact and
effectiveness. Using a similar simulation methodology, Kumara and Pfau
(2011) find that cash transfer programs targeting poor children would be
the most cost-effective way to reduce child poverty and encourage school
attendance. Their findings suggest that even a limited program budget
can provide significant impacts. On the other hand, Bourguignon,
Ferreira, and Leite (2003) evaluated the Bolsa Escola program in Brazil,
with results that suggest approximately 60% of poor children from age 10
to 15 not in school enroll in response to the program. They conclude
that the targeting of this CCT is accurate, but that poverty reduction,
though effective, does not cause a large positive effect. Therefore,
governments must transfer cash in an intelligent and efficient way,
substantially increasing the amounts if they hope to cause bigger
effects in reducing poverty.
Gender Exclusion
Reviewing some studies country by country in the developing world,
conducted by some significant authors, we continue to analyze the effect
of gender exclusion in education. One of the main factors found to be a
cause for the gender gap in child education is cultural, taking an
elevated importance in the household decisions.
Related to this, Colclough, Rose, and Tembon (2000) argue that
poverty is associated with an underenrollment of school-age children,
but that the gendered outcomes of such underenrollment are the product
of cultural practice, rather than of poverty per se. Their study shows
the variety and extent of adverse cultural practice that impedes the
attendance and performance of girls at school, relative to boys. Taking
into account these findings, the authors warn that gender inequalities
in schooling outcomes, measured in qualitative and quantitative terms,
will not necessarily be reduced as incomes rise. Defining the cultural
aspect in rural areas, the presence of a public school for girls in the
village makes an enormous difference for girls in primary enrollment,
given parents' reluctance for girls to travel far from home. Lloyd,
Mete, and Sathar (2005) find that girls' enrollment in public
primary school is particularly responsive to improvements in some
aspects of school quality, in particular whether the teacher resides in
the village. This would suggest that school quality is important not
only for retention but also for enrollment. As a proof, Sawada and
Lokshin (2009) discovered serious supply-side constraints that might
arise from a village-level lack of demand for primary schools for girls.
It is also important to take into account the education level of
the head of the household, as Rose and Al-Samarrai (2001) did by showing
that the probability of attending and completing school was lower for
girls than for boys in economically constrained households with
illiterate parents but was equal for girls and boys in better-endowed
households.
Furthermore, the economic changes also affect the rates of
schooling in rural areas. Kajisa and Palanichamy (2010) found that the
initial high correlation between children's attainment of basic
schooling and the household's assets for farming disappeared during
the mid-1980s. However, even after that time, the attainment of advanced
education is still affected by rainfall and thus by farm income,
indicating the lack of insurance markets and the segregation of poor
households under agriculturally unfavorable conditions from advanced
education. Meanwhile, segregation based on gender and adult
members' education has been disappearing.
Analyzing the gender gap in child education, some authors locate
the larger difference between boys' and girls' attendance in
the primary school-age group. For example, Sawada and Lokshin (2009)
revealed a high education retention rate and observed that school
progression rates between male and female students after secondary
school are comparable. In particular, they find gender-specific and
schooling-stage-specific birth-order effects on education. Their overall
findings are consistent with the implications of optimal schooling
behavior under binding credit constraints and the self-selection of
education-friendly households. On the other hand, Aslam and Kingdon
(2008) investigated whether the intrahousehold allocation of educational
expenditure favors males over females, finding that in middle and
secondary school ages, evidence points to significant promale biases in
the enrollment decision as well as the decision of how much to spend
conditional on enrollment. However, in the primary school, only the
former channel of bias applies. Their results suggest that the observed
strong gender difference in education expenditure is within rather than
across household phenomena.
Child Labor
Finally, focusing on the works of some authors, country by country
in the developing world, we can analyze the effect of child labor in
education, taking it into account as a clearly huge obstacle for
children's education. As we have previously read in some
conclusions, children from poor households and households with parents
with a low level of education are less likely to attend school and, by
consequence, are more likely to be engaged in child labor, giving
strength to the hypothesis that poverty is the root cause of child
labor, according to Friedrich Huebler (2008). As well, Jensen and
Nielson (1997) investigate what affects school attendance and child
labor and find with the empirical analysis that economic and
sociological variables are important determinants for the choice between
school attendance and child labor. In particular, Jensen and Nielson
find some support for the hypothesis that poverty forces households to
keep their children away from school.
The labor force participation is nontrivial among those below the
legal working age or supposed to be in school, and these working
children contribute significantly to total household income, according
to Psacharopoulos (1997). The fact that a child is working reduces his
or her education attainment by about 2 years of schooling relative to
the control group of nonworking children. Also, Psacharopoulos found
that grade repetition is closely associated with child labor.
Nevertheless, poverty does not appear alone among the causes that
enhance child labor. The empirical analysis by Canagarajah and Coulombe
(1998), analyzing the determinants of child labor in conjunction with
decision to school, shows, though not very convincingly, proof that
poverty is the main culprit of child labor; however, it is correlated
significantly with attendance and enrollment in school. They show a
significant negative relationship between going to school and working.
According to the authors, the high cost of schooling and the low quality
and weak relevance of education has also pushed many children into work.
On the other hand, family characteristics have a big role to play in the
decision about children going to school or work, and the parents'
education has a significant negative effect on child labor and the
effect is stronger for girls than boys. In addition, Moyi (2011) finds
that socioeconomic status and structure of the household have a strong
effect on child labor.
In regard to the household structure, Patrinos and Psacharopoulos
(1997) analyzed the effects of being indigenous, number of siblings,
sibling activities, and sibling age structure on child schooling
progress and child nonschool activity. Their analysis shows that family
size is important. However, the analysis also demonstrates the
importance of taking into consideration the siblings' activities.
The age structure of siblings is important, but in conjunction with
their activities. According to these authors, having a greater number of
younger siblings implies less schooling, more age-grade distortion in
the classroom, and more child labor.
Paying attention to the gender differences inside child work,
Canagarajah and Coulombe (1998) show some clear gender-based
distinctions in the type of tasks performed by a girl and boy worker
(girls do more household chores, while boys are in the labor force). As
work, broadly defined, substantially reduces schooling for boys and
girls, Assaad, Levison, and Zibani (2007) present evidence that lower
rates of school attendance for girls are caused by a substantial burden
of household work. Although market work is a serious impediment to
schooling for boys, a much larger proportion of girls than boys engage
in substantial hours of work, when work is defined to include both the
labor force and domestic work.
