首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月18日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Fiscal responsibility: a critical analysis of FRDL (2005) Pakistan.
  • 作者:Qasim, Muhammad Ali ; Khalid, Mahmood
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2012
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics

Fiscal responsibility: a critical analysis of FRDL (2005) Pakistan.


Qasim, Muhammad Ali ; Khalid, Mahmood


INTRODUCTION

The term fiscal responsibility in financial dictionary is defined as "A balanced budget". That is a budget wherein expenditures during a given period of time equal to revenues. The fiscal responsibility also includes a budget in which revenue is greater than the expenditures. Fiscal responsibility is achievable and most of the individuals in their private life practice fiscal responsibility. At individual level everybody knows that they have to live within the budget and usually they do not overspend. Usually overspending by individual results in bad crediting rating which one receives from their creditors due to non-payments or late payments of installments and thus denies future benefits to the person concern.

Fiscal responsibility at national level implies that a government has a balanced budget and has sufficient revenue to pay for its all expenditures. There would be no overspending if government had a true balanced budget in each period. The economic future of a nation largely depends on the way fiscal responsibility is practiced. There is a direct link between budget deficit today and what nation can enjoy in future. Fiscal responsibility is crucial for a nation to remain prosperous and stronger in future. Fiscal responsibility will also determine what kind of future we are leaving to our children and grandchildren for the next 20 years and beyond. If the fiscal responsibility is not practiced the government would spend more money than its income and it borrows for the difference. If the money borrowed come from domestic savings or from domestic lenders the economy will have less money available for capital investment and future productivity growth rates and levels would be lower. If on the other hand deficit is financed by foreign organisation/country the country will be indebted with growing debt to the rest of the world, with growing interest costs which must be served every year. If we rely more on foreign sources to finance the resource gap the foreign ownership of our resources would grow and so has our dependences on the actions of foreign governments and investors.

At least for the last two decades poor/weak fiscal responsibility is being practiced in Pakistan as the fiscal deficit for these two decades remained more than five percent of GDP. The persistent fiscal deficit resulted in the increased debt burden both in terms of internal as well as external debt and interest payments. Our growing dependence on the action of foreign organisations/countries is manifested from one of the conditions laid by IMF on the loan given to Pakistan in 2008; the condition was that the government would raise electricity charges during the loan period. Perceiving the poor fiscal responsibility practiced by the federal government the then finance minister, Mr. Shaukat Aziz, in his budget speech 2001-2002 made a policy commitment by stating that:" government is considering promulgation of a fiscal responsibility law that would limit the government's access to borrowing for financing its expenditure". The policy commitment, made by the finance minister, was materialised in the form of "Fiscal Responsibility and Debt Management Act-2005. The objective of the paper is to critically evaluate the FRDL Act-2005 and also see the extent of implementation of various conditions laid down in the act. The paper is organised as follows: Section--I would deal with the History of FRDL type law enacted in other countries like India etc. Section--II would deal with the Constitutional provision for framing of FRDL. Section--III would deal with the critical evaluation of FRDL and the implementation status of various sub-heads of the act. Finally the conclusion is drawn on the preceding discussion.

1. FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY IN HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE

Fiscal Responsibility Laws (FRLs) are now popular and many countries have enacted FRLs so as to enhance the reliability, certainty, and transparency of fiscal policy. Generally FRLs are combination of rules and regulation needed to strengthen fiscal transparency and budget management, with numerical ceilings on fiscal deficits and public debt to achieve fiscal discipline. The aim of FRLs is to provide a comprehensive framework for management of fiscal policy through a single legislation. New Zealand was at the forefront to adopt FRL in 1994 with a too much emphasis on transparency requirements. After the adoption of FRL by New Zealand it has been implemented in several countries in Asia, Europe and in Latin America.

FRLs are different than stand-alone numerical fiscal rules, which are defined as a permanent constraint on fiscal policy through simple numerical limits on budgetary aggregates [Kopits and Symansky (1998)]. FRLs can be classified according to several characteristics, including the emphasis placed on procedural versus numerical fiscal rules, the jurisdictional coverage (e.g. central versus federal government), sanctions, escape clauses, and cyclical considerations.

