Development reframed: comments on the 2013 Romanian regionalization approach.
Maniu, Mircea Teodor
General Outlook
Soon after the 2005 reconsideration of the Lisbon Strategy, a
process mainly aiming to improve the competitive position of EU's
regions in a more and more competitive world economy by fostering
growth, employment and overall competitiveness, the crisis was already a
widespread phenomenon. Looking back in the 2007-2013 EU budget, we can
notice that Romania has been allocated almost 20 billion Euros under the
Convergence Objective 1 and more than 450 million Euros under the
European Territorial Cooperation Objective, while the very Regional
Operational Program amounts to 3.7 million Euros. In EU's planning
the bulk of these funds, actually more than 80%, was supposed to
contribute to the so called Convergence Regions, defined as those
territorial units situated under 75% of EU's average income, which
will obviously depict the situation of Romania. Only the less than 20%
rest was supposed to finance European competitiveness. But if we adjust
these figures with the degree of absorption (1) of EU funds in Romania,
we will suddenly become much less optimistic for the overall evolution
of the regionalization approach.
Nevertheless, interpreting recent data we can state that EU
Cohesion Policy Programs in Romania could contribute to at least an
increase of 15% in GDP, as computed for the whole 2007-2013 budget
period. Such a vision was definitely tributary to the largely overrated
absorption capacity of the country, in connection with the lack of
proper econometric means in order to assess the amplitude of the crisis.
(2) Since one cannot judge without significant political bias what
worked, falling right in place, and what was spent inefficiently in this
process, I favor a procedure that could embed all the measurable inputs,
and to a large extent also outputs, at regional level. Let's assume
that such an approach would necessarily be a "smart",
innovative, regional pattern for development. This could work for
Romania, for reasons to be elaborated below, on the long run, just as
the administrative reform initiated in Poland (Petrakas, Maier and
Gorzelak, 2001) in 1999 was proven successful and fruitful only a decade
later, and even more relevant, this happened in harsh crisis conditions.
(3)
So, my point is that any growth engine that worked in various
moments for Romania (domestic consumption, exports) cannot make the
difference on the short run as a politically induced "push-up"
process that would build the necessary entropy for the next EU budgetary
cycle. Making viable the Romanian regions among the 273 NUTS II (4) type
of regions does not mean only updating a task that was embedded in the
Romania's Accession Treaty and should have occurred anyway long
time ago. In a juncture when it is obvious that the regions of Europe
become increasingly quasi-independent players, EU or even world scale,
doing this means only to play the game of the moment. As the regions are
motivated by the increased challenges that derive today from global
economic perspectives, and various and complex exogenous factors tend to
re-shape even less opened economies, the managerial layer of governance
of the regions turns to be a proper decisional step. (5)
Romania on the Regionalization Track
EU inspired approaches towards regional development and consequent
regionalization occurred in most Central and Eastern European (CEE)
countries during the 90s. At this stage Romania's regionalization
policy has been described in numerous sources as a classical effect of
"Europeanization" (6) bluntly meaning the chase for
pre-accession funds. Following preliminary results in respect to EU
funding a Green Card concerning regional development and the Law of
Regional Development (151/1998--modified in 2004) were passed. Almost on
the spot, Romania was "divided" into 8 development regions
(DR). True, the law was conceived in such a manner that the counties in
place would negotiate and later on join a certain development region on
volunteer basis, according to the results of negotiations, public
consultations and feasibility studies. But it was clear that the
priority task of the Government, namely to create a territorial frame of
NUTS II type in Romania, implicitly designed in order to absorb EU
money, was accomplished.
