首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月08日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Public-private investment and economic growth in Pakistan: an empirical analysis.
  • 作者:Bint-e-Ajaz, Maryam ; Ellahi, Nazima
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2012
  • 期号:December
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:Investment is an important component of aggregate demand and a leading source of economic growth. Change in investment not only affect aggregate demand but also enhance the productive capacity of an economy. A third important role highlighted in the literature refers to the innovation and modernisation of the capital equipment via technological progress. The investment plays an essential and vital role in expanding the productive. Maryam capacity of the economy and promoting long term economic growth [Jongwanich and Kohpaiboon (2008)]. Levine and Renelt (1992) argued that investment in capital goods is the most robust and vital determinant of economic growth. Gross domestic investment boosts economic growth by increasing physical capital directly and indirectly through technological spillovers [De Long and Summers (1995)].
  • 关键词:Economic growth

Public-private investment and economic growth in Pakistan: an empirical analysis.


Bint-e-Ajaz, Maryam ; Ellahi, Nazima


1. INTRODUCTION

Investment is an important component of aggregate demand and a leading source of economic growth. Change in investment not only affect aggregate demand but also enhance the productive capacity of an economy. A third important role highlighted in the literature refers to the innovation and modernisation of the capital equipment via technological progress. The investment plays an essential and vital role in expanding the productive. Maryam capacity of the economy and promoting long term economic growth [Jongwanich and Kohpaiboon (2008)]. Levine and Renelt (1992) argued that investment in capital goods is the most robust and vital determinant of economic growth. Gross domestic investment boosts economic growth by increasing physical capital directly and indirectly through technological spillovers [De Long and Summers (1995)].

1.1. The Role of Investment in Growth Process

There has been heated debate in policy-making and academic circles regarding the roles of public and private investment in the process of economic growth. In the 1950s and 1960s available economic models seemed to offer only limited insight into the practical problems facing by developing world. The dominant one-sector macro models of the day, from Keynesian to Harrod-Domar [see Harrod (1939) and Domar (1957)] to Solow 1956, seemed to have relatively little relevance for developing societies like Pakistan.

Available literature including recent extensions of the neo-classical growth model as well as the theories of endogenous growth has highlighted the role of investment in economic growth [see, for example, Kormendi and Meguire (1985); Romer (1986); Lucas (1988); Grier and Tullock (1989); Barro (1991); Levine and Renelt (1991); Rebelo (1991); Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992); Barro and Lee (1993); Fischer (1993) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1999)]. The effect of public investment on economic growth depends on how the increased spending is financed by the government [Bukhari (2006)]. If public and private investments are perfect substitutes, then an increase in public investment would have the same effect on growth as an increase in private investment. Both contribute to the accumulation of physical capital, which increases the productive capacity sustains a higher level of output [Lachler and Aschauer (1964)]. Public investment in the infrastructure has to boost up private investment indirectly that in turn increases the marginal productivity of private capital and enhances the growth of GDP [Looney, et al. (1997)]. It generates positive spillovers by provision of health, education, basic scientific research and physical infrastructure, and may also "crowd in" the private investments. In contrast, the literature also suggests that public investment negatively effects the private investment via the well-known "crowding out" phenomenon via attracting the domestic scare sources through bond floating [Erden and Holcomble (2005)]. These contrasting views about the impact of public investment on private investment are important, however yet unsettled.

So for as Pakistan is concerned, several studies have been carried out, which concentrate on public and private investment and economic growth. The most important are the studies inter-alia by Khan (1988), Looney and Frederiken (1995), Loony, et al. (1997), Khan and Sasaki (2001), Naqvi (2003), Ghani and Din (2006), Khan and Khan (2007), Ahmad and Qayyum (2007) and Majeed and Khan (2008). In some studies the relationship between growth and investment is investigated, while others have attempted to examine the determinants of public and private investment.

Given the vital importance of investment in the process of economic growth, this study endeavours to develop an econometric model to examine the relationship between public and private investment and growth. The present study attempts to follow a comprehensive approach by examining the overall effect of investment on growth, explaining the determinants of public and private investment and evaluating the mutual relationship of the both the components. Thus the rationale is obvious; instead of following a piece meal strategy, it looks more efficient to place all the components in one place and discuss the issue as a whole using different models.

2. REVIEW OF EMPIRICAL LITERATURE

A number of empirical studies are available, which illustrate the relationship between public investment, private investment and economic growth with reference to Pakistan economy. This part presents a brief review of the empirical literature relating to the issue concerned.

Looney and Frederiken (1995) estimated the relationship between public and private investment and concluded that certain types of government investment--especially in rural works 'crowded out' private investment in non-manufacturing activities. Likewise, the public infrastructure investment in energy projects provided the greatest inducement to private investment. Side by side Loony, et al. (1997) studied the impact of Government investment on private sector in Pakistan over the period 1972 to 1995 and concluded private sector investment depends on the lagged change in GDP, the change in private sector credit, the lagged value of private investment, government expenditure in the infrastructure and other projects.