By studying rural areas in particular and comparing them with urban
areas, Ersado (2005) finds that though strong evidence shows that
poverty drives child labor in rural areas, there is a general lack of
support for the poverty hypothesis in urban areas. This suggests that
policies such as a ban on child labor in rural areas could have an
adverse effect, as child labor decisions are more likely a response to
poverty and subsistence requirements. Similarly improving access to
credit has greater potential for alleviating child labor and enhancing
school enrollment in rural than urban areas. On the other hand, the
availability of alternative child care options appears to considerably
decrease child labor and create conditions for higher school attendance
rates in urban than in rural areas. Finally, the evidence indicates that
efforts to bolster adult education levels and wages will help curb the
prevalence and intensity of child labor and improve the likelihood that
children stay in school.
Concerning the actions taken to reduce child labor and increase
children's schooling, Ravallion and Wodon (1999) studied the
effects on children's labor force participation and school
enrollments of the pure school-price change induced by a targeted
enrollment subsidy. In their theoretical model, these authors predict
that the subsidy increases schooling, but its effect on child labor is
ambiguous. Their empirical findings indicate that the subsidy increased
schooling by far more than it reduced child labor. (4) Moreover,
Hazarika and Bedi (2002) draw a distinction between child labor within
the household (intrahousehold) and child work in the labor market (extrahousehold), and examine the separate effects of schooling costs on
the two types of child labor. The authors found that extrahousehold
child labor and schooling costs are positively related, whereas
intrahousehold child labor is insensitive to changes in schooling costs.
Lastly, their results suggested that reduction in schooling costs will
have limited success in the abatement of child labor.
It is also important to indicate that a large proportion of working
children attend school. According to Moyi (2011), if the consequence of
working is to hinder educational attainment, then policymakers need to
focus on the dimension of education inequality between students who
combine work and school and those who do not.
METHOD
To solve some methodological problems related with the evaluation
of the models by traditional methods, (5) we propose one method (based
on Arellano & Bond, 1991) that consists of obtaining consistent
estimators.
As a result of the above consideration, we propose an empirical
study based on a dynamic panel model for a sample of 216 countries over
the period 1970 to 2010. With this objective in mind, in the next
subsections we develop the methodology used for the empirical analysis
and present the main empirical results obtained.
Econometric Model
Arellano and Bond (1991) proposed an extension of GMM introduced
initially by Hansen (1982), to the case of panel data for a simple model
AR (1):
[y.sub.it] = [alpha] x [y.sub.it-1] + [[mu].sub.i] + [v.sub.it]
where [absolute value of [gamma]]<0 (1)
As we noted, our sample has 216 countries over the period 1970 to
2010. For this reason, we consider the case where temporal dimension is
small or medium (T = 41), whereas individual dimension (N = 216) is
important. Also, we consider that individual effects are stationary and
we assume traditional hypotheses of residues. Difference models (1) can
be written as below:
[DELTA][y.sub.it] = [alpha] x [DELTA][y.sub.it-1] + [u.sub.it]
where [absolute value of [gamma]]<0 (2)
Where [u.sub.it] = [v.sub.it] - [v.sub.it-1]. The gait of Arellano
and Bond, in presence of the exogenous variables, consists in estimating
the model in difference (6):
[DELTA][y.sub.it] = [p.summation over (k=1)]
[[alpha].sub.k][DELTA][y.sub.i(t-k)] + [beta]'(L)[X.sub.it] +
[DELTA][v.sub.it] (3)
The preceding dynamic model can be rewritten for each individual in
the following form:
[y.sub.i] = [w.sub.i] x [delta] + [[tau].sub.i] x [[mu].sub.i] +
[v.sub.i] (4)
where r is a vector of parameter and vv, is a matrix that contains
the retarded dependent variable and explanatory variables (7).
To have previous value GMM, it is necessary to pass by a first
stage that consists of making wished transformation (first difference or
orthogonal deviation) to find and to use instruments matrix and to
achieve a first evaluation, named "evaluation of first stage."
This stage corresponds to an evaluation that allows for providing
estimated residues after transformation. The objective of transformation
is, as at Anderson and Hsiao (1982), to eliminate individual
heterogeneity of the model. (8)
Finally, Arellano and Bond (1991) propose a test verifying the
absence of autocorrelation of first and second order. (9)
We specify a dynamic model characterized by presence of one
endogenous variable delayed among explanatory variables. Our specified
model is a dynamic panel model given by:
[y.sub.it] = [alpha] x [y.sub.it-1] + [beta]' x [x.sub.it] +
[[mu].sub.i] + [v.sub.it] (5)
where [y.sub.it] is the endogenous variable, [y.sub.it-1]
symbolizes endogenous variable appearing in the regression as being a
retarded explanatory variable. X represents the vector of exogenous
variables, ([alpha], [beta]) designate parameters to estimate, and
[[mu].sub.i] is the specific effect of country (i). This specific effect
can be a stationary or uncertain effect and constitute individual
heterogeneity as: [[mu].sub.i], i.i.d ~ N[(0,1)]; [v.sub.it] is
stochastic term as: [v.sub.it] ~ i.i.d N[(0,1)]. The bias is positive
and increases with the variance of the specific effect. Indeed,
[y.sub.it] is a function of [v.sub.it] as is [v.sub.it-1] x [y.sub.it-1]
is an explanatory variable correlated with stochastic term. It
introduces a bias in the value of ordinary least squares. Even as
putting forth the hypothesis that stochastic terms are not correlated,
this value is nonconvergent. (10)
In our model, [y.sub.it] is the rate of primary school-age female
children out of school ([COSf.sub.it]) in period (t) and country (i).
This rate is explained by (1) ([COSf.sub.it]) of the period (t - 1); (2)
family workers contributing, (11) female ([FWCf.sub.it]) (% of females
employed); (3) total vulnerable employment (TVEit) (% of total
employment); (4) poverty headcount ratio at national poverty line (12)
([PHR.sub.it]) (% of population); (5) proportion of seats held by women
in national parliaments ([SWP.sub.it]) (%); and (6) total population
([TP.sub.it]) like control variable.