It is not beyond discussion the fact that such a scheme was drawing
upon the 1976 National Territorial Plan, a politically driven plan that
imposed on Romania a development model having as main target diminishing
of the economic imbalances between counties and historical provinces but
purposely ignoring the past and the historical peculiarities of those
territories. (7) While keeping in place the 1968 administrative grid
(actually still valid in 2013), regions, in the sense we are branding
them today, were inexistent during the communist regime, though the very
name of region, used in the sense of county, was in legal use between
1951-1968. Such an approach, fully consistent with the communist
obsession of even industrialization throughout the country, and the fact
that the overall development should be nothing but a consequence of
industrialization, led to the situation that practically all the
Romanian macro-regions (historical provinces) developed heavy
industries, obviously redundant, while inter-regional linking
infrastructure was the least priority of the regime. Not to mention that
significant developmental discrepancies were still to be observed during
the late 80s. (8)
There is no wonder that building on such grounds and mechanically
conceiving the regional framework in order comply with EU funding
procedures has been branded as strongly artificial and ultimately
conceived as nothing more than "another transitional tool" of
regionalization, subject to change as soon as the economic geography
will start to matter in terms of transactions' costs. (9) It is
exactly what is invoked by those willing to approach the issue in a
top-down manner, through major legal administrative changes, including
the Constitution. Namely the Government decided to launch a campaign in
order to familiarize the society with the fact that the very core of the
process of regionalization should be the economic optimality and
cohesion only a subsidiary effect, to be boosted mainly through EU
platforms. It is empirically proven (in other countries) that any decent
SWOT analysis would indicate the cost effectiveness of this approach.
The opponents of this view are favoring a bottom-up approach which
implies the "natural" non political creation of regions on
dual basis: a decent macro PEST (Political, Economic, Social,
Technological) investigation, conducted country wide along with general
public consultations in order to determine precisely the state of the
public opinion concerning the issue. The non political trade-off would
be definitely the timing of the operation, the second implying a much
longer period till in place, while the first would inevitably trigger
public unrest concerning decisions that would influence the destiny of
common people simply by political will.
Main Rationale for Regionalization: Diminishing Transactions Costs
While some sources point out to the fact that the term European
regionalism refers to the emergence of overtly political regional
pressures across Europe, mainly due to the resurrection of multilayered
identity, most of them consider that economic competitiveness would be
the capital driving force behind regionalism. (10) From an
economist's point of view, the territorial evolution of the
geographic areas of Romania has been traditionally conducted through
factorial analysis. Interpreting the factors one can explain the various
correlations of demographic, social, business, infrastructural,
etc.--features that illustrate the process of territorial economic
growth and development. But this traditional framework was developed in
a lesser opened economy than today's world and became obviously
obsolete from many standpoints. Building primarily on factor endowment
and trading based on a Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson factorial case seem
irrelevant for so many developed countries. Therefore, "clustered
development" (Rostow, 1971) points towards comparable territorial
meaningful structures, stable over time and also flexible enough to
adapt to the present day technological rapid changes. (11) Territorial
clustering means more than analyzing the inputs, outputs and business
environment, it deals with infrastructure, security, social life culture
and identity and overall living standards.
As the main (political) deciding factors in EU as well as relevant
stakeholders become aware of the benefits of increased competitiveness
of European regions from the viewpoint of the clustered development,
regional, national and European frameworks of development are today
under scrutiny. Regions as territorial-geographic concentrations of not
only demographic communities, but also firms, NGOs, infrastructure,
public and private services. Clusters of regional consistence usually
take advantage commercially of the specific bond that is more or less
generated throughout history, to a far larger extent than countries as a
whole. This is also the case of Romania, let's face it. But can
they become really functional unless the triad of micro, intermediate
(dedicated to a specific branch of the economy) and macro levels of
policies would be effectively in place for that purpose? (12)
Regionalization, no matter if we are dealing the Romanian case or else,
should tackle the issue of "creating" a territorial unit with
a specific morphology and also a structural dynamic of governance that
could push evolutionary processes in a more vivid manner than government
proved to be able. It is precisely this "centripetal regional
dynamics" that generates cohesion, the feeling of belonging to the
core instead of periphery, and generating action consequently.
If one can identify a location share differential, forcing regions
to be different and actually get more different as benchmarked to
national or international territorial entities, mainly for trading
reasons, this cannot be valid unless the difference translates into
diminishing the costs of transactions, not only for commodities and
common services, but also for peculiar services such as the cost of
investing, within that specific territorial unit, as opposed to the
country wide determined cost. Of course, elaborating at this crossroad
of the issue, I would say this is not feasible without a proper
(regional) institutional framework, fully operational, able to implement
and make fully functional several layers of governance, situation which
brings to surface the issue of evaluation. Because it is obvious that
regionalization seen exclusively from an administrative standpoint (as
the Romanian case appears, at least from a PR perspective) implies
plenty of political interface, which due to the lack of popularity of
the domain, could and probably would reverberate negatively over the
whole process.