Khan and Sasaki (2001) analysed the role of public capital in Pakistan s' economy. The results showed that public labour ratio and public capital had significantly positive effect on output. Public capital productivity contributes largely at the aggregate and sectoral level and so it played an effective role in the production process. According to Naqvi (2003) public investment had a positive impact on private investment, and that economic growth pushes forward both private and public investment. Naqvi (2003) proved that long run estimates of the elasticities of public and private investment are different under different assumptions made about the evolution of technology. If technology was considered exogenous, the elasticities of private and public capital with respect to output and rate of return were similar to each other.

Same relationship is examined by Ghani and Din (2006) and indicated that public investment had a negative, though insignificant, impact on output. In contrast, there was a positive relationship between private investment and economic growth. Public investment had no favourable impact on private investment; in other words, it 'crowded out' private investment and this result raises some concern about the efficiency of public investment.

Khan (1988) examined the impact of fiscal and monetary policies on private investment in Pakistan. Private investment in aggregate as well as investment in manufacturing and agriculture sector was estimated. The study concluded that market conditions appear to have a strong influence on private investment in general, while changes in output had minor impact. Khan and Khan (2007) investigated the determinants of private investment in Pakistan. The results showed that real GDP had positive but insignificant impact on private investment while public investment had negative but insignificant impact on private investment. According Ahmed and Qayyum (2007) there was long run relationship between private fixed investment, public consumption and development expenditure and market activities. The relationship between public investment and private investment was positive.

3. INVESTMENT AND GROWTH IN PAKISTAN

Pakistan economy has faced many crises since independence in 1947. These crises have hampered the sustainable economic growth. During the 1950's decade, the Korean war boosted our exports and foreign exchange earnings that helped maintaining high economic growth. In 1960's, the continuous inflow of foreign aid and assistance also contributed to high and rapid growth. However, this momentum could not continue during 1970's due civil war, oil price shock and nationalisation policy. But above all, the political instability after 1970-71 has been the major cause of deterioration in Pakistan. High level of defense spending since then is one of the critical factors, which absorbs a significant fraction of scarce revenues and adversely affects public savings otherwise meant for development purpose. The tax revenues in Pakistan could not cope with faster growth in the non-development spending.

Table 1 illustrate the rate of GDP growth and public/ private investment and the total investment as percent of GDP.

Because of nationalisation policies during the period of 1970's, significant involvement of government in commercial activity and increase in the share of public sector squeezed private investment and adversely affected its growth. At that time, public investment was twice in volume relative to private investment. Domination of state owned/controlled institutions adversely affected the financial sector development in Pakistan. In the decade of 1980's, we notice some revival in private sector activity because of encouragement and incentives provided by the government. However, due to sever political instability during 1990's, the picture of the economy remained gloomy. The growth rate fell from 6.2 percent in 1980's to 3.99 percent in 1990's. There was a slowing down of public investment activity when compared to the trend level especially in the latter part of the decade, while there was some acceleration in the rate of private investment during 1990's relative to the position in the 1980's decade. Political instability during the 1990's decade negatively affected the growth rate of the economy.

With the advent of 21st century, we observe some kind of revival in growth and investment activities. Economic reforms programme such as fiscal adjustment, privatisation of energy, telecommunication and production, reforms in the banking and trade sectors launched in 2000, played a vital role in the economic recovery of the Pakistan. Table 2 presents the year-wise percentage of public, private investment, total investment and percentage of GDP from 2000-2001 to 2011-2012 respectively.

On the average GDP growth rate increased twice as compared to 1990s decade and total investment also increased from 16.48 percent of GDP in 1990s to 18.08 percent of GDP in the early years of the current decade. Private investment has increased overtime and public investment relatively slowed down. Economy has grown by more than 6.5 percent per year on the average since 2003-04. As a percentage of shares of GDP, investment increased from 15.5 percent in 2001-02 to 20.4 percent in 2007-08, which is a healthy sign. After that it declined rapidly in 2008-09 and in 2009-10 its growth rate became negative both in public and private investment. In 2011-12 its rose slightly due to some increase in both type of investment due to recent election era.

The financial sectors reforms after 1990 have shown a positive impact on the degree of interest rate liberalisation, moderate reduction in credit subsidies and progress towards the market-based transactions. However, because of high rate of inflation, the interest rate on deposits became negative in real term and discouraged the financial saving [Hassan (1997)]. To finance expenditures, the governments (both democratic and authoritative) have to rely heavily on external and internal borrowing and deficit financing. This practice has resulted into high stakes of debt and high inflation, which has increased debt servicing. The rising interest rate burden along with high defense spending together absorb about two-third of gross revenues. Consequently, nothing is left for the development budget and provision of social services like health and education. The political conditions deteriorated during 2007-08 and the new democratic government that took over in March 2008, has to face a lot of challenges both on the internal and external fronts. The rate of investment has surely slowed down during 2008 and 2009 due to the terrorist activities and shortage of electricity and gas for the industrial sector. The practice of out-wards looking policies on part of the government continues as usual and the prospects of growth and development depend heavily on the availability of foreign aid and assistance. 2012 has passed on the dream of self-sustaining growth and investment is yet far from turning into reality.

4. DATA, MODEL AND METHODOLOGY

Most of the data is retrieved from the International Financial Statistic (IFS) Yearbook published by International Monetary Fund (IMF). The data on some variables is collected from various issues of Pakistan Economic Survey compiled by the Federal Bureau of Statistics, Government of Pakistan and from the Annual Reports of the State Bank of Pakistan. All the data is expressed in million rupees except the Credit-to-GDP ratio, inflation rate, exchange rate and lending rate.

