The contemporaneous correlation of structural shocks and inflation-output variability in Pakistan.
Nasir, Muhammad ; Malik, Wasim Shahid
Monetary policy has changed in a number of ways in the last two
decades. Along with other characteristics, modern monetary policy is
forward-looking and today central banks, to maintain credibility,
respond contemporaneously to structural shocks that might make inflation
deviate from the target in future. This study aims at investigating this
aspect of monetary policy for Pakistan. Using the modified version of
Structural Vector Autoregression (SVAR) developed by Enders and Hum (2007), the authors have found a weak policy response to supply side
shocks as the correlation coefficient between demand and supply shocks
is only 0.041. Moreover, the results show that the demand shocks have no
significant contribution in output variability. On the other hand, both
demand and supply shocks, along with foreign supply shocks,
significantly contribute to inflation variability.
JEL classification: E31, E42, E52, E58
Keywords: Monetary Policy, Contemporaneous Correlation, Pakistan,
Structural Shocks, Vector Autoregression
1. INTRODUCTION
In the last two decades monetary policy has changed in a number of
ways. It all started with the adoption of inflation targeting as
monetary policy by the Reserve Bank of New Zealand (RBNZ) in 1989. After
recognition that inflation targeting was a better option to control
inflation, academicians and researchers started working on theoretical
modelling of the framework [for early contributions, see for instance,
Svensson (1997, 1999); Bernanke and Mishkin (1997) among others]. (1)
Among other things a modern monetary policy would announce an
explicit inflation target and make its achievement its prime objective,
ensure transparency of policy decisions and implementation, make the
monetary authority credible, the central bankers accountable and keep
policy decisions forward-looking. This last characteristic makes central
banks to respond contemporaneously to structural shocks that are
expected to deviate inflation from the target in future. An)'
contemporary news that is relevant to inflation is reflected in the
inflation forecast, which in turn calls for changes in the operational
target or policy instrument. Doing so makes demand and supply shocks
contemporaneously correlated. A supply shock, which may result in the
deviation of inflation from the target, calls for policy response that
in turn affects the aggregate demand. This issue is of particular
importance for decomposition of structural innovations into demand and
supply shocks. More details on the issue are given in Blanchard and Quah
(1989) and Enders and Hurn (2007).
Work on this aspect of monetary policy issues relating to Pakistan
is limited. The authors may be right in thinking their study to be the
first such attempt to estimate the contemporaneous response of demand to
supply shocks and to find the contribution of structural shocks in
output and inflation variability. The prime objective of this study,
therefore, is to investigate the presence of contemporaneous correlation
between demand and supply shocks in Pakistan. For this purpose the
methodology of Enders and Hum (2007) has been used which is a
modification of the Blanchard and Quah (BQ) method. The second objective
is to use the identified structural shocks, which otherwise are
unobserved, to estimate the contribution of demand and supply shocks in
output and inflation variability with the help of impulse response functions (IRFs) and forecast-error variance decomposition.
The rest of the study proceeds as follows: Section 2 discusses the
theoretical model whereas econometric methodology used in the study is
explained in Section 3. The fourth section deals with data and the
construction of variables. The results and discussion are given in
Section 5, and Section 6 concludes the study identifying some policy
implications.
2. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
In a forward-looking monetary policy, inflation forecast is used as
an intermediate target. Consequently, any shock which affects inflation
forecast calls for contemporaneous change in the monetary policy
instrument. The resultant changes in aggregate demand induced by this
simultaneous response make demand and supply shocks contemporaneously
correlated. Accordingly, we first develop a theoretical model that shows
how the monetary policy instrument responds to contemporaneous shocks of
inflation and economic activity.2 Consider the following AS-AD model:
[[pi].sub.t] = [alpha][y.sup.e.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t] ... (2.1)
[y.sub.t] = -[beta][r.sup.e.sub.t] + [u.sub.t] ... (2.2)
Equation (2.1) represents expectations-augmented-phillips curve,
where n, is inflation Rate. (3) Equation (2.2) describes aggregate
demand relationship where output gap, y,, negatively depends on expected
real interest rate, [r.sup.e]. (4) Both u, and [v.sub.t] are
independently and identically distributed and contemporaneously
uncorrelated to demand and supply shocks. After simple mathematical
manipulation the above equations take the following form. (5)
[[pi].sub.t] = [[gamma].sub.1][[pi].sub.t-1] +
[[gamma].sub.2][y.sub.t-1] + [[omega].sub.t] ... (2.3)
[y.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[[lambda].sub.2][r.sub.t][[eta].sub.t] ... (2.4)
The coefficients [[gamma].sub.2] and [[lambda].sub.2] are assumed
to be positive; where as [[lambda].sub.2] is non-negative and less than
1 and [[gamma].sub.1] may be less than or equal to 1. In case the
monetary policy is forward-looking, the objective of the central bank in
period t is to choose an arrangement of current and future course of
action for policy rates that minimises the expected sum of discounted
squared future deviations of inflation from the target [Svensson
(1997)], is referred for more details] Moreover, the choice of a policy
rate in period t by the central bank is conditional upon the information
available in that period. The period loss function is, therefore, given
as
L([[pi].sub.t] = 1/2 [([[pi].sub.t] - [pi]*).sup.2] ... (2.5)
Taking Equation (2.3) one period forward and then making use of
Equations (2.3) and (2.4) would result in the following equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.6)
where
[c.sub.1] = [[gamma].sup.2.sub.1][c.sub.2] = [[gamma].sub.2]
([[gamma].sub.1] + [[lambda].sub.1]),[c.sub.3] = [[gamma].sub.2]
[[lambda].sub.2]
In this case, the interest rate in period t will only affect the
inflation rate in period t+l, and onwards, and the interest rate in
period t+1 will only affect the inflation rate in period I+2 and
onwards, and so on. Hence, the solution to the optimisation problem can
be obtained by assigning the policy rate in period t to hit, on an
expected basis, the inflation target for period t+1. The same is
possible for the future periods. Thus, the central bank can find the
optimal policy rate in period t as the solution to the simple
period-by-period problem:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.7)
where [delta] is the discount factor whose value lies between 0 and
1. The first-order condition for the minimisation of Equation (2.7) with
respect to [i.sub.t] gives the following result:
[[pi].sub.t+1/t] = [pi]* ... (2.8)
where [[pi].sub.t+1/t] denotes [E.sub.t] [[pi].sub.t+1/t].