Under another form, one can write our model as below:
[COSf.sub.it] = [alpha] x [COSf.sub.it-1] + [[beta].sub.1] x
[CFWf.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.2] x [TVE.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.3] x
[PHR.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.4] x [SWP.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.5] x
[TP.sub.it] + [[mu].sub.i] + [v.sub.it] (6)
Data and Variables
The statistical sources used for this analysis are the World
Bank's World Development Indicators Database (13) and the World
Bank's Education Statistics Database (14).
The primary World Bank collection of development indicators is
compiled from officially recognized international sources. It presents
the most current and accurate global development data available and
includes national, regional, and global estimates.
The World Bank compiles data on education inputs, participation,
efficiency, and outcomes. Data on education are compiled by the United
Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)
Institute for Statistics from official responses to surveys and from
reports provided by education authorities in each country (for more
details about the data, see The World Bank EdStatsQuery (15)).
These databases provide more than 800 development indicators, with
time series for 209 countries and 18 country groups from 1960 to 2011.
Table 1 presents a summary of the key variables used to empirically
validate the dynamic models proposed.
From the World Bank's World Development Indicators Database
and World Bank's Education Statistics Database, we have temporal
observations (T = 41) by countries for the period 1970 to 2010. We are
able to form a balanced panel data; see descriptive statistics of
variables in Table 2.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Starting with a descriptive analysis of data, Table 3 shows large
differences between regions when we compare the current rates (total and
only female) of primary school-age children out of school for 1970 to
2010 in low-income countries. We can underline the rates of East Asia and Pacific (50.6 and 50.1, respectively) and Europe and Central Asia
(7.50 and 7.03, respectively). The other regions have values of 39.27
and 37.72 (Sub-Saharan Africa), 26.98 and 24.14 (South Asia), and 34.4
and 29.6 (Latin America & Caribbean).
If we are considering countries with lower middle income, taxes
will be substantially reduced in East Asia and Pacific, going from 50.1
to 12.68 (one fourth), similar to what occurs in Latin America and the
Caribbean, reducing female dropout rate to one third.
Taking into account the current rates (total and only female) of
contributing family workers, we can highlight for 1970 to 2010 the cases
of East Asia and Pacific (43.97 and 56.15, respectively, in low-income
countries) and 11.90 and 11.20 (Latin America & Caribbean). The
other regions have values of 30.74 and 40.45 (Sub-Saharan Africa), 15.78
and 21.53 (Europe and Central Asia), and 24.56 and 54.30 (South Asia).
Finally, when comparing the proportion of seats held by women in
national parliaments (%) by income level, we can see large differences
between regions that are reduced as we compare them to samples of
countries with higher incomes within each region. Focusing on low-income
level countries, we can underline the cases of East Asia and Pacific
(15.06), South Asia (13.83), Sub-Saharan Africa (13.17), Europe and
Central Asia (10.30), and Latin America and Caribbean (3.88).
On the other hand. Table 4 shows small differences between regions
when we compare the current percentages (by income level) of the
population that is female. These differences are higher when we compare
the rates of the population between age 0 to 14 as a percentage of the
total population. The low-income East Asia and Pacific region has a
value of 35.45. The other regions have values of 39.54 (Europe and
Central Asia), 40.89 (Latin America & Caribbean), 42.86 (South
Asia), and 45.14 (Sub-Saharan Africa).
In Table 4, we also can see large differences between regions when
we compare the poverty headcount ratios at national poverty line (in
terms of % of population). Focusing on low income level, we can
highlight the cases of Latin America and Caribbean (77.00), Europe and
Central Asia (59.67), Sub-Saharan Africa (54.40), South Asia (42.14),
and East Asia and Pacific (36.98).
Finally, taking into account the current rates (total and only
female) of Vulnerable employment (in terms of % of total employment)
(see Table 4), we can emphasize for 1970 to 2010 the cases of East Asia
and Pacific (84.90 and 87.05, respectively, in low-income countries).
The other regions have values of 82.69 and 88.58 (Sub-Saharan Africa),
75.60 and 84.28 (South Asia), and 49.62 and 49.54 (Europe and Central
Asia).
The evaluation that we present in Table 5 corresponds to the GMM
evaluation of Arellano and Bond (1991). In Table 5, the empirical
evaluations show a negative relation between contributing family workers
(female) and primary school-age children out of school rate (female), in
Europe and Central Asia region. In this case for GMM method in first
difference, the variable contributing family workers (female) is
negative and significant (-.5869098), (T-Stat = .3082361). The result is
consistent with the findings of Canagarajah and Coulombe (1998) who
report some clear gender-based distinctions in the type of tasks
performed by a girl and a boy worker; girls do more household chores,
while boys are in labor force.
However, we cannot find empirical evidence between primary
school-age children out of school rate (female) and the variables used
to analyze the effect of poverty and social exclusion (poverty headcount
ratio at national poverty line and total vulnerable employment,
respectively). In other words, like in Colclough et al. (2000), we do
not find sufficient evidence that poverty is associated with an
underenrollment of school-age female children. In other words, the
gendered outcomes of such underenrollment could be the product of
cultural practice, rather than of poverty per se. Under this point of
view, and according to these authors, gender inequalities in schooling
outcomes, measured in qualitative and quantitative terms, will not
necessarily be reduced as incomes rise.
Finally, identification of effects of other variables is far from
being obvious according to different evaluations. For example, a
positive and significant value on proportion of seats held by women in
national parliaments (.2914276) with a (T-Stat = .1309497) in Europe and
Central Asia region. This result is not consistent with the findings of
Brown and Park (2002). According to these authors, women's
empowerment reduces the likelihood of dropping out.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The literature on poverty, gender exclusion, and child labor and
schooling is large and continually growing. This article considered the
impact of each of these factors, while controlling others at the same
time. It examined geographic regions individually and separately, with
the anticipation that differentials in livelihood strategies and
opportunities could be reflected in female child schooling decisions.
Given the data, it is noteworthy that in most low-income countries
the male dropout rate is higher than the female rate, which may give us
a first indication of the relationship between child labor (more men
than women) and dropouts.