4.1. The Model

The link between private, public investment and economic growth is examined by the researchers like Ibrahim (2000). The relationship may be expressed as under in somewhat modified form:

[Y.sub.t] = f([I.sub.pt], [I.sub.gt], [Cred.sub.t], [l.sub.rt]) (1)

Where Y = real GDP, Ig = public investment, Ip = private investment, lr =lending rate, Cred = ratio of private sector credit to GDP. Theoretically both types of investments are positively related to the GDP but empirically it depends on the efficiency and productivity of investment. Private sector credit and lending rate is also included in the function as it affects the private investment directly and also the growth rate of GDP indirectly since the availability of easy credit provides incentives to private investors, which increases the growth rate of GDP. Similarly, an increase in the real interest rate increases the cost of borrowing and thus discourages new investment and growth of GDP.

Public investment is mainly determined by foreign aid and government revenue. It also depends on GDP. We expect positive coefficients of these three variables. Exchange rate and inflation rate also influence the public investment negatively. Following Rahman (2008), we specify following public investment function as under:

[I.sub.gt] = f ([Y.sub.t], [Aid.sub.t], [er.sub.t], [Gr.sub.t], [Inf.sub.t]) (2)

Where the symbols stand for: Aid = foreign aid, er = exchange rate, Gr = Government Revenue, Inf= inflation rate.

GDP plays an important role in determining private investment. The investment decisions are affected by domestic credit available to private sector, lending rate and inflation, while public investment may also include as explanatory variable to capture the "crowding out" or "crowding in" effect on private investment. Following Khan and Khan (2007), we specify the private investment function as follows:

[I.sub.pt] = f ([Y.sub.t], [Cred.sub.t], [Ig.sub.t], [lr.sub.t], [er.sub.t], [Inf.sub.t]) (3)

The above three functions can be written in a testable form as:

ln[Y.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1] ln[I.sub.pt] + [[alpha.sub.2] ln[I.sub.gt] + [[alpha].sub.3]ln[Cred.sub.t] + [[alpha].sub.4] [lr.sub.t] + [u.sub.t] (4)

ln[I.sub.gt] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] ln[y.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.2] ln[Aid.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.3] ln[Gr.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.4] ln[er.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.5] [Inf.sub.t] + [v.sub.t] (5)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)

The terms u, v and w are the stochastic/error terms as usual.

4.2. Econometric Methodology

The above model will be estimated in three steps. First, using the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) unit root tests and assuming individual time series as non-stationary, we examine the time series properties of the data. Second, conditional to the results of the unit root test, we check co-integration between the variables specified in each equation using the method proposed by Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990). Third, based on the results of the long-run co-integration parameters, we will estimate the short-run error-correction models of each equation.

4.2.1. Co integration Analysis

Let's we have an endogenous variable of kth order, which can be written in a vector error correction model (VECM) as follows:

[Y.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.0] + [[pi].sub.1] [Y.sub.t-1] + [[pi].sub.2][Y.sub.t-2] + ... ... ... + [[pi].sub.k][Y.sub.t-k] + [v.sub.t] (7)

Where [Y.sub.t] is a (pxl) random time series vector (the variables with order of integration of at most one are denoted by 1 (1), [PI] represents the vector of constant term and [v.sub.t] is the vector of error term which is I(0) and distributed with (0, [[sigma].sup.2]). Defining [DELTA] = 1-L, where L is the lag operator, the dynamics of the error correction model (ECM) is deduced as follows:

[DELTA] [Y.sub.t] = [[pi].sub.0] + [k-1.summation over (i=1)] [[GAMMA].sub.i] [DELTA] [Y.sub.t-1] + [PI] [Y.sub.t-k] + [v.sub.t] (8)

[[GAMMA].sub.i] = - (I - [[PI].sub.l] - .... - [[PI].sub.i]) [v.sub.t] i = 1, 2, 3 (9)

where [PI][Y.sub.t-1] is a (px p) matrix of parameters, the rank of which contains information about long-run relationships among the variables in the model. If [PI][Y.sub.t-1] has full rank p, all elements in [Y.sub.t] are stationary. If the rank of [PI] is zero, the model reduces to VAR in the first-differences. When 0 < rank < p , there exist co-integrating relationships equal to the rank. In this case there exist (pxr) matrices [alpha] and [beta]. If the individual series is I(1), then the first differences of the series are stationary. If there is co-integration relationship between I(1) series, then the linear combination of these variable is I(0), so that the [[PI].sub.t][Y.sub.t] term is stationary.

To test whether there exists co-integration between the variable or otherwise, two test statistics are used, which determine the rank of co-integration space. One is the likelihood ratio test based on the maximum Eigen value ([[lambda].sub.max]) of the stochastic matrix and the second test is the value of the likelihood ratio test based on the trace of the stochastic matrix ([[lambda].sub.trace]). The likelihood ratio test statistics developed by Johansen are given below:

LR [[lambda].sub.trace] = - T [n.summation over (t=r+1)] ln (1 - [[lambda].sup.[??].sub.1] (10)

Where [[lambda].sub.t+1], [[lambda].sub.t+2] ..., [[lambda].sub.n] are the n-r smallest eigen-values and T stands for number of observations.