According to Equation (2.8), the policy rate in period t should be such
that the forecast of the one-period forward inflation rate, conditional
upon information available in period t, equals the inflation target.
Consequently, we can write the loss function as:
[L.sup.i][[pi].sub.t+1/t] = 1/2 [[pi].sub.t+1/t] - [pi]* ... (2.9)
The expectations of Equation (2.6) illustrate that the one-period
inflation forecast is affected by both the previous and the current
state of the economy as is evident from Equation (2.10) below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.10)
Assuming [pi]* = 0 and equating the terms on the right hand side of
Equations (2.8) and (2.10) would result in optimal reaction function of
the central bank,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2.11)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Equation (2.11) is like the Taylor (1993) type rule. From this
equation it is clear that the demand side variable, [r.sub.t] is
contemporaneously correlated with the supply side shock,
[[omega].sub.t]. This explains why the methodology of Enders and Hum
(2007) has been used to identify structural shocks, allowing for
contemporaneous response of aggregate demand to aggregate supply shocks.
Moreover, Equation (2.11) states that this contemporaneous response is
possible only if monetary policy is forward-looking. In case monetary
policy minimises the loss function described in Equation (2.5), rather
than that given in Equation (2.9)--when the policy is not
forward-looking--the contemporaneous response of aggregate demand to
supply shock will be zero.
3. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY
Econometrics got new life from Sims (1980), in which he introduced
the Vector Autoregression (VAR) model. Sims responded to "Lucas
Critique" given in Lucas (1976) by treating all variables in the
model as endogenous. The VAR in standard form is a reduced form methodology which could be estimated by Ordinary Least Squares. This,
however, gave birth to the "identification problem", which
calls for imposing restrictions on some of the structural parameters so
that identification could be achieved. One response came in the form of
Cholesky decomposition which provided an additional equation for the
identification of the structural models [Enders (2004)].
However, the VAR analysis was criticised by many economists arguing
that these models could only be used for forecasting purpose and not for
policy analysis [Sargent (1979, 1984); Learner (I 985)]. In response to
this criticism, the Structural Vector Autoregression (SVAR) approach was
developed by Sims (1986), Bernanke (1986) and Blanchard and Watson
(1986). The SVAR approach allows for imposing restrictions on the basis
of economic theory. Nevertheless, the SVAR developed by the above
mentioned authors imposed only short-run restrictions on the structural
parameters for identification purpose. An extension to the SVAR of Sims
(1986) and others were made by Shapiro and Watson (1988) and Blanchard
and Quah (1989) by imposing long-run restrictions on the structural
parameters. Especially, the methodology developed by Blanchard and Quah
(1989), henceforth B-Q, got tremendous popularity among the economists
because the assumptions used by this methodology for the exact
identification of structural shocks were innocuous. This methodology
assumes that the structural shocks are orthogonal; these shocks are
normalised to have unit variance; and one structural shock has no long
run effect on one of the variables. In an AD-AS model, the first
assumption would mean that the aggregate demand and aggregate supply
shocks are uncorrelated, while the third assumption would imply that the
aggregate demand shocks have no effect on output in the long run.
However, the assumptions of B-Q also faced criticism by both
economists and econometricians. For example, the New Keynesian
economists argue that monetary shocks need not be neutral [Mankiw and
Romer (1991)]. On the other hand, Waggoner and Zha (2003) and Hamilton,
et al. (2004) gave information about the important consequences for
statistical inference of different normalisations in a structural VAR.
Similarly, Cover, et al. (2006) argues that there are sound economic
reasons for allowing a contemporaneous correlation between the aggregate
demand and aggregate supply shocks. Specifically, it points to the
intertemporal optimising models and the New Keynesians models in which
aggregate supply may respond positively to a positive aggregate demand
shock. Hence, Cover, et al. (2006) allowed for the contemporaneous
correlation between the structural shocks and this correlation was found
to be 0.576 for the US. Enders and Hurn (2007) then extended the
alternative methodology developed in Cover, et al. (2006) for a small
open economy and allowed for the contemporaneous correlation between the
structural shocks for the reason that the economy was following an
inflation targeting policy. The correlation between the structural
shocks was found to be 0.736.