Since the 1990s many governments made serious efforts to devise such mechanisms which would not be used for winning election and retaining public office. One of the mechanisms for National governments to prevent these problems was to pass a fiscal responsibility law (FRL) which prescribes proper fiscal behaviour for Subnational Governments (SNGs), provides guidelines for parameters of SNG fiscal legislation, or sets incentives rewards for success or sanctions for failure in following the rules. Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, India, and Peru have done so. The countries such as Turkey, Poland and Mexico have not adopted fiscal responsibility legislation for subnational but they have established fiscal rules or debt limitations for SNGs. At this stage it would be appropriate to briefly discuss FRLs for the countries who have recently adopted these laws. The prominent countries are Brazil, India, Argentine and Australia.

Brazil

"In Brazil's political opening through mid-1990s, there were two major subnational debt crises. Each initial agreement that tried to resolve a crisis actually made the next crisis more likely, because they reinforced the perception that the federal government would provide debt relief, they provided such relief in the form of rescheduling (allowing the stock of debt to keep growing), set ceilings on debt service and thus on the effective political cost, bought out (without penalty) the foreign and private creditors to the SNGs and left the federal government holding the debt. Thus the state politicians suffered minimal consequences for their imprudence and their creditors suffered almost none, and so until 1997 the ex-ante constraints written in the rescheduling agreements were usually quickly evaded" [Dillinger (1997); Rodden (2003)]. In late 1990s, this subnational debt crises came to end because of adoption of national macroeconomic adjustment programme which not only ended hyperinflation and stabilised the economy. During 1997-98 the federal government made debt restructuring agreements with 25 states and the objective was to cease unsustainable borrowing. As a result of this debt agreement three largest debtor states supported the reforms and formed the core of a critical mass of states ready to cooperate in fiscal restraint, making it worthwhile for additional states join at the margin of cooperation. Also, the large scale of the states' non-performing debt to the federal government strengthened the resolve of the federal Congress to enact the FRL. The federal government negotiated agreements with 25 states in 1997 and 1998. These agreements were sanctioned by Law 9496 of September 1997 to reschedule the states' debt conditioned on states undertaking fiscal reforms and compliance with fiscal targets. The FRL in 2000 codified fiscal adjustment programs sanctioned by various resolutions [Alfonso (2002); Dillinger (2002)].

Argentine

The provinces in Argentine, during, the 1980s had no budget constraint they borrowed a lot, and effectively could monetise this debt, contributing to hyperinflation. The stabilisation programme in 1991 was centered on the Convertibility Plan, which fixed the Argentine exchange rate to the U.S. dollar. During the 1990s a market based strategy was followed by the national government mainly for coordinating fiscal discipline between provinces: the central government would enforce hard budget constraints ex post and force the provinces to pay their debts [Dillinger and Webb (1999)]. By the end of the 1990s, the absence of the ex-ante fiscal controls had allowed a number of Argentine provinces to over-borrow, party fragmentation had narrowed the scope for fiscal compromises, and the national government had overcommitted itself by setting floors on transfers, even if national revenues fell [Gonzalez, Rosenblatt, and Webb (2004)].

At the national level, the budget balance was deteriorating and there were growing debt payments, a Fiscal Solvency Law was approved by the Congress in 1999--its first try at an FRL. It aimed to and did inspire a third of the provinces to pass their own FRLs. During 2001, however, the FRLs virtually stopped working because there was extreme mismatch between the fiscal and monetary policies of the national government and furthermore the provincial FRLs do not have enforcement power and most of the economically important provinces had not passed them. Only 5 out of 11 provinces that imposed a hard budget constraint actually fulfilled their commitment [Braun and Tomassi (2004)]. In 2004, Argentina tried anew with a national FRL that applied to the provinces as well as the national government and capital federal district. It passed Congress hastily [Braun and Gadano (2006); Laudonia (2009)], and it did not come out of a consensus building process with the provinces nor reflect a solid technical consideration of how the provinces might adjust their finances to meet the legal requirements. Although many provinces complied with some of the law's procedural requirements, almost none were meeting the quantitative targets even before the onset of the global crisis in 2009. After that the quantitative targets were put on hold, which further undermined the credibility of the FRL process in Argentina.

India

The Indian Constitution does not allow the states to borrow from abroad and the states are require to obtain permission from central government for domestic borrowing. The borrowing by states is allowed by the central government after discussing with states on financing state development plans. The constitution provision, to limit the state borrowing, could not limit the explosive growth of state debt, the system could not stopped fiscal deterioration as indicated by high levels of debt over GSDP ratio in many states in the late 1990s. The factors responsible for deterioration in fiscal accounts of states in Indian are: increased expenditures on salaries, pensions, retirement benefits, and on subsidies, increased borrowing to finance the growing revenue deficit, and growth in contingent liabilities related with fiscal support to cooperatives, public sector units, and the statutory boards.