LR [[lambda].sub.max] = - T ln (1 - [[lambda].sup.[??].sub.t+1]) (11)

The first statistics ([[lambda].sub.max]) tests the null hypothesis that there are less than or equal to "r" co-integrating vectors against the general alternative where "r" is the number of co-integrating relations. The second statistics ([[lambda].sub.trace]) tests the hypothesis that there are "n" numbers of co-integrating vectors against the alternative of r+1.

4.2.2. Short-run Analysis of the Variables

The short run dynamics are examined using the error correction mechanism (ECM), the ECM is important for many reasons. It is a convenient model, which is formulated in term of first differences. It measures the correction from disequilibrium of the previous period. ECM eliminates trend from the variables and resolves the problem of spurious regression. This model follows the general to specific approach in econometric modeling. By definition of co-integration disequilibrium, the error term is stationary. Two variables are co-integrated implies that there is some adjustment process which prevents the error into the long-run relationship. Thus the concepts of co-integration and the error correction mechanism (ECM) are closely related.

We formulate the error correction models for the real GDP, public investment and private investment respectively as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (13)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (14)

Where [DELTA] is the difference operator and [ECM.sub.t-1] is an error correction term. The expected signs of the parameters [gamma], [sigma] and [delta] should be negative, which will measure the speed of adjustment towards long run equilibrium.

5. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

We examine the order of integration using Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) unit root test. All variables, except the lending rate and inflation are in log form. Table 3 reports the results.

It can be seen from above that all the variables are non-stationary at their levels but stationary at their first differences.

5.1. The Long Run Growth Function

To examine the co integration between real GDP and its determinants we use multivariate co-integration test. Two lags were selected on the basis of Akaike information criterion (AIC). By applying the two stage likelihood ratio tests the number of co-integrating vectors is investigated. We follow the degree of freedom adjustment method (1) due to Cheung and Lai (1993) for trace and max statistics. The results are reported in Table 4 below.

The maximum Eigen-values test ([lambda]-max) indicates the existence of two co-integrating vectors, while the trace statistics ([lamdba]-trace) indicates the existence of three co-integrating vectors at the 5 percent level of significance. However, when we use the adjusted max and the adjusted trace statistics, it is indicated that there are one and three co-integrating vectors respectively included in the model.

The long run output function (real GDP) is obtained by normalising the first co-integrated vector on the growth rate. The results of long run relationship are reported in Table 5 below.

It is evident from the table that in long run public investment exerts negative impact on the growth rate of GDP. This is because government is mainly investing in the sectors, which are unproductive and inefficient. This result is line with Ghani and Din (2006). On the other hand, private investment positively affects the GDP in long run and enhances the growth rate. This result confirms the findings of Khan and Sasaki (2002) and Ghani and Din (2006). The coefficient of private sector credit relative to GDP is positive but insignificant. The lending rate has negative and insignificant impact, which reflects that economic growth is not much responsive to lending rate.

5.2. The Long Run Public Investment Function

The estimated results are quoted in Table 6. Two lags were selected on the basis of Akaike information criterion (AIC). The likelihood ratio statistics for ([lambda]-max) indicates the existence of five co-integrating vectors where the ([lambda]-trace) indicates the existence of six co-untegrating vectors at 5 percent level of significance. By using the test with degree of freedom adjusted, the max statistics indicates existence of four co-integration while the trace statistics shows six co-integrating relationships in the model.

The long run public investment function is obtained by normalising the first co-integration vector on public investment. The results are reported in Table 7 below.

The above results indicate that the real GDP has positive and significant impact on public investment. It confirms the theoretical relationship of these two variables as implied by accelerator model. The foreign aid is important but to a limited extent so far as public investment in Pakistan is concerned. This result hardly supports the findings of Rahman (2008) in the case of SAARC countries and the Blejer and Khan (1984) that inflow of foreign capital positively affects the investment rate. This is because the flow of foreign aid has been irregular and too much fluctuating during the period of study. The exchange rate shows negative but insignificant impact on public investment. An increase in exchange rate makes imported goods relatively expensive which is likely to compress investment. On the other hand, the government revenue has (surprisingly) a negative and significant impact. This could be explained by the fact that government revenue is merely used to finance current expenditure of the government and seldom available for development purposes [Rahman (2008)]. The inflation rate exerts a negative and significant impact on public investment because an increase in inflation leads to increase the nominal interest rate as well as the cost of raw material and machinery/equipment.

5.3. The Long Run Private Investment Function

The co-integrating relationship between private investment and its determinants based on Johansen co-integration test, is presented below in Table 8. The model includes unrestricted intercept and no trend. Two lags were selected on the basis of Akaike information criterion (AIC).

The likelihood ratio statistics ([lambda]-max) indicates the existence of six co-integrating vectors while ([lambda]-trace) indicates the existence of seven co-integrating vectors at 5 percent level of significance. By using the degree of freedom adjusted test statistics, the max-test indicates the existence of two co-integrating vectors and the trace-statistics indicates that of five co-integrating vectors. Thus the estimated results confirm the existence of long-run relationship among the variables concerned. The long-run private investment function is obtained by normalising the estimated co-integrated vector on the private investment function. The results are reported in Table 9.