In the following lines we discuss the econometric methodology used
in the study. We discuss both the B-Q methodology, proposed by Blanchard
and Quah (1989), and the alternative methodology developed by Enders and
Hurn (2007) for a small open economy, as both the methodologies are used
in the study.
3.1. The Blanehard-Quah Methodology
Suppose the real foreign output, the real domestic output, and the
domestic inflation rate are represented by [[??].sub.t], [y.sub.t] and
[[pi].sub.t], respectively. Then a VAR model for a small open economy,
as in Enders and Hum (2007), can be written as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.1)
It is obvious from the structure of the above equation that the
foreign output evolves independently of domestic variables for the
reason that the domestic country is assumed to be a small open economy.
Nonetheless, the same small-country assumption requires the domestic
variables to be dependant on the current and lagged values of foreign
output.
The regression residuals, [e.sub.1t], [e.sub.2t] and [e.sub.3t] are
assumed to be linked to each other through three different structural
shocks, namely, a foreign productivity shock, [[epsilon].sub.1t], a
domestic supply shock, [[epsilon].sub.2t], and a domestic demand shock,
[[epsilon].sub.3t]. One of the important tasks is the identification of
the three structural shocks, [[epsilon].sub.1t], [[epsilon].sub.2t], and
[[epsilon].sub.3t], from the VAR residuals, since these structural
shocks are not observable. Suppose the unobservable structural shocks
and the observable VAR residuals are linked by the following
relationship:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.2)
So there are fifteen unknowns in this set-up that need to be
identified. These unknowns include nine elements, [h.sub.ij], of the
matrix H, and three variances [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] along with the three covariances [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] of the variance-covariance matrix of the
structural shocks. The variance-covariance matrix of the VAR residuals
is given by:
[[SIGMA].sub.e] = H [SIGMA].sub.s]H' (3.3)
Hence, six of the fifteen restrictions, required for the exact
identification, are provided by the distinct elements of the
variance-covariance matrix of the VAR residuals. The standard
Blanchard-Quah methodology assumes that all the variances are normalised
to unity ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]) and all
covariances are equal to zero ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII]). Moreover, the domestic shocks do not affect the large
country, [h.sub.] = [h.sub.13] = 0, and finally and most importantly,
the demand shocks have no effect on domestic output in the long run:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.4)
Thus, with all these fifteen restrictions, the identification is
achieved in the B-Q methodology. However, Waggoner and Zha (2003) and
Hamilton, et al. (2004) have warned that normalisation can have effects
on statistical inference in a structural VAR. The main objection,
nonetheless, is raised by Cover, et al. (2006) and Enders and Hum (2007)
about the assumed orthogonality of the structural shocks in BQ
methodology. They argue that, in the presence of a normal demand curve,
a negative supply shock will reduce output and increase inflation.
However, if the country is following the inflation targeting strategy,
then the monetary authorities will contemporaneously raise the policy
rate to shift the demand curve inward in order to keep inflation on
target. The reverse will be done in case of a positive supply shock.
This implies that the correlation between the demand and supply shocks
may not necessarily be zero. The orthogonality assumption of B-Q
methodology does not let demand to respond to supply shocks and hence in
this methodology the correlation is forcibly set equal to zero.
3.2. The Alternative Methodology
Enders and Hurn (2007) start with the following simple AD-AS model:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.5)
In this model, [E.sub.t-1] [y.sub.t] and [E.sub.t-1] [[pi].sub.t],
are the expected domestic output and inflation in period t conditional
upon the information available at the end of period t-1. The
superscripts s and d represent supply and demand, respectively. It is
obvious that the first equation is the Lucas supply curve and the second
equation represents aggregate demand relationship.
This AD-AS model is consistent with a VAR if agents form their
expectations based on it. Taking one period lag of Equation (3.1) and
then taking the conditional expectations will result in [E.sub.t-1]
[y.sub.t] and [E.sub.t-1] [[pi].sub.t]. The parameters of the
macroeconomic model enter into the following matrix H, placing
restrictions on the relationships between the regression residuals and
the structural shocks:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.6)
Here the six elements of the estimated variance-covariance matrix
of VAR residuals can be used for the identification of three variances
and three covariances of structural innovations along with [h.sub.11],
[theta], [rho]. For the identification of the whole system, three more
restrictions include [h.sub.11] = I, [[sigma].sub.[epsilon]1[epsilon]2]
= 0, and the long-run neutrality of demand shock. This decomposition
differs from the standard BQ decomposition in three ways. First, the
assumption of normalisation of all structural shocks to unity is not
imposed. Second, no restriction has been imposed on the contemporaneous
correlation between structural shocks. It is allowed to be determined
independently within the model. Third, the small country assumption
outlines that domestic shock has no effect on global economy.
4. DATA AND CONSTRUCTION OF VARIABLES
This study uses quarterly data over the period 1991:4 to 2010:2 for
Pakistan's economy. (6) The constant price GDP is used to represent
domestic real output. For this purpose, we need to have the series of
quarterly real GDP for Pakistan. Kemal and Arby (2004) have constructed
such series for Pakistan for the period 1975-2004, whereas we use data
up to 2010:2. Nonetheless, the absence of trends and the negligible
variance in the already identified shares for the respective quarters in
different years justify the use of average of these quarterly shares for
the next few years to obtain the values of quarterly real GDP. Data on
GDP is then seasonally adjusted using XI2 method. Furthermore, the
domestic inflation rate is calculated using the data on CPI.