The fiscal reforms adopted by the government, since the early 2000s, has focused on to a more flexible, market-linked borrowing regime within sustainable overall borrowing limits imposed by the central government and self-imposed state-level deficit limits. Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act was enacted by the federal government in 2003 which applies to the national government only, but some states had also adopted their own FRLs before the enactment of the federal FRL [e.g., Karnataka and Punjab in (2002)] and many states have since 2003 adopted FRLs in line with the national law. After the Twelfth Finance Commission (2005), FRL has become mandatory for all the provinces and the federal government has offered a sizeable incentive to provinces for passing their FRL.

Australia

In Australia, during 1990s there was growing concern that the country do not have legislation for fiscal responsibility. The idea of legislation for fiscal responsibility gained considerable attention in the 1990s. At the federal level, the Business Council of Australia called for legislation requiring a surplus budget on average over the business cycle. The federal government adopted the Charter of Budget Honesty Act in 1998 and there was improvement in fiscal outcomes. Australia adopted, in the mid 1980s, its first fiscal rules which put limits on the growth of expenditure, taxation and budget deficit. During the recession in the 1990s the net debt of the country increased more than 20 percent of GDP and in fact net debt has never went beyond 20 percent of GDP. The combined state and Commonwealth general government net debt had not exceeded 30 percent of GDP in the 1990s [Simes (2003)]. Some states had adopted fiscal responsibility legislation prior to the federal government's adoption. New South Wales passed legislation in 1995 to commit itself and future governments to medium- and long-term fiscal responsible targets including the elimination of the net debt. Victoria passed the Financial Management Act in 1994, which was amended in 2000 through the Financial Management (Financial Responsibility) Act, which outlines principles of sound financial management, reporting standards and pre-election budget update. Minister must produce a pre-election budget update 10 days after the issue of a writ for an election. The Act broadly states what the update must contain and the principles upon which it must be based.

2. FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY LAW IN PAKISTAN

The approval and implementation of Fiscal Responsibility and Debt Limitation Act-2005 was meant to provide for elimination of revenue deficit and reduction of public debt to a prudent level by effective public debt management. The Federal government has completed seven fiscal years since the implementation of FRDL in June 2005. In the following paragraphs we will analyse major conditions laid down for sound fiscal and debt management.

3. AN EVALUATION OF FRDL ACT--2005

The implementation of Fiscal Responsibility and Debt Limitation Act, 2005 was the serious effort by the government to create strong institutional mechanism to restore fiscal discipline at the level of central government. The other objective was to introduce greater transparency in fiscal operations of the central government. In the following paragraphs we will evaluate FRDL act-2005.

According to Act No. VI of 2005 the Federal government shall take all appropriate measures to achieve following policy objectives:

* To eliminate the revenue deficit.

* To reduce total public debt and maintain it within prudent limits thereof.

Short Title, Extent Commencement of the Act

The Act may be called Fiscal responsibility and debt limitation Act. 2005.

* It extends to the whole of Pakistan.

* It shall come into force at once.

The coverage of the act is whole of the Pakistan which means that the four provincial governments, AJK and Northern Areas are required to follow the two policy objectives of the FRDL. Here the question is that in the wake of more provincial autonomy, more transfer of financial resources to provinces, through NFC award and, furthermore, transfer of public related sectors, like health, education and social welfare, to provinces, how the federal government can administered its control over provincial expenditures and revenues?. The fact is that the act imposes restrictions only on the federal government but the provincial governments are not, practically, in the scope/preview of the act. It is therefore imperative that FRDL may also be framed for the provincial governments. The federal government has no control over the provincial expenditures. It worth to note that the first policy objective is related to revenue deficit which is the interplay of revenue and expenditure.

* The FRDL is silent about the absolute fiscal deficit which otherwise is the source of concern for fiscal policy makers. The fiscal deficit is one of the important indicators of fiscal imbalances. The government has given top priority to contain fiscal deficit in it expenditure management strategy. It worth to note that how and why the FDRL act does not consider fiscal deficit as a source of concern, therefore, no targets has been set for reduction in fiscal deficit.