Another finding of note is that though in poor countries in East
Asia and the Pacific, the proportion of women contributing to family
workers is higher than the total (56.9 vs. 43.9), in terms of dropout
percentage coincides (50.1 and 56.1), in regions such as Latin America
and Caribbean, this percentage of contribution of family workers is much
lower compared to the female dropout rate (29.6 and 11.2). In Europe, it
is the opposite; this relation is inverse, with a 21.6 female family
contributions and 7.03 female dropout rate.
It seems that some correlation exists between female dropouts and
contributing family workers and the level of development of the region.
As we analyze the poorest regions (in global terms), contributing family
workers and dropout have similar rates (women leave school and go to
work on their own, the economy has high rates of informal employment
that can withstand it); this is the case in East Asia and Pacific, where
the dropout rate is much lower than the proportion of contributing
family workers in the most developed region, whereas school dropout is
much higher in less-developed regions with high levels of inequality
income--though the number of women working on their own is lower, like
in Latin America and the Caribbean.
Our econometric analysis shows a negative and significant relation
between contributing family workers (female) and primary school-age
children out of school rate (female), in Europe and Central Asia region.
However, we cannot find empirical evidence between primary school-age
children out of school rate (female) and the variables used to analyze
the effect of poverty and social exclusion when we analyze other regions
(poverty headcount ratio at national poverty line and total vulnerable
employment).
Moreover, identification of effects of other variables, like amount
of seats held by women in national parliaments, is far from being
evident according to different evaluations.
Even though our results were obtained considering aggregate primary
school-age children out of school rate as the explanatory variable, we
think it will be a very useful disaggregate (data by family) approach,
to evaluate if our findings are robust.
We believe that efforts in these directions could be very
productive for a deeper understanding of the factors that may affect the
education of socially excluded girls in developing countries.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
As for the policy implications that can be associated with our
analysis, we start by considering that education systems in many regions
leave out a significant number of people, especially girls, forcing us
to recommend that if investments in education are discriminate then the
inversions should focus on resolving structural impediments that go
beyond education. Consequently, it is noteworthy that education policies
will not solve the problem of discrimination as there are many factors
and sectors involved in this relationship and in any case the level of
development determines any action.
Taking into account the last consideration, we judge especially
relevant all research about programs that work to mitigate the effects
of social exclusion, child labor, poverty, and education, to offer
policy recommendations and unanswered research questions. In this line
of work, we recommend the excellent work of Tembon and Fort (2008),
where the authors have an interesting list of interventions that have
worked to improve girls' education.
According to Tembon and Fort (2008), and taking into account what
has been said so far, the first thing to consider is that an increase in
demand should reduce tuition fees but mostly promote conditional
transfer programs to women's education.
Another important issue regards concentrating research efforts on
gender inequality above all factors and strengthening community action
policy as a way to improve the social and cultural limitations
associated with access of female children to education.
Finally, it is necessary to promote female secondary education
because it involves improving returns on investment in female education.
Attending to educational models, including diffusion and awareness of
this gender discrimination is linked to education.
DOI: 10.1080/02568543.2014.884028
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The authors thank the editor and two anonymous reviewers for their
constructive comments and kindness in helping us improve the manuscript.
Also, the authors thank Diana C. Prieto for her inspiration to conduct
our research on gender issues.
REFERENCES
Anderson, T. W., & Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 18, 47-82.
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some test of specification for
panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and application to employment
equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277-297.
Aslam, M., & Kingdon, G. (2008). Gender and household education
expenditure in Pakistan. Applied Economics, 40, 2573-2591.
Assaad, R., Levison, D., & Zibani, N. (2007). The effect of
child work on schooling: Evidence from Egypt (Minnesota Population
Center Working Paper 2007-4). Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota
Press.
Bourguignon, F., Ferreira, F., & Leite, P. (2003). Conditional
cash transfers, schooling and child labor: Micro- simulating
Brazil's Bolsa Escola program. The World Bank Economic Review,
17(2), 229-254.
Boyle, S., Brock, A., Mace, J., & Sibbons, M. (2002). Reaching
the poor: The "costs" of sending children to school. Synthesis
report. London, UK: Department for International Development (DFID).
Brown, P., & Park, A. (2002). Education and poverty in rural
China. Economics of Education Review, 21(6), 523-541.
Canagarajah, R. S., & Coulombe, H. (1998). Child labor and
schooling in Ghana (Policy Research Working Paper 1844). Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Colclough, C., Rose, P., & Tembon, T. (2000). Gender
inequalities in primary schooling: The roles of poverty an adverse
cultural practice. International Journal of Educational Development,
20(1), 5-27.
De Janvry, A., Finan, F., Sadoulet, E., & Vakis, R. (2006). Can
conditional cash transfer programs serve as safety nets in keeping
children at school and from working when exposed to shocks? Journal of
Development Economics, 79, 349-373.
Ersado, L. (2005). Child labor and schooling decisions in urban and
rural areas: Comparative evidence from Nepal, Peru, and Zimbabwe. World
Development, 33(3), 454-480.
Filmer, D. (2005). Disability, poverty, and schooling in developing
countries: Results from 11 household surveys. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Filmer, D. (2006). Gender and wealth disparities in schooling:
Evidence from 44 countries. International Journal of Educational
Research, 43(6), 351-369.
Gubert, F., & Robilliard, A. (2006). Do household income shocks
affect school attendance in rural areas?: A case study of Madagascar
(Working Paper). Paris, France: Developpement, Institutions &
Analyses de Long Terme.
Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method
of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50, 1029-1054.
Hazarika, G., & Bedi, A. S. (2002). Schooling cost and child
labor in rural Pakistan (ZEF Discussion Paper on Development Policy, No.
52). Bonn, Germany: ZentrumfurEntwicklungsforschung.
Herz, B., & Sperling, G. B. (2004). What works in girls'
education. Evidence and policies from the developing world. New York,
NY: Council on Foreign Relations.
Huebler, F. (2008, September). Child labour and school attendance:
Evidence from MICS and DHS surveys. Paper presented at Seminar on Child
Labour, Education and Youth Employment. Understanding Children's
Work Project, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Madrid, Spain.
Jensen, P., & Nielson, H. S. (1997). Child labor or school
attendance? Evidence from Zambia. Journal of Population Economics, 10,
407-424.
Kajisa, K., & Palanichamy, N. V. (2010). Schooling investments
over three decades in rural Tamil Nadu, India: Changing effects of
income, gender, and adult family members' education. World
Development, 38(3), 298-314.