As revealed from the above, the effect of real GDP is positive but statistically insignificant, showing weak accelerator. This finding is consistent with Blejer and Khan (1984), Naqvi (2003), Ahmed and Qayyum (2007) and Khan and Khan (2007). Surprisingly, the coefficient of private sector Credit-to-GDP ratio has negative and significant impact on private investment. This may be explained by the factual position that credit was extended mainly to sick units who used the funds to repay their outstanding loans to the banks [Khan and Khan (2007)]. The negative and significant values of lending rate and inflation confirm the theoretical relationship between these variables and private investment. Likewise, an increase in the rate of inflation leads to enhance the prices of raw material, machinery and equipment as well as the wage bill, which discourage private investment. Same is the case with exchange rate since depreciation of domestic currency definitely increases the cost of imported goods. The public investment has negative and significant impact on private investment, which implies the "crowding out" effect. The results is consistent with findings of Ghani and Din (2006), Khan and Sasaki (2001), Khan and Khan (2007) and Majeed and Khan (2008).

5.3.1. The Short-run Growth Function

The results show that three regressors are important in establishing the short run relationship with the growth rate of GDP and the remaining two variables, being insignificant, are dropped front the model following the general to specific methodology. The change in private investment lagged by one year ([DELTA][LI.sub.pt-1]), current public investment ([DELTA][LI.sub.gt]) and a dummy included for uncertainty ([UN.sub.t]) (2) are significant variables while other variables like the credit-to-GDP ratio and lending rate are proved to be insignificant. The results are given below in Table 10.

The estimated error correction coefficient ([ECM.sub.t-1]) (3) is--0.0058 has theoretically correct negative sign and significant at 5 percent level. In short run private investment positively and significantly affects the growth rate of GDP, likewise public investment is positive and significant, thereby indicating a strong impact on the growth of GDP. The reason is that in short run it stimulates the demand in some extant but in long run its effect dampen. The estimated coefficient of uncertainty is negative which indicates that macroeconomic instability and uncertainty has always depressed economic growth in Pakistan. The estimated model passes different diagnostic tests, such as ARCH test for serial correlation (F-statistics: 0.244, probability: 0.784) and White test for Hetroscedasticity (F-Statistics: 2.21, probability: 0.669).

5.3.2. Short-run Public Investment Function

Estimated results for the short run relationship between the public investment and its determinants like real GDP, foreign aid, exchange rate, government revenue and inflation rate shows that all variables are insignificant in the short run except changes in public investment lagged by one year ([DELTA][LI.sub.gt-1]), current inflation rate ([DELTA]Linf) and lending rate ([DELTA]lr). These three variables show significant short-run relationship with public investment. The results are presented on Table 11.

The estimated coefficient of ECM shows that approximately 59 percent of disequilibrium in the public investment is instantly corrected. The coefficient of lagged government investment is significant and has positive sign, which indicates that changes in previous period's public investment positively affect the short-run changes in current public investment. The changes in inflation rate and exchange rate exert significant and negative impacts on current public investment. The estimated model passes different diagnostic tests, such as ARCH test for serial correlation (F-statistics: 0.163, probability: 0.84) and White test for Hetroscedasticity (F-Statistics: 1.03, probability: 0.44).

5.3.3. The Short-run Estimation of Private Investment Function

The results show that the variables significant in determining changes in private investment include changes in public investment lagged by one year ([DELTA][I.sub.gt-1]), changes in lending rate lagged by one year ([DELTA][Ir.sub.t-1]) and current inflation rate ([DELTA]Linf). The remaining variables are insignificant in the short-run. The results are presented below in Table 12.

The estimated error coefficient is -0.0117, with theoretically correct sign and significant at 5 percent level. The coefficient of lagged public investment is positive and significant, indicating a positive effect on current private investment. The coefficients of inflation rate and lending rate are significant. The negative signs confirm the theoretical relationship that these variables negatively affect private investment in the short-run. The estimated model passes different diagnostic tests, such as ARCH test for serial correlation (F-statistics: 0.355, probability: 0.703) and White test for Hetroscedasticity (F-statistics: 2.13, probability: 0.069).

6. CONCLUSION

The study has attempted to evaluate the inter-relationship among the three macrovariables, namely public and private investment and GDP growth both in the long and short run with reference to Pakistan- economy. We have tried to pinpoint the important determinants of each variable, using the standard econometric techniques. As expected, the GDP growth has a strong positive relationship with public and private investment and there is a two-way causality between GDP and investment. The public investment is affected by the level of GDP, inflation and exchange rates. Likewise, private investment is affected by inflation and exchange rates, the lending rate, besides the level of GDP. The general negative theoretical relationship between public and private investment is confirmed in the context of Pakistan economy, i.e. public investment exerts a "crowdingout" effect on private investment at large. This is because public investment has primarily been financed in the past through internal and external borrowing. The government revenues collected through taxation has little contribution in promoting public investment.

Comments

Paper is a good contribution in the field of macroeconomics. It shows the causal link among growth, private investment and public investment. One of the most interesting result came out of the study is that public investment crowds out private investment which is contrary to the previous studies which shows crowding in hypothesis, i.e., public investment crowds in private investment. After this paper government should stay away from investing in all those sector where there is a chance for private sector to invest. However to improve the paper authors may need to revise it according to the following comments.