What I have in mind in this respect is the fact that the potential
burst of bargaining concerning the potential limits of the regions, the
status of regional capital cities, governors, appropriate institutional
bodies, inevitably re-considering the administrative status of various
communities are painful and time consuming processes, that could easily
jeopardize the regionalization process at this stage, due mostly to the
wrong public perception. But if the civil society's perspective
could be somehow switched from the present day "administrative
blueprint" and the emphasis could fall on clustering local
businesses following a process of technological and even social
networking, and therefore giving territorial consistency to a certain
output, this would be a meaningful approach indeed. Putting the accent
on proper regional diffusion of knowledge, transfer of good practices
and emphasizing success stories, could work much better in my opinion in
the case of Romania. Combining various layers of expertise (research
units and higher education institutions, innovative companies and, why
not, pilot administrative units of governmental bodies) to a degree that
was never functional in Romania, though theoretically existent, would
probably make those entities gather momentum for more sharing of their
assets to the benefit of the whole region, just as this format of
sharing is documented of not being operational countrywide.
Moreover, if a regionally administered conglomerate of fiscal
contributors are "glued" by the same giving-receiving
pecuniary interests, and the process is supplemented by "local
pride", branding, and provided there is in place a preliminary
scheme of contractual consistence targeting this limited associative
pattern regulating the process, the chances to register positive
outcomes of regionalization seem increasingly decent. I see this pattern
of clustering more or less as a must adopt "risk minimizing
tool" for both the business environment and regional communities.
Such an approach could enforce, to a much larger degree than free market
can do, and actually did in Romania, that in a certain area all the
needed inputs are available in place, but also the necessary
infrastructure and even supra-structural regulations and institutions
are available for the business environment and citizens. Bottom line,
the idea that transaction costs diminishing has as a prerequisite a
public layer of governance that would be the guarantor of evolution in
terms of secure sustainable development in a friendly environment.
Strongly believing that a region, as depicted above, has the
potential to eliminate most of the intermediate levels of decision and
therefore enable a more efficient development of all social and economic
processes that occur in that region, some extra-economic details should
be enhanced. Transactions as dealt in this paper are exceeding by far
pecuniary transactions, and the issue of diminishing costs is definitely
applicable to a larger extent in this respect. The region should extract
assets from a multilayered type of cohesion, historically generating
networking of various consistencies. If that breeds social identity on
the one hand, economic links that forge peculiar coordinates of economic
life on the other hand, all these scripts cannot be put at test on the
short run but through the emergence of "pools of
regionalization". Just as the economic clustering process is
illustrated by the emergence of the alpha-clusters, (13) industrial type
of structures that are characterized by innovation above all,
regionalization should cover a far larger landscape, including the
inherent sprawl that comes with the urbanization process, the
territorial agglomerations of factors (IT, education, health, but also
some public services) designed from scratch for the reduction of the
transactions' costs. Last but not least, a true region in a
multilaterally developed society offers not only higher incomes and
material compensations, but also more important, increasingly higher
quality of life.
Top-down Regional Approach
Much energy was dedicated throughout EU towards the so called
political regionalization (14) or the granting of significant
legislative power to regional representative bodies (Catalonia and
Basque country in Spain, Flanders in Belgium, Scotland in UK and even in
the archetypal model of a centralized state, France, for the case of
Corsica) usually having in mind historically delicate, to say the least,
ethnic specificities. Though the model appealed to many political forces
in the ethnic mosaic of Central and Eastern Europe, not a single country
decided yet for such a radical model, encapsulating too many
(previously) seen and unforeseen dangers. But this random example only
illustrates the fact that the most publicized bottom-up case of
regionalization turned (at least for the time being) unsuccessful. Could
it work, again bottom-up, on different coordinates, such as purely
administrative ones? It is my strong opinion that no matter how relevant
would be the effort to convince the public opinion to back a certain
pattern or to debate mass scale concurrent models of regionalization,
whatever that could be accomplished would be further dividing the
society when it comes to this matter. I will try to insert a couple of
argumentative facts illustrating this view.