Kakwani, N., Soares, F., & Son, H. H. (2006). Cash transfers
for school-age children in African countries: Simulation of impacts on
poverty and school attendance. Development Policy Review, 24, 553-569.
doi: 10.1111/j.14677679.2006.00347.x
Kumara, A. S., & Pfau, W. D. (2011). Impact of cash transfer
programmes on school attendance and child poverty: An ex ante simulation
for Sri Lanka. Journal of Development Studies, 47(11), 1699-1720.
Lewis, M. A., & Lockheed, M. E. (2006). Inexcusable absence:
Why 60 million girls still aren't in school and what to do about
it. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.
Lloyd, C. B., Mete, C., & Sathar, Z. A. (2005). The effect of
gender differences in primary school access, type, and quality on the
decision to enroll in rural Pakistan. Economic Development and Cultural
Change, 53(3), 685-710.
Miles, S., & Singal, N. (2010). The Education for All and
inclusive education debate: Conflict, contradiction or opportunity?
International Journal of Inclusive Education, 14(1), 1-15.
Morduch, J. (1999). The microfinance promise. Journal of Economic
Literature, 37(4), 1569-1614.
Moyi, P. (2011). Child labor and school attendance in Kenya.
Educational Research and Reviews, 6(1), 26-35.
Mugisha, F. (2006). School enrollment among non-slum, slum and
rural children in Kenya: Is the urban advantage eroding? International
Journal of Educational Development, 26(5), 471-482.
Patrinos, H. A., & Psacharopoulos, G. (1997). Family size,
schooling and child labor in Peru: An empirical analysis. Journal of
Population Economics, 10, 387-405.
Psacharopoulos, G. (1997). Child labor versus educational
attainment: Some evidence from Latin America. Journal of Population
Economics, 10(4), 377-386.
Ravallion, M., & Wodon, Q. (1999). Does child labor displace schooling? Evidence on behavioral responses to an enrollment subsidy
(Working Paper 2116). Washington, DC: World Bank.
Rose, R, & Al-Samarrai, S. (2001). Household constraints on
schooling by gender: Empirical evidence from Ethiopia. Comparative
Education Review, 45(1), 36-63.
Sawada, Y., & Lokshin, M. (2009). Obstacles to school
progression in rural Pakistan: An analysis of gender and rivalry using
field survey data. Journal of Development Economics, 88, 335-347.
Shapiro, D., & Tambashe, O. B. (2001). Gender, poverty, family
structure, and investments in children's education in Kinshasa,
Congo. Economics of Education Review, 20(4), 359-375.
Son, H. H., & Florentine, J. (2008). Ex-ante impact evaluation
of conditional cash transfer program on school attendance and poverty:
The case of Philippines (ADB Economics Working Paper Series, No. 142).
Manila, Philippines: Asian Development Bank.
Tembon, M., & Fort, L. (2008). Girls' education in the
21st century: Gender equality, empowerment, and economic growth.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Yu, G. (2007). Research evidence of school effectiveness in
sub-Saharan countries (EdQual Working Paper, 7). Bristol, UK: University
of Bristol Press.
Leopoldo Laborda Castillo
The World Bank and Institute of Latin American Studies, University
of Alcala, Spain
Daniel Sotelsek Salem
Institute of Latin American Studies, University of Alcala, Spain
Leopold Remi Sarr
The World Bank SASHD, Washington, District of Columbia
Submitted May 5, 2012; accepted April 19, 2013.
Address correspondence to Dr. Leopoldo Laborda Castillo, Institute
of Latin American Studies, University of Alcala, c/ Trinidad no. 1,
Colegio de Trinitarios, Alcala de Henares, 28801, Madrid, Spain. E-mail:
llabordacatillo@gmail.com
NOTES
(1.) According to the 2012 Education for All Global Monitoring
Report, many young people the world--especially the disadvantaged--are
leaving school without the skills they need to thrive in society and
find decent jobs. The report will focus on skills development,
emphasizing strategies that increase employment opportunities for
marginalized groups.
(2.) To achieve these, we need to solve some methodological
problems related with the estimation of models by traditional methods,
such as Ordinary Least Square (OLS) and Least Squares Dummy Variable (LSDV), that led to ad hoc results. In order to solve this problem, we
propose one method (based on Arellano & Bond, 1991) that consists of
obtaining consistent estimators.
(3.) According to Filmer (2006), the gender gap is still
substantial in countries in South Asia and North and West Africa. In
countries where the gender gap is large among youth in the poorest
quintile, it is not nearly as large in the richest quintile.
(4.) A plausible explanation, according these authors, is that
substitution effects helped protect current incomes from the higher
school attendance induced by the subsidy.
(5.) Ordinary least square (OLS) and least squares dummy variable
(LSDV) give biased and non convergent values because of
inter-relationship between retarded endogenous variable and individual
heterogeneity. Under these circumstances, our models should not be
estimated by the method of OLS and LSDV due to the fact that estimating
by these methods led to ad hoc results.
(6.) Previously, we tested for every individual of the linear
restrictions of type:
E[([DELTA][Y.sub.it] = [alpha] x [DELTA][y.sub.it-1])[y.sub.it]] =
0 for j = 2,..., t; t = 3,...t
(7.) The method proposed by these authors permit a GMM in two
stages, written in the following form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(8.) The number of instrument increases in the time for every
individual. In the case where explanatory variables exist, [x.sub.it],
is the model correlated with heterogeneity individual [[mu].sub.i];.
(9.) Thus, if distribution is non auto-correlated, this test gives
a value of residues differentiated negative and significant to first
order and non significant to the second order. This test is based on
auto-covariance of residues following a normal law N(0,1) under
hypothesis [H.sub.0].
(10.) The evaluation of the models by traditional methods (OLS and
within) gives biased and non convergent values because of
inter-relationship between retarded endogenous variable and individual
heterogeneity. In this context, our models should not be estimated by
OLS and LSDV methods due to the fact that estimating by these methods
led to ad hoc results. We propose one method that consists of obtaining
consistent estimators.
(11.) Originally, we used other variables to approach child labor,
like total economically active children (% of children age 7-14) or
economically active children, work only (% of economically active
children, ages 7-14). Unfortunately, the available data for these
variables do not allow applying the proposed methodology.