* The fiscal deficit is the excess of total expenditure (Current and Development) over revenue receipts and grants. If we do not consider fiscal deficit as a source of concern but consider revenue deficit as a source of concern this clearly implies that we neglect the development needs of the country. The capital expenditure/development expenditure contributes to the development process in the country. The share of development expenditure in total expenditure is less than 20 percent which is the manifestation of neglect of development need in FRDL-2005.

4. ANALYSIS OF THE PRINCIPLES OF SOUND FISCAL AND DEBT MANAGEMENT

In the following paragraphs we will analyse principle of sound fiscal and debt management in seriatim and also the current implementation status of each principle.

(a) Reducing the Revenue Deficit to Nil Not Later Than the Thirtieth June 2008 and Thereafter Maintaining a Revenue Surplus

* No specific targets have been set to bring revenue deficit to zero up to 30-62008 and thereafter maintaining a revenue surplus. The act is devoid of any strategy/implementation plan to bring revenue deficit to zero. Such as what amount of revenue deficit should be reduced each year i.e. say 0.5 percent of GDP at the end of each financial year.

* While formulating the act the possibility that reducing the expenditure and/or raising the revenue might have adverse affects on the growth of the country keeping in view the prevalent and emerging economic conditions. I.e. the possible impact of expenditure reducing/revenue raising strategy on growth of the economy has not been fully estimated.

* As the revenue deficit is the result of expenditure and revenue. The revenue side includes both tax and non tax and surcharges of the government. In crease in revenue by increasing non-tax revenue requires that public services be appropriately priced which may be difficult in the presence of high inflation and increasing cost of fuel and electricity.

* The above table indicates that the revenue deficit is not zero as on 30-06-2008 and thereafter it is not in surplus. Thus the first condition of FRDL is not met till the fiscal year 2010-11. The objective was to fund for consumption from government's own resources and not borrowing. "The existence of a high and persistent revenue deficit indicates government's inability in maintaining fiscal discipline and instilling austerity measures in order to curtail increasing current expenditures". The revenue deficit is mostly due to two reasons firstly revenue receipts are short off the target revenue and secondly the current expenditure is over and above the planned expenditure. The increased current expenditure is primarily due to increased expenditure on security related affairs, interest payments and subsidies.

(b) Ensure "that within a period of ten financial year, beginning from the first July, 2003 and ending on thirtieth June, 2013, the total public debt at the end of the tenth financial year does not exceed sixty percent of the estimated gross domestic product for that year and thereafter maintaining the total public debt below sixty percent of gross domestic product for any given year."

As it is stated in the debt policy statement that "future levels of debt hinge around the primary balance of the government". Mathematically, the primary balance is the fiscal deficit before the interest payments. Empirically there exists a long run relationship between fiscal deficit and debt relative to GDP. It is argued that large structural primary deficits and interest payments relative to GDP have had an adverse effect on growth in recent years. The FRDL -2005 does not consider the fiscal deficit as its objective; therefore, the targets of debt to GDP ratios for coming years are not seemed to be realistic. In other words the act should have to define targets for fiscal deficit along with the target for debt to GDP ratio.

The FRDL -2005 is not effective on the provincial governments, therefore, federal government cannot control borrowing by the provincial governments. For effective debt management policy it is therefore felt that there is a need for provincial fiscal responsibility legislations. The necessity of legislation is supported by the fact that the debt-GDP ratio is combined federal and provincial debt.

As per above table the government seems to full fill the FRDL condition and it is expected that total public debt to GDP ratio will be maintained from the fiscal year 2012-13 and own wards.

There is a need for through investigation that how the target for 60 percent debt to GDP ratio has been determined.

(c) Ensure "that in every financial year, beginning from the first July, 2003, and ending on the thirtieth June 2013, the total public debt is reduced by no less than two and a half percent of the estimated gross domestic product for any given year, provided that social and poverty alleviation related expenditures are not reduced below 4.5 percent of the estimated gross domestic product for any given year and budgetary allocation to education and health, will be doubled from the existing level in terms of percentage of gross domestic product during the next ten years."

The above condition has following three objectives:

* The reduction in total public debt beginning from 01-07-2003 and ending on 3006-2013, the total public debt is reduced by no less than two and a half percent of the estimated GDP for any given year.

