Asset pricing behaviour with dual-beta in case of Pakistani stock market.
Javid, Attiya Y. ; Ahmad, Eatzaz
This study investigates the dynamics of beta by the asymmetric response of beta to bullish and bearish market environment on 50 stocks
traded in Karachi Stock Exchange during 1993-2007. The results show that
the betas increase (decrease) when the market is bullish (bearish). The
results however suggest that investors receive a positive premium for
accepting down-side risk, while a negative premium is associated with
up-market beta. The results suggest that the conditional Fama and French
three factor model has performed better than the conditional CAPM when
news asymmetry was taken into account compared with the unconditional Fama and French three factor model and the unconditional dual-beta CAPM
in explaining the relationship in beta and returns in case of Pakistani
market.
JEL classification: G12, G15
Keywords: Beta Instability, High Market Beta, Low Market Beta,
EGARCH Model, News Asymmetry, Fama and French Three Factor Model
1. INTRODUCTION
In the realm of asset pricing models the Sharpe (1964) and Lintner
(1965) Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) continues to be the primary
and dominant model. However, after the introduction of CAPM academics
have presented many critiques invalidating its statistical significance
[Fama and French (1993) and numerous other studies]. They have
consistently held that the CAPM's single factor (beta) defined as
covariance of asset returns with market return was unable to capture all
risks associated with the explanation of an assets expected returns. On
the one hand, it leads to the development of a two-beta model that
incorporates the up and down market responses of stock returns which
allows the separation of systematic risk into favourable and
unfavourable variations respectively from up-side and down-side
responses[Kim and Zumwait (1979)]; on the other hand, the
characteristics of the firms that are likely to explain the anomalies in
asset returns need to be specified such as small firm effect, January
effect, earning-to-price ratio, book to market value and leverage. The
most prominent work in this regard is the series of papers by Fama and
French (1993, 1995, 1996, 1998 and 2004), (1) which construct hedge
portfolios with long/short positions in firms with attributes that are
known to be associated with mean returns. The three-factor model of Fama
and French (1996) says that the expected returns in excess of risk free
rate are explained by the excess market return, the difference between
the returns on portfolio of small stocks and returns on portfolio of
large stocks and the difference between the returns on portfolio of high
book-to-market stocks and returns on a portfolio of low book-to-market
stocks. The three-factor model of Fama and French (1993) is now widely
used in empirical research that requires a model of expected returns.
Among practitioners, the model is offered as an alternative to the CAPM
for estimating the cost of equity capital (for example, Ibbotson
Associates), and portfolio performance [Fama and French (2004)].
Since the Fama and French (1992) study, several studies have argued
that it might be too early to reject beta as systematic measure of risk
[Clare, Priestley, and Thomas (1998); Kathori, Shanken, and Salon (1995); Davis and Desai (1998) and Faff (2001)]. The empirical evidence
shows that the downside risk may be a more appropriate measure of
portfolio risk than the conventional single beta [Grundy and Malkiel
(1996) and Kiln and Zumwalt (1979)]. One view is that the inadequacy of
the single factor CAPM is due to non-stability or randomness of betas.
Fabozzi and Francis (1977) document the results to determine that the
regression coefficient of standard CAPM are significantly different in
bull and bear markets. Levy (1974) allows the beta to change with good
news and bad news in the model, while Black (1993) estimates the
regression model in which intercept term varies overtime. Another view
is that the time variability is due to the time varying nature of beta,
therefore, testing CAPM in various market conditions with constant risk
parameters is over-simplified because the returns distribution is time
varying in nature, (2) This stylised fact is first examined in the time
varying behaviour of conditional covariances by Engle, Lillen, and
Robins (1987), Bollerslev, Engle, and Wooldridge (1988), and Bollerslev,
Engle, and Nelson (1994). Some studies investigate the effect of good
and bad news measured by positive and a negative return i.e., the
leverages effects, on beta of CAPM [Braun, Nelson, and Sunier (1995);
Chou and Engle (1999) and Granger and Silvapulle (2002)]. Pagan and
Sussounov (2000) show that the nature of bull and bear market depends on
the type of data generating process which generates capital gains in the
market. (3) Granger and Silvapulle (1999) use value-at-risk to define
various market conditions. Maheu and McCurdy (2000) use duration
dependence as a source of nonlinearity in the stock market cycles. (4)
The purpose of the present study is to look in to the failure of
beta to explain the cross-section variation in expected returns for
Pakistani market and to investigate the hypothesis that stock returns
respond differently to up and down markets. The model allows total
systematic risk to be separated into variation due to upside response
which is considered as good news and variation due to down side response
which is viewed as bad news. (5) In the next stage, the dual-beta CAPM
model is extended by including Fama and French (1993) size and book to
market value as risk factors. Thereafter, dual-beta CAPM and Fama and
French three factor models are extended by incorporating conditional
information by allowing variance equation to capture news asymmetry. The
final issue investigated is the risk premium for market risk in the bull
and bear market conditions in conditional and unconditional settings.
The dual-beta CAPM and Fama and French three factor models have not been
tested for Pakistan. The current study contributes to existing
literature firstly by testing the static and dynamic dual-beta CAPM and
Fama and French three factor models on individual stocks' daily and
monthly data. Secondly, different time intervals are investigated as the
market has different sentiments at different periods.
The study is organised as follows. The previous empirical findings
are briefly reviewed in Section two. Section three outlines the
empirical methodology. The results are presented in Section four,
followed by a concluding section.
2. REVIEW OF PREVIOUS EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
The standard CAPM has been extensively tested by many studies and
evidence shows that there is no significant relationship between average
returns and market beta. That beta does not sufficiently explain the
variation in expected return is strongly presented in the study by Fama
and French (1992) and (1993). Further this finding is confirmed by
Grinold (1993), Davis (1994), He and Ng (1994), Fama and French (1995),
(1996), (1998) and (2004) and Javid and Ahmad (2008) in addition to
numerous other studies. On the other hand there is considerable counter
evidence that supports beta to explain risk return relationship such as
Black (1993), Bhardwaj and Brooks (1993), Harris and Marston (1994),
Pettengill, Sundaram, and Muthar (1995), Kothari, et al. (1995) and
Clare, et al. (1998).
Fabbozi and Francis (1978) and Levy (1974) extend CAPM by computing separate betas for bull and bear markets to test for the instability of
beta and the validity of the return-beta relationship. Following Levy
(1974) several studies test for randomness of beta. Fabozzi and Francis
(1977) estimate and test the stability of betas over the bull and bear
markets but they find no evidence supporting beta instability. Chen
(1982) allows beta to be non-stationary in up and down markets and
conclude that under the condition of either constant or changing beta,
investors get premium for downside risk. Braun, et al. (1995) and Chou
and Engle (1999) investigate the effect of good and bad news called
leverage effects, as measured by positive and negative returns on beta.
Braun, et al. (1995) examine the variability of beta using exponential GARCH models allowing market volatility, portfolio-specific volatility
and beta to respond asymmetrically to positive and negative market and
portfolio returns using monthly data, however they do not uncover this
relationship. Chou and Engle (1999), on the other hand, use a two-beta
model with an EGARCH variance specification and daily stock returns of
individual firms and conclude that news asymmetrically affects the
betas. Woodward and Anderson (2001) find different betas for bull and
bear conditions using the Australian industry portfolios. Faff (2001)
apply multivariate one-step procedure to investigate CAPM in bull and
bear market conditions and find that there is minimal evidence of a
difference between up-market and down-market industry beta. However,
when the excess market return is negative (positive) he finds strong
evidence of a negative (positive) relationship between beta and return.
An alternative approach to capture market movements is through
various market volatility regimes. Galagedera and Faff (2003) examine
the validity of a conditional three-beta model in the low, flat and high
volatility regimes and find most of the asset portfolio betas not
significantly different in the three regimes. The Markov regime
switching model is used by Huang (2000) to investigate the instability
of beta and concludes that CAPM is stable in the low risk state and not
stable in the high risk state.
While investigating whether the variation in the stock returns
volatility is different in expansionary and in contractionary phases of
business cycles, Schwert (1989), Hamilton and Lin (1996) and McQueen and
Thorley (1993) show that conditional volatility in stock returns exists
which is counter-cyclical, and this behaviour is more pronounced in the
recession than in the expansion phases of the business cycle. Some
studies investigate the conditional CAPM and conclude that the
fluctuations and events that affect the market might change the leverage
of the firm and the variance of stock return and change the beta.
Bhaduri and Dural (2006) explore the stability of beta for India for
individual stocks and strongly validate that betas are stable in all
market conditions.
The poor empirical response of standard CAPM due to a number of
seemingly unexplained patterns in asset returns has resulted in using
sorted portfolios of stocks to represent the factors in a multifactor
model. The lack of any generally acceptable explanation and acceptance
and persistence of these patterns are the main reasons why they are
described as anomalies. Some of such puzzling anomalies are the small
firm effect, January effect, earning-to-price ratio, book to market
value and leverage etc. The most influential work in this regard is the
three-factor model of Fama and French (1993, 1995, 1996, 1997, 1998 and
2004), which adds two variables besides the market return, namely the
returns on SMB and the returns on HML stock. Fama and French (1993) show
that there is virtually no cross-sectional beta mean returns
relationship. They show that variation on average returns of 25 size and
book/market sorted portfolio can be explained by betas on the latter two
factors. Fama and French explain the real macroeconomic aggregates as
non-diversifiable risks that are provided by the returns of HML and SMB
portfolios. In a later study, Fama and French (1996) extend their
analysis and find that HML and SMB portfolios comfortably explain
strategies based on alternative price multiplier strategies based on
five-year sale growth and the tendency of five-year returns to reverse.
All these strategies are not explained by CAPM betas. Fama and French
(1996) conclude that many of the CAPM average returns anomalies are
related and can be captured by their three-factor model. However Chang,
Johnson, and Schill (2001) have observed that as higher-order systematic
co-moments are included in the cross-sectional regressions for portfolio
returns, the SMB and HML generally become insignificant. Therefore, they
argue that SMB and HML are good proxies for higher-order co-moments.
Ferson and Harvey (1999) claim that many multifactor model
specifications are rejected because they ignore conditioning
information. They have shown that identified predetermined conditional
variables have significant explanatory power for cross-sectional
variation in portfolio returns. They reject the three factor model
advocated by Fama and French (1993). They come to the conclusion that
these loadings are important over and above the three factors of Fama
and French and also the four factors of Elton, Gruber, and Blake (1995).
This study investigates the risk return relationship under
different market conditions for the Pakistani equity market. It is
believed that testing the dual-beta CAPM and dual-beta Fama and French
three-factor models in unconditional and conditional context would yield
some interesting results for the Pakistani equity market.
3. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND DATA
The analysis begins by estimating the model developed by Sharpe
(1964) and Lintner (1965) in which a relationship for expected return is
written as:
[r.sub.1] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.rm][r.sub.mt] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
[[epsilon].sub.t] ~(0, [h.sub.t]) ... (1)
Where [r.sub.t] is the excess return on asset i and [r.sub.mt] is
the excess return on market portfolio over the risk-free rate. The
[[alpha].sub.i] and [[beta].sub.rm] are regression coefficients and
[[beta].sub.rm] is the measure of risk or market sensitivity parameter defined [[beta].sub.rm] = cov([r.sub.t], [r.sub.mt])/var([r.sub.mt]).
The market beta is the slope coefficient of time series regression of
asset return on market portfolio given in the above Equation (1) and it
is used as explanatory variable in the following crosssection regression
equation estimated by the Generalised Least Square (GLS):
[r.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.0] + [[lambda].sub.rm][[beta].sub.rm] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] ... (2)
The coefficient [[lambda].sub.1] is the premium associated with
beta risk and an intercept term [[lambda].sub.0] has been added in the
equation. If [[lambda].sub.0] = 0 and, [[lambda].sub.rm]> 0 this
implies that Sharpe-Lintner CAPM holds.