We have not used United States' GDP to represent foreign
output. Due to its large size of the economy and being the major trading
partner of many countries, the United States is expected to affect the
economic environment of its partners. That is why most studies take the
real GDP of the US as proxy for the entire external sector, [for
instance in Enders and Hum (2007)]. However, this may not be a true
representative of an external shock. Subsequently, the US GDP may not be
a suitable proxy of foreign output for Pakistan as it is not the only
trade partner which can have significant effects on Pakistan's
economy. Although the US has major share in the export composition of
Pakistan, Saudi Arabia has a major import share in the import portfolio.
In order to avoid any ambiguity, therefore, we have constructed an index
of the foreign output where major trading partners of Pakistan are
represented. These countries include the US, UK, Japan, Germany, Saudi
Arabia, Kuwait and Malaysia. The index is constructed by taking the
weighted average of its partners' GDP where the weights are
Pakistan's trade shares with each country. (7) The sources of data
for construction of the index of foreign output include International
Financial Statistics (IFS) and various issues of Economic Survey of
Pakistan.
5. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
5.1. Unit Root and Cointegration Tests
The application of Vector of Autoregression (VAR) requires absence
of unit roots in variables. Moreover the variables should not be
cointegrated. Therefore, in order to check whether the variables are
stationary or integrated to some order, the Augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF) test has been used. The results of the ADF test are reported in
Table 1 below.
The results of the ADF test in the above table indicate that all
variables are non-stationary at conventional levels of significance.
However, all these variables are stationary at first difference and
hence are integrated of order 1. Nonetheless, the application of the VAR
model necessitates the absence of any cointegrating relationship among
the set of non-stationary variables. Thus it is desirable to check the
number of cointegrating vectors among these variables. For this purpose,
we make use of Johansen's approach to investigate the relationship
among the three variables. Table 2 portrays the results.
Results in Table 2 reveal that the null hypothesis of the absence
of cointegrating relationship cannot be rejected at the conventional
significance levels. Both trace statistics and maximum eigenvalue statistics confirm the absence of any cointegration vector. The absence
of cointegrating relationship necessitates the application of VAR in the
first difference.
5.2. Estimation Results
5.2.1. Results of the Standard B-Q Decomposition
The results of the standard Blanchard-Quah decomposition bring
forth the determinants of output and inflation in Pakistan) It is
evident from the forecast-error variance decomposition reported in Table
3 that demand shocks do not explain any significant variation in
domestic output at any forecasting horizon. After three periods, the
explained variation in output due to demand shocks remains at 0.12
percent for the rest of the horizon. On the other hand, domestic supply
shocks have a dominant role in output variation. Almost 88 percent of
variation in output is attributed to domestic supply shocks. However,
the foreign GDP shocks explain little (around 11.7 percent) output
variability. Results in Table 3 also demonstrate the determinants of
inflation variability. Interestingly, all the three shocks contribute to
inflation variability. For the first two quarters, for instance, both
domestic supply shocks and foreign GDP shocks explain 23 percent and 38
percent variations respectively. However, beyond this two-step horizon,
the explained variation by the two shocks changes to 36 percent and 33
percent respectively. Likewise, the demand shocks initially explain 38
percent variation in inflation which then slides down to 30.5 percent
after the two-period horizon.
The results of Table 3 highlight some important issues that call
for attention. First, the foreign GDP shocks explain smaller variation
in output and relatively greater variation in inflation. So the effects
of the shocks transmit more to price level than to output in Pakistan.
This is true for most developing countries which confront the problem of
capacity utilisation due to various reasons such as unskilled workforce,
energy crises, weak infrastructure etc. Furthermore, this pattern is
more likely if the basket of imported goods contain more finished
products than intermediate products. The second issue is concerned with
the effects of the shock on different forecast horizons. As is evident
from the above table, after the two-step horizon, the inflation
variability, explained by foreign output shocks, reduces whereas that by
the domestic supply shocks increases. One possible interpretation is
that the effects of foreign shocks translate into domestic supply
shocks. For example, an adverse oil price shock is initially a foreign
supply shock for Pakistan. However, after some time the effects of
increased oil price transmit to domestic prices which ultimately result
in backward shift of the aggregate supply curve.
The impulse response functions for the standard B-Q model are
illustrated in Figure 1. One can easily observe the similarity of
results shown both by the variance decomposition and the impulse
response functions. Panel a of Figure 1 demonstrates that one unit shock
in foreign output shifts the domestic output up by 0.35 units in the
first quarter, 0.09 standard deviation in the second quarter, and -0.08
standard deviations in the third quarter. Afterwards, the successive
values of domestic GDP steadily converge to zero. The reason for the
positive effect of foreign GDP shock on domestic output is more than
obvious. A favourable output shock in foreign countries will raise their
national incomes. Since a country's exports depend on her trading
partners' income, there will be an increase in demand for Pakistani
exports, thereby boosting the domestic output. Panel b confirms that the
domestic supply shocks have significant effect on output. The effect,
however, is short-lived as it converges to zero in the second quarter.
Demand shocks do not affect output as is evident from Panel c. The
possible reason could be the assumptions in the standard Blanchard-Quah
model that call for long run neutrality of demand shocks and the zero
correlation between aggregate demand and aggregate supply shocks.