* The above condition of FRDL-2005 protects the federal government expenditure on social and poverty related sectors. The act restricts that while reducing debt the social and poverty related expenditure should not be reduced below 4.5 percent of estimated GDP for any given year. The social and poverty related expenditure includes Infrastructure (highways, roads and bridges), water supply and sanitation, food subsidies, food support programmes, village electrification, rural development etc.

* The budgetary allocation to education and health will be doubled from the existing level in terms of percentage of gross domestic product during the next ten years. The investment in health and education is vital for economic development of any country.

Billion of Rupees

The three sub-conditions of clause-c are analysed in the above table.

* The debt reduction strategy ensures continues reduction in total public debt from July 2003 till June 2013 and the and for each year the extent of reduction in debt is not less that 2.5 percent of estimated GDP for any given year. The row "debt as debt reduction strategy" contains the amount of debt if the strategy is fully followed. The total public debt for fiscal year is Rs. 10709 billion whereas the debt should have been Rs 1515.4 Billion in case the debt strategy is fully implemented. There is a gap of Rs.9193.6 Billion between the existing and planned total public debt for 2010-11. In fact the total public debt has increased from Rs 3623 billion in 2002-03 to Rs. 10709 billion in 2010-11. The increase in total public debt over the FRDL period is mainly due to persistent high level of fiscal deficit which for Yll is 6.6 percent of GDP. In net shall the debt reduction strategy failed due to unrealistic targets/non inclusion of important fiscal variable (fiscal deficit) in the FRDL-2005.

* The only positive recommendation of FRDL is that in the act expenditure on social and poverty alleviation has been protected up to 4.5 of GDP for any given year. By comparing rows 4.5 percent of GDP and social & poverty related expenditure it will be clear that for first three years of FRDL social & poverty related expenditure remained below the 4.5 percent of GDP but since Fy06 the expenditure has increased rather than any reduction in it and are more than the minimum limit set in the FRDL but these increased expenditure are at the cost of higher debt. In other words we have increased expenditures on social & poverty sector but at the same time we have also increased public debt.

* The FRDL is silent about the expenditures incurred by the provincial governments on social & poverty related issues.

* The budgetary allocation to education and health as percent of GDP was required to be doubled from FY03 to FY13. The budgetary allocation to education and Health during FY03 as % of GDP was 1.6 percent and 0.5 percent respectively. The FRDL is silent over the rate by which the expenditure on education and health would be double. In the absence of any indicated growth rate for increased expenditure on education and health it is difficult to check the compliance of FRDL on yearly basis from 2003 to 2010-11. However the above table indicates that expenditures on education and health have not witnessed any significant increase since 2002-03.

(d) Not issue "new guarantees, including those for rupee lending, bonds, rates of return, output purchase agreements and all other claims and commitments that may be prescribed, from time to time, for any amount exceeding two percent of the estimated gross domestic product in any financial year: Provided that the renewal of existing guarantees shall be considered as issuing a new guarantee."

* This clause put restriction only on issue of new guarantees and does not speak about the stock of contingent liabilities which are associated with major hidden fiscal risk.

* The act in fact put restriction on contractually binding guarantees i.e. explicit contingent liabilities and does not put restriction on implicit contingent liabilities. (Economic Survey 2002-03 page-241).

* Keeping in view the past trends of contingent liabilities one can ask the question that what is economic rational of including guarantees in the FRDL. The following table contains description of contingent liabilities:

The above table indicates that neither prior to the formulation of FDRL nor after the imposition of FRDL the contingent liabilities pose any threat to the fiscal policy formulation. In fact the FRDL target only new and renewal of explicit guarantees whose share in total liabilities is less than 30 percent for the period 2002-03 to 2007-08. This small share in no way is a source of concern for the fiscal policy formulation of the country.

Interestingly the FRDL overlooked the one of the important action of the government i.e. FRDL did not put any restriction on the federal government borrowing from the SBP. The government borrowing from SBP for budgetary support is steadily increasing over the last two decades.