The poor empirical response of standard CAPM [Javid and Abroad
(2008) and Iqbal and Brooks (2007)] motivated to extend the standard
CAPM by incorporating Fama and French (1993) three-factor model, in
order to examine whether size and book to market value can explain the
portion of expected returns, which cannot be explained by CAPM. (6) Fama
and French (1993) have incorporated two more risk factors: the
difference between the expected return on portfolios of stocks of small
and larger firms (SMB) and difference between the expected return on
portfolios of stocks that exhibit high and low book to market value HML.
Book to market value and firm size are risk proxies which means that a
firm with a high book to market equity ratio (a relatively low market
equity value) is likely to be a distressed firm and such firms have
sustained losses recently and consequently have a substantial risk of
bankruptcy (may have high leverage as well). Likewise, a small firm has
more chances of failure than a large firm. The two step procedure is
followed to estimate Fama and French three-factor model. The following
time series regression model is estimated in the first stage:
[r.sub.t] = [alpha] +[[beta].sub.rm][r.sub.mt]
+[[beta].sub.SMB][SMB.sub.t] + [[beta].sub.HML] [HML.sub.t]+
[[epsilon].sub.t] ... (3)
The risk premium associated with these risk factors are estimated
by cross-section regression Equation (3) that is estimated by GLS,
[r.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.0] + [[lambda].sub.rm][[beta].sub.rm] +
[[lambda].sub.SMB][[beta].sub.SMB] + [[lambda].sub.HML][[beta].sub.HML]
[[epsilon].sub.t] ... (4)
Where SMB (Small minus Big) represents the risk factor diverge of
the rate of returns with size effect; the HML (High minus Low)
represents the risk factor of return rate with ratio book to market
value effect. The [beta]s measure the sensitivity of each asset
associated to these variables. The [lambda]s are GLS coefficient which
indicate the extent to which the cross-section of asset returns can be
explained by these variables each year.
In this study the SMB portfolio is sorted by market value or size
following Fama and French (1996), and the mean market equity is
calculated which is the cutting point. All stocks are divided into two
parts; companies having market value of more than cutting point are big
company stocks (B) while companies having market value of less than
cutting point are small company stocks (S). It is believed that high and
low market conditions have asymmetric effect on beta. In addition to
bringing the book to market value the ratio of stocks is divided into
three groups according to book to market sorting: the first group with
30 percent of whole stocks has the highest book to market ratio called
high group (H), the second group with 40 percent of whole stocks has
medium book to market ratio called medium group (M) and the last group
with 30 percent of whole stocks has the lowest book to market ratio
called low group (L). In the next step, stocks are organised into six
groups according to the cross of stocks group in the first and second
step as S/L, S/M, S/H, B/L, B/M, B/H. The weight average monthly returns
of each group is calculated equally according to the method of Fama and
French (1996). (7)
The standard CAPM is extended by incorporating two betas, one for
high market and the other for low market conditions and thereafter it is
modified with Fama and French (1993) size and book to market risk
factors. Following Fabozzi and Francis (1977) the positive market return
is defined as up (bull) market while negative market return is defined
as down (bear) market. To capture the asymmetric effects of various
market conditions on beta, two betas are estimated for each stock
corresponding to bear and bull market conditions by introducing two
dummy variables [D.sub.H] and [D.sub.L] in the models (I) and (3). Dummy
variable [D.sub.h] is defined as 1 if market return is greater than zero
and 0 otherwise and [D.sub.L] is defined as1 if market return is
negative and zero otherwise. In order to examine the beta coefficient in
the bull and bear market conditions the Equation (I) is modified as:
[r.sub.t]=[alpha]+[[beta].sub.H][D.sub.H][r.sub.mt]+[[beta].sub.L][D.sub.L][r.sub.mt] +[[epsilon].sub.t] (5)
Equation (5) gives the dual-version of the standard model, where
two betas [[beta].sub.H] and [[beta].sub.L] are estimated for each stock
corresponding to positive and negative market conditions. The asymmetric
effects of various market conditions on beta is investigated by
estimating two betas for each stock corresponding to bear and bull
market conditions and to test the equality of the up and down market
betas on pair-wise basis by applying the Wald test. The cross sectional beta-return relationship using these two sets of beta estimates is as
follows:
[r.sub.1] = [[lambda].sub.0] +
[[lambda].sub.H][[beta].sub.H]+[[lambda].sub.L][[beta].sub.L]+[[epsilon].sub.l] (6)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
The [[lambda].sub.L] and [[lambda].sub.H] are risk premium
corresponding to bull and bear market conditions. According to Kim and
Zunwait (1979) and others as [[lambda].sub.L]>0 an investor would
like to receive a positive premium for accepting downside risk and as
[[lambda].sub.H]<0 an investor is willing to pay a positive premium
in the up market. The equality of these pricing parameters is tested by
applying the Wald test. The [[lambda].sub.SMB] and [[lambda].sub.HML]
are risk premium for size and book to market value risks respectively.
In models (3) and (4) is a dual-beta CAPM and Fama and French
three-factor model in which the asymmetric effect on expected return is
captured in unconditional context. It has been argued in the empirical
literature that as beta depends on good news and bad news defined as
negative and positive returns respectively, the volatility is also
affected by news asymmetry [Braun, et al.(1995)]. Nelson (1991) points
out that the changes in stock returns' volatility have negative
correlation with returns themselves. As a result, volatility increases
in response to bad news and falls in response to good news. (8) To
capture the asymmetric effect on conditional variance, the exponential
GARCH model suggested by Nelson (1991) is used. The main advantage of
this model is that the parameters are not restricted to be non-negative.
The following Equations (8) and (9) allow the asymmetric effect of
various market conditions on volatility of stock returns in conditional
CAPM-with EGARCH(1,1) model:
[r.sub.t] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.rm] [r.sub.mt] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] ... (8)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
The extended Equations (10), (11) and (12) are estimated to capture
the asymmetric effect of high and low market conditions on mean and
volatility of stock returns in dualbeta CAPM-with-EGARCH(1,1) model and
dual-beta Fama and French-with-EGARCH (1,1) model:
[r.sub.1] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.H][D.sub.H][r.sub.mt] +
[[beta].sub.L][D.sub.L][r.sub.mt] + [[epsilon].sub.t] ... (10)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (11)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
The conditional variance on the left hand side of Equations (9) and
(12) are in log form implying that the forecasts of conditional variance
are always positive. The news impact is asymmetric if [[gamma].sub.i]
[not equal to] 0 for at least one i in Equations (9) and (12).
Furthermore, if [[gamma].sub.i]< 0 it implies that the leverage
effect is present. To examine if betas of CAPM and Fama and French model
respond differently in two market conditions, the equality of high and
low market beta is tested in Equations (10) and (11), the equality of
[[theta].sub.L] and [[theta].sub.H], in volatility Equation (12) is
tested by the Wald test.
The risk premium for conditional CAPM-with-EGARCH(I,I) is estimated
by the cross section Equation (2) and extended cross-section regression
Equations (6) and (7) that estimate the risk premium for conditional
dual-beta CAPM and Fama and Frenchwith-EGARCH(I,1).
Data and Sample
The econometric analysis to be performed in the study is based on
the data of 50 firms listed on the Karachi Stock Market (KSE), the main
equity market in the country for the period January 1993 to December 2007. These 50 firms contributed 90 percent to the total turnover of KSE
in the year 2000. (9) In selecting the firms three criteria were used:
(1) companies have continuous listing on exchange for the entire period
of analysis; (2) almost all the important sectors are covered in data,
and (3) companies have high average turnover over the period of
analysis.
From 1993 to 2000, the daily data on closing price turnover and KSE
100 index are collected from the Ready Board Quotations issued by KSE at
the end of each trading day, which are also available in the files of
Security and Exchange Commission of Pakistan (SECP). For the period 2000
to 2007 the data are taken from KSE website. Information on dividends,
right issues and the bonus share book value of stocks are obtained from
the annual report of companies. Using this information, daily stock
returns for each stock are calculated. (10) The six months'
treasury-bill rate is used as risk free rate and KSE 100 Index as the
rate on market portfolio. The data on six-month treasury-bill rates are
taken from Monthly Bulletin of State Bank of Pakistan. The test of CAPM
and Fama French three-factor models is carried out on individual stocks.
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The empirical validity of unconditional and conditional dual-beta
CAPM is examined by using daily as well as monthly data of 50 individual
stocks traded at Karachi Stock Exchange during the period 1993 to 2007.
The extended dual-beta CAPM with Fama and French three-factor model
(1993) are tested in unconditional and conditional context using monthly
data. The tests of these models are carried out in the excess return
form and the risk factor in excess market return above the treasury-bill
rate. The sample period is divided into sub-periods of three years:
1993-1995, 1996-1998, 1999-2001, 2002-2004 and 2005-2007; two large sub
periods: 1993-2000 and 2001-2007; and for the whole sample period
1993-2007. (11)
First, it is established how well the extended version of CAPM with
dual beta (one beta for the bull market and one for the bear market)
explains the cross-section variation in the expected returns, which is
tested by using daily as well as monthly data of 50 individual stocks.
The dual version of CAPM is extended by including Fama and French (1993)
size and book to market variables to examine whether these variables can
explain the portion of expected returns, which cannot be explained by
CAPM. The two-step procedure proposed by Fama and McBeth (1973) is
followed, the betas or sensitivity of asset returns to market returns
(high beta and low market betas) and firm characteristic variables
(size, and book-to-market value), which capture anomalies are estimated
in the first stage using Generalised Method of Moment approach (GMM) and
the lagged market return and lagged asset returns are used as
instruments. In the second step, a cross section regression of actual
returns on betas is estimated for each month in the test period by
applying the Generalised Least Square (GLS). The standard deviations of
residuals from the beta estimation equation are used for the estimation
of error covariance matrix involved in the GLS estimation procedure.
(12) Finally, the parameter estimates are obtained for all the months in
the test periods by taking the average of the premium for the test
period. The mean risk premium so obtained is used to test, applying
t-statistics, the null hypothesis that the risk premium is equal to
zero. Since betas are generated in the first stage and then used as
explanatory variables in the second stage, the regressions involve
error-in-variables problem. Therefore the t-ratio for testing the
hypothesis that average premium is zero is calculated using the standard
deviation of the time series of estimated risk premium which captures
the month by month variation following Fama and McBeth (1973). The
alternative t-ratios are also calculated using a correction for errors
in beta suggested by Shanken (1992). (13) The [R.sup.2] is average of
month by month coefficient of determination.
In the first stage the sensitivity of the asset returns to market
return in high and low market conditions is estimated using the daily
data and monthly data in excess return form over risk free rate for the
period 1993 to 2007. In the second stage the risk premium is estimated
using high and low betas estimates from the first stage. The results
from the first stage, presented in Appendix Table A3, show for almost
all cases that bull and bear market betas are significantly different as
shown by the Wald test. However, for 33 stocks, beta estimates are
higher for positive market return than for negative market return, while
for other 16 stocks the reverse is true based on monthly data. Including
the Fama and French variables for 21 stocks, the greater beta estimate
is obtained for positive market while for the rest the opposite is found
to be true. These results are in accordance with the widely held view
that the stock beta is higher in the bull market than in the bear
market. It is also evident that the hypothesis of pair-wise equality of
up-and-down market betas is rejected. These results confirm the other
findings in the literature. Kim and Zunwait (1979), Davis and Desai
(1998), Faff (2001) Granger and Silvapulle (2002) find that in bull
market, higher beta stocks provide higher return than do the lower beta
stocks.