The results in panel d illustrate that foreign output shocks have
positive effects on domestic inflation as well. As explained earlier,
the effect of foreign shocks, whether positive or negative, are absorbed
more by the price level than by domestic output. Panel e suggests that a
favourable domestic supply shock will reduce inflation in the first
quarter. Though it goes up in the second quarter, possibly due to the
cobweb phenomenon, it converges to zero in the fourth quarter. Panel f
indicates that demand shocks positively affect inflation. A one unit
demand shock increases inflation by 0.97 units in the first quarter.
However, the successive values of the effect on inflation, thereafter,
converge to zero. This means that in the B-Q methodology, approximately
the whole effect of the demand shock is absorbed by inflation only.
Cover, et al. (2006) and Enders and Hurn (2007) argue that these results
may be the consequence of the assumptions of standard B-Q model. We now
turn to the results obtained by using Enders and Hum (2007) methodology.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
5.2.2. Results of the Alternative Decomposition
Interestingly, the results obtained by using the alternative model
are not much different from those of the standard Blanchard-Quah model.
This is obvious from both Table 4 and Figure 2. Both the forecast-error
variance decomposition and the impulse response functions obtained using
the identified structural shocks demonstrate almost the same pattern as
was found for B-Q decomposition. Table 4 results indicate that demand
shocks explain only 0.16 percent variation in output beyond a two-step
horizon. This suggests that demand shocks do not have significant effect
on output in Pakistan. On the other hand, output variability is
explained more (88 percent) by the domestic supply shock. Foreign output
shocks explain only 11.86 percent of the variation in output.
As reported in Table 4, all the three types of structural shocks
contribute in explaining variation in inflation even in this
decomposition. However, the variation explained by domestic supply
shocks increased to 43 percent in the current decomposition compared to
36 percent obtained using the BQ method. Nevertheless, the contribution
of demand shocks and foreign output shocks to inflation variability
declines from 30.5 percent and 33 percent to 27 percent and 30 percent
respectively. Hence, the results obtained from alternative decomposition
do not significantly differ from those obtained through B-Q
decomposition. However, the findings of this work are in significant
contrast to both Enders and Hum (2007) and Covers, et al. (2006) who
found that the effect of demand shocks was more on output and less on
inflation.
The results of impulse response functions in Figure 2 tell a
similar story. These response functions are obtained using structural
shocks identified by alternative decomposition. Results in panel a show
that a one unit foreign GDP shock raises the output by 0.35 units in the
first quarter, and after the third quarter, the successive values of the
shock converge to zero. It is clear from panel b that a favourable
domestic supply shock has immediate effect on output, and the effect
starts declining to zero after the second quarter. Yet again, demand
shocks fail to show any significant impact on output as is evident from
Panel c. The impact of foreign output shocks, domestic supply shocks,
and demand shocks on inflation are portrayed in Panels d, e and f
respectively. These response functions confirm and validate the results
shown by the forecast-error variance decomposition.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
5.3. Contemporaneous Correlation of Demand and Supply Shocks
The main objective of this study is to establish whether or not the
State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) responds contemporaneously to supply side
shocks. For this purpose, the contemporaneous correlation was allowed
between the two structural shocks. Using the alternative decomposition
method mentioned above, the findings suggest that there is correlation
of only 0.041 between the two shocks which is negligible. Consequently,
it may be concluded that the SBP has not been responding
contemporaneously to supply side shocks. (9) This result points to the
fact that the policy has not been forward-looking in the sample period.
Another possible reason for this result may be the absence of a proper
forecasting model with the SBP, at least until recently.
5.4. Estimation Results for Sub-sample Period
It is usually believed that the appointment of Ishrat Hussain as
Governor of the SBP was the beginning of an era when the central bank
started enjoying relatively greater independence from the government
since the institution of financial sector reforms. This provides the
grounds for the use of a sub-sample period for this analysis. Using data
over the period 1999:1 to 2010:2, both the B-Q and alternative
methodologies have been used for the identification of structural shocks
as well as for the detection of any contemporaneous correlation among
these shocks. The results of forecast-error variance decomposition using
both methodologies are reported in Table 5 and Table 6. It is clear that
there is no significant difference in outcomes of both methodologies.
The results in Table 6 show that the foreign output shock, domestic
supply shock and domestic demand shock explain, respectively, 31
percent, 69 percent and 0.12 percent of variation in output. Similarly,
it is found that 52 percent of inflation variability is explained by
foreign output shock, 31.5 percent by domestic supply shock, and 16.6
percent by domestic demand shock. The results for the B-Q model are the
same with a slight difference of approximately 1 percent.