Despite the fact that quasi-liberal measures were undertaken all
over the communist at the time Central and Eastern Europe starting with
the 70s, Romania adopted a radically different path. While the Hungarian
patterned "goulash communism" took off as early as 1968,
Yugoslavia already experimented self-management and private
entrepreneurship. Poland was definitely an "out of the box"
case by communist standards. Not to mention the fact that China moved
towards "one country two systems" in the early 80s, a time
that witnessed also the Soviet glassnost and perestroika. Though, in
line with international developments, Romania formally adopted a
so-called New Economic Mechanism in 1978, allegedly giving more decision
power to lower levels of the economy, this was by far only a propaganda
tool. The short and even long run implications of this oxymoronic
situation was a false perception of the mechanisms that govern the
economy and the market, situation which was fully visible in the early
90s, when Romania took such a divergent path from the bulk of the
comparable countries.
So, on these grounds of knowledge concerning the basics of free
market, supplemented with the exacerbated mimesis in mocking EU
procedures which could not be assimilated rationally, regionalization
consonant with the rest of Europe seemed a far cry for Romania. Not
quite the same situation throughout CEE. As the Report on Economic and
Social Cohesion, determined by the assessment of EU's regional
policy, having in view the new geo-political realities of Europe, was
published in 1996 and clearly pointed there is no direct link between
the type of regionalization (15), as observed in the 12 member states of
the moment, and the peculiarities of the economic development in those
countries. Soon after joining EU, most if not all CEE countries adopted
coordinates of regionalization that suited better their interest. While
Bulgaria, Estonia, Lithuania, Slovakia and Slovenia created an
administrative frame entirely subordinated to the central government,
but acting on regional basis, other countries, such as Hungary and
Romania, implement regional policy mainly through the existing local
authorities, obviously created for other ends in the previous regime,
but mandated specifically for this task. On the other hand Poland and
Czech Republic (16) effectively adopted regional decentralization,
consisting in the creation of specific decentralized structures, new
categories of territorial authorities, in larger constituencies,
obviously targeted towards growth and development.
If we interpret empirically the path and the accomplishments of CEE
countries it seems evident that early in terms of timing and top-down in
a procedural perspective are the winning cards. Evidently diversity and
initial differences are assets for a successful regionalization track,
but EU offers sufficient conditions in order to assess that initial
conditions could not matter less, if a "smart" policy
framework is put in place (Hilpert (2003). In the case of Romania that
evidently means to the re-interpretation of the administrative
decisional levels. Conferring powers to regions would actually mean
de-periphery-zation of at least the most competitive regions of the
country with potential significant "locomotive" effects.
Facing the fact that the Romanian economy is peripheral within the
overall economy of the EU full integration at this stage (i.e. within
Eurozone) cannot but enhance the scale of becoming more peripheral. It
is difficult to assess at this stage if factual de-periphery-zation
could be accomplished at regional level, but there are sufficient
examples in this world that could prove the contrary.
Let's add one more important argument, illustrating the
top-down case. It is a fact that development is interpreted in most
sources as a phenomenon which is definitely more related to the
territory where it occurs, that simple growth. While overall development
grounded on high value added output represents the ideal approach in the
present day economy, there are no significant examples that such a
framework could be operational from start countrywide. The empirical
evaluations of high-tech mono industries located at regional level are
definitely better, and more important, less prone to collapse under
crisis conditions, than any development scheme conceived for the whole
country ab initio. Of course the Achilles's heel in this case would
be the potential inadequacy to the juncture of the world, continental or
national markets, inducing severe recession in that mono industrialized
region. But it seems that nowadays it is more important and more
convenient to undertake the risk of acquiring top class technology that
would put a region I another technological league, at all risks than
simply evolve in full synergy with the past of that particular
territory. (17)
Another supplementary argument pleading in favor of the idea that
regionalization is today one of the most important triggering factors
for development in Romania would be, paradoxically, the assessment of
the growth and development in connection with the accumulated experience
of transition and joining EU. While the process of transition occurred
evidently spontaneous and falls into the "stop and go"
pattern, it definitely could be branded as mostly endogenous, while
joining the EU was obviously an exogenous process that change the
coordinates of evolution, up to the point of distortion (Mattli and
Pluemper, 2004). If there is a point in considering that the heavily
political exogenous process of acceding to EU, inevitably forged
"aggregated identity" sometime ignoring lessons derived from
centuries of peculiar evolution, regionalization simply might be the
answer. The deeper implications of moving from traditionally organized
national frameworks to regional ones could be interpreted in this view
as the de facto empowerment of the endogenous dimension of the economy.