(1) As far as growth modelling is concerned. Why do we neglect Harrod-Domer Model while studying the link between investment and growth? Paper should include Harrod-Domer model and other theories related to effect of private and public investment on growth.

(2) Paper used data till 2008 so they need to update it.

(3) They have written some blunt statement in the paper such as "public and private investment would have same effect on GDP". If this is true then how come there is crowding out, which shows that public investment crowds out private investment. If author's statement is true then crowding out does not have any impact on the GDP.

(4) As per literature, inflation variability and exchange rate variability effects investment decision instead of just inflation and exchange rate movements. Thus it would be good to use these two variables as well in the model.

(5) Paper has used Johansen approach of cointegration. Model explained in the paper does not represent the Johansen model since it takes all the variables as endogenous variables. Otherwise there might be problems of simultaneity and identification. Authors need to check before sending the revised version of the paper since it is a big mistake they are doing while estimating their parameters. Johansen method applies on the system of equations where all the equations are exactly identified.

M. Ali Kemal

Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

REFERENCES

Ahmad, Imtiaz and Abdul Qayyum (2007) Do Public Expenditure and Macroeconomic Uncertainity Matter to Private Investment? Evidence from Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 46:2, 145-161.

Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 407-444.

Barro, R. J. and X. Sala-i-Martin (1999) Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

Blejer, M. and Mohsin S. Khan (1984) Government Policy and Private Investment in Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers 31:2, 379-403.

Blejer, M. I. and Mohsin S. Khan (19484) Government Policy and Private Investment in Developing Countries. IMF Staff Papers 31:2.

Bukhari, S. A. A. S. Ali, L. and Sadaqat (2006) Public Investment and Economic Growth in the Three Little Dragons. Evidence from Heterogeneous Dynamic Panel Data. Karachi: Applied Economics Research Centre, University of Karachi, Pakistan.

Cheung, Y. W. and K. Lai (1993) A Fractional Cointegration Analysis of Purchasing Power Parity. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 11, 103-112.

Erden, L. and H. R. (2005) The Effect of Public Investment on Private Investment in Developing Economies. Public Finance Review 133:5, 575-602.

Fischer, S. (1993) The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth. National Bureau of Economic Research. (Working Paper No. 4565).

Ghani, E. and Musleh-ud Din (2006) The Impact of Public Investment on Economic Growth in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 45:1, 87-98.

Grier, K. and G. Tullock (1989) An Empirical Analysis of Cross-National Economic Growth: 1951-1980. Journal of Monetary Economics 24:2, 259-276.

Hassan, P. (1997) Learning from the Past: A Fifty Year Perspective of Pakistan's Development. The Pakistan Development Review 36:4, 355-402.

Ibrahim, M. H. (2000) Public and Private Capital Formation and Economic Growth in Malaysia. HUM Journal of Economics and Management 8:1, 21-40.

Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12, 231-254.

Johansen, S. and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration with Application of Demand for Money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 12, 169-210.

Jongwanich, J. and A. Kohpaiboon (2008) Private Investment: Trends and determinants in Thailand. World Development 36:10, 1709-1724.

Khan, Ashfaque H. (1988) Macroeconomic Policy and Private Investment in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 27:3, 277-291.

Khan, M. T. and Sasaki Komei (2001) Roles of Public Capital in Pakistan s' Economy: Productivity, Investment and Growth Analysis. Rural Urban Development Studies 13, 143-161.

Khan, Sajawal and Khan Arshad (2007) What Determines Private Investment? The Case of Pakistan. (P1DE Working Papers 2007:36).

Levine, Ross and David Renelt (1992) A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions. American Economic Review 82:4, 942-963.

Looney and Frederiken (1995) Privatization of Public Sector Enterprises In Pakistan: Prospects For Reducing Regional Imbalances. Review of Urban and Rural Development Studies 7, 143-152.

Looney, R. E. and Peter C. Frederic (1997) Government Investment and Follow-on Private Sector Investment in Pakistan. Journal of Economic Development 22:1, 91-100.

Lucas Jr., R. E. (1988) On the Mechanics of Economic Development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3-42.

Majeed, T. M. and S. Khan (2008) The Determinants of Private Investment and the Relationship between Public and Private Investment in Pakistan. NUST Journal of Business and Economics 1:1, 41-48.

Mankiw, G. N., D. Romer, and D. Weil (1992) A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:2, 407-437.

Naqvi (2003) Is Public Capital More Productive than Private Capital? Macroeconomic Evidence from Pakistan, 1965-2000. School of Finance and Business University of Durhan. (Working Paper in Economics and Finance No. 03/03).

Pakistan, Government of (Various Issues) Economic Surveys. Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.

Phillips, P. C. B. and Bruce Hansen (1990) Statistical Inference in Instrumental Variables Regression with 1(1) Processes. Review of Economic Studies 57, 99-125.

Rahman, M. M. (2008) Macro-economic and Trade Link Models of SAARC Countries: An Investigation for Regional Trade Expansion. Journal of Asia Pacific Economy 13:1, 50-62.

Rebelo, S. (1991) Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 94:5, 56-62.

Roberto, M.S. (2005) An Estimation of Residential Water Demand Using Co-Integration and Error Correction Techniques. (MPRA Paper 615), ppl-4.