Table 1 presents the results of dual-beta CAPM based on daily and
monthly data. The results indicate that the risk premium for high market
conditions has the correct sign, negative in all sub-periods, but it is
significantly different from zero in the sub-period 2002-2004,
2005-2007, 2001-2007 and for the overall period 1993-2007. For low
market conditions, the risk premium is positive but significant in
1993-1995, 2002-2004, 2005-2007 and 1993-2007. In the other sub period
the risk premium corresponding to up market is negative and for down
market it is positive but not significantly different from zero. The
theoretical proposition is supported by these empirical findings in some
sub-periods that the risk premium is positive in the down market and
negative in the up market respectively. The hypothesis of pair-wise
equality of risk premium in bull and bear market is rejected. The
positive beta-return relationship in bear market is consistent with
other findings [Chan and Lakonishok (1993); Davis and Desai (1998); Faff
(2001); Granger and Silvapulle (2002)] which conclude that in bear
markets high beta stocks fare worse than do the low beta stocks. (14)
With the addition of Fama and French (1993) size and book to market
portfolios in the cross-section equation with high and low market betas,
the premium for market beta for bull remain almost the same. However,
for the bear market the risk premium becomes positive and significant
for all sub-periods and the overall sample period. The premium of size
of the firm is positive and significant except for period 1993-95. The
book to market value remains insignificant for only two sub-periods
2005-2007 and 1993-2000 while in the rest of the periods the premium for
book-to-market value is positive and significant. This suggests that the
risk factors associated with high and low market returns, size and style
of the firm are significantly rewarded in the market. The intercept
terms are significantly different from zero. These results are
consistent with other findings in literature, such as the one for the UK
market by Clare, Priestly, and Thomas (1998) and for Pakistan by Iqbal
and Brooks (2007).
The conditional version of dual beta CAPM with EGARCH specification
is tested and the results are presented in Table 3. The betas acquired
from dual beta CAPM-with-EGARCH model are used to test the conditional
relationship between beta and returns and the results of time series
betas based on monthly data estimates are reported in Appendix Table A4.
The results indicate a positive and significant relation between stock
returns and market returns as shown by market [beta].
The asymmetric effect of positive and negative shock is measured by
[[gamma].sub.1]. If the coefficient is not equal to zero it would imply
that the impact of negative and positive shocks is asymmetric. This
coefficient is significant for 38 stocks with daily data, and for 24
stocks with monthly data. It is confirmed that good and bad news have
asymmetric effect on volatility. Out of 38 significant parameters, 24
are negative (out of 24 cases 19 are negative with monthly data). This
implies that volatility tends to fall in more cases when return
surprises are negative, that is, when they come as bad news. For the
remaining stocks [[gamma].sub.t], is positive indicating that negative
shocks cause more volatility than positive shocks. Ahmad and Qasim
(2004) come up with the same conclusion using sector indices for the
Pakistani market. The results of conditional CAPM and conditional Fama
and French three-factor model extended for two-beta CAPM equation as the
mean equation along with EGARCH specification are reported in the
Appendix Table A5 and A6. Two market conditions are allowed to affect
the conditional mean and variance of market return through the nonlinear threshold regime switching model. The results show that there is
statistically significant difference in beta in high and low market
conditions which suggests that the betas are significantly affected by
high and low market conditions. In the variance equation the additional
effect of negative effect on variance compared to positive effect is
measured by [[gamma].sub.1]. The results reveal that this coefficient is
significant in 32 cases based on CAPM model and 36 cases based on Fama
and French model. Out of 32 significant parameters, 16 are negative and
out of 36 cases 25 are negative, which implies that variance tends to
fall when return surprises are negative. In other words negative shocks
cause the same volatility as the positive shocks. The coefficient for
remaining cases is positive, indicating that in these firms negative
shock causes more change in variance than positive shocks. The magnitude
of coefficients however, shows that the incidence of asymmetry though
significant is not very large. These results provide support for the
theoretical proposition that negative shocks cause greater volatility
than positive shocks. The parameters of sensitivity to firm attribute
suggested by Fama and French (size, and book-to-market value), that is
[[beta].sub.SMB] and [[beta].sub.HML] reported in Table A6 have shown a
mixed relationship. The effect of increase in size of the firm and
book-to-market value on asset return is not consistent as indicated by
the estimated values of [[beta].sub.SMB] and [[beta].sub.HML], but for
most of the firms it is positive, while only for a few firms these
factor loadings are negative.
After estimating two conditional betas for each stock corresponding
to bull and bear market conditions, using the dual-beta-with-EGARCH
models, the cross-section regressions are estimated with these betas to
estimate the premium. The results of testing the conditional single
factor CAPM with EGARCH specification are given in Table 3. The results
show that there is positive and significant compensation on an average
to bear conditional market risk in the period 1999-2001, 2002-2004,
1993-2000, 2001-2007 and in overall sample period 1993-2007. The
intercept terms [[lambda].sub.0] are not significantly different from
zero in most of the sub-periods. These results support the
Sharpe-Lintner model when symmetry of beta is taken into account in the
model. The results of cross-sectional regression using two-betas with
Fama and French (1993) variables are reported in Table 4. The risk
premium for high market conditions has the correct sign, negative in all
sub-periods and is significantly different from zero in sub-periods
1993-1995, 1996-1998, 1999-2001, 2005-2007, 2001-2007 and the overall
period 1993-2007. For low market conditions the risk premium is positive
but significant in 1993-1995 and 1999-2001, 2005-2007, 2001-2007 and the
overall period 1993-2007. In the other sub period the risk premium
corresponding to up market is negative and for down market it is
positive which supports the theoretical proposition and empirical
findings. These results are consistent with the findings of Davis and
Desai (1998) which show that if the relationship beta and returns are
positive in bull market and bear market combined, it does not show up in
aggregate unless the positive relationship is strong.
The results of dual-beta Fama and French model with EGARCH (1,1)
are presented in Table 4. The risk premium for high market conditions is
negative in all sub-periods and for down market it is positive which
supports the theoretical proposition and empirical findings. When the
dual beta CAPM is augmented by the size and style variables, the market
risk premium for both high and low become positive and negative
respectively for almost all sub-periods and overall sample period. The
book-to-market value is positively and significantly priced except the
sub-period 2005-2007. The premium of size of the firm is positive for
1993-95, 1996-98, 2002-04, 2001-2007 and 1993-2007. These results
indicate that the conditional Fama and French (1993) model shows
improvement in explaining the cross-section variation in the expected
returns. These results are consistent with the ones obtained in a series
of papers for US market by Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995, 1997,
2004), which suggest that these variables have some role in explaining
cross-section of expected return and these variables outperform the
market returns. Similarly Chan, Hamao, and Lakonishol (1991) find a
strong relationship between book-to-market value and average return in
Japanese market, while Capual, Rowley, and Sharpe (1993) observe a
similar effect that is book-to-market value effect in four European
stock markets. Likewise Fama and French (1998) find that the price
ratios produce the same results for twelve major emerging markets.
Grundy and Malkiel (1996) and Davis and Dasai (1998), Kim and Zumwait
(1979) document that downside risk may be a more appropriate measure of
portfolio risk than the conventional single beta. Pettengill, et al.
(1995) using the dual-beta framework find consistent and significant
relationship between beta and return and positive payment for beta risk.
For Australian resource and industrial sector, Faff (2001) finds
contrary evidence that success of the model does not depend on a beta
instability argument. Granger and Silvapulle (2003) find that for bull,
bear and usual market conditions the risk premium is positive and
significant for usual market condition while for extreme market
conditions these are insignificant. Davis and Desai (1998) comparing the
analysis of beta-return and return-firm size relationship across bull,
bear and flat market conditions find that beta is a superior measure of
down-market risk, while firm size is positive in flat market. Iqbal and
Brooks (2007) also confirm that Fama and French three-factor model
performs better than the higher moments CAPM model.
To sum up, it can be argued that the overall positive risk-return
relationship could occur if the relationship is stronger in bear market
than in bull market. However this is not the case in Pakistan where the
relationship is marginally stronger in bull market than in the bear
market. (15) Davis and Desai (1998) find that if the relationship beta
and return is positive in bull market and bear market combined, it does
not show up in aggregate like Fama and French (1992, 1993) because the
beta-return relationship in the flat market is opposite to extreme
market conditions: high beta stocks have lower return than low beta
stocks. Based on these results one can say the dual-beta Fama and French
three factor model performed very well in the conditional context
compared to dual-beta conditional CAPM model.
5. CONCLUSION
The beta dynamics is investigated by asymmetric response of beta to
bullish and bearish market environment applying the dual beta CAPM and
dual beta Fama and French three factor model on the 50 stocks traded in
Karachi Stock Exchange during 1993-2007. There is evidence of beta
instability when its randomness is investigated. Comparing it in the
high and low market conditions the results show that beta is higher in
most of the cases in the bullish market than in the bearish market.
These results are in accordance with the widely held view that betas
increase (decrease) when the market is bullish (bearish). The Wald test
pair-wise equality of up and down market betas is rejected. These
findings suggest that there is difference in up and down market beta
across stocks. These findings show that risk premium corresponding to up
market is negative and the beta pricing parameter for down market is
positive in all cases. However, these pricing parameters are significant
in a few sub-periods. The dual beta CAPM is extended with Fama and
French (1993) variables, size and book-to-market value, in unconditional
and conditional settings. The conditional Fama and French (1993) model
shows improvement in explaining the cross-section variation in the
expected returns. The findings however suggest that investors receive a
positive premium for accepting down-side risk, while a negative premium
is associated with up-market beta, which is in accordance with
theoretical proposition. It is observed that the dynamic size and style
coefficient explains the cross-section of expected returns in almost all
sub-periods and in the overall sample period. The results suggest that
in case of Pakistani market when news asymmetry is taken into account to
explain the relationship in terms of beta and returns, the conditional
Fama and French three factor model performs better than the conditional
CAPM for comparing unconditional Fama and French three factor model and
unconditional dual-beta CAPM.
Appendices
Appendix Table A1
List of Companies Included in the Sample
Name of Company Symbol Sector
AI-Abbas Sugar AABS Sugar and Allied
Askari Commercial Bank ACBL Insurance and Finance
AI-Ghazi Tractors AGTL Auto and Allied
Adamjee Insurance Company AICL Insurance
Ansari Sugar ANSS Sugar and Allied
Askari Leasing ASKL Leasing Company
Bal Wheels BWHL Auto and Allied
Cherat Cement CHCC Cement
Crescent Textile Mills CRTM Textile Composite
Crescent Steel CSAP Engineering
Comm. Union Life Assurance CULA Insurance and Finance
Dadabhoy Cement DBYC Cement
Dhan Fibres DHAN Synthetic and Rayon
Dewan Salman Fibre DSFL Synthetic and Rayon
Dewan Textile DWTM Textile Composite
Engro Chemical Pakistan ENGRO Chemicals and Pharmaceuticals
Faisal Spinning. FASM Textile Spinning
FFCL Jordan FFCJ Chemicals and Pharmaceuticals
Fauji Fertiliser FFCL Fertiliser
Fateh Textile FTHM Textile Composite
General Tyre and Rubber Co. GTYR Auto and Allied
Gul Ahmed Textile CULT Textile Composite
Habib Arkady Sugar HAAL Sugar and Allied
Hub Power Co. HUBC Power Generation & Distribution
I.C.I. Pak ICI Chemicals and Pharmaceuticals
Indus Motors INDU Auto and Allied
J.D.W. Sugar JDWS Sugar and Allied
Japan Power JPPO Power Generation & Distribution
Karachi Electric Supply Co. KESC Power Generation & Distribution
Lever Brothers Pakistan LEVER Food and Allied
Lucky Cement LUCK Cement
Muslim Commercial Bank MCB Commercial Banks
Maple Leaf Cement MPLC Cement
National Refinery NATR Fuel and Energy
Nestle Milk Pak Ltd NESTLE Food and Allied
Packages Ltd. PACK Paper and Board
Pak Electron PAEL Cables and Electric Goods
Pakistan Tobacco Company PAKT Tobacco
Pakland Cement PKCL Cement
Pakistan State Oil Company. PSOC Fuel and Energy
PTCL (A) PTC Fuel and Energy
Southern Electric SELF Cables and Electric Goods
ICP SEMF Modarba SEMF Modarba
Sitara Chemical SITC Chemicals and Pharmaceuticals
Sui Southern Gas Company SNGC Fuel and Energy
Sui Northern Gas Company SSGC Fuel and Energy
Tri-Star Polyester Ltd TSPI Synthetic and Rayon
Tri-Star Shipping Lines TSSL Transport and Communication
Unicap Modarba UNIM Modarba
Table A2
Summary Statistics of Daily Stock Returns
No.