5. CONCLUSION

The FRDL was implemented to improve overall fiscal discipline in the country so as to put the country on the desire path of economic growth. The FRDL was not frame on the basis of overall economic situation of the country rather it was frame on the basis of constitutional provision. The jurisdiction of FRDL is only the federal government and provincial governments are not in its jurisdiction. The FRDL put constrain only on the revenue deficit and ignores the fiscal deficit which is source of concern for the fiscal policy makers. The FRDL put numerical restriction on total public debt but these restrictions (targets of debt to GDP ratios) do not seems to be realistic because empirically there exists a long run relationship between fiscal deficit and debt relative to GDP. As already stated above fiscal deficit is not considered as source of concern and that is why no restriction/limitation is set for the growth of fiscal deficit. The only positive recommendation of FRDL is that in the act the expenditure on social and poverty alleviation has been protected up to 4.5 of GDP for any given year. Since Fy06 the expenditure on social & poverty alleviation has increased rather than any reduction in it and is more than the minimum limit set in the FRDL but these increased expenditures are at the cost of higher debt. In other words we have increased expenditures on social and poverty sector but at the same time we have also increased public debt. The FRDL is silent about the expenditures incurred by the provincial governments on social and poverty related issues.

The budgetary allocation to education and health as % of GDP was required to be doubled from FY03 to FY13. The budgetary allocation to education & Health during FY03 as % of GDP was 1.6 percent and 0.5 percent respectively. The FRDL is silent over the rate by which the expenditure on education and health would be double. In the absence of any indicated growth rate for increased expenditure on education and health it is difficult to check the compliance of FRDL on yearly basis from 2003 to 2010-11. However the above table indicates that expenditures on education and health have not witnessed any significant increase since 2002-03.

Interestingly the FRDL overlooked the one of the important action of the government i.e. FRDL did not put any restriction on the federal government borrowing from the SBP. The government borrowing from SBP for budgetary support is steadily increasing over the last two decades.

Recommendations

Following recommendations are suggested to improve the quality of FRDL and to make it more effective.

* The basis of FRDL should be more on economic reality of the country rather than on the basis of constitutional provision.

* There is a need to put restrictions on fiscal deficit besides revenue deficit.

* The jurisdiction of FRDL should be enhanced from federal government to all provincial governments.

* The increased expenditures on social and poverty sector should not be at the cost of increased public debt.

* In order to double expenditure on education and health as percentage of GDP from 2003 to 2013 there must be specific rates by virtue of which the expenditure on these two sectors would be doubled.

* There is a need to put restrictions on federal government borrowing from SBP.

REFERENCES

Braun, Mignel and Mariano Tomassi (2004) Fiscal Rules for Subnational Government: Some Organising Principles and Latin American Experiences. The Paper Presented at the IMF/World Bank Conference "Rule Based Fiscal Policy in Emerging Markets Economies", Oaxaca, Mexico, February 14-16.

Braun, Mignel and Nicolas Gadano (2007) What are Fiscal Rules for: A Critical Analysis of the Argentine Experience. CEPAL Review 91.

Brazil (2002) Fiscal Responsibility Law. Constitution of Pakistan 1973.

Dillinger, William (1997) The Brazilian Debt Crisis. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Dillinger, William (2002) Brazil: Issues in Fiscal Federalism. Washington, D.C, WB. (World Bank Report 22523-BR).

Dillinger, William and Steven B. Webb (1999) Fiscal Management in Federal Democracies: Argentina and Brazil. World Bank. (Draft Report).

Kopits, George and Steven A. Symansky (1998) Fiscal Policy Rules. IMF, July. (Occasional Paper No. 162).

Laudonia, Mare (2009) Responsabilidad Fiscal, unaley bajola lupa del fondo. Economia, September.

Pakistan, Government of (n.d.) Pakistan Debt Policy Statement 2011-12. Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.

Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Pakistan Economic Survey. Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.

Punjab, Government of (2002) White Paper on State's Finance. Chandigarh Department of Finance, India.

Simes, Iric (2003) Fiscal Policy Rules in Australia. Australia: Chifley Research Center.

Steven, B. Webb (2004) Fiscal Responsibility Laws for Subnational Discipline: The Latin American Experience. (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3307).

Comments

Study is a good contribution in the field of fiscal and especially in Pakistan there was a need to see the FRDL critically and study has done quite a good job. It seems like the study is a part of big assignment and it was at preliminary stage. It would be good to see the entire study when it will be finalised. While reading the literature of different countries mentioned in the study on the Fiscal law, Pakistan made in 2005, I felt that there are several analysis done in the past on Pakistan's FRDL are missing, which needs to be cited in the paper. Those include Ashfaque H. Khan's paper on the "A Rule Based Fiscal Policy" in which he stated that all targets in the FRDL are achieved during 2002-03 to 2006-07. However authors may need to emphasise on what happened after that. There is another audit report by the Auditor General of Pakistan which stated that Government is consistently violating the core objectives of FRDL. Similarly there is a report by SBP "The State of Pakistan's Economy" which criticised the FRDL. Dr Hamza Malik, Direct Research at the State Bank of Pakistan, also proposed some amendments to the FRDL.