However, the results of this sub-sample are much different in terms
of explanation of variation in output and inflation from those of the
full sample. For instance, with the alternative decomposition,
variability in output and inflation explained by foreign GDP shock
increase from 12 percent and 30 percent to 31 percent and 52 percent
respectively. This indicates the increased exposure of domestic economy
to foreign shocks in the sub sample period. Likewise, the role of
domestic supply shock in both output and inflation variability reduces
to 69 percent and 31.5 percent respectively. Nonetheless, it still
remains the major source of variation in output. Interestingly, the role
of demand shock in inflation variability reduces from 29 percent to 16.6
percent. This is an important result for the SBP to consider when it
goes for tight monetary policy to reduce inflation in the economy. The
lesser share of demand shocks in explaining inflation variability
suggests that the SBP should be careful while controlling inflation,
through demand management policy, as it may be caused more by supply
shocks. Yet again, demand does not play any significant role in output
variability for the sub-sample period. (10) Finally, the findings of
this study give no indication of a forward-looking policy even in this
era of central bank independence. In fact, the contemporaneous
correlation coefficient between demand and supply shocks reduces to
0.012, which is less than the value obtained for the entire period of
the analysis. This shows the presence of enough fiscal pressure for the
SBP to be not able to target an explicit inflation rate.
6. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The objectives of this study include the identification of
structural shocks, examining the relative contributions of these
structural shocks in output and inflation variability, and the
investigation of whether or not the SBP responds contemporaneously to
supply side shocks. For this purpose, use has been made of the
Structural Vector Autoregression (SVAR) by considering both
Blanchard-Quah methodology and an alternative methodology initially
developed by Cover, et al. (2006) and later extended by Enders and Hurn
(2007). Some important findings are given in the following lines.
The first and the main finding of the study is that the SBP has not
been pursuing a forward-looking policy. The contemporaneous correlation
between the aggregate demand and aggregate supply in Pakistan is only
0.041, which suggests a negligible contemporaneous policy response to
supply-side shocks. The second outcome is concerned with the role of
structural shocks in explaining variation in both inflation and output.
Interestingly, but not surprisingly, the results of both methodologies
do not differ significantly. The domestic supply shock is considered to
be the major factor contributing in output variability, followed by
foreign shock. Domestic demand shock, on the other hand, does not play a
significant role in output variation. Moreover, the domestic supply
shock is the central cause of variation in inflation with foreign supply
shock at the second and domestic demand shock at the third place.
The third finding concerns the impact of foreign supply shock on
domestic output and inflation. A positive foreign supply shock affects
domestic inflation more than the domestic output. This may be due to the
fact that whenever due to increase in foreign output, the income of
foreigners and, consequently, the demand for Pakistani exports rises,
the economy does not respond positively or in a suitable manner. Instead
of increasing domestic output, the effect of the shock is allowed to
transmit more to the price level. The weak response of output may be the
result of an inefficient real sector because &unskilled labour
force, weak infrastructure, and energy constraints etc.
The results of this study bring forth important policy
implications. Firstly, and most importantly, the central bank should be
careful in controlling inflation through tight monetary policy. An
increase in interest rate in order to reduce demand may not reduce
inflation to the desired extent as demand contributes less to inflation.
Rather, the cost channel of monetary policy may come into play. In this
context, the continuous increase in the policy rate by the SBP in recent
times can be said to be undesirable. Moreover, a tight monetary policy
may not be efficient in the absence of coordination between demand
management policies. Secondly, the policy-makers should avoid exploiting
inflation-output trade-off, since the role of demand in output growth is
negligible.
In this study the researchers have modelled monetary policy on the
contemporaneous response of demand to supply shock. Therefore, for
future research, it will be more appropriate if interest rate is
directly included in the VAR as a monetary policy instrument. This is
important as monetary policy is not the only factor that makes changes
in demand. Subsequently, by including interest rate in the model, one
can differentiate among changes in demand brought about by monetary
policy and those by the other factors.
APPENDIX
Let the expectation augmented Phillips Curve is given by the
following equation:
[[pi].sub.l] = [alpha][y.sup.e.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t] ... (I)
Also we know that
[DELTA] [y.sup.e.sub.t-1] = a([y.sub.t-1] - [y.sup.e.sub.t-2]
or
[y.sup.e.sub.t-1] = a[y.sub.t-1] - (1 - a) [y.sup.e.sub.t-2] ...
(II)
Now taking Equation (1) one period backward and solving for
[[y.sup.e].sub.t-2] gives the following equation:
[y.sup.e.sub.t-2] (III) = (1/[alpha]) [[pi].sub.t-1] - (1/[alpha])
[v.sub.t-1] ... (III)
Substituting Equation (III) in Equation (II) would result in
following:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (IV)
Substituting equation (IV) in Equation (I) would give the following
result:
[[pi].sub.t]= [[gamma].sub.t] [y].sub.t-1] + [[gamma].sub.2]
[[pi].sub.t-1] + [[omega].sub.t] (V)
Where
[[gamma].sub.1] = a[alpha], [[gamma].sub.2] = (1 - a),
[[omega].sub.t] = [v.sub.t] - (1 - a) [v.sub.t-1]
Similarly the aggregate demand relationship is given by following
equation:
[y.sub.t] = [beta][r.sup.e.sub.t] + [u.sub.t] ... (VI)
Since
[DELTA][r.sup.e.sub.t] = b([r.sub.t] - [r.sup.e.sub.t-1])
Or
[r.sup.e.sub.t] = [br.sub.l] + (1 - b)[r.sup.e.sub.t-1] ... (VII)
Now taking Equation (VI) one period backward and solving for
[r.sup.e.sub.t-1] gives the following result:
[r.sup.e.sub.t-1] = (1/beta) [y.sub.t-1] + (1/[beta])[u.sub.t-1]
... (VIII)
Substituting the Equation (VIII) in Equation (VII) and then putting
the resultant value of [r.sup.e.sub.t] in Equation (VI) gives the
following equation:
[y.sub.t] = [[lambda].sub.1][y.sub.t-1] -
[[lambda].sub.2][[gamma].sub.t] + [[eta].sub.t] ... (IX)
Where
[[lambda].sub.1]= (1-b), [[lambda].sub.2] = [beta]b, [[eta].sub.t]
= (1-b/[beta])[u.sub.t-1] + [u.sub.t]
Equations (V) and (IX) are the ones representing Equations (2.3)
and (2.4) in the text.