Company of Obs. Mean St. Dev.
AABS 1990 0..13 ** 3.57 *
ACBL 2697 0.10 *** 2.81 *
AGTL 2094 0.21 * 3.15 *
AICL 2681 0.08 3.54 *
ANSS 1544 0.00 7.75 *
ASKL 2426 0.09 3.46 *
BWHL 1644 -0.01 4.61 *
CHCC 2491 0.07 3.42 *
CRTM 2149 0.07 4.36 *
CSAP 1829 0.12 4.44 *
CULA 1664 0.06 4.31 *
DBYC 2166 0.00 6.57 *
DHAN 1489 -0.05 4.34 *
DSFL 2707 0.02 3.25 *
DWTM 385 -0.02 4.90 *
ENGRO 2660 0.08 2.63 *
FASM 1405 0.18 2.96 *
FFCJ 2080 0.03 3.26 *
FFCL 2704 0.08 2.29 *
FTHM 239 0.50 8.33 *
GTYR 2192 0.08 3.51 *
GULT 587 0.26 5.96 *
HAAL 1863 0.20 ** 3.81 *
HUBC 2380 0.08 3.13 *
ICI 2667 0.03 2.90 *
INDU 2659 0.06 3.13 *
JDWS 1716 0.14 5.74 *
JPPO 1944 -0.02 4.10 *
KESC 2702 -0.02 3.97 *
LEVER 2429 0.06 2.35 *
LUCK 2310 0.04 4.13 *
MCB 2714 0.08 3.20 *
MPLC 2430 -0.04 4.18 *
NATR 2391 0.09 3.19 *
NESTLE 986 0.26 ** 4.18 *
PACK 1856 0.09 3.20 *
PAEL 1933 0.02 5.79 *
PAKT 1862 0.01 3.97 *
PKCL 1776 0.02 4.53 *
PSOC 2713 0.11 *** 2.71 *
PTC 2402 0.03 2.80 *
SELP 2024 0.01 3.92 *
SEMF 2598 0.10 3.14 ***
SITC 1807 0.09 3.24 *
SNGP 2711 0.08 3.13 *
SSGC 2706 0.05 3.25 *
TSPI 1833 -0.05 11.32 *
TSSL 1304 -0.11 8.79 *
UNIM 1999 -0.04 10.35 *
Excess
Company Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera
AABS 0.65 * 4.54 * 1849.67 *
ACBL -0.02 8.62 * 8342.60 *
AGTL 0.40 11.48 * 11556.03 *
AICL 0.02 8.25 * 7604.82 *
ANSS -0.61 11.34 * 8364.52 *
ASKL 0.22 8.32 * 7016.92 *
BWHL 0.31 7.29 * 3665.67 *
CHCC 0.36 ** 4.36 * 2023.86 *
CRTM 0.20 11.14 * 11127.45 *
CSAP 0.49 12.77 * 12504.90 *
CULA 0.34 6.07 * 2528.65 *
DBYC 0.45 16.36 * 24229.89 *
DHAN 1.37 * 9.23 * 5749.70 *
DSFL 0.48 ** 4.85 * 2753.04 *
DWTM 0.68 11.43 * 2125.84
ENGRO 0.11 8.55 * 8107.69 *
FASM -1.28 23.45 * 32574.22 *
FFCJ 0.62 ** 7.23 * 4656.48 *
FFCL -0.24 5.54 * 3479.76 *
FTHM 0.39 5.63 * 321.46 *
GTYR 1.40 * 13.89 * 18339.20 *
GULT 0.43 * 10.28 * 2601.98 *
HAAL 0.45 * 3.77 * 1167.39 *
HUBC -0.81 17.86 ** 31877.97 *
ICI 0.34 4.32 * 2128.42 *
INDU 0.59 *** 4.41 * 2307.69 *
JDWS 0.25 * 8.01 * 4607.77 *
JPPO 0.94 * 8.13 * 5637.21 *
KESC 0.69 * 6.52 * 5002.83 *
LEVER 0.51 ** 8.54 * 7491.23 *
LUCK 0.47 ** 6.31 * 3914.20 *
MCB -0.07 4.76 * 2567.14 *
MPLC 0.54 3.75 * 1540.80 *
NATR 0.47 *** 6.14 * 3850.41 *
NESTLE 0.14 7.44 * 2279.29 *
PACK -0.43 10.24 * 8169.93 *
PAEL 0.42 19.20 * 29760.13 *
PAKT -0.02 9.26 * 6654.47 *
PKCL 0.21 5.57 * 2307.90 *
PSOC -0.28 11.19 ** 14189.96 *
PTC 0.08 7.35 * 5415.82 *
SELP -0.47 43.68 * 161003.70 *
SEMF 0.91 *** 9.67 *** 10486.12 *
SITC 0.38 11.33 * 9708.85 *
SNGP 0.29 4.59 * 2418.05 *
SSGC 0.56 10.77 * 13220.94 *
TSPI 0.12 7.71 * 4542.77 *
TSSL -0.34 18.43 * 18478.51
UNIM 0.54 16.61 * 23068.60 *
Note: * Indicates significant at 1 percent, ** at 5 percent
and *** is at 10 percent.
Table A3
Market Sensitivity for High and Low Market
[H.sub.0]:
[[beta] [[beta] [[beta].sub.H]=
.sub.H] .sub.L] [[beta].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
AABS 0.35 * 38 * 83 * 03
ACBL 0.96 * 0.99 * 0.51 * 0.35
AGTL 0.54 * 0.37 * 0.11 * 0.06
AICL 0.96 * 0.99 * 0.51 * 0.35
ANSS 0.41 ** 0.79 * 0.36 * 0.01
ASKL 0.76 * 0.78* 0.90 * 0.25
BWHL 0.50 * 0.90 * 0.06 *** 0.26
CHCC 0.87 * 0.84 * 0.76 * 0.17
CRTM 0.63 * 1.00 * 0.02 0.19
CSAP 0.75 * 0.68 * 0.74 * 0.26
CULA 0.66 * 0.63 * 0.89 * 0.27
DBYC 0.96 * 1.51 * 0.03 0.19
DHAN 0.95 * 0.69 * 0.10 * 0.23
DSFL 1.21 * 1.18 * 0.72 * 0.38
DWTM 0.31 0.70 * 0.47 * 0.02
ENGR 0.81 * 0.91 * 0.19 * 0.27
FASM 0.31 ** 0.73 * 0.16 * 0.22
FFCJ 1.16 * 1.14 * 0.76 * 0.4
FFCL 0.88 * 0.85 * 0.63 * 0.41
GTYR 0.51 * 0.70 * 0.10 * 0.29
GULT 0.23 0.38 *** 0.731 0.01
HAAL 0.30 * 0.61 * 0.02 0.05
HUBC 1.21 * 1.37 * 0.01 0.54
ICI 1.18 * 1.09 * 0.26 * 0.41
ICPS 1.09 * 0.93 * 0.10 * 0.3
INDU 0.803 * 0.74 * 0.49 * 0.27
JDWS 0.46 * 0.17 ** 0.23 * 0.21
JPPO 1.43 * 1.24 * 0.11 * 0.35
KESC 1.51 * 133 * 0.06 ** 0.37
LEVER 0.48 * 0.50 * 0.78 * 0.23
LUCK 1.19 * 1.21 * 0.87 * 0.22
MCB 1.14 * 1.21 * 0.38 * 0.39
MPLC 1.29 * 1.14 * 0.21 * 0.25
NATR 0.80 * 0.78 * 0.85 * 0.27
NESTE 0.47 * 0.62 * 0.53 * 0.24
PACK 0.49 * 0.55 * 0.61 * 0.27
PAEL 0.93 * 0.79 * 0.53 * 0.26
PAKT 0.46 * 0.85 * 0.03 0.26
PKCL 0.81 * 0.90 * 0.577 * 0.1
PTC 1.09 * 1.14 * 0.41 * 0.49
PSO 1.40 * 1.30 * 0.06 ** 0.72
SELP 1.28 * 1.28 * 0.95 * 0.35
SITC 0.57 * 0.39 * 0.16 ** 0.16
SNGP 1.23 * 1.27 0.611 * 0.46
SSGC 1.23 * 1.16 * 0.41 * 0.39
TSPI 0.4 1.03 * 0.20 * 0.21
TSSI 0.22 0.67 * 0.28 * 0.21
UNIM 0.78 * 1.04 * 0.52 * 0.22
[H.sub.0]:
[[beta] [[beta] [[beta].sub.H]=
.sup.H] .sup.L] [[beta].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
AABS 0-31 ** 0.75 0.75 0.61
ACBL 1.24 * 0.99 * 0.60 * 0.59
AGTL 0.94 * 0.51 * 0.03 0.64
AICL 1.24 * 0.99 * 0.60 * 0.64
ANSS 1.26 * 0.47 * 0.36 * 0.63
ASKL 1.15 * 0.93 * 0.95 * 0.67
BWHL 0.43 0.23 ** 0.71 * 0.61
CHCC 1.26 * 0.97 * 0.19 ** 0.59
CRTM 1.56 * 0.96 * 0.05 0.62
CSAP 0.69 * 0.66 * 0.001 0.63
CULA 1.25 * 0.38 * 0.93 * 0.63
DBYC 1.93 * 1.18 * 0.18 ** 0.68
DHAN 0.70 * 0.90 * 0.49 * 0.62
DSFL 1.40 * 1.33 * 0.15 ** 0.66
DWTM 0.02 0.16 * 0.60 *** 0.65
ENGR 0.57 * 0.78 * 0.91 * 0.66
FASM 1.00 * 0.63 * 0.47 * 0.66
FFCJ 0.07 -0.03 0.79 * 0.58
FFCL 0.73 * 0.82 * 0.67 * 0.62
GTYR 0.66 ** 0.71 * 0.89 * 0.67
GULT -0.25 0.14 0.30 * 0.62
HAAL 0.73 * 0.56 * 0.61 * 0.67
HUBC 0.63 * 1.32 * 0.01 0.59
ICI 0.91 * 1.38 * 0.08 ** 0.62
ICPS 1.47 * 1.05 * 0.143 ** 0.59
INDU 1.27 * 0.89 * 0.19 ** 0.62
JDWS 0.92 0.41 * 0.26 * 0.67
JPPO 1.71 * 0.89 * 0.01 0.59
KESC 1.53 * 1.63 * 0.75 * 0.64
LEVER 0.29 ** 0.55 * 0.20 * 0.63
LUCK 1.42 * 1.13 * 0.34 * 0.59
MCB 1.39 * 1.23 * 0.51 * 0.65
MPLC 1.74 * 1.15 * 0.11 * 0.64
NATR 1.05 * 0.83 * 0.47 * 0.65
NESTE -0.09 -0.02 0.79 * 0.62
PACK 0.64 * 0.68 0.86 * 0.65
PAEL 1.99 * 0.68 * 0.04 0.63
PAKT 1.61 * 0.51 * 0.02 0.62
PKCL 0.17 0.84 * 0.18 ** 0.64
PTC 0.85 * 1.38 * 0.02 0.71
PSO 0.74 * 1.13 * 0.03 0.69
SELP 0.87 * 0.91 * 0.92 * 0.63
SITC 0.76 * 0.54 * 0.34 * 0.63
SNGP 1.42 * 1.36 * 0.07 ** 0.71
SSGC 1.42 * 1.23 * 0.37 * 0.71
TSPI 1.23 * 0.75 * 0.46 * 0.62
TSSI 0.35 0.39 * 0.94 * 0.64
UNIM 1.11 * 0.81 * 0.66 * 0.69
Note: * Indicates significant at I percent, ** at 5 percent and
*** is at 10 percent.
Table A4
CAPM-with EGARCH Specification Based on Monthly Data
[alpha] [beta] [[gamma].sub.0] [delta]
AABS 0.02 * 0.22 * -2.76 * -0.35 **
ACBL 0.02 * 1.03 * -0.33 0.07
AGTL 0.02 * 0.72 * -8.47 * 0.41 *
AICL 0.03 * 1.42 * -2.50 ** 0.54 *
ANSS -0.01 0.39 * -1.82 * 0.54 *
ASKL 0.01 0.91 * -5.09 ** 0.49 **
BWHL -0.01 0.19 ** -0.56 * 0.21 *
CHCC 0.02 * 0.98 * -0.89 * 0.58 *
CRTM 0.01 0.96 * -5.09 0.27
CSAP 0.02 *** 0.60 * -7.59 * -0.14
CULA 0.02 0.001 -0.35 * 0.17 *
DBYC 0.01 1.44 * 0.05 -0.13 *
DHAN -0.01 0.93 * -3.60 ** -0.27 **
DSFL 0.01 1.37 * -4.93 *** 0.20
DWTM 0.03 0.001 -1.98 * 0.52 *
ENGRO 0.01 *** 0.79 * -5.30 0.18
FASM 0.01 0.62 * -0.09 * -0.09 *
FFCJ 0.001 0.004 -1.12 * 0.50 *
FFCL 0.01 ** 0.75 * -0.67 0.19 **
GTYR 0.02 * 0.55 * -7.17 * 1.03 *
GULT 0.01 0.14 * -1.50 * 0.70 *
HAAL 0.01 0.49 * -1.11 * 0.41 *
HUBC 0.02 * 1.11 * -7.57 * 0.26
ICI 0.002 1.29 * -3.79 ** 0.29
ICPSEMF 0.02 * 1.31 * -3.07 * 0.80 *
INDU 0.01 0.88 * -6.07 * 0.003
JDWS 0.01 0.27 * -5.83 * 0.62 *
JPPO 0.01 0.91 * -1.51 * 0.56 *
KESC 0.01 1.57 * -0.79 0.17 **
LEVER 0.01 0.47 * -2.46 * 0.74 *
LUCK 0.01 1.18 * -6.71 * 0.18
MCB 0.01 ** 1.23 * -8.42 * 0.18
MPLC 0.002 1.26 * -3.98 * 0.54 **
NATR 0.02 1.05 * -2.77 * 0.35 **
NESTLE 0.03 0.002 -0.773 0.513
PACK 0.01 0.67 * -7.63 * 0.40 *
PAEL -0.01 0.81 * -3.87 * 0.19 **
PAKT 0.01 0.701 -1.421 0.531
PKCL 0.00 0.78 * -5.78 * 0.18
PSO 0.03 * 1.22 * -3.46 ** 0.12
PTC 0.01 1.19 * -2.21 * 0.81 *
SELP 0.02 * 0.003 -0.01 -0.34 *
SITC 0.02 0.67 * -0.03 -0.18 *
SNGP 0.01 * 1.25 * -9.58 * 0.28 *
SSGC 0.01 *** 1.28 * -0.78 * 0.21 *
TSPI -0.02 0.95 * -1.37 * 0.49 *
TSSI -0.03 * 0.58 * 0.08 -0.16 *
UNIM 0.01 0.73 * -0.60 0.04
[[gamma].sub.i] [[mu].sub.i] [R.sup.2]
AABS 0.55 * 0.32 * 0.57
ACBL -0.12 * 0.94 * 0.54
AGTL -0.05 ** -0.92 ** 0.62
AICL -0.14 0.46 *** 0.71
ANSS 0.17 *** 0.63 * 0.69
ASKL -0.11 -0.11 0.67
BWHL -0.14 ** 0.89 * 0.63
CHCC -0.22 *** -0.36 *** 0.69
CRTM 0.11 -0.15 0.70
CSAP -0.16 *** -0.80 * 0.73
CULA 0.07 0.94 * 0.71
DBYC -0.04 0.99 * 0.66
DHAN 0.12 0.08 0.62
DSFL 0.05 -0.11 0.66
DWTM -0.09 0.70 * 0.70
ENGRO -0.10 -0.13 0.75
FASM -0.11 * 0.96 0.65
FFCJ -0.10 0.82 * 0.65
FFCL -0.10 ** 0.90 ** 0.62
GTYR -0.08 -0.58 * 0.66
GULT -0.20 *** 0.75 * 0.62
HAAL 0.08 0.81 * 0.76
HUBC -0.46 * -0.55 * 0.56
ICI -0.08 0.23 0.61
ICPSEMF -0.34 * 0.47 * 0.67
INDU 0.34 * -0.34 0.71
JDWS 0.16 *** -0.47 * 0.71
JPPO 0.01 0.74 * 0.65
KESC -0.12 ** 0.85 * 0.64
LEVER -0.46 * 0.64 * 0.69
LUCK 0.05 -0.50 0.69
MCB 0.24 * -0.69 * 0.65
MPLC 0.11 0.10 0.63
NATR -0.10 0.43 ** 0.63
NESTLE -0.243 0.893 0.69
PACK -0.31 * -0.47 * 0.65
PAEL -0.24 * -0.03 0.68
PAKT 0.261 0.751 0.67
PKCL -0.03 -0.67 *** 0.63
PSO -0.34 * 0.33 0.68
PTC 0.10 0.71 * 0.68
SELP -0.68* 0.95 * 0.64
SITC -0.26 * 0.96 * 0.67
SNGP 0.17 * -0.87 * 0.70
SSGC 0.07 0.88 * 0.70
TSPI 0.08 0.66 * 0.88
TSSI -0.03 0.98 * 0.73
UNIM 0.14 ** 0.79 * 0.88
Note: * Indicates significant at 1 percent, ** at 5 percent and
*** is at 10 percent.
Table A5
CAPM in Bull and Bear Market with EGARCH Specification
Based on Monthly Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[beta] [[beta] [[beta].sub.H]=
.sub.H] .sub.L] [[beta].sub.L] [h.sub.0]
AABS 0.48 * 0.31 * 0.11 * -4.49 *
ACBL 0.93 * 0.91 * 0.95 * -2.47 *
AGTL 0.42 * 0.49 * 0.49 * -2.71 *
AICL 0.82 * 1.09 * 0.001 -0.40 *
ANSS 0.68 * 0.70 * 0.92 * -0.18 *
ASKL 0.65 * 0.64 * 0.95 * -2.78 *
BWHL 0.45 * 0.76 * 0.11 * -0.26 *
CHCC 0.95 * 0.82 * 0.16 * -1.35 *
CRTM 0.78 * 0.89 * 0.47 * -0.72 *
CSAP 0.72 * 0.50 * 0.10 * -0.55 *
CULA 0.001 0.07 * 0.04 -0.50 *
DBYC 1.41 * 1.24 * 0.38 * -1.02 *
DHAN 1.03 * 0.78 * 0.11 * -1.43 *
DSFL 1.19 * 1.34 * 0.03 -1.01 *
DWTM 0.43 0.44 * 0.99 * -0.55 *
ENGR 0.96 * 0.88 * 0.15 * -4.80 *
FASM 0.28 * 0.77 * 0.03 -0.96 *
FFCJ 1.17 * 1.04 * 0.13 * -2.29 *
FFCL 0.86 * 0.83 * 0.57 * -1.45 *
GTYR 0.58 * 0.71 * 0.19 * -1.61 *
GULT 0.52 * 0.72 * 0.52 * -0.38 *
HAAL 0.45 * 0.43 * 0.92 * -1.37 *
HUBC 1.17 * 1.07 * 0.070 * -1.42 *
ICI 1.14 * 1.10 * 0.61 * -1.95 *
ICPS 1.11 * 1.02 * 0.17 * -2.33 *
INDU 0.86 * 0.78 * 0.38 * -0.70 *
JDWS 0.41 * 0.25 * 0.34 * -0.81 *
JPPO 1.18 * 1.28 * 0.36 * -1.50 *
KESC 1.46 * 1.34 * 0.23 * -1.24 *
LEVE 0.41 * 0.38 * 0.65 * -1.71 *
LUCK 1.17 * 1.48 * 0.003 -0.64 *
MCB 1.13 * 1.18 * 053 * -1.97 *
MPLC 1.38 * 1.24 * 0.26 * -1.86 *
NATR 0.86 * 0.74 * 0.22 * -1.18 *
NESTE 0.33 * 0.18 * 0.27 * -0.61 *
PACK 0.44 * 0.47 * 0.727 * -0.72 *
PAEL 0.68 * 0.70 * 0.82 * -0.47 *
PAKT 0.47 * 0.65 * 0.18 * -0.52 *
PKCL 0.89 * 0.64 * 0.10 * -0.91 *
PTC 1.29 * 1.23 * 0.15 * -1.58 *
SELP 1.03 * 1.16 * 0.12 -0.51 *
SITC 0.42 * 0.44 * 0.89 * -0.48 *
SNGP 1.24 * 1.27 * 0.62 * -1.93 *
SSGC 1.22 * 1ll * 0.05 -1.81 *
TSPI 1.03 * 1.61 * 0.09 ** -0.38 *
TSSI 0.75 * 0.78 * 0.94 * -0.04 *
UNIM 1.55 * 1.23 * 0.28 -0.11 *
[[delta] [[sigma [[mu [[theta]
.sub.i] .sub.i] .sub.i] .sub.H]
AABS 0.51 * 0.01 0.39 2.17 ^
ACBL 0.41 * -0.14 0.73 * 1.28 *
AGTL 0.55 * 0.07 * 0.69 * 1.42 *
AICL 0.28 * -0.03 * 0.97 * -0.26 *
ANSS 0.15 * -0.04 * 0.99 * 2.98 *
ASKL 0.53 * 0.01 0.67 * 1.46 *
BWHL 0.18 * -0.03 * 0.98 * 1.37 *
CHCC 0.34 * 0.02 0.85 * 1.79 *
CRTM 0.21 * 0.01 0.92 * 1.51 *
CSAP 0.31 * -0.05 * 0.95 * 2.01 *
CULA 0.41 * -0.03 * 0.97 * 0.58 *
DBYC 0.37 * -0.05 * 0.88 * 2.76 *
DHAN 0.31 * 0.03 * 0.83 * 3.59 *
DSFL 0.28 * 0.05 * 0.90 * 1.47
DWTM 0.09 * 0.15 * 0.94 * 7.50 *
ENGR 0.91 * 0.01 0.45 * 3.09 *
FASM 0.43 * 0.01 0.90 * 1.61 *
FFCJ 0.41 * -0.06 * 0.74 * 1.91 *
FFCL 0.19 * 0.01 0.84 * 1.05 *
GTYR 0.43 * 0.05 * 0.82 * 2.16 *
GULT 0.24 * 0.07 * 0.96 * 1.00 *
HAAL 0.32 * 0.01 0.83 * -0.24
HUBC 0.34 * -0.03 * 0.86 * 1.97 *
ICI 0.35 * -0.10 * 0.78 * 2
ICPS 0.49 * -0.05 * 0.74 * 2.81 *
INDU 0.17 * 0.02 * 0.92 * 1.15
JDWS 0.38 * 0.06 * 0.91 * 1.57 *
JPPO 0.33 * 0.02 0.82 * 1.92 *
KESC 0.25 * -0.01 0.86 * 2.18 *
LEVE 0.41 * -0.04 * 0.82 * 1.82
LUCK 0.26 * -0.04 * 0.94 * 0.49 *
MC13 0.29 * 0.07 * 0.77 * 1.02 *
MPLC 0.26 * 0.04 0.76 * 2.49 *
NATR 0.27 * 0.03 * 0.87 * 2.34 *
NESTE 0.38 * 0.01 0.95 * 0.19
PACK 0.27 * -0.01 0.93 * 0.44 *
PAEL 0.39 * -0.06 * 0.97 * 0.85 *
PAKT 0.29 * 0.01 0.96 * 0.33
PKCL 0.38 * -0.04 * 0.91 * 1.23 *
PTC 0.40 * 0.03 * 0.86 * 1.93 *
SELP 0.19 * -0.07 * 0.95 * 0.50 *
SITC 0.32 * 0.01 0.96 * 0.59
SNGP 0.32 * 0.02 * 0.79 * 2.41 *
SSGC 0.36 * -0.02 * 0.80 * 2.87
TSPI 0.25 * -0.06 * 0.96 * 1.07 *
TSSI 0.02 * -0.05 * 0.99 * 1.23 *
UNIM 0.12 * 0 0.99 * 0.37 *
[H.sub.0]:
[[theta] [[theta].sub.H]=
.sub.L] [[theta].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
AABS 1.07 * 0.03 0.63
ACBL 2.94 * 0.01 0.65
AGTL 1.80 * 0.42 * 0.66
AICL 0.67 * 0.01 0.64
ANSS -0.56 * 0.01 0.61
ASKL 3.17 * 0.01 0.55
BWHL 0.41 * 0.02 0.66
CHCC 0.59 * 0.01 0.57
CRTM 0.30 ** 0.01 0.59
CSAP -0.18 0.01 0.56
CULA 0.22 * 0.13 * 0.61
DBYC 1.42 * 0.01 0.68
DHAN 0.61 * 0.02 0.63
DSFL 0.68 * 0.01 0.58
DWTM 2.79 * 0.01 0.62
ENGR 1.66 * 0.01 0.66
FASM 5.94 * 0.02 0.62
FFCJ 0.71 * 0.01 0.64
FFCL 1.69 0.10 * 0.61
GTYR 0.63 ** 0.002 0.59
GULT 0.32 0.22 * 0.61
HAAL 1.17 0.03 0.64
HUBC 2.11 * 0.09 * 0.52
ICI 1.19 * 0.02 0.61
ICPS 1.99 * 0.10 * 0.53
INDU 0.46 0.001 0.57
JDWS 0.99 * 0.11 * 0.51
JPPO 0.65 * 0.02 0.55
KESC 1.04 0.03 0.57
LEVE 1.27 * 0.21 * 0.53
LUCK 1.41 * 0.002 0.61
MCB 1.50 * 0.30 * 0.69
MPLC 1.07 * 0.001 0.64
NATR 1.28 * 0.003 0.67
NESTE 0.54 0.57 * 0.63
PACK 1.76 * 0.01 0.67
PAEL 0.29 0.09 ** 0.65
PAKT 1.13 * 0.021 0.66
PKCL 0.65 * 0.23 * 0.63
PTC 2.09 * 0.59 0.71
SELP 1.09 * 0.01 0.64
SITC 0.16 0.29 * 0.65
SNGP 1.97 0.19 * 0.66
SSGC 1.27 * 0.002 0.69
TSPI 0.95 * 0.76 * 0.62
TSSI -0.16 * 0.01 0.69
UNIM -0.23 * 0.001 0.71
Note: * Indicates significant at 1 percent, ** at 5 percent and
*** is at 10 percent.
Table A6
Fama French Three Factor Model in Bull and Bear Market with
EGARCH Specification Based on Monthly Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[beta] [[beta] [[beta] [[beta] [[beta].sub.H]=
.sub.H] .sub.L] .sub.SMB] .sub.HML] [[beta].sub.L]
AABS 0.65 * 0.17 * 0.29 0.56 0.40 *
ACBL 0.99 * 1.11 * 0.12 * 0.22 * 0.24 *
AGTL 0.87 * 0.39 * 0.36 0.39 0.34 *
AICL 1.86 * 1.32 * 0.30 0.17 0.49 *
ANSS 1.95 * 0.46 * 0.56 0.20 0.32 *
ASKL 1.22 * 0.86 * 0.80 0.59 0.88 *
BWHL 0.53 * 0.48 * 0.10 0.64 0.93 *
CHCC 1.45 * 0.94 * 0.38 0.11 0.12 **
CRTM 1.66 * 0.90 * 0.24 0.80 0.05
CSAP 0.66 * 0.69 * 0.17 0.13 0.003
CULA 0.02 0.40 * 0.3 0.14 0.61 *
DBYC 2.04 * 1.20 * 0.39 0.90 0.25 *
DHAN 0.49 * 0.73 * 0.023 0.033 0.98 *
DSFL 1.50 * 1.40 * 0.004 0.003 0.15 **
DWTM 0 0.02 * 0.041 0.025 0.49 *
ENGRO 0.90 * 0.96 * 0.11 -0.06 * 0.96 *
FASM 1.07 * 0.71 * 0.040 0.036 0.03
FFCJ 0.56 0.18 * 0.21 * 0.34 0.99 *
FFCL 0.71 * 0.80 * 0.001 -0.008 0.67 *
GTYR 0.28 * 0.56 * 0.041 -0.020 0.20 **
GULT -0.03 0.05 0.24 0.41 0.81 *
HAAL 0.63 * 0.49 * 0.28 0.45 0.56 *
HUBC 0.35 0.92 * 0.30 0.61 0.07 **
ICI 0.81 * 1.38 * 0.31 0.25 0.04
ICPS 1.56 * 1.29 * 0.015 -0.030 0.32 *
INDU 0.94 * 0.83 * 0.39 0.43 0.41 *
IDWS 0.68 * 0.06 * 0.36 0.14 0.04
IPPO 1.71 0.002 0.28 0.13 0.001
KESC 1.14 * 1.45 * 0.51 0.46 0.45 *
LEVER 0.49 * 0.51 * 0.11 0.32 0.79 *
LUCK 1.50 * 1.12 * 0.19 0.25 0.18 **
MCB 1.35 * 1.21 * 0.32 0.12 0.62 *
MPLC 1.24 * 1.27 * 0.14 0.26 0.94 *
NATR 1.05 * 0.88 * 0.23 0.34 0.69 *
NESTE 0.37 * 0,21 * 0.25 0.13 0.38 *
PACK 0.61 * 0.60 * 0.26 0.15 0.956 *
PAEL 1.93 * 0.59 * 0.27 0.29 0.003
PAKT 1.25 * 0.43 * 0.17 0.30 0.02
PKCL 0.39 0.90 * 0.10 0.15 0.60 *
PTC 0.82 * 1.30 * 0.32 0.28 0.02
PSO 0.85 * 1.27 * 0.25 0.27 0.01
SELP 1.11 * 0.67 * 0.35 0.51 0.001
SITC 0.83 * 0.63 * 0.10 0.47 0.20 *
SNGP 1.37 * 1.33 * 0.32 0.24 0.68 *
SSGC 1.61 * 1.23 * 0.42 0.15 0.003
TSPI 1.1 0.90 * 0.57 0.25 0.83 *
TSSI 0.46 * 0.40 * 0.31 * 0.27 0.49 *
UNIM 0.74 0.52 0.047 0.033 0.75 *
[[delta] [[gamma] [[mu] [[theta]
[h.sub.0] .sub.i] .sub.i] .sub.i] .sub.H]
AABS -2.83 * 0.33 * 0.51 * 0.28 * -1.42 *
ACBL -6.18 * -0.07 -0.13 -0.31 37.41
AGTL -8.32 * 0.94 * -0.02 -0.76 * 1.84
AICL (-2.34) 0.54 * -0.22 ** 0.52 ** 24.76
ANSS (-5.14) 0.60 * 0.27 * -0.14 71.03
ASKL (-5.53) 0.53 ** -0.07 -0.18 28.7
BWHL -5.79 * 0.04 0.15 -0.40 * -18,34 *
CHCC -0.68 * -0.64 * -0.19 * 0.78 * -19.76 *
CRTM -0.49 0.03 0.12 0.85 -22.49
CSAP -3.96 ** -0.28 ** -0.06 0.03 -11.14
CULA -6.49 * -0.86 -0.25 * -0.15 21.22 *
DBYC -1.16 0.18 0.08 0.74 * -3.35
DHAN -9.08 * 0.54 * 0.37 * -0.79 * 10.76
DSFL -4.27 * 0.27 ** 0.04 0.1 7.75
DWTM -1.36 * 0.36 * -0.09 0.77 * -38.53 *
ENGRO -0.56 * -0.38 * -0.04 0.87 * 13.42 *
FASM -0.11 -0.33 * -0.13 0.91 * -11.54 *
FFCJ -0.53 * 0.25 ** -0.15 * 0.92 * -4.28
FFCL -1.5 -0.01 -0.11 0.74 * 0.4
GTYR -7.21 * 1.11 * -0.13 * -0.56 * -10.22
GULT -3.52 * 0.38 * -0.79 ** 0.33 * 72.29 *
HAAL -0.64 ** 0.30 ** -0.04 0.85 * -27.9 **
HUBC -3.87 * -0.13 -0.03 0.32 81.68 *
ICI -1.01 * -0.07 0.02 0.78 * -36.1 **
ICPS -3.14 * 0.82 * -0.33 * 0.49 * 35.43
INDU -5.60 * -0.06 0.40 * -0.26 (-47.2)
IDWS -7.52 * 0.85 * 0.07 -0.73 2.53
IPPO -2.09 * 0.92 * -0.27 * 0.78 * 63.76 *
KESC -5.05 * 0.34 ** -0.03 0.01 35.86
LEVER -2.55 * 0.52 * -0.39 * 0.61 * -11.45 *
LUCK -5.53 * 0.29 0.06 -0.16 -14.34
MCB -8.36 * 0.26 0.22 ** -0.68 * -3.74
MPLC -4.49 * 0.48 * 0.15 0.04 21.73
NATR -1.44 * -0.22 * -0.1 0.69 * 66.07 *
NESTE -9.56 * 0.801 * -0.12 * -0.77 * -17.57
PACK -8.39 * 0.63 * -0.28 * -0.53 * -10.9
PAEL -3.47 * 0.19 ** -0.29 * 0.1 -9.26
PAKT -0.28 ** -0.34 * 0.09 ** 0.91 * 17.49 *
PKCL -2.63 0.04 -0.01 0.21 12.4
PTC -4.68 * 0.03 -0.13 0.16 4.82
PSO -1.75 0.67 * 0.1 0.81 * 6.07
SELP -1.79 * -0.52 * -0.63 * 0.57 * -65.10 *
SITC 0.06 -0.09 * -0.20 * 0.98 * -12.93 *
SNGP -2.87 * -0.27 * 0.03 0.46 * 66.22 *
SSGC -0.1 -0.21 -0.11 0.95 -8.88
TSPI -1.24 * 0.42 * 0.07 0.69 * 13.11
TSSI -5.79 * 6.28 ** -0.07 -0.65 * -33.5 *
UNIM -0.44 0.10 0.07 0.80 -20.49
[H.sub.0]:
[[theta] [[theta].sub.H]=
.sub.L] [[theta].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
AABS 15.4 * 0.18 * 0.63
ACBL -23.50 * 0.22 0.54
AGTL 13.51 * 0.42 * 0.56
AICL 0.95 0.87 * 0.55
ANSS 10.86 0.54 * 0.63
ASKL 4.24 0.61 * 0.71
BWHL 29.04 * 0.61 * 0.70
CHCC 17.43 * 0.14 ** 0.69
CRTM -14.80 * 0.01 0.62
CSAP 6.9 0.21 ** 0.73
CULA 17.36 * 0.78 * 0.68
DBYC 8.54 0.31 * 0.62
DHAN 18.44 * 0.74 * 0.56
DSFL 17.02 * 0.13 0.67
DWTM -20.77 * 0.01 0.62
ENGRO 17.16 * 0.11 * 0.67
FASM 3.38 *** 0.23 ** 0.64
FFCJ 1.81 0.57 * 0.69
FFCL 13.39 ** 0.33 * 0.62
GTYR -0.77 0.78 * 0.64
GULT 40.33 * 0.10 ** 0.63
HAAL -21.9 ** 0.72 * 0.69
HUBC 57.69 * 0.48 * 0.63
ICI 9.65 *** 0.03 0.63
ICPS 7.67 0.30 * 0.71
INDU 8.18 0.001 0.72
IDWS -20.20 * 0.41 * 0.74
IPPO 30.33 * 0.100 ** 0.79
KESC 36.70 * 0.97 * 0.68
LEVER 16.58 ** 0.001 0.69
LUCK 23.86 * 0.59 * 0.70
MCB -12.01 0.81 * 0.68
MPLC 21.77 * 0.99 * 0.59
NATR 17.48 * 0.003 0.72
NESTE 15.31 * 0.23 * 0.73
PACK 24.46 * 0.34 * 0.69
PAEL -1.34 0.833 * 0.62
PAKT 14.87 * 0.60 * 0.59
PKCL -9.57 0.58 * 0.74
PTC 34.54 * 0.67 * 0.65
PSO 16.14 * 0.70 * 0.59
SELP 32.87 * 0.003 0.71
SITC -0.06 0.99 * 0.56
SNGP 28.90 * 0.45 * 0.67
SSGC 3.6 0.12 ** 0.64
TSPI -3.2 0.62 * 0.63
TSSI -6.88 0.30 * 0.71
UNIM -17.49
Note: * Indicates significant at 1 percent, ** at 5 percent and
*** is at 10 percent.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Eatzaz and Mohammad Ali Qasim (2004) Stock Market Volatility
in Pakistan: An Empirical Analysis. The Middle East Business and
Economic Review 16:2.