(12.) Also, we used other variables, like GINI Index, in order to
approach the inequality. One more time, the available data for these
variables do not allow applying the proposed methodology.
(13.) World Development Indicators Database is the primary World
Bank database for development data from officially recognized
international sources.
(14.) Education Statistics Database provides data on education from
national statistical reports, statistical annexes of new publications,
and other data sources.
(15.) The World Bank EdStats Query holds around 2,500
internationally comparable education indicators for access, progression,
completion, literacy, teachers, population, and expenditures. The
indicators cover the education cycle from pre-primary to tertiary
education. The query also holds learning outcome data from international
learning assessments (Programme for International Student Assessment [PISA], Trends in International Mathematics and Science Study [TIMSS],
etc.), equity data from household surveys, and projection data to 2050.
EdStats website: http://go.worldbank. org/ITABCOGIV1.
TABLE 1
Key Variables
Variable Definition
Rate of primary school-age Rate of primary school-age
children out of school. Total children out of school. Total is
the total number of out-of-school
children as a percentage of all
primary school-age children.
Rate of primary school-age Rate of primary school-age
children out of school. Female children out of school. Female is
the total number of female
out-of-school children as a
percentage of all female primary
school-age children.
Contributing family workers, total Contributing family workers are
(% of total employed) those workers who hold
"self-employment jobs" as
own-account workers in a
market-oriented establishment
operated by a related person
living in the same household.
Contributing family workers, Contributing family workers are
female (% of females employed) those workers who hold
"self-employment jobs" as
own-account workers in a
market-oriented establishment
operated by a related person
living in the same household.
Vulnerable employment, total (% of Vulnerable employment is unpaid
total employment) family workers and own-account
workers as a percentage of total
employment.
Vulnerable employment, female Vulnerable employment is unpaid
(% of female employment) family workers and own-account
workers as a percentage of total
employment.
Poverty headcount ratio at national National poverty rate is the
poverty line (% of population) percentage of the population
living below the national poverty
line. (a)
Proportion of seats held by women Women in parliaments are the
in national parliaments (%) percentage of parliamentary seats
in a single or lower chamber held
by women.
Population, total Total population is based on the
de facto definition of
population, which counts all
residents regardless of legal
status or citizenship--except for
refugees not permanently settled
in the country of asylum, who are
generally considered part of the
population of their country of
origin. (b)
Population, female (% of total) Female population is the
percentage of the population that
is female. (c)
Population ages 0-14 (% of total) Population between the ages 0 to
14 as a percentage of the total
population. (c)
Source: Author's elaboration using World Bank's World Development
Indicators Database (2011) and World Bank's Education Statistics
Database (2011). http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/
(a) National estimates are based on population-weighted subgroup
estimates from household surveys. (b) The values shown are
midyear estimates. (c) Population is based on the de facto
definition of population.
TABLE 2
Descriptive Statistics
Variable Observations Mean
Total Sample
Primary school-age children 2,568 19.87
out of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 1,718 9.93
Vulnerable employment, total 1,494 25.65
Poverty headcount ratio at national 537 37.09
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 2,561 13.84
in national parliaments
Population, total 8717 24,600,000
East Asia & Pacific
Primary school-age children out of 296 9.31
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 237 15.73
Vulnerable employment, total 211 28.20
Poverty headcount ratio at national 60 24.72
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 368 10.62
in national parliaments
Population, total 1476 49,300,000
Europe & Central Asia
Primary school-age children out of 613 5.63
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 782 6.72
Vulnerable employment, total 679 16.21
Poverty headcount ratio at national 101 24.37
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 720 18.27
in national parliaments
Population, total 2,358 14,300,000
Latin America & Caribbean
Primary school-age children out of 434 11.56
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 422 6.27
Vulnerable employment, total 394 32.37
Poverty headcount ratio at national 216 40.82
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 465 14.88
in national parliaments
Population, total 1,625 11,100,000
Middle East & North Africa
Primary school-age children out of 422 23.66
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 93 17.06
Vulnerable employment, total 93 23.41
Poverty headcount ratio at national 21 17.09
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 250 6.19
in national parliaments
Population, total 838 12,300,000
North America
Primary school-age children out of 36 3.33
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 58 0.67
Proportion of seats held by women 30 17.21
in national parliaments
Population, total 123 94,000,000
South Asia
Primary school-age children out of 61 35.86
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 43 38.05
Vulnerable employment, total 46 52.96
Poverty headcount ratio at national 25 35.66
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 103 10.29
in national parliaments
Population, total 328 141,000.000
Sub-Saharan Africa
Primary school-age children out 706 38.95
of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 83 26.19
Vulnerable employment, total 71 56.15
Poverty headcount ratio at national 114 51.80
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 625 13.32
in national parliaments
Population, total 1,969 11,100,000
Variable SD Minimum
Total Sample
Primary school-age children 22.03 0.06
out of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 14.83 0.00
Vulnerable employment, total 19.55 0.40
Poverty headcount ratio at national 18.07 2.80
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 9.93 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 101,000,000 5450
East Asia & Pacific
Primary school-age children out of 9.68 0.06
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 17.06 0.00
Vulnerable employment, total 24.68 2.00
Poverty headcount ratio at national 13.94 2.80
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 9.49 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 186,000,000 7296
Europe & Central Asia
Primary school-age children out of 4.97 0.12
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 11.29 0.00
Vulnerable employment, total 12.64 0.80