REFERENCES
Ball, L. and N. Sheridan (2003) Does Inflation Targeting Matter? In
B. S. Bernanke and M. Woodford (eds.) The Inflation Targeting Debate.
University of Chicago Press.
Bernanke, B. S. (1986) Alternative Explanations of the Money-income
Correlation. Carnegie-rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, pp.
49-100.
Bernanke, B. S. and F. Mishkin (1997) Inflation Targeting: A New
Framework for Monetary Policy. Journal of Economic Perspective 11,
97-116.
Blanchard, O. J. and M. W. Watson (1986) Are Business Cycles All
Alike? The American Business Cycle. University of Chicago Press.
Blanchard, O. J. and D. Quah (1989) The Dynamic Effects of
Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances. American Economic Review 79,
655-473.
Calvo, G. A. and E. Mendoza (2000) Capital-market Crises and
Economic Collapse in Emerging Markets: An Informational-frictions
Approach. Duke University and University of Maryland, January.
(Mimeographed).
Calvo, G. A. (2001) Capital Markets and the Exchange Rate: With
Special Reference to the Dollarisation Debate in Latin America. Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking 33, 312-334.
Cover, J. P., W. Enders, and C. J. Hueng (2006) Using the Aggregate
Demand-aggregate Supply Model to Identify Structural Demand-side and
Supply-side Shocks: Results Using a Bivariate VAR. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 38, 777-790.
Enders, W. (2004)Applied Econometric Time Series. John Wiley &
Sons, Inc.
Enders, W. and S. Hum (2007) Identifying Aggregate Demand and
Supply Shocks in a Small Open Economy. Oxford Economic Papers 59,
411-429.
Hamilton, J. D., D. Waggoner, and T. Zha (2004) Normalisation in
Econometrics. Econometric Review 26, 221-252.
Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical and Hypothesis Testing of
Cointegration Vector. Journal of Economics Dynamics and Control 12,
231-254.
Kemal, A. R. and F. Arby (2004) Quarterisation of Annual GDP of
Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. (PIDE Statistical Papers Series No. 5).
Learner, E. E. (1985)Vector Autoregression for Causal Inference? In
Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer (ed.) Understanding Monetary Regimes.
Carnegie-rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 22, 255-304.
Lucas, R. E. (1976) Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.
Carnegie-rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1, 19-46.
Malik, W. S. and A. M. Ahmed (2007) Taylor Rule and the
Macroeconomic Performance in Pakistan. Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad. (PIDE Working Paper Series No. 34).
Mankiw, N. G. and D. Romer (1991) New Keynesian Economics.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
McCallum, B. T. (1997) Inflation Targeting in Canada, New Zealand,
Sweden, the United Kingdom, and in General. In I. Kuroda (ed.) Towards
More Effective Monetary Policy. London: MacMillan.
Sargent, T. J. (1979) Estimating Vector Autoregression Using
Methods Not Based on Explicit Economic Theories. Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis Quarterly Review 3, 8-15.
Sargent, T. J. (1984) Autoregression, Expectations, and Advice.
American Economic Review 76, 408-415.
Shapiro, M. D. and M. W. Watson (1988) Sources of Business Cycle
Fluctuations. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 111-148.
Sims, C. (1980) Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica 48, 1-48.
Sims, C. (1986) Are Forecasting Models Usable for Policy Analysis.
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 2-16.
Svensson, L. E. O. (1997) Inflation Forecast Targeting:
Implementing and Monitoring Inflation Targets. European Economic Review
41, 1111-1146.
Svensson, L. E. O. (1999) Inflation Targeting as a Monetary Policy
Rule. Presented at the Sveriges Riksbank-IIES Conference on Monetary
Policy Rules, Stockholm. (IIES Seminar Paper No. 646).
Taylor, J. B. (1993) Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.
Carnegie-rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, 195-214.
Waggoner, D. and T. Zha (2003) Likelihood Preserving Normalisation
in Multiple Equation Models. Journal of Econometrics 114, 329-347.
(1) For critics on the subject, [see Calvo and Mendoza (2000);
Calvo (2001) and Ball and Sheridan (2003), among others].
(2) For this type of model, see for instance, Svensson (1997).
(3) [y.sub.t-1.sup.e] is the expected value of aggregate
expenditures for period t, expected in period t-1.
(4) [r.sup.e.sub.t] denotes real interest rate for period t+1,
expected in period t.
(5) The detailed mathematical derivations of Equations (2.3) and
(2.4) are given the Appendix.
(6) The reason for not extending this period beyond 1991 is that
the SBP was not independent in setting the policy instrument before
financial sectors reforms initiated in 1989.
(7) A problem that is confronted is the unavailability of both Real
GDP in volume and GDP Index for some countries such as Saudi Arabia and
Kuwait on quarterly basis. So we have taken the Index of Crude Petroleum
Production as proxy of GDP Index for these two countries.