Bakaert, G. and G. Wu (1997) Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in
Equity. Review of Financial Studies 13:1, 1-42.
Basu, S. (1977) Investment Performance of Common Stocks in Relation
to their Price Earnings Ratios: A Test of Efficient Market Hypothesis.
Journal of Finance 12:3, 129-56.
Bhaduri, Saumitra N. and Raja Sethu Durai (2006) Asymmetric Beta in
Bull and Bear Market Conditions: Evidence from India. Applied Financial
Economic Letters, 2, 55-59.
Bhardwaj, R. and L. Brooks (1993) Dual Beta as from Bull and Bear
Markets: Revision of Size Effect. Journal of Financial Research 16,
209-283.
Black, Fischer (1993) Beta and Return. Journal of Portfolio
Management 20, 8-18.
Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle and D. Nelson (1994) ARCH Models. In R.
F. Engle and D. L. McFadden (eds.) Handbook of Econometrics 6.
Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle and J. M. Wooldridge (1988) A Capital
Asset Pricing Model with Time Varying Covariance. Journal of Political
Economy 96, 116-131.
Braun, P. A., D. B. Nelson, and A. M. Sunier (1995) Good News, Bad
News, Volatility and Beta. Journal of Finance 50, 1575-1603.
Chart, Lious K. C., Yasushi Hamoa, and Josef Lakonishok (1991)
Fundamentals and Stock Return in Japan. Journal of Finance 46:5,
1739-1789.
Chan, Louis K.C. and Josef Lakonishok (1993) Are Reports of
Beta's Death Premature? Journal of Portfolio Management 19,51-62.
Chang, Y. P., H. Johnson and M. J. Schill (2001) Asset Pricing When
Returns are Non-normal: Fama-French Variables Versus Higher-Order
Systematic Comovement. Gary Anderson Graduate School of Management,
University of California, Riverside. (Working Paper).
Chen, Nai-fa (1982) An Examination of Risk Return Relationship in
Bull and bear Markets Using Time-Varying Security Betas. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 17, 265-286.
Chou, Y. H. and R. F. Engle (1999) Time Varying Betas and
Asymmetric Effect of News. Empirical Analysis of Blue Chip Stocks.(UCSD Working Paper).
Chou, Y. H. and R. F. Engle (1999) Time Varying Betas and
Asymmetric Effect of News. Empirical Analysis of Blue Chip Stocks. UCSD.
(Working Paper).
Clare, A. D., R. Priestley, and S. H. Thomas (1998) Report of
Beta's Death are Premature: Evidence from the UK. Journal of
Banking and Finance 22, 1207-1229.
Daniel, Kent and Sheridan Titman (1997) Evidence on the
Characteristics of Cross-Sectional Variation in the Stock Return.
Journal of Finance 52, 1-33.
Davis, J. (1994)The Cross-section of Realized Stock Return: The
Pre-CompUSA Evidence. Journal of Finance 49, 1579-1593.
Davis, James L. and Anand S. Desai (1998) Stock Return, Beta and
Firm Size: The Case of Bull, Bear and Flat
Markets.info.cba.ksu.edu/desai/beta.pdf.
Elton, Edward, J. Martin, J. Gruber, and Cristopher R. Blake (1995)
Fundamental Economic Variables, expected Return and Bond Fund
Performance. Journal of Finance 50, 1229-1256.
Engle, R. F., D. M. Lillen, and R. P. Robins (1987) Estimating Time
Varying Risk Return in the Term Structure: The ARCH-M Model.
Econometrica 55, 381--407.
Fabozzi, F. J. and J. C. Francis (1977) Stability Tests for Alphas
and Betas Over Bull and Bear Market Conditions. Journal of Finance 32,
1093-1099.
Fabozzi, F. J. and J. C. Francis (1978) Beta as a Random
Coefficient. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 13, 101-115.
Faff, Robert (2001)A Multivariate Test of a Dual-Beta CAPM:
Australian Evidence. The Financial Review 36, 157-174.
Fama, Eugene F. (1965) The Behaviour of Stock Market Prices.
Journal of Business 38, 34-10.
Fama, Eugene F. and James D. MacBeth (1973) Risk, Return and
Equilibrium: Empirical Tests. Journal of Political Economy 81:3,607-36.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1992) The Cross Section of
Expected Return. Journal of Finance 47:2,427-465.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1993) Common Risk Factors in
the Returns of Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33,
3-56.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1995) Size and
Book-to-Market Factors in Earnings and Returns. Journal of Finance 50:1,
131-155.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1996) Multifactor
Explanation of Asset Pricing Anomalies. Journal of Finance 51, 55-87.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1997) Industry and Cost of
Capital Equity, Journal of Financial Economics 42:3, 153-194.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1998) Value versus Growth:
The International Evidence. Journal of Finance 53:6, 1975-1999.
Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (2004) The Capital Asset
Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Economic Perspectives
18:1, 25-46.
Ferson, Wayne E. and Campbell R. Harvey (1999) Economic, Financial
and Fundamental Global Risk In and Out of EMU. Swedish Economic Policy
Review 6, 123-184.
Galagedera, D. A. U. and R. Faff (2003) Modelling the Risk and
Return Relationship Conditional on Market Volatility, Evidence From
Australian Data. Proceedings From Sixtieth Australian Finance and
Banking Conference. University of New South Wales, Sidney, Australia.
Granger, C. W. J. and P. Silvapulle (2002) Capital Asset Pricing
Model, Bear, Usual and Bull Market Conditions and Beta Instability: A
Value-At-Risk Approach. (NBER Working Paper 1062).
Grinold, R. (1993) ls Beta Dead Again? Financial Analysis Journal
49, 28-34.
Grundy, B. and B. Malkiel (1996) Reports of Beta Death have been
Greatly Exaggerated. Journal of Portfolio Management 22, 36-44.
Hamilton, J. D. and G. Lin (1996) Stock Market Volatility and the
Business Cycles. Journal of Applied Economics 11,573-593.
Harris, R. and F. Marston (1994) Value Versus Growth Stocks:
Book-to-Market, Growth and Beta. Financial Analyst Journal 50, 18-24.
Harvey, C. R. (1995) Predictable Risk and Return in Emerging
Markets. The Review of Financial Studies 8, 773-816.
Haugen, Robert R. and Nardin I. Baker (1996) Commonality in the
Determinants of Expected Stock Return. Journal of Financial
Economics' 41, 401-440.
He, J. and L. Ng (1994) Economic Forces, Fundamental Variables and
Equity Returns. Journal of Business 67, 599-639.
Howton, S. and D. Peterson (1998) An Examination of Cross-section
Realised Stock Return Using a Varying Risk Beta Model. Financial Review
33, 199-213.
Huang, H. R. (2000) Tests of Regimes Switching CAPM. Applied
Financial Economics 10, 573-578.
Iqbal, Javed and R. D. Brooks (2007) Alternate Beta Risk Estimation
and Asset Pricing Test in Emerging Market: Case of Pakistan.
Multinational Journal of Finance 17, 75-93.
Ilqbal, Javed, Robert Brooks, and D. U. Galagedera (2008) Testing
Conditional Asset Pricing Model: An Emerging Market Perspective. Monash
University, Australia. (Working Paper 3/08.)
Javid, Attiya Y. and Eatzaz Ahmad (2008) Conditional Capital Asset
Pricing Model: Evidence from Pakistani Listed Companies. (PIDE Working
49).
Kim, Moon K. and Kenton Zumwalt (1979)An Analysis of Risk in Bull
and Bear Markets. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
14:5, l 015-1025.
Kothari, S. P., Jay Shanken and Richard G. Sloan (1995) Another
Look at the Cross Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance
50: l, 185-224.
Levy, R. A. (1974) Beta Coefficient as Predictor of Returns.
Financial Analyst Journal 30, 61-69.
Lintner, J. (1965) The Valuation of Risk Assets and Selection of
Risky Investments in Stock Portfolio and Capital Budgets. Review of
Economics and Statistics 47:1, 13-47.
MacKinlay, A. Craig (1995) Multifactor Models Do Not Explain
Deviations from the CAPM. Journal of Financial Economics 38, 3-28.
Maheu, J. and T. McCurdy (2000) Identifying Bull and Bear Markets
in Stock Returns. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics 18,
100-112.
McQueen, G. and S. Thorley (1994) Bubbles, Stock Returns and
Duration Dependence. Journal of Finance and Quantities Analysis 29,
379-401.
McQueen, Grant and Steven Thorley (1993) Asymmetric Business Cycle
Turning Points. Journal of Monetary Economics 31:3, 341-362.
Nelson, D. B. (1991) Conditional Hetroscedasticity in Asset
Pricing: A New Approach. Econometrica 59:2, 347-370.
Pagan, A. and K. Sossounov (2000) A Simple Framework for Analysing
Bull and Bear Markets. Australian National University.(Working Paper).
Pettengill, G., S. Sundaram and I. Muthar (1995) The Conditional
Relation between Beta and Return, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 30, l 01-116.
Scholes, M. and J. Williams (1977) Estimating Beta from
Nonsynchronous Data. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 309-327.
Schwert, William G. (1989) Why Does the Stock Price Volatility
Change Over Time? Journal of Finance 44, 1115-1153.
Shanken, Jay (1992) On the Estimation of Beta Pricing Models.
Review of Financial Studies 5, 1-34.
Sharpe, W. F. 0964) Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market
Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk. Journal of Finance 19:3,425-442.
State Bank of Pakistan (Various Issues) Monthly Statistical
Bulletin. Karachi: State Bank of Pakistan.
Woodward, G. and H. Anderson (200 l) Does Beta React to market
conditions? Estimates of Bull and Bear Betas using a Non-Linear Market
Model with an Endogenous Threshold Parameters. Monash Econometric and
Business Statistics. Monash University, Australia. (Working Paper
9/2003.)
(1) There are several arguments on the firm specific attributes
that are used to form Fama and French factors. Haugen and Baker (1996),
Daniel and Titman (1997) are of the view that such variables may be used
to find assets that are systematically mispriced by the market. Others
argue that these measures are proxies for exposure to underlying
economic risk factors that are rationally priced in the market [Fama and
French (1993, 1995 and 1996)] Another view is that the observed
predictive relation are largely the result of data snooping and various
biases in the data [MacKinley (1995), Black (1993), Kothari, Shanken,
and Sloan (1995)].
(2)Harvay (1995) for emerging markets, Iqbal and Brooks (2007) and
Javid and Ahmad (2008) for Pakistani market.
(3) Pagan and Sussounov (2000) argue that the macroeconomics is
able to interpret some of the observed characteristics of data which are
based on some economic behaviour. For example it may be that the
volatility seen in equity prices stem from volatility in the making of
monetary policy and hence might disappear as monetary policy regime
changes.
(4) They argue that possible explanation of persistence of bull is
that investors become more optimistic about the future and hence wish to
invest more in the stock market. This positive feedback means that the
probability of switching out of the bull market decreases with duration.
(5) There is positive relationship between beta and return in up
market and a negative one in the down market, so the beta-return
relationship is not shown up in aggregate. It is possible that the
positive beta-return relationship in bull markets offsets the negative
beta return relationship m the bear market. Therefore unless the
positive beta relationship m bull market is stronger than negative
beta-return in bear market, the overall long run relationship between
return and beta would not be positive.