Poverty headcount ratio at national 16.50 4.90
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 10.58 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 25,000,000 19,136
Latin America & Caribbean
Primary school-age children out of 12.85 0.15
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 6.61 0.00
Vulnerable employment, total 11.15 3.90
Poverty headcount ratio at national 14.62 9.90
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 8.53 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 27,200,000 5,450
Middle East & North Africa
Primary school-age children out of 21.30 0.52
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 17.93 0.00
Vulnerable employment, total 16.88 0.40
Poverty headcount ratio at national 9.87 3.80
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 6.56 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 16,800,000 108,401
North America
Primary school-age children out of 2.29 0.10
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 0.57 0.10
Proportion of seats held by women 4.02 7.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 116,000,000 53,000
South Asia
Primary school-age children out of 24.93 1.40
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 21.19 3.40
Vulnerable employment, total 15.21 29.60
Poverty headcount ratio at national 11.10 15.20
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 7.94 2.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 281,000,000 115,772
Sub-Saharan Africa
Primary school-age children out 24.63 0.74
of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 25.94 0.40
Vulnerable employment, total 31.26 3.50
Poverty headcount ratio at national 14.49 10.10
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 9.20 0.00
in national parliaments
Population, total 18,200,000 36,755
Variable Maximum
Total Sample
Primary school-age children 95.38
out of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 89.10
Vulnerable employment, total 96.40
Poverty headcount ratio at national 92.30
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 56.30
in national parliaments
Population, total 1,340,000,000
East Asia & Pacific
Primary school-age children out of 45.30
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 64.20
Vulnerable employment, total 90.10
Poverty headcount ratio at national 61.10
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 33.60
in national parliaments
Population, total 1,340,000,000
Europe & Central Asia
Primary school-age children out of 25.43
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 71.30
Vulnerable employment, total 65.10
Poverty headcount ratio at national 92.30
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 47.30
in national parliaments
Population, total 149,000,000
Latin America & Caribbean
Primary school-age children out of 77.95
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 40.20
Vulnerable employment, total 66.10
Poverty headcount ratio at national 77.00
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 43.20
in national parliaments
Population, total 195,000,000
Middle East & North Africa
Primary school-age children out of 95.38
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 56.10
Vulnerable employment, total 58.10
Poverty headcount ratio at national 40.10
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 31.50
in national parliaments
Population, total 81,100,000
North America
Primary school-age children out of 9.71
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 2.10
Proportion of seats held by women 22.10
in national parliaments
Population, total 309,000,000
South Asia
Primary school-age children out of 91.58
school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 77.30
Vulnerable employment, total 85.00
Poverty headcount ratio at national 56.60
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 33.20
in national parliaments
Population, total 1,170,000,000
Sub-Saharan Africa
Primary school-age children out 93.17
of school rate. Female
Contributing family workers, female 89.10
Vulnerable employment, total 96.40
Poverty headcount ratio at national 81.60
poverty line
Proportion of seats held by women 56.30
in national parliaments
Population, total 158,000,000
Source: Author's elaboration using World Bank's World Development
Indicators Database (2011) and World Bank's Education Statistics
Database (2011). http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/
TABLE 3
Descriptive Statistics
Primary school-
age children out Contributing
of school rate family workers
Variable Total Female Total Female
Total sample
High income: OECD 3.64 2.63 2.57 4.78
High income: non-OECD 3.90 2.80 1.42 2.58
Low income 36.14 34.60 28.82 39.61
Lower middle income 18.94 16.79 14.44 22.89
Upper middle income 11.21 9.22 6.68 10.70
East Asia & Pacific
High income: OECD 5.24 10.92
High income: non-OECD 1.00 1.91
Low income 50.60 50.10 43.97 56.15
Lower middle income 13.66 12.68 21.83 33.18
Upper middle income 15.10 14.40 19.33 29.20
Europe & Central Asia
High income: OECD 3.64 2.63 2.35 4.18
High income: non-OECD 2.38 4.00
Low income 7.50 7.03 15.78 21.53
Lower middle income 21.16 19.64 10.19 12.70
Upper middle income 12.61 10.94 9.01 16.88
Latin America & Caribbean
High income: OECD
High income: non-OECD 3.90 2.80 1.00 1.80
Low income 33.40 29.60 11.90 11.20
Lower middle income 15.86 11.48 10.59 11.57
Upper middle income 9.36 6.99 4.14 5.53
Middle East & North Africa
High income: OECD 0.41 0.73
High income: non-OECD 0.05 0.17
Lower middle income 12.50 10.32 14.60 32.09
Upper middle income 5.06 9.26
North America
High income: OECD 0.39 0.67
South Asia
Low income 26.98 24.24 24.56 54.30
Lower middle income 8.80 7.57 17.75 38.81
Upper middle income 6.55 11.25
Sub-Saharan Africa
High income: non-OECD 39.50 76.50
Low income 39.27 37.72 30.74 40.45
Lower middle income 28.35 27.22 19.83 28.79
Upper middle income 21.57 20.54 4.35 6.01
Proportion of
seats in national
parliaments
Variable Held by women
Total sample
High income: OECD 21.64
High income: non-OECD 11.18
Low income 12.88
Lower middle income 10.11
Upper middle income 14.12
East Asia & Pacific
High income: OECD 16.82
High income: non-OECD 13.54
Low income 15.06
Lower middle income 8.26
Upper middle income 9.92
Europe & Central Asia
High income: OECD 23.21
High income: non-OECD 15.49
Low income 10.30
Lower middle income 11.66
Upper middle income 13.96
Latin America & Caribbean
High income: OECD
High income: non-OECD 14.46
Low income 3.88
Lower middle income 13.20
Upper middle income 16.07
Middle East & North Africa
High income: OECD 12.83
High income: non-OECD 3.58
Lower middle income 7.32
Upper middle income 6.05
North America
High income: OECD 17.21
South Asia
Low income 13.83
Lower middle income 8.64
Upper middle income 7.79
Sub-Saharan Africa
High income: non-OECD 9.67
Low income 13.17
Lower middle income 11.30
Upper middle income 18.90
Source: Author's elaboration using World Bank's World Development
Indicators Database (2011) and World Bank's Education Statistics
Database (2011). http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/
Note. OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation &
Development.