(8) The estimation results are obtained using RATS software.
(9) The finding that the SBP has not been following inflation
targeting policy is consistent with Malik and Ahmed (2007) who find,
while estimating Taylor rule, the coefficient of inflation is less than
one failing to satisfy the requirement of Taylor principle.
(10) Like the forecast-error variance decomposition, there is not
any significant difference in the impulse response functions of the two
decompositions for the selected sub-sample. These results of the IRFs
can be obtained on request from the authors.
Muhammad Nasir <nasirawan84@yaheo.com> is Research Economist
at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Wasim
Shahid Malik <wsmalick@gmail.com> is Assistant Professor,
Department of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Table 1
Results of the Unit Root Test Statistics
Variables Level First Difference Conclusion
Foreign Output -1.190 -3.610 ** 1(1)
Domestic Output -1.464 -12.230 *** 1(1)
Inflation -1.490 -6.395 *** 1(1)
Note: The regressions include a constant. The ** and *** show
rejection of null hypothesis at 5 percent and 1 percent levels
of significance respectively.
Table 2
Johansen Test for the Cointegrating Relationship
Trace 5% Critical Max. Eigen 5% Critical
No. of CE(s) Statistics Value Statistics Value
None 15.131 29.797 8.833 21.131
At most 1 6.297 15.494 5.560 14.264
At most 2 0.737 3.841 0.737 3.841
Note: The Johansen cointegration test is conducted using two lags which
are chosen using AIC. The test used the specification which allows
for an intercept term but there is trend neither in cointegrating
equation nor in VAR.
Table 3
Forecast-error Variance Decomposition Using B-Q Decomposition
Percentage Variation in Percentage Variation in
Domestic Output due to Domestic Inflation due to
Horizon FGDPS DSS DDS FGDPS DSS DDS
1 11.437 88.484 0.079 38.114 23.454 38.340
2 10.894 89.022 0.085 38.226 23.396 38.377
3 11.350 88.530 0.119 33.003 36.072 30.925
4 11.655 88.224 0.121 33.083 36.296 30.621
5 11.683 88.196 0.121 33.137 36.261 30.602
6 11.724 88.156 0.121 33.218 36.219 30.563
7 11.729 88.150 0.121 33.215 36.225 30.559
8 11.733 88.146 0.121 33.225 36.220 30.555
9 11.734 88.145 0.121 33.225 36.220 30.554
10 11.735 88.145 0.121 33.226 36.220 30.554
Note: FGDPS= Foreign GDP Shock, DSS= Domestic Supply Shock,
DDS= Domestic Demand Shock.
Table 4
Forecast-error Variance Decomposition Using Alternative Decomposition
Percentage Variation in Percentage Variation in
Domestic Output due to Domestic Inflation due to
Horizon FGDPS DSS DDS FGDPS DSS DDS
1 11.564 88.311 0.126 33.370 33.568 33.062
2 10.019 88.849 0.132 33.479 33.416 33.105
3 11.474 88.361 0.165 29.666 42.948 27.387
4 11.782 88.052 0.167 29.774 43.074 27.152
5 11.810 88.023 0.166 29.826 43.036 27.138
6 11.851 87.982 0.166 29.903 42.991 27.107
7 11.856 87.977 0.166 29.901 42.995 27.104
8 11.861 87.973 0.166 29.910 42.990 27.100
9 11.861 87.972 0.166 29.910 42.990 27.100
10 11.862 87.972 0.166 29.911 42.989 27.099
Table 5
Forecast-error Variance Decomposition Using B-Q Decomposition
Percentage Variation in Percentage Variation in
Domestic Output due to Domestic Inflation due to
Horizon FGDPS DSS DDS FGDPS DSS DDS
1 33.417 66.518 0.064 58.446 19.294 22.261
2 30.670 69.254 0.085 59.123 18.909 21.968
3 30.653 69.242 0.106 53.712 28.994 17.294
4 30.607 69.283 0.110 53.027 29.892 17.081
5 30.673 69.217 0.110 52.992 29.943 17.065
6 30.758 69.132 0.110 52.972 29.988 17.041
7 30.770 69.119 0.110 52.979 29.988 17.033
8 30.783 69.107 0.110 52.994 29.979 17.027
9 30.784 69.105 0.110 52.997 29.977 17.026
10 30.785 69.105 0.110 52.999 29.976 17.025
Table 6
Forecast-error Variance Decomposition Using Alternative Decomposition
Percentage Variation in Percentage Variation in
Domestic Output due to Domestic Inflation due to
Horizon FGDPS DSS DDS FGDPS DSS DDS
1 33.510 66.416 0.074 56.816 21.640 21.544
2 30.767 69.137 0.096 57.535 21.180 21.285
3 30.751 69.132 0.117 52.584 30.558 16.858
4 30.707 69.171 0.122 51.935 31.407 16.658
5 30.772 69.106 0.122 51.903 31.453 16.643
6 30.857 69.021 0.122 51.886 31.494 16.620
7 30.870 69.008 0.122 51.894 31.494 16.613
8 30.883 68.996 0.122 51.908 31.484 16.608
9 30.884 68.994 0.122 51.911 31.482 16.607
10 30.885 68.993 0.122 51.913 31.481 16.606