The trajectory of Poland during the crisis, a country that really took
into consideration the endogenous growth perspective, is a relevant
indeed example in this respect.
Admitting the fact that such a perspective actually leads to the
conclusion that regional integration mainly targets lowering different
economic and social transaction costs between participants, as opposed
to non-participants, we should take into consideration other kinds of
possible interpretations. For instance, beyond the already discussed
ethnical regionalization, exclusively building upon the dichotomy
endogenously/ exogenously driven type of growth, could make us end up in
interpretations of regionalism as "postmodern feudalism"
(Siebert, 2002) therefore encapsulating much of the liabilities this
epoch is associated with, autarchy coming first. But we should
acknowledge that in a more and more competitive environment, in a world
infested by so many non-tariff types of barriers, bringing competition
towards lower and informal levels of PR manipulation, there is nothing
wrong if EU tries to bring to life patterns that are deeply rooted in
its own history. Therefore at first glance, and this time strictly form
an economist's perspective, the "Union of the Regions"
mainly appears to be a federalist approach, especially designed for a
better specification of the division of powers between central and
regional administrative levels. Such a scenario could not be, in my
opinion, anything but benefic for a country like Romania.
I put on paper these comments exactly at a time when it became
public the official announcement that the revision of the Constitution
and consequently the regionalization process are "regrettably"
postponed for 2014, exclusively for political reasons. Correlating the
dimensions of the process with the constraints of the new EU budgetary
cycle starting in 2014, the news cannot be worse for Romania's
developmental perspectives. But the public debate conducted in such a
manner that everybody should be aware of the negative consequences of
indefinite postponement, should start on the spot. Dixit et salvavi
animam meam.
Bibliography
1. Bukovski, J., Piattoni, S., Smyrl, M. (2003), Between
Europeanization and Local Societies, The Space for Territorial
Governance, Rowman and Littlefield Publishers, Lanham, Boulder, New
York, Oxford, 2-7.
2. Herschel, T., Newman, P. (2002), Governance and Europe's
City Regions, London/New York: Routledge, 25-28.
3. Hilpert, U. (Ed.) (2003), Regionalization of Globalised
Innovation, New York: Routledge.
4. Daianu, Daianu (2000), Incotro se indreapta tarile
postcomuniste?, Iasi: Polirom.
5. Martins-Rodriguez, B., Viedma-Marti, J. M. (2006), "The
Region's Intellectual Capital Benchmarking System: Enabling
Economic Growth through Evaluation", in Journal of Knowledge
Management, Vol. 10, No. 5.
6. Mattli, W., Pluemper, T. (2004), The Internal Value of External
Options --How the EU Shapes the Scope of Regulatory Reforms in
Transition Countries, EUP--European Union Politics, Vol. 5 (3), London:
SAGE.
7. Nagarajan, A., Mitchell, W. (1998), "Evolutionary
Diffusion: Internal and External Methods Used to Acquire Encompassing,
Complementary and Incremental Technological Changes in the Lithotripsy
Industry", in Strategic Management Journal, Wiley Inter Science,
No. 19.
8. Patterson, W. (1994), Rebuilding Romania, Energy, Efficiency and
the Economics of Transition, London: Earthscan.
9. Peterson, John, Shackleton, M. (2002), The Institutions of the
European Union--"Chapter 15, Social and Regional Interests: ESC and
the Committee of the Regions", Oxford: Oxford University Press,
326-346.
10. Petrakas G., Maier G., Gorzelak G. (2001), Integration and
Transition in Europe: Economic Geography of Interaction, London:
Routlegde.
11. Popa, E. (1999), Autonomia locala in Romania, Bucuregti:
Editura ALL BECK.
12. Porter, Michale (1998), "Clusters and the New Economics of
Competition", in Harvard Business Review, Boston, November/
December.
13. Rostow, W. (1971), Politics and the Stages of Growth, (First
Ed.) Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
14. Schoales, J. (2006), "Alpha Clusters: Creative Innovation
in Local Economies", in Economic Development Quarterly, SAGE, No.
20.
15. Siebert, H. (2002), The World Economy, Second Edition, London:
Routledge, 199-208.
16. Traistaru, Iulia, Pauna, Carmen (2003), "The Emerging
Economic Geography in Romania", in I. Traistaru, P. Nijkamp, L.