TABLE 4
Descriptive Statistics
Population
Variable Total Female Ages 0-14
Total sample
High income: OECD 29,548,585 51.04 21.14
High income: non-OECD 1,189,143 47.75 29.45
Low income 1,4881,133 50.49 43.67
Lower middle income 31,682,649 50.10 40.81
Upper middle income 37,324,952 50.35 33.35
East Asia & Pacific
High income: OECD 45,947,661 50.41 23.57
High income: non-OECD 1,266,778 48.93 29.51
Low income 22,776,484 51.10 35.45
Lower middle income 20,196,383 49.32 40.69
Upper middle income 238,100,000 49.31 32.74
Europe & Central Asia
High income: OECD 18,554,854 51.21 20.27
High income: non-OECD 530,138 50.88 20.30
Low income 4,668,863 50.76 39.54
Lower middle income 12,321,953 52.13 29.41
Upper middle income 20,562,176 51.44 25.20
Latin America & Caribbean
High income: non-OECD 568,787 51.31 28.94
Low income 7,197,950 50.64 40.89
Lower middle income 4,460,522 50.32 42.13
Upper middle income 18,661,863 50.23 35.02
Middle East & North Africa
High income: OECD 5,045,210 50.28 30.56
High income: non-OECD 3,285,539 41.90 32.16
Lower middle income 19,680,477 49.88 43.95
Upper middle income 16,015,017 49.17 39.01
North America
High income: OECD 140,900,000 50.68 21.92
High income: non-OECD 58,864
South Asia
Low income 48,747,619 48.82 42.86
Lower middle income 245,700,000 48.61 37.67
Upper middle income 216,408 48.24 42.19
Sub-Saharan Africa
High income: non-OECD 402.619 49.62 40.59
Low income 11,143,525 50.59 45.14
Lower middle income 14,487,527 50.38 44.37
Upper middle income 5,810,620 50.30 39.85
Population Vulnerable
employment
Poverty
headcount
Variable ratio Total Female
Total sample
High income: OECD 14.15 12.80 11.72
High income: non-OECD 11.15 11.65 9.65
Low income 52.94 77.95 82.95
Lower middle income 42.17 47.75 52.63
Upper middle income 29.21 29.38 29.61
East Asia & Pacific
High income: OECD 14.50 14.71
High income: non-OECD 7.57 5.39
Low income 36.98 84.90 87.05
Lower middle income 29.31 59.81 61.45
Upper middle income 14.00 45.00 47.53
Europe & Central Asia
High income: OECD 14.15 12.70 11.47
High income: non-OECD 11.15 17.82 16.87
Low income 59.67 49.62 49.54
Lower middle income 36.78 47.05 47.29
Upper middle income 19.64 23.46 25.65
Latin America & Caribbean
High income: non-OECD 15.39 13.35
Low income 77.00
Lower middle income 52.20 44.11 48.89
Upper middle income 35.65 30.82 29.53
Middle East & North Africa
High income: OECD 7.31 5.16
High income: non-OECD 6.57 3.27
Lower middle income 22.43 35.60 44.47
Upper middle income 9.97 19.72 20.23
North America
High income: OECD
High income: non-OECD
South Asia
Low income 42.14 75.60 84.28
Lower middle income 32.01 50.76 56.79
Upper middle income 45.03 47.60
Sub-Saharan Africa
High income: non-OECD
Low income 54.40 82.69 88.58
Lower middle income 50.18 64.35 73.96
Upper middle income 39.70 22.22 25.63
Source: Author's elaboration using World Bank's World Development
Indicators Database (2011) and World Bank's Education Statistics
Database (2011). http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/
Note. OECD = Organisation for Economic Co-operation &
Development.
TABLE 5
Arellano-Bond Dynamic Panel-Data Estimation
Europe &
Total East Asia Central
sample & Pacific Asia
Primary school-age children .5807747 -.6373511 5.237717
out-of-school rate. Female (3.661537) (1.995393) (4.840322)
(t-1)
Contributing family workers, .2410075 .2718573 -.5869098 *
female (8.989808) (1.500356)
Vulnerable employment, total -.1096033 1.992803
(8.989808) (1.500356)
Poverty headcount ratio at .0482351 -.6984193
national poverty line (.5444332) (.8583749)
Proportion of seats held by .1320133 -.1338773 .2914276 **
women in national parliaments (2.924875) (.3214143) (.1309497)
Population, total 8.67e-08 5.49e-09 3.93e-06
(7.83e-07) (3.23e-07) (4.49e-06)
Constant -1.022577 5.641936 -165.2246
(343.0793) (27.46188) (165.0323)
Wald test 21.10(6) 4.60(4) 895.64(6)
p = 0.0018 p = 0.3303 p = 0.0000
Z1 -.29097 .24454 1.213
p = 0.7711 p = 0.8068 p = 0.2251
Z2 .33551 -1.3442 .11813
p = 0.7372 p = 0.1789 p = 0.9060
Number of observations 62 42 22
Number of countries 16 7 6
Number of instruments 61 43 23
Middle
Latin East &
America & North North
Caribbean Africa America
Primary school-age children .1069637 1.735705 -.7145833
out-of-school rate. Female (.8839579) (2.522761) (1.096824)
(t-1)
Contributing family workers, .2522918 -.8473913
female (4.860935)
Vulnerable employment, total 1.099444
(4.860935)
Poverty headcount ratio at -.1193502
national poverty line (.3750561)
Proportion of seats held by -.4332201 16.8154
women in national parliaments (1.173789) (16.90888)
Population, total 9.66e-09 -5.36e-06
(3.17e-06) (6.25e-06)
Constant 14.01507 -20.8496 6.169449
(60.3795) (83.19342) (4.534489)
Wald test 2.56(4) 34904.89(5) 0.42(1)
p = 0.6334 p = 0.0000 p = 0.5147
Z1 -.10265 -1.0399 .35266
p = 0.9182 p = 0.2984 p = 0.7243
Z2 .42416 .35869 -.59595
p = 0.6715 p = 0.7198 p = 0.5512
Number of observations 37 33 22
Number of countries 8 5 2
Number of instruments 38 34 23
Sub-
Saharan
South Asia Africa
Primary school-age children .4515872 1.946769
out-of-school rate. Female (4.007345) (2.168624)
(t-1)
Contributing family workers, -.7275889
female
Vulnerable employment, total
Poverty headcount ratio at
national poverty line
Proportion of seats held by 2.047856 5.09946
women in national parliaments (15.88617) (4.817993)
Population, total -1.00e-07 -.0000165
(8.25e-07) (.0000115)
Constant 3.144029 277.2494
(583.0526) (162.2576)
Wald test 53.90(3) 1020.45(4)
p = 0.0000 p = 0.0000
Z1 .11264 -.63949
p = 0.9103 p = 0.5225
Z2 -.27875 .93073
p = 0.7804 p = 0.3520
Number of observations 16 13
Number of countries 4 5
Number of instruments 17 14
Source: Author's elaboration using World Bank's World Development
Indicators Database (2011) and World Bank's Education Statistics
Database (2011). http://datacatalog.worldbank.org/
Note. Z Arellano-Bond test for zero autocorrelation in
first-differenced errors, where HO: no autocorrelation. Model
with WC-Robust Standard Error and Two-Step Results.