Romer, Paul M. (1986) Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy 94:5 (October), 1002-1037.

Shahbaz, et al. (2008) Does Foreign Remittances Reduce Government Spending? Longand Short Run Phenomenon. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics ISSN 1450-2887 Issue 14.

(1) Cheung and Lai (1993) method is used to scale up the Johansen Critical Value by the factor (T-K/T), where T indicates the number of observations and K stands for the number of variables used in the study.

(2) A dummy for uncertainty is used in the short-run under the assumption that investment decisions are likely to be affected by recent uncertainty which is created by macro economic uncertainty.

(3) The term error correction (ECM) consists of residual obtained from the long run output (real GDP), public investment and private investment functions. The estimated error correction coefficient is obtained by resetting the normalising coefficients obtained from long run growth function.

Maryam Bint-e-Ajaz <maryabbasi@gmail.com> is Research Scholar at University of AJ&K, Muzaffarabad. Nazima Ellahi is Assistant Professor at Foundation University, Islamabad.
Table 1
Average GDP Growth Rate and Ratio of Public/
Private Investment to GDP Overtime

              GDP Growth   Public .Inv.   Priv.Inv   Total.Inv
Time Period      (%)          Ig/GDP       Ip/GDP    Ig+Ip/GDP

1971-80          4.78          9.44         5.32       14.76
1981-90          6.25          9.17         7.79       16.96
1991-2000        3.99          7.34         9.14       16.48
2001-2012        4.70         20.28        10.009      30.28

Source: Pakistan Economic Survey (various issues).

Table 2
Percentage of GDP Growth and Public/
Private Investment and Total Investment

              GDP Growth   Public .Inv.   Priv.Inv   Total.Inv
Time Period      (%)          Ig/GDP       Ip/GDP    Ig+Ip/GDP

2000-01          2.0           5.7          10.2       15.9
2001-02          3.1           4.2          11.3       15.5
2002-03          4.7           4.0          11.3       15.3
2003-04          7.5           4.0          10.9       14.9
2004-05          9.0           4.3          13.1       17.1
2005-06          5.8           4.7          15.7       20.4
2006-07          6.8           5.7          16.2       21.9
2007-08          3.7           5.4          15.0       20.4
2008-09          1.7          -0.34         1.4        1.06
2009-10          3.1          -1.74         -1.1       -2.84
2010-11          3.0          -0.133        0.3        0.167
2011-12          3.7           5.03         5.8        10.83

Source: Pakistan Economic Survey (various issues).

Table 3
Results for Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test of Unit Roots

                              ADF at First
Variables      ADF at Level    Difference    I()(Decision)

In y              0.4973        -5.3540          I(1)
In [I.sub.g]      -0.370        -6.2386          I(1)
In [I.sub.p       -2.421        -4.8709          I(1)
In Cred          -0.4618        -5.1788          I(1)
In Aid            0.9546        -8.7650          I(1)
In er            -1.6619        -7.1341          I(1)
Lr               -2.6125        -4.3394          I(1)
Inf              -2.3405        -5.5965          I(1)

Note: ADF test is based on the Mackinnon (1991) critical values.

Table 4
GDP & Co-integrating Factors: Johansen Test

Maximum Eigen-values Test ([lambda]--max)

Null         Alternative      Test      (T-K/T) Adjusted   5% Critical
Hypothesis   Hypothesis    Statistics    Max Statistics       Value

r=0              R=1        40.649 *        32.77 *          33.87
r=1              R=2        26.988          22.66            27.584
r=2              R=3        18.011 *        15.93            21.136
r=3              R=4         8.881           7.46            14.264
r=4              R=5         2.419           2.0             3.8416

Trace Test ([lambda]--trace)

r=0          R [greater     109.95 *        85.67 *          69.818
               than or
             equal to] 1
r=1          R [greater     67.301 *         54.9 *          47.856
               than or
             equal to] 2
r=2          R [greater     34.312 *        29.85 *          29.797
               than or
             equal to] 3
r=3          R [greater      17.300          12.492          15.494
               than or
             equal to] 4
r=4          R [greater      5.419            2.03           3.8414
               than or
             equal to] 5

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 5
Normalised Coefficients of Co-integrating Vector on Real GDP

Variables      Coefficients   Standard Error   t-Value

In [I.sub.g]     -0.785 *         0.153         5.78
In [I.sub.p       0.558 *         0.169        -4.181
In Cred           0.107           0.345        -0.227
Lr               -0.0732          0.0437        0.980
Constant          -9-44             --           --

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 6
Public Investment and Co-integrating Factors: Johansen Test

Maximum Eigen-values Test ([lambda]--max)

Null         Alternative      Test      (T-K/T) Adjusted   5% critical
Hypothesis   Hypothesis    Statistics   Trace Statistic       Value

r=0              r=1        66.893 *        55.454 *         40.077
r=1              r=2        52.223 *        43.292 *         33.876
r=2              r=3        33.995 *        28.181 *         27.584
r=3              r=4         18.673          15.479          21.131
r=4              r=5        15.674 *         12.971          14.264
r=5              r=6        7.525 *         6.238 *           3.841