(6) The ratios involving stock prices have information about
expected return missed by the betas. This is because stock's price
depends not only on expected cash flows but also on the expected return
that discount on expected cash flow back to the present. Thus a high
expected return implies a high discount rate and a low price. These
ratios thus are prime candidates to expose shortcomings of CAPM [Basu
(1977)]. The earningprice ratio, debt-equity, and book-to-market ratios
play their role in explaining expected return.
(7) SMB (Small minus Big) represent the risk factor diverge of rate
return which involve with size effect, SMB will different in each month
among average return rate of small sample group (S/L, S/M and S/H) with
the average return rate of 3 large groups (B/L, B/M, B/H).
SMB= Small minus Big = Average Returns of Small Size minus Big Size
= 1/3 (S/H + S/M + S/L) - 1/3 (B/H + B/M + B/L)
HML (High minus Low) represent the risk factor of return rate that
involve with ratio book to market value (BE/ME) effect. HML each month
has differ between average return rate of two portfolios that has BE/ME
high (S/H and B/H) with average return rate of two portfolios has BE/ME
low (S/L and B/L)
HML= High Minus Low = Average Returns of High BE/ME minus Low BE/ME
ratio = 1/2 (S/H + B/H) - 1/2 (S/L + B/L)
(8) The asymmetry between positive and negative shocks can be
explained as follows. An unexpected decline in prices causes volatility,
thereby increasing the expected volatility in future. Since the increase
in the volatility has to be compensated by an increase in risk premium,
the expected rate of return must rise. Therefore the unexpected shock
result in decline in the current stock price, and hence further
reinforce the initial negative shock mad increase the level of current
and future volatility. In case of positive price shock the initial
impact is the same however, the decrease in stock price tend to offset
the impact of positive shock. Therefore the initial increase in level of
current and future volatility is partially offset. At firm level the
asymmetry between the effects of good and bad news on the level of
volatility can be explained through the leverage effect [Bakaert and Wu
(1997)].
(9) Appendix Table A1 provides the list of companies included in
the sample.
(10) [R.sub.t] = ln [P'.sub.t] -ln [P'.sub.t-i], where
[R.sub.t,] is stock return and [p'.sub.t], the stock price is
adjusted for capital changes that is dividend, bonus shares and rights
issued.
(11) In financial economics it is common practice to test the
models for different sub periods to check the robustness of the results.
(12) For the empirical analysis of individual stocks GMM is used
for time series estimation technique due to non-synchronous returns.
Instrument variable is considered as a better choice [Scholes and
William (1977)]. The cross-section regression has problem because the
returns are correlated and heteroskedastic, therefore GLS is used in
cross-section regression.
(13) Shanken (1992) suggests multiplying [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is mean of market return and [[sigma].sub.m]
is standard deviation of market return.
(14) Davis and Desai (1998) report the difference in average return
between the lowest beta portfolio and highest beta portfolio is 11.28
percent, and beta-return is monotonic and positive. They find that
difference in average return between the lowest beta portfolio and
highest beta portfolio is -14.03 percent and beta return relationship is
again monotonic, but negative. Grundy and Malkiel (1996) find similar
results in their study for bear markets and argue that beta can still be
used as measure of down-market risk.
(15) Davis and Desai (1998) findings show that when they combine
both bull and bear market, the beta return relationship is slightly
positive and their result shows that the difference between the lowest
beta portfolio and the highest beta portfolio is 2.23 percent and the
relationship is positive and monotonic.
Attiya Y. Javid <attiyajavid@pide.org.pk> is Professor at
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Eatzaz Ahmad
<eatzaz@qau.edu.pk> is Professor, Department of Economics,
Quaid-iAzarn University, Islamabad.
Authors' Note: The authors wish to thank two anonymous
referees for their valuable comments. They are grateful to Dr Muhammad
Ali Bhatti for providing assistance in compiling data. Any remaining
errors and omissions are the authors' sole responsibility.
Table 1
Average Risk Premium for Unconditional CAPM with High /Low Market
Daily Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda] [[lambda] [[lambda].sub.H]=
.sub.H] .sub.L] [[lambda].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 0.11 0.04 0.31 * 0.31
(0.32) (1.84)
1996-98 -0.12 0.10 0.47 * 0.47
(-0.67) (0.24)
1999-01 -0.01 0.02 ** 0.77 ** 0.77
(-0.49) (2-06)
2002-04 -0.03 * 0.03 ** 0.26 * 0.36
(-2.43) (1.84)
2005-07 -0.11 * 0.11 0.65 *** 0.65
(-2.75) (0.92)
1993-00 -0.01 0.01** 0.53 ** 0.53
(-0.97) (1.89)
2001-07 -0.01 ** 0.04 0.50 * 0.50
(-1.87) (1.11)
1993-07 -0.12 ** 0.04 ** 0.57 * 0.57
(-1.87) (1.83)
Monthly Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda] [[lambda] [[lambda].sub.H]=
.sub.H] .sub.L] [[lambda].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 0.01 0.03 ** 0.32 * 0.32
(-2.10) (1.82)
1996-98 0.02 ** 0.01 ** 0.21 * 0.38
(2.24) (0.37)
1999-01 -0.01 0.01 0.17 ** 0.36
(0.94) (0.30)
2002-04 -0.01 ** 0.01 ** 0.48 * 0.38
(-1.86) (1.94)
2005-07 -0.01 0.01 0.10 *** 0.39
(-3.04) (0.87)
1993-00 -0.01 0.01 0.20 ** 0.38
(-0.57) (0.78)
2001-07 -0.11 ** 0.05 ** 0.87 * 0.40
(-1.88) (1.87)
1993-07 -0.12 ** 0.11 ** 0.89 * 0.41
(-1.87) (1.89)
Note: The t-values reported in the parenthesis is error adjusted
Shanken t-values. * Shows significant at 1 percent,
** is significant at 5 percent and *** is significant
at 10 percent level.
Table 2
Average Risk Premium for Unconditional Fama French Model with
High /Low Market
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda] [[lambda] [[lambda] [[lambda].sub.H]=
.sub.o] .sub.H] .sub.L] [[lambda].sub.L]
1993-95 -0.33 -0.11 0.13 ** 0.27 *
(-0.88) (-1.13) (1.89)
1996-98 -0.12 -0.15 0.21 ** 0.43 *
(-0.67) (-0.67) (1.88)
1999-01 -0.01 -0.12 0.12 ** 0.65 **
(-0.49) (-0.88) (1-97)
2002-04 -0.11 -0.11 * 0.12 ** 0.31 *
(-1.43) (-2.01) (1.89)
2005-07 0.03 -0.22 * 0.13 ** 0.57 ***
(-2.75) (-2.01) (1.95)
1993-00 -0.01 -0.21 ** 0.17 ** 0.50 **
(-0.97) (-1.97) (1.89)
2001-07 -0.01 ** -0.22 ** 0.14 ** 0.46 *
(-0.68) (-1.85) (1.93)
1993-07 -0.02 ** -0.12 * 0.13 * 0.51 *
(-0.98) (-2.08) (2.06)
[[lambda] [[lambda]
.sub.SMB] .sub.HMLL] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 0.34 0.15 ** 0.38
(0.88) (0.46)
1996-98 0.31 ** 0.16 ** 0.39
(2.24) (0.37)
1999-01 0.42 0.15 0.40
(0.94) (0.30)
2002-04 0.31 ** 0.23 ** 0.38
(1.86) (1.94)
2005-07 0.27 0.19 0.39
(-3.04) (0.87)
1993-00 0.31 0.15 0.39
(-0.57) (0.78)
2001-07 0.29 ** 0.17 ** 0.41
(1.88) (1.85)
1993-07 0.30 ** 0.21 ** 0.42
(1.87) (1.89)
Note: The t-values reported in the parenthesis is error
adjusted Shanken t-values. * Shows significant at 1
percent, ** is significant at 5 percent and
*** is significant at 10 percent level.
Table 3
Average Risk Premium for Conditional CAPM with High/Low Market
Daily Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda].sub.H]=
[[[lambda].H] [[[lambda].L] [[lambda].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 0.11 0.04 0.31 * 0.31
(0.32) (1.84)
1996-98 -0.12 0.10 0.47 * 0.47
(-0.67) (0.24)
1999-01 -0.01 0.02 ** 0.77 ** 0.77
(-0.49) (1-96)
2002-04 -0.03 0.03 ** 0.26 * 0.36
(-2.43) (1.84)
2005-07 -0.14 * 0.12 0.65 *** 0.48
(-2.75) (0.92)
1993-00 -0.14 * 0.11 0.12 ** 0.49
(-2.01) (0.34)
2001-07 -0.13 ** 0.13 *** 0.14 ** 0.50
(-2.84) (1.74)
1993-07 -0.15 ** 0.14 *** 0.13 * 0.53
(-2.82) (1.76)
Monthly Data
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda].sub.H]=
[[[lambda].H] [[[lambda].0L] [[lambda].sub.L] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 -0.01 0.03 ** 0.32 * 0.39
(-2.10) (1.82)
1996-98 -0.02 ** 0.01 ** 0.21 * 0.38
(-2.24) (0.37)
1999-01 -0.13 * 0.14 0.80 ** 0.39
(-2.57) (0.30)
2002-04 -0.01 ** 0.01 ** 0.12 ** 0.40
(-1.86) (1.94)
2005-07 -0.21 0.14 0.07 *** 0.40
(-3.04) (0.87)
1993-00 -0.12 0.13 0.20 ** 0.41
(-0.57) (0.78)
2001-07 -0.14 ** 0.12 ** 0.76 * 0.41
(-1.83) (1.93)
1993-07 -0.13 ** 0.14 ** 0.89 * 0.42
(-1.94) (1.93)
Note: The t-values reported in the parenthesis is error adjusted
Shanken t-values. The * shows significant at 1 percent,
** is significant at 5 percent and *** is significant at
10 percent level.
Table 4
Average Risk Premium for Conditional Fama French
Model with High/Low Market
[[lambda].0] [[lambda].H] [[lambda].L]
1993-95 -0.33 -0.17 0.15 *
(-0.88) (-1.32) (2.01)
1996-98 -0.12 -0.24 0.19 *
(-0.67) (-1.67) (2.24)
1999-01 0.02 -0.23 * 0.22 ***
(0.92) (-2.25) (1.98)
2002-04 -0.03 -0.27 * 0.15 **
(-2.43) (-2.43) (1.97)
2005-07 0.03 -0.24 * 0.21
(-2.75) (-2.75) (0.92)
1993-00 -0.01 -0.18 0.14 **
(-0.97) (-1.03) (1.89)
2001-07 -0.01 ** -0.12 ** 0.15
(-0.68) (-1.85) (1.83)
1993-07 -0.01 ** -0.21 ** 0.17 **
(-0.98) (-1.98) (1.95)
[H.sub.0]:
[[lambda].sub.H]= [[LAMBDA] [[LAMBDA]
[[lambda].sub.L] .sub.SMB .sub.HMLL] [R.sup.2]
1993-95 0.27 * 0.67 ** 0.53 ** 0.41
(1.98) (1.90)
1996-98 0.33 * 0.31 ** 0.42 ** 0.40
(1.88) (1.92)
1999-01 0.25 ** 0.42 0.15 * 0.41
(0.94) (2.30)
2002-04 0.29 * 0.65 ** 0.52 ** 0.40
(1.96) (2.24)
2005-07 0.52 *** 0.40 * 0.70 0.43
(3.04) (0.87)
1993-00 0.47 ** 0.94 * 0.71 ** 0.44
(2.42) (1.98)
2001-07 0.43 * 0.53 ** 0.80 ** 0.44
(1.88) (1.85)
1993-07 0.41 * 0.73 * 0.84 ** 0.45
(2.07) (2.09)
Note: The t-values reported in the parenthesis is error
adjusted Shanken t-values. The * shows significant at 1
percent, ** is significant at 5 percent and
*** is significant at 10 percent level.