It is my suggestion to include all the previous studies which will improve the current study and eventually tells us the important conclusions which will help government to make policy to achieve the targets of FRDL or changed FRDL towards better management of fiscal responsibility.

Last, I would like to see some kind of empirics in the paper which will make the argument stronger what is explained theoretically in the paper.

M. Ali Kemal

Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

Muhammad Ali Qasim <qasim@pide.org.pk> is Research Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Mahmood Khalid <mahmoodkhalid@pide.org.pk> is Research Economist at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

Authors' Note: The authors are grateful to Dr Fazal Husain for his encouragement and valuable support in the research. The views expressed in the paper are purely those of the author's and does not represent the Institution view on the issue.
Table 1
Revenue Deficit as a Percentage of GDP

                              2007-08   2008-09   2009-10   2010-11

Revenue Balance as % of GDP    -3.2      -1.2      -2.4      -3.3

Source: Debt Policy Statement 2011-12.

Table 2
Debt Composition

                                FY03    FY04    FY05    FY06    FY07

Domestic Currency Debt          1852    1995    2152    2322    2601
Foreign Currency Debt           1771    1816    1913    2038    2201
Total Public Debt               3623    3810    4065    4359    4802
GDP                             4876    5641    6500    7623    8673
Total Public Debt As % of GDP   74.3    67.6    62.5    57.2    55.4

                                FY08    FY09    FY10    FY11

Domestic Currency Debt          3266    3852    4651    6015
Foreign Currency Debt           2778    3776    4270    4694
Total Public Debt               6044    7629    8921    10709
GDP                             10243   12724   14837   18063
Total Public Debt As % of GDP    59      60     60.1    59.3

Source: Pakistan Debt Policy Statement 2011-12.

Table 3
Domestic Debt and Budgetary Allocations

                         FY03      FY04      FY05      FY06      FY07

Domestic Currency
  Debt                   1852      1995      2152      2322      2601
Foreign Currency Debt    1771      1816      1913      2038      2201
Total Public debt
  (existing)             3623      3810      4065      4359      4802
GDP                      4876      5641      6500      7623      8673
Debt as per debt
  reduction strategy              3481.98   3319.48   3128.90   2912.08
  4.5% of GDP           219.42    253.84     292.5    343.04    390.28
Social & poverty
  Related expenditure   175.54    219.99      273     373.53    424.98
Budgetary allocation
  to Education as %
  of GDF                  1.6       1.7       1.8       1.9       1.9
Budgetary allocation
  to Health as % of
  GDP                     0.5       0.5       0.5       0.5       0.6

                         FY08      FY09      FY10      FY11

Domestic Currency
  Debt                   3266      3852      4651      6015
Foreign Currency Debt    2778      3776      4270      4694
Total Public debt
  (existing)             6044      7629      8921      10709
GDP                      10243     12724     14837     18063
Debt as per debt
  reduction strategy     2656     2337.9    1966.98   1515.4
  4.5% of GDP           460.94    572.58    667.66    812.84
Social & poverty
  Related expenditure   952.60    877.96    994.08    1246.35
Budgetary allocation
  to Education as %
  of GDF                  1.8       1.9       1.8       1.8
Budgetary allocation
  to Health as % of
  GDP                     0.6       0.7       0.8       0.6

Source: Pakistan Debt Policy Statement 2011-12.

Table 4
Contingent Liabilities
                                                      Share in Total
Years           Contingent Liabilities                 Liabilities
                                         Total as
          Explicit   Implicit   Total    % of GDP   Explicit   Implicit

2002-03    16.18      84.47     100.65     2.47      16.08      83.92
2003-04    13.18      62.69     75.87      1.35      17.38      82.62
2004-05    15.02      79.55     94.57      1.44      15.88      84.12
2005-06    16.17      67.86     84.03      1.10      19.24      80.76
2006-07    35.56      88.62     124.18     1.42      28.64      71.36
2007-08    63.05      154.17    217.21     2.07      29.02      70.98

Source: Economic Survey (Various Issues).


联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有