Trace Test ([lambda]--trace)

r=0          r [greater     194.96 *        161.62 *          95.75
               than or
             equal to] 1
r=1          r [greater     128.06 *        106.17 *         69.818
               than or
             equal to] 2
r=2          r [greater     75.842 *        62.87 *          47.856
               than or
             equal to] 3
r=3          r [greater     41.846 *        34.69 *          29.797
               than or
             equal to] 4
r=4          r [greater     23.173 *        19.21 *          15.494
               than or
             equal to] 5
r=5          r [greater     7.525 *          6.24 *           3.841
               than or
             equal to] 6

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 7
Normalised Coefficients of Co-integrating Vector on Public
Investment Function

Variables   Coefficients   Standard Error   t-Value

In y          6.403 *          0.785        -5.585
In Aid         0.178           0.023        -0.981
In Gr          -2.371          0.403         7.003
In er          -0.276          0.172         1.256
Inf           -0.109 *         0.013         9.654
Constant       25.134            --           --

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 8
Private Investment and Co-integrating Factors: Johansen Test

Maximum Eigen-values Test ([lambda]--max)

Null         Alternative      Test      (T-K/T) Adjusted   5% Critical
Hypothesis   Hypothesis    Statistics   Trace Statistics      Value

r=0              r=1        97.994 *        57.995 *         46.231
r=1              r=2        87.880 *        75.995 *         40.077
r=2              r=3        43.805 *         30.391          33.876
r=3              r=4        35.395 *         20.708          27.584
r=4              r=5        21.151 *         15.630          21.131
r=5              r=6         13.992          11.225          14.264
r=6              r=7        11.078 *         7.022            3.841

Trace Test ([lambda]--trace)

r=0          r [greater    266.297 *       211.705 *         125.615
               than or
             equal to] 1
r=1          r [greater    186.302 *        148.74 *         95.753
               than or
             equal to] 2
r=2          r [greater    116.422 *        89.754 *         69.818
               than or
             equal to] 3
r=3          r [greater     77.617 *        66.362 *         47.856
               than or
             equal to] 4
r=4          r [greater     42.222 *        31.654 *         29.797
               than or
             equal to] 5
r=5          r [greater     18.070 *         15.193          15.494
               than or
             equal to] 6
r=6          r [greater     9.078 *          4.022            3.841
               than or
             equal to] 7

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 9
Normalised Coefficients of Co integrating
Vector on Private Investment Function

Variables      Coefficients   Standard Error   t-Value

In y              0.375           0.437        -0.623
In Cred          -0.567 *         0.038         5.946
In [I.sub.g]     -1.973 *         0.387         5.271
In er            -0.578 *         0.076         9.207
lr               -3.262 *         0.766         5.255
Inf              -0.243 *         0.026         5.946
Constant          -4.761            --           --

Note: * Indicates significance at 5 percent level.

Table 10
Error Correction Model of Real (GDP)

Variables              Coefficient   Std. Error    t-Statistic

[DELTA][ln.sub.pt-1]    0.0808 **      0.0463         1.744
[DELTA][ln.sub.gt-1]    0.1195 *       0.0467         2.553
[UN.sub.t]             -0.0035 **       0.018         1.84
[ECM.sub.t-1]           -0.0058 *      0.00085        6.861
R-squared = -0.20              Adjusted R-squared = -0.13
D.W Test = 2.32                F(4,33) = .466

Note: * Shows significance at 5 percent level
and ** shows significance at 10 percent level.
[ECM.sub.t-1] = (In [y.sub.t] + 0.785 * ln [I.sub.gt]
-0.585 * ln [I.sub.pt] -0.1017 * [lncred.sub.t] +0.0738 * lr)

Table 11
Error Correction Model of Public Investment Function

Variables              Coefficients   Standard Error   t-Values

[DELTA][ln.sub.gt-1]     0.4102 *         0.148         2.769
[DELTA]ln inf           -0.0906 *         0.035         -2.530
ln [er.sub.t]            -0.842 *         0.254         -3.302
Constant                 -6.385 *         1.234         -5.17
[ECM.sub.t-1]            -0.591 *         0.115         -5.14
R-squared = 0.54       Adjusted R-squared = 0.48
D.W stat = 2.59

Note: * Shows significant at 5 percent level
and ** shows significant at 10 percent level.

[ECM.sub.t-1] = (ln [I.sub.gt] + 2.371 * ln [G.sub.rt]
-0.195 * [lnaid.sub.t] -6.841 * [lny.sub.t] +0.10inf
* +0.276 [lner.sub.t])

Table 12
Error Correction Model of Private Investment Function

Variables                Coefficients   Standard Error   t-Values

[DELTA][ln.sub.gt - 1]    0.00015 **      7.78 E-05       1.936
[DELTA][lr.sub.t-1]       -0.0438 *         0.0179        -2.438
[DELTA]ln inf             -0.0892 *         0.0339        -2.630
[ECM.sub.t-1]             -0.0117 *         0.0029        -3.952
R-squared = 0.37         Adjusted R-squared = 0.31
D-W Test = 2.421

Note: * Shows significant at 5 percent level and ** shows
significant at 10 percent level.

[ECM.sub.t-1] = [lnI.sub.pt] -0.375 * [lnY.sub.t-1] +5.567 *
[lncred.sub.t] +3.262 * lr +1.973 * [lnI.sub.gt] +0.243 * lninf
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有