Resmini (Eds.), The Emerging Economic Geography in EU Accession
Countries, Aldershot: Ashgate, 242-283.
Mircea Teodor Maniu *
* Mircea Teodor Maniu is Associate Professor at the Faculty of
European Studies of Babes-Bolyai University in Cluj-Napoca, Romania.
E-mail: mmaniu@euro.ubbcluj.ro.
(1) Romanian Prime Minister Victor Ponta assesses that while at the
end of 2012 Romania could not reach more than 12% of the allocated
funds, in July 2013 this figure significantly improved but it will not
exceed 20% in the first half of 2013. (Romanian Academy, Debate about
Regionalization, Bucharest, April 2, 2013)
(2) See in this respect Gh. Zaman, G. Georgescu, "Structural
fund absorption: a new challenge for Romania?", in Romanian Journal
of Economic Forecasting, Nr. 1/2009
(3) G. Petrakas, G. Maier, G. Gorzelak, Integration and Transition
in Europe: Economic Geography of Interaction, London: Routlegde, 2001
(4) The Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics (NUTS) is
an Eurostat device providing a single "uniform breakdown of
territorial units for the production of regional statistics";
although NUTS has no legal value per se throughout EU, NUTS was
effectively in place since 1988, the reviewed 1999 version indicating
five territorial levels, for the Romanian case (2011) these are: NUTS I:
the whole country; NUTS II: 8 development regions; NUTS III: 42
counties); NUTS IV: not applicable (EU pattern indicates territorial
associations, mainly big cities); NUTS V: 323 municipalities and towns
and 2859 rural communities (consisting of approximately 13.000
villages).
(5) John Peterson, M. Shackleton, The Institutions of the European
Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002, pp. 326-346.
(6) Daniel Daianu, Incotro se indreapta tarile postcomuniste?,
Iasi: Polirom, 2000; J. Bukovski, S. Piattoni, M. Smyrl, Between
Europeanization and Local Societies, The Space for Territorial
Governance, Lanham, Boulder: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers, 2003,
pp. 2-7.
(7) E. Popa, Autonomia locala in Romania, Bucurefti: Editura ALL
BECK, 1999.
(8) W. Patterson, Rebuilding Romania, Energy, Efficiency and the
Economics of Transition, London: Earthscan, 1994
(9) Iulia Traistaru, Carmen Pauna, "The Emerging Economic
Geography in Romania", in Iulia Traistaru, Peter Nijkamp, Laura
Resmini (Eds.), The Emerging Economic Geography in EU Accession
Countries, Aldershot: Ashgate, 2003, pp. 242-283.
(10) T. Herschel, P. Newman, Governance and Europe's City
Regions, London/New York: Routledge, 2002, pp. 25-28.
(11) Michale Porter, "Clusters and the New Economics of
Competition", in Harvard Business Review, November/December, 1998
(12) B. Martins-Rodriguez, J.M. Viedma-Marti, "The
Region's Intellectual Capital Benchmarking System: Enabling
Economic Growth through Evaluation", in Journal of Knowledge
Management, Vol. 10, No. 5, 2006
(13) J. Schoales, "Alpha Clusters: Creative Innovation in
Local Economies", in Economic Development Quarterly, SAGE, No. 20,
2006.
(14) Several authors point out to the fact that the term
regionalism refers first of all to the emergence of overtly political
regional pressures across Europe, due to the inadequacies of the present
day state; others consider that economic competitiveness is by far the
major driving force of regionalism (see in this respect T. Herschel, P.
Newman, op.cit., pp. 25-28.)
(15) Five main types of regionalization could be identified in the
legal (constitutional and administrative) domain of most EU countries in
the early 90s: administrative regionalization; regionalization through
the local authorities already in place; political regionalization;
regional decentralization; federalization.
(16) Actually the former Czechoslovakia was the only CEE to have in
place a regional form of territorial unit comparable with NUTS II. The
Polish voivodships also matched several criteria of regional framework,
as present throughout EU.
(17) A. Nagarajan, W. Mitchell, "Evolutionary Diffusion:
Internal and External Methods Used to Acquire Encompassing,
Complementary and Incremental Technological Changes in the Lithotripsy
Industry", in Strategic Management Journal, Wiley Inter Science,
No. 